Macro-economic health-focussed assessment of GHG emission reduction strategies in the UK DRAFT PAPER- PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR CITE Henning Tarp Jensen* Marcus Keogh-Brown Richard D Smith Zaid Chalabi Mike Davies Alan Dangour Phil Edwards Tara Garnett Moshe Givoni Ulla Griffiths Ian Hamilton Ian Roberts Paul Wilkinson James Woodcock Andy Haines, *Corresponding author: Senior Researcher Henning Tarp Jensen, Institute of Food and Resource Economics, University of Copenhagen, Rolighedsvej 25, DK-1958 Frederiksberg, Denmark. Email: htj@foi.ku.dk. Acknowledgements Funded by the UK Department of Health Policy Research Programme. 1 1 Introduction High and increasing greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions have remained an urgent priority on the international political agenda since the first Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC 1990).1 The most recent IPCC report found a high likelihood of a range of serious impacts at global mean temperature increases above 2°C (IPCC 2007). Climate model predictions suggest that this scenario is very plausible since future temperature rises will, most likely, fall within the interval of 2.0-4.5°C over the course of this century (Roe and Baker 2007). Hence, there is a need for immediate global action. The need for global action is further underlined by recent evidence suggesting that the current Copenhagen Accord commitments are insufficient to maintain a medium (50-66%) chance of achieving the 2°C target (den Elzen, Hof and Roelfsema 2011), and that delayed action until 2030 will be virtually impossible to compensate for in later years (den Elzen et al. 2010). In response to the call for action, a vast inter-disciplinary literature has emerged on a range of economically-related aspects of climate change, including the costs of mitigation and adaptation, and the use of policy instruments such as carbon pricing and accelerated technological innovation (Stern 2007). The UK has committed itself through the adoption of global treaties (the Kyoto protocol) and unilateral legislation (the 2008 Climate Change Act), to reduce GHG emissions by 80% in 2050 relative to 1990 levels (DECC 2008). Preliminary estimates suggest that UK emissions have been reduced by around 25% in 2010 (DECC 2011). This is better than the formal 23% reduction target for the first carbon budget period 2008-2012, but remains well below future targets (and some emissions have been ‘exported’ as a result of purchasing products from emerging economies such as China). A number of new UK mitigation initiatives are, therefore, needed in order to achieve the intermediate 50% reduction target in 2030 and the final 80% reduction target in 2050. Even this target may be conservative in the light of current trends in emissions. Policies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions may also result in substantial ancillary (co-) benefits to health, for example as a result of reduced fine particulate air pollution from cuts in coal combustion, or from increased physical activity as a result of increased active travel (walking and cycling) and reduced car use in urban centres. The current study uses a single-country Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model to assess UK GHG mitigation initiatives, which can help to achieve the 50% UK reduction target in 2030. The study focuses on initiatives with important health benefits, and concentrates on three sectors: urban transport, home insulation, and food and agriculture. Previous macroeconomic CGE model studies have focussed on health co-benefits related to reduced air pollution (Garbaccio, Ho and Jorgenson 2000; Li 2002; Dessus and O’Connor 2003; Bosello, Roson and Tol 2006; Ciscar et al 2010). The current study follows Haines et al. (2009) and Jack and Kinney (2010) and applies an extended health co-benefits concept. The extended methodology is important for capturing the full economic effects and to address the long-standing critique that macroeconomic cost-benefit analyses may overestimate the net cost of GHG interventions (van den Bergh 2010). Four previously established UK household-level GHG scenarios with important health benefits are analysed: (1) a healthy diet scenario (Friel et al. 2009), (2) a household insulation and improved 1 Although a more accurate term would be “greenhouse pollutants”, we will employ the widely used term “greenhouse gases” to refer to all anthropogenic climate-active atmospheric species including both gases and aerosols. 2 ventilation control scenario (Wilkinson et al. 2009), (3) a cleaner cars scenario (Woodcock et al. 2009), and (4) an active travel scenario (Woodcock et al. 2009). Standard and breakeven methodologies are applied to assess the cost-effectiveness of the four scenarios. Previous macroeconomic assessment studies have been criticized for assuming a trade-off between global warming initiatives and economic activity (van den Bergh 2010). In contrast, the current study seeks to assess potentially cost-effective ways of achieving a given reduction in GHG emissions – in this case the 2030 UK target reduction. The rest of this article is structured as follows: Section 2 provides background information and reviews the existing macroeconomic literature on GHG emission reductions and health co-benefits; Section 3 present our emission reduction scenarios and discusses the measurement of health effects; Section 4 presents the macroeconomic methodology for our cost-effectiveness analyses; Section 5 presents the main results; and section 6 presents conclusions. 2 Background We seek to analyse cost-effective ways of achieving a given reduction in UK GHG emissions. The analytical starting point is that scientific evidence attaches wide probability distributions to global temperature increases and inter alia to possible changes in human living conditions. Since excessive temperature increases and associated changes in precipitation and (extreme) weather patterns are likely to have catastrophic consequences for many areas around the globe, this study acknowledges that it is imperative to limit GHG emissions to levels which are consistent with the IPCC upper bound of a long term 2°C temperature increase (within reasonable levels of confidence). The key issue then becomes how to achieve the given emission targets in a cost-effective way.2 Due to the urgency and multi-facetted nature of global warming, a vast inter-disciplinary literature has emerged over the last couple of decades (Stern 2007). In view of the global nature of the problem, macroeconomic impact studies have typically employed national or global Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) simulation models. Global models have the proper dimensions for measuring, for example, the impact of international emissions trading schemes (Klepper and Peterson 2005; Nijkamp, Wang and Kremers 2005; Hagem et al. 2006; Böhringer and Helm 2008) and multilateral agreements such as the Copenhagen Accord (den Elzen, Hof, Beltran et al. 2011; Lim 2011; Peterson, Schleich and Duscha 2011). In contrast, detailed single-country models are better equipped to assess the national impact of domestic emission reduction strategies (Telli, Voyvoda and Yeldan 2008; Böhringer and Rutherford 2010) and specific interventions such as the introduction of abatement technologies (Dellink et al. 2004; Grepperud and Rasmussen 2004; Fisher-Vanden and Wing 2008). Previous CGE model studies of health benefits have focused narrowly on health co-benefits from air pollution. The multi-country studies have focussed on global temperature-related health effects of specific global warming scenarios (Bosello, Roson and Tol 2006; Ciscar et al 2010), while the singlecountry studies have typically focussed on health effects of changes in local air pollution due to demand-constraining carbon tax interventions (Garbaccio, Ho and Jorgenson 2000; Li 2002; Dessus 2 Previous macroeconomic studies have been criticized for assessing the economic value of undertaking GHGrelated interventions (van den Bergh 2010). The main line of criticism seems to be that the imperative of avoiding extreme climate change cannot be traded off against potential welfare losses from required investments in mitigation measures. Hence, it has been argued that the key issue is “whether consumption growth can compensate for environmental degradation caused by global warming” (Neumayer 1999). 3 and O’Connor 2003). This study extends the existing single-country CGE model methodology by employing an extended health effects concept, and by analysing a set of interventions which includes both demand-constraining and efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements. Two of the existing single-country studies characterized health outcomes in terms of disease symptoms and evaluated them based on willingness-to-pay (WTP) estimates (Garbaccio, Ho and Jorgenson 2000; Dessus and O’Connor 2003). A different approach was adopted by Li (2002), who measured the impact of morbidity and mortality effects on (1) labour supplies and (2) health-system costs, and imposed these shocks on the CGE model and evaluated their overall impact based on an equivalent variation (EV) welfare measure. The current study relies on a similar but more wellfounded public health methodology. Basic health effects have been measured on the basis of WHOs Comparative Risk Assessment (CRA) approach (Woodcock et al. 2009; Friel et al. 2009; Wilkinson et al. 2009). However, while the existing literature focused on health co-benefits related to reduced emissions of local air pollutants, the current study applies an extended health effects concept encompassing other sectors (Haines et al. 2009; Jack and Kinney 2010). The extended methodology includes health externalities associated with (1) direct effects of GHG interventions (for example reduced fine particulate air pollution as a result of switching to low emission vehicles), and 2) indirect effects of GHG interventions, (for example increased physical activity associated with a switch in transport mode from motorized vehicles to walking and cycling).3 The current study also extends the existing CGE model literature on GHG-related health effects, by explicitly including both demand-constraining and efficiency-enhancing mitigation interventions. Demand-constraining interventions lower GHG emissions through reduced demand (and production) of pollution-intensive goods and services. They are typically implemented through the use of tax instruments (or outright regulatory constraints). Efficiency-enhancing interventions are characterised by reducing GHG emissions through the introduction of new efficiency-enhancing technologies or by increased efficiency of existing technologies. Below, we analyse interventions of both types of efficiency-enhancing interventions including e.g. the introduction of cleaner cars (emission-saving technology), and a reduction in urban congestion (which increases the flow of urban traffic, and thereby lowers emissions from the existing car pool). We demonstrate below how the costeffectiveness of specific GHG policies depends critically on whether they contain (1) efficiencyenhancing mitigation elements, and (2) other positive (health) externalities. This is particularly important in order to capture the full economic effects and provide proper measures of the costeffectiveness of UK GHG intervention strategies. 3 Data base and simulation model4 3.1 Macroeconomic CGE model The economy-wide dynamically-recursive Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model, used in this study, is based on the ‘IFPRI standard model’ (Löfgren, Lee Harris and Robinson 2002). This is a well-known and widely applied comparative static, single country, open economy, multi-sector CGE model, which has recently been used in health and trade-related applications by some of the authors 3 Our focus is on measuring other health co-benefits. Hence, health co-benefits from reduced local air pollution is only taken into account in one scenario, below (cleaner cars). 4 For details, see Annex A. 4 (Smith, Keogh-Brown et al. 2009; Lock, Smith et al. 2010, Jensen, Robinson and Tarp 2010). The model accounts for different types of agents including producers/enterprises, private households, the government sector and the foreign sector. The CGE model for the UK economy was calibrated on the basis of a 2004 social accounting matrix (SAM) dataset taken from the GTAP database v7 (Narayanan and Walmsley 2008). The model is a neo-classical model based on the fundamental principles of profit-maximization among producers and utility maximization among households. The standard model specification was expanded to account for household production of transport services and heating services. Furthermore, a set of factor updating equations was added to turn the static model into a dynamically-recursive UK CGE model. A standard neo-classical model closure is used in all simulations, implying that flexible prices are clearing all goods and factor markets and that a flexible real exchange rate is clearing the current account of the balance of payments. Furthermore, all simulations are based on a revenue-neutral government budget closure (endogenous household tax rate) which ensures that changes in individual government revenue components (e.g. due to the introduction of a fat tax or road pricing tax) will not affect the relative size of the government sector in the economy. The dynamically-recursive UK CGE model had to be run forward from 2004 (the year of the data set) to 2010 (the pre-starting year of the simulations). To ensure that the model mirrored the 2010 UK economy, we targeted key macroeconomic aggregates (nominal and real GDP) over the period 20042010. Furthermore, we created a reasonable 2011-2030 counterfactual growth path by targeting 19902010 historical UK growth rates for nominal GDP (5.1% p.a.) and real GDP (2.1% p.a.). This implies that the GDP deflator (our numeraire price index) grows at historical UK growth rates (2.9% p.a.) as well, along our counterfactual growth path. 3.2 Assessment methodology Two types of assessment methodologies are applied to evaluate the cost-effectiveness of policy scenarios: (1) a standard methodology, and (2) a breakeven methodology. The standard methodology is based on standard factor accumulation and therefore compares standard policy simulations to the counterfactual growth path. In contrast, the breakeven methodology calculates the maximum (timeconstant) non-productive investment costs, which are consistent with an unchanged NPV value of GDP over the 20 year simulation horizon (2011-2030). More specifically, non-productive investment replaces productive investment until NPV of GDP is similar to the counterfactual growth path, and the value of the potential non-productive investment is equal to the breakeven investment cost. The breakeven methodology is targeted at policy scenarios with an investment element and, in particular, towards scenarios where there is significant uncertainty about the size of the future investment intervention. The breakeven methodology is useful, since it provides an accurate measure of the non-productive investment financing which can be extracted from the UK economy (on a recurring basis) without reducing future income generation. The breakeven measure is superior to e.g. the NPV of GDP measure from standard simulations, which does not account for the ripple effects of reduced productive investment/capital accumulation on future income generation. Due to crowdingout of productive investment and capital accumulation, a £1 increase in current non-productive investment (and crowding-out of £1 of productive investment) reduces future income generation. Hence, increased investment financing today will reduce potential investment financing tomorrow. This mechanism is automatically taken into account in the breakeven methodology. When the purpose 5 is to evaluate a scenario where investment costs are uncertain, the breakeven methodology may therefore provide a tool for generating key information on breakeven investment costs.5 3.3 Health effects For each disease, detailed age- and gender-specific calculations of disease burdens, Years of healthy Life lost due to Disability (YLD) and Years of Life Lost (YLL) were used to calculate implied changes to UK healthcare costs, UK labour supplies, and UK social security transfers. Gender and age-specific health effects (YLD/YLL) were determined by the WHO Comparative Risk Assessment (CRA) approach (see Woodcock et al. 2009; Friel et al. 2009; Wilkinson et al. 2009), and distributed over the 20 year horizon (see Smith et al. 2012). The resulting dynamic patterns of health effects were used to derive (1) changes in the effective labour force and (2) changes in social security transfers including reduced labour market benefits and increased pension payments. Furthermore, changes in healthcare costs were measured on the basis of changes in disease burden for various health outcomes and injuries. (See Smith et al. 2012 for details on the methodology, and Table 1, below, for scenariospecific health effects imposed on the CGE model.) 4 Policy scenarios6 The four policy scenarios are presented in the Box below (see Annex B for details). These scenarios focus on household-level interventions, and include one food and agriculture scenario (‘healthy diet’), two transport sector scenarios (‘active travel’ and ‘cleaner cars’), and one household energy scenario (‘home insulation’). The agriculture and energy sector scenarios were designed to achieve UK-wide 50% sector-specific emission reduction targets in 2030, while the two transport scenarios were designed to achieve a combined urban 60% emission reduction target for England and Wales. It has previously been argued that the scenarios may bring substantial benefits for both climate protection and health outcomes (Haines et al. 2009). The four scenarios include one demand-constraining mitigation scenario (healthy diet), two efficiency-enhancing mitigation scenarios (home insulation and cleaner cars), and one scenario with both demand-constraining and efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements (active travel). Efficiencyenhancing elements include increased efficiency in household production of private transportation (active travel and cleaner cars) and heating services (home insulation), while demand-constraining mitigation elements include a ‘fat tax’ and a ‘road pricing tax’ to reduce household demand for meat and dairy products (healthy diet) and private transportation (active travel). 5 The breakeven methodology required the specification of a time-indexed dynamically recursive CGE model, with endogenous calculation of the NPV of future GDP (2011-2030). This provides an intertemporal constraint on the model under the breakeven methodology, and allows for calculating the maximum (time-constant) level of non-productive investment costs which can be financed without reducing NPV of future GDP. 6 For details, see Annex B. 6 Box. Policy Scenarios Description Healthy Diet Reduced meat and dairy consumption will improve UK health + lower UK livestock production and GHG emissions from ruminants. Emission Targets The healthy diet scenario was designed to achieve a 50% emissions reduction target for UK agricultural activities in 2030. The scenario builds on efficiency-improvements which are in the pipeline (not modelled). Policy Targets (Demandconstraining) 30% reduction in household consumption of meat and dairy. Policy Targets (Efficiencyimprovements) Economic Instruments (Tax) Economic Instruments (Other) Assessment Methodology lllnesses/Injuries included in health impact assessment Fat Tax Active Travel A switch from car travel to active travel (walking and biking) in urban areas will improve UK health + lower UK fossil fuel-based transport and associated GHG emissions. The active travel scenario was designed to achieve a 38% reduction in GHG emissions from the transport sector (with the cleaner cars scenario, this was designed to achieve a combined 60% emissions reduction target in urban areas in England and Wales in 2030.) 41% reduction in urban fossil-fuel based private transport. Implemented as 15.6% UK-wide reduction in private transport. 16% urban fuel-efficiency improvement for general (private and commercial) traffic. Implemented as 6% UK-wide fuel-efficiency improvement for general traffic. Home Energy Improved insulation and ventilation of the housing stock will improve in-door climate and thereby UK health + improve efficiency of fossil-fuel based heating and thereby lower GHG emissions. The home energy scenario was designed to achieve a 50% emissions reduction target for UK dwellings in 2030 Cleaner Cars A switch to more a more fuel-efficient car stock will improve UK health Dynamic growth path of efficiency-gains in household heating derived from household energy model 38% fuel-efficiency improvement for private traffic The cleaner cars scenario was designed to achieve an additional 35% reduction in GHG emissions from the transport sector (with the active travel scenario, this achieves a combined 60% emissions reduction target in urban areas in England and Wales in 2030). Road Pricing Tax Investment in household insulation and ventilation, measured by unit investment costs (per unit of efficiency gain) Standard Standard Standard and Breakeven Breakeven Improved diets with reduced intakes of saturated fats and cholesterol leads to reduced disease burdens of ischaemic heart disease and stroke. Increased physical activity leads to reduced disease burdens of diabetes, Alzheimers disease, hypertensive heart disease, ischaemic heart disease, cerebrovascular disease, breast cancer, colorectoral cancer, and depression. Increased walking and biking also leads to increased traffic-related injuries: Short- and longterm intracranial injuries, and spinal cord injuries. Improved home insulation ensures reasonable in-door temperatures and reduced concentrations of externally produced particulate pollutants, leading to reduced disease burdens of cardiovascular disease, depression, cardiopulmonary disease and lung cancers. Improved insulation also leads to health harms in the form of lung cancers (due to higher in-door radon concentrations), asthma (due to mould growth), and cerebrovascular disease and ischaemic heart disease (due to increased in-door concentrations of environmental tobacco smoke). A new car pool with lowercarbon-emission motor vehicles reduces local air pollution in urban centres and thereby lowers disease burdens and, in some case, premature deaths due to trachea, bronchus and lung cancers, lower and upper respiratory infections, hypertensive heart disease, ischaemic heart disease, cerebrovascular disease, inflammatory heart diseases, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease, asthma and other respiratory diseases. Note: See Annex for more details on the scenario specifications. 7 As discussed in Section 3, the four scenarios will be assessed with two assessment methodologies: (1) a standard methodology and (2) a breakeven methodology. The ‘standard’ assessment methodology requires well-defined economic instruments to achieve stated policy targets. Three of our four policy scenarios are associated with well-defined economic instruments, including a fat tax (healthy diet), a road pricing tax (active travel), and an insulation and ventilation investment scheme (home insulation). These scenarios will therefore be assessed using the ‘standard’ methodology. The home insulation scenario will also be assessed using the breakeven methodology, since there is some uncertainty surrounding the scale of efficiency improvements and required investment outlays (which are derived from the home energy model).7 The final cleaner cars scenario is not associated with a specific policy instrument. However, a key element in this strategy is likely to be investment in new fuel-efficient cars. The cleaner cars scenario will therefore (together with the home insulation scenario) be evaluated using the ‘breakeven’ methodology. There is a general tendency for tax instruments to be applied to achieve demand-reductions (fat tax and road pricing tax) while investment instruments are used to achieve efficiency-improvements via introduction of new technology (insulation investment and fuel-efficient car investment). It should be noted, however, that the road pricing tax (in the active travel scenario) serves the double purpose of reducing transport demand and reducing urban congestion – and that reduced urban congestion leads to an efficiency-improvement of an existing technology (improved fuel-efficiency of existing car stock). The road pricing tax is therefore a special instrument which has both demand-reducing and efficiency-enhancing effects on GHG emissions and economic outcomes. The temporal implementation of the four scenarios differs between (1) instantaneous implementation and (2) gradual implementation. The home insulation and cleaner cars scenarios are implemented gradually since efficiency-enhancing interventions require large (and time-consuming) investment programmes. In contrast, the healthy diet and active travel scenarios are implemented instantaneously. These scenarios are based on demand-constraining tax interventions which may be implemented without much delay. Instantaneous implementation therefore seems like a reasonable first approximation for these scenarios.8 The measurement of health co-benefits also differs between the four scenarios. Two approaches with distinct health focus may be distinguished, including focus on (1) direct health benefits from reduced local air pollution (cleaner cars), and (2) indirect health effects from e.g. improved diets (healthy diet), increased physical activity (active travel) and better in-door climate (home insulation). A list of the specific health effects included in the scenarios, both benefits and harms, are presented in Box 1. 7 The housing energy model (DECC 2011) provide measures of energy consumption which exceeds national accounts numbers obtained from the Office of National Accounts (ONS). It was therefore decided to compute a dynamic growth path of relative efficiency improvements from the housing energy model (relative reduction in energy use consistent with an unchanged consumption of heating services) and impose it on the CGE model. Similarly, it was decided to compute a dynamic growth path of unit investment costs (per unit of efficiency improvement). This essentially allowed us to scale investment costs in proportion to efficiency gains. Since the necessary investment costs required to support the derived energy efficiency gains are uncertain, it was decided to apply both the standard methodology as well as the breakeven methodology to the home insulation scenario. 8 Note that the active travel scenario also requires investment in infrastructure for pedestrians and cyclists (the costs of which are assumed to be counteracted by reduced road maintenance costs), so the assumption of instantaneous implementation is not fully valid. Similar concerns arise for the healthy diet scenario, indicating that the latter scenarios should be viewed as stylized scenarios. In contrast, the home insulation scenario is based on a detailed dynamic household insulation model (DECC 2011), indicating that the temporal dimension of this scenario is more realistically described. 8 The three scenarios with a focus on indirect health effects (healthy diet, active travel, and home insulation) are also the scenarios with well-defined economic instruments. The standard assessments of these scenarios are therefore comparable except for one distinction: The home insulation scenario is implemented gradually over the 20 year period, while the healthy diet and active travel scenarios are implemented instantaneously. As for the breakeven assessment of the home insulation and cleaner cars scenarios, they are both implemented gradually but differ in their focus on indirect health effects of improved insulation and ventilation and direct health effects of reduced local air pollution. Neither the standard nor the breakeven assessments are therefore fully comparable across scenarios. 5 Results Two sets of simulation analyses are presented: The standard simulations in section 5.1 analyses the three scenarios with a focus on indirect health effects (healthy diet, active travel, and home insulation), while the breakeven simulations in section 5.2 analyses the two investment-based efficiency-enhancing mitigation scenarios (cleaner cars and home insulation).9 Health-related shock values for each of the four policy scenarios are given in Table 1. The health shocks are imposed on the CGE model, and the discussion of results, below, therefore refers to the UK-wide economic impacts of these health co-benefits. Three types of health effects are analysed including (1) UK healthcare savings, (2) UK social security transfers, and (3) health effects on the UK labour force. Table 1. Health-related Shocks (mn £; NPV value in 2010 prices) Individual Scenarios Combined Scenario III. Home Insulation I. Healthy Diet 2,533 II. Active Travel 13,526 IIA. Cleaner Cars 51 15 16,073 -618.7 10.2 628.8 -789.9 101.2 891.1 -27.8 1.7 29.5 -71.5 17.5 89.0 -1,480.0 128.9 1,608.9 3,151.9 42,203 159,121 14,315.6 78,738 217,662 78.7 2,383 7,630 86.0 9,845 21,979 17,553.5 130,787 398,762 YLD (accumulated years)2 - Working age change - Labour force change - Dependents change 10,346 3,924 2,862 6,422 94,098 40,171 28,793 53,926 1,790.6 660.0 478.3 1,130.6 8,725 6,887 4,909 1,839 113,169 50,982 36,564 62,187 YLL (accumulated years)2 - Working age change - Labour force change - Dependents change 159,121 54,006 39,341 105,115 217,662 69,294 49,946 148,368 7,629.8 2,621.5 1,904.8 5,008.3 21,979 6,846 4,936 15,133 398,762 130,146 94,223 268,616 Total Public Budget Net Savings Social Security Net Savings1 - Social Security Savings (labour force) - Social Security Costs (dependents) Healthcare Savings1 Total Labour Force Change Total Population Change (I + II + III) NB: 1 Net Present Value over 2011-2030 (million £ in 2010 prices); 2 Accumulated years over 2011-2030 without discounting 5.1 Standard Simulations Aggregate health co-benefits and macroeconomic effects are presented in Table 2, price and tax changes are presented in Table 3, and sector impacts on domestic production are presented in figure 1. 9 The home energy scenario is analysed using both methodologies. 9 Table 2. Macroeconomic Effects and Health Co-benefits (NPV in 2010 prices) Individual Scenarios I. Healthy Diet Macro effects ΔGDP (2011-2030)1 ΔGDP decomposition - marginal effects - Demand-constrained mitigation II. Active Travel -96,085 -10,007 -100,437 -49,044 - Efficiency-enhancing mitigation Combined Scenario III. Home Insulation -24,580 - Investment costs 24,408 63,529 -49,431 -49,431 4,429 15,902 469 20,800 -96,008 5,875 -24,554 -115,609 - ΔGDP per capita (2015)2 -77.1 -19.0 2.0 -95.9 - ΔGDP per capita (2020)2 -78.4 -14.8 -20.3 -114.4 - ΔGDP per capita (2030)2 -68.3 4.9 -46.4 -109.9 ΔGDP Total (marginal effects) Per Capita GDP Health Co-benefits -131,990 -150,507 39,016 - Health co-benefits (I + II + III) ΔGDP (2011-2030)1 4,429 15,902 469 20,800 (2015)2 -1.64 0.32 0.07 -1.25 - ΔGDP per capita (2020)2 -0.28 5.78 0.00 5.50 - ΔGDP per capita (2030)2 2.60 21.45 -0.43 23.62 - ΔGDP per capita NB: 1 Net Present Value over 2011-2030 (mio. £ in 2010 prices); 2 Net Present Value of value in 2015, 2020, and 2030 (£ per capita in 2010 prices) Table 3. Prices and Tax Rates Individual Scenarios I. Healthy Diet II. Active Travel Combined Scenario III. Home Insulation (I + II + III) Price indices (2030)1 - Real Exchange Rate -0.55% 0.22% 0.22% -0.12% - Consumer Price Index - Investment Price Index 0.58% 0.00% 0.31% 0.00% -0.04% 0.00% 0.85% 0.00% Agricultural Terms-of-Trade (2030)1 - Market Prices - Producer Prices - Value Added Prices -0.28% 0.39% -0.53% -0.15% 0.03% -0.04% 0.14% 0.02% -0.06% -0.30% 0.44% -0.64% Factor Returns (2030)1 - Land - Unskilled wages - Skilled wages - Capital Return -4.55% -1.49% -1.04% -1.28% -0.32% -1.05% -0.71% -0.58% -0.25% -0.15% -0.20% 0.41% -5.16% -2.69% -1.95% -1.47% 0.00% 0.01% 0.01% 0.33% 0.00% 0.02% 0.02% 0.31% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% -0.70% 0.00% 0.03% 0.03% -0.05% 0.04% 26.1% 28.9% -1.19% Factor Stocks (2030)1 - Land - Unskilled labour - Skilled labour - Capital Tax Rates (2030)2 - Fat Tax (%-point change) - Road Tax (%-point change) - Household Tax (%-point change) 25.9% -0.64% NB: 1 Percentage changes in 2030; 2 Percentage point changes in 2030. 10 29.1% -0.58% Domestic Production (Percent change) 5.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% -5.0% -10.0% -15.0% 2020 2030 -15.0% 2011 2020 2030 Domestic Production (Percent change) -20.0% 5.0% -20.0% 11 -5.0% -10.0% Home Energy (Percent) 0.0% -5.0% -10.0% -15.0% -20.0% Crops Livestock Forestry and… Fossil Extraction Oth Extraction Meat and Dairy Oth Processed… Fossil Fuel Transport… Oth… Energy Construction Trade Land Transport Non-land… Government… Other Services Healthy Diet Scenario (Percent) Crops Livestock Forestry and Fishery Fossil Extraction Oth Extraction Meat and Dairy Oth Processed Food Fossil Fuel Transport Equipmnt Oth Manufacturing Energy Construction Trade Land Transport Non-land Transport Government Service Other Services -10.0% 2011 Domestic Production (Percent change) 5.0% Crops Livestock Forestry and… Fossil Extraction Oth Extraction Meat and Dairy Oth Processed… Fossil Fuel Transport… Oth… Energy Construction Trade Land Transport Non-land… Government… Other Services -5.0% Crops Livestock Forestry and… Fossil Extraction Oth Extraction Meat and Dairy Oth Processed… Fossil Fuel Transport… Oth… Energy Construction Trade Land Transport Non-land… Government… Other Services Domestic Production (Percent change) Figure 1. Domestic Production Active Travel (Percent) 2011 2020 2030 -15.0% -20.0% Combined Scenario (Percent) 5.0% 2011 2020 2030 Health effects The health shocks in Table 1 indicate that the three GHG scenarios, combined, may reduce healthcare costs by as much as £17.6bn over the 20 year period (2011-2030). At the same time, social security costs increases by £1.5bn, leaving a net public sector gain of £16.1bn. The positive health effects also increase the labour force by 130,000 person-years or 6,500 workers per year. Table 2 shows that these health shocks raise overall GDP by £20.8bn. In comparison, the overall macroeconomic cost of implementing the three scenarios is estimated at £132.0bn (Table 2). Hence, health co-benefits, alone, may lower the macroeconomic net costs of implementation by around 14%. This demonstrates the importance of accounting for health-related externalities, when assessing the cost-effectiveness of GHG interventions. Looking at the individual scenarios, health effects are particularly important for the active travel scenario. Increased physical activity associated with increased walking and cycling, leads to significant reductions in disease burdens for diabetes, Alzheimer’s disease and ischaemic heart disease with other notable contributions from cerebrovascular disease, breast cancer and depression. The potential healthcare savings amounts to an appreciable £14.3bn. Since the £0.8bn net increase in social security transfers is relatively small (increased pensions slightly outweighs reduced benefit payments to working age people), the scenario reduces the overall public deficit by a total of £13.5bn over 2011-30 (Table 1). The increased physical activity also raises the effective labour force by almost 80,000 person-years or nearly 4,000 workers per year, and, in combination with the £14.3bn deficit reduction, leads to a £15.9bn increase in GDP over 2011-30. This macroeconomic health cobenefit is big enough to cover more than 60% of the net macroeconomic cost of the active travel scenario (net cost= efficiency loss from increased road pricing tax (29.1%) ÷ efficiency gains from reduced urban congestion/improved fuel efficiency of existing car stock (6%)). This demonstrates that health externalities may, in some cases, be large enough to cover the entire macroeconomic net cost of implementing specific GHG interventions. Health effects are less important for the two remaining healthy diet and home insulation scenarios. The most significant health effect is associated with the introduction of healthy diets. Reduced saturated fat intake may significantly lower the disease burden of ischaemic heart disease. This should lower healthcare costs by around £3.2bn and reduce the public deficit by £2.5bn over the 20 year period (Table 1). The reduced disease burden also raises the labour force by 42,000 person-years or 2,100 workers per year. These health-system shocks amount to respectively 10% (public deficit reduction) and 50% (labour force increase) of health benefits in the active travel scenario. This shows that individual GHG scenarios may have widely different impacts on individual types of health effects. The relatively large labour force shock means that health effects lead to a macroeconomic £4.4bn increase in GDP for the healthy diet scenario. The home insulation scenario has relatively small overall health effects and this leads to a £0.5bn GDP gain. Nevertheless, it should be noted that the current estimates of health co-benefits were based on conservative estimates. This applies in particular to common mental disorder (depression) attributable to alleviation of winter indoor cold, which was assumed to apply for only the first season following the introduction of home insulation interventions. Furthermore, the gradual roll-out of the insulation and ventilation programme over 2011-2030 means that the maximum health co-benefits will not be achieved until 2030 and beyond. Apart from the economic impact of health effects, it may also be observed that there are wide differences in the relative contributions of morbidity (YLDs) and mortality (YLLs) effects across 12 scenarios. These alternative welfare indicators show that morbidity-effects are particularly important for the active travel scenario (>40% of total DALYs = YLDs + YLLs), while mortality-effects are particularly important for the healthy diet scenario (>90% of total DALYs). These differences are due to differences in targeted diseases among the GHG scenarios. Hence, the active travel scenario (with a focus on increased physical activity) affects chronic diseases such as diabetes, Alzheimer’s disease, and depression, while the healthy diet scenario (with a focus on reduced intakes of saturated fat and cholesterol) mainly affects diseases for which periods of disability may be relatively short lived (e.g. a myocardial infarction in the case of ischaemic heart disease). In general, the relatively large number of disability-adjusted life years (DALYs) saved in the healthy diet (and home insulation) scenarios shows, that macroeconomic indicators such as GDP cannot stand alone when evaluating the welfare consequences of health externalities and the cost-effectiveness of GHG interventions with important health effects. A more general holistic evaluation approach is needed in this case. The need for a more holistic approach is further underlined by the impact of health effects on on GDP per capita (Table 2) which is (1) negative in the short and medium term for the healthy diet scenario, (2) negative in the long term for the home insulation scenario, and (3) positive for the active travel scenario. These results are not surprising since they reflect the substantial increase in survival which is projected to occur in the scenarios. Hence, the highly welfare improving survival of large groups of old-age people turns into a welfare reduction measured by GDP per capita (since it increases the denominator in GDP per capita calculation). Macroeconomic Effects Having detailed the positive economic effects in isolation, we consider the combined health and wider-macroeconomic effects of our three scenarios. Table 2 shows that the healthy diet scenario will be the most costly to implement (in the absence of substitution effects whereby reductions in animal products may be counterbalanced to some degree by increased consumption of fruit and vegetables). The scenario uses demand-constrained mitigation without any efficiency-enhancing elements, and the high cost was therefore to be expected. A 25.9% fat tax is required to achieve the 30% reduction in consumption of meat and dairy products (Table 3). The net cost of the healthy diet scenario is £96.1bn over the 20 year period, while the economic cost of the demand-constrained mitigation alone exceeds £100bn. In comparison, the home insulation scenario (with efficiency-enhancing elements) will cost the UK economy £24.6bn in welfare losses while the active travel scenario (with both demandconstrained and efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements), surprisingly, is the least costly GHG scenario with an aggregate welfare loss of £10.0bn. The results exemplify that demand-constrained mitigation may be very costly to implement, while mitigation scenarios with efficiency-enhancing elements are less costly and may even prove beneficial to the economy over the very long term (beyond our time horizon). In this context, it should, however, be noted that health co-benefits are more closely associated with demand-constraining interventions. Accounting for these (and other) types of co-benefits may therefore disproportionately reduce the cost of demand-constraining interventions (as well as providing significant welfare improvements through saved DALYs). Nevertheless, the results do suggest that (required) demand-constraining scenarios are likely to be relatively costly compared to scenarios with efficiency-enhancing elements. In view of the substantial tax distortions and welfare improving increasing survival of the population, it is not surprising that the healthy diet scenario leads to substantial GDP per capita losses. Our model predicts that losses amount to: £77.1, £78.4 and £68.3 in the short, medium and long terms (Table 2). The implementation of a 25.9% fat tax under the assumption of a cost-neutral government budget 13 closure yields a 0.64% decline in household tax (Table 3). This partly compensates households for increasing food costs. Nevertheless, real household incomes are significantly reduced, since the fat tax distortions reduce factor returns across the board. In particular, factor returns to land decrease by 4.6% over the 20 year period reflecting income loses due to ineffective reallocation of land towards other productive uses. Domestic production in processed meat and dairy industries are reduced by >17% and lay-offs spills over into livestock and other processed food sectors, manufacturing and trade as shown in Figure 1. At the same time, less closely related sectors such as extraction industries, increase production. This ‘leakage’ of carbon emissions emphasizes the need for economy-wide strategies to reduce GHG emissions. The large fat tax creates distortions without introducing any efficiency improvements in the economy. Health co-benefits provide a positive economic contribution of £4.4bn, but this is not sufficient to significantly dampen the economic losses of this demand-constrained mitigation intervention. Nevertheless, changing the speed of introduction and taking into account possible substitution effects (whereby an increase in fruit and vegetable consumption could occur as animal product consumption declines) could substantially offset the potential adverse effects on the economy. Another strategy to increase the income of the agricultural sector is through production of lignocellulosic biofuels which have the advantage of not competing with land for food production unlike some other biofuels. The active travel scenario requires a road pricing tax which raises private transport costs by 29.1% (Table 3). This demand-constrained mitigation creates inefficiencies and distortions which are similar to the healthy diet scenario. The associated welfare loss amounts to £49bn (Table 2). However, the efficiency-enhancing element of this scenario, i.e. improved fuel efficiency from reduced congestion and idling, also brings a £39bn gain. This suggests that the non-health aspects of this scenario (assuming cost-neutral investment in walking and biking infrastructure) yield an approximate loss of £10bn. However, the interaction of reduced traffic volumes and improved fuel efficiency introduces a non-linearity, suggesting that non-health welfare losses are around £26bn. The £16bn health cobenefits are therefore ‘only’ able to finance around 60% of the net (non-health) welfare losses. (The importance of health co-benefits is illustrated in Figure 2.) Furthermore, the results show that health co-benefits and efficiency-improvements together cover around 80% of gross welfare losses. (The contribution of efficiency-improvements and health co-benefits is illustrated in Figure 3.) These results illustrate that efficiency-improvements (for existing technologies) and health co-benefits can significantly reduce costs associated with demand-reducing mitigation interventions. Due to the revenue-neutral budget closure, the road pricing tax reduces household tax rates by 0.58%. This partly compensates households for increasing transport costs. Nevertheless, tax distortions reduce factor returns and lowers household income levels over the long term. The negative factor returns, are reflected in declining GDP per capita over the short and medium terms (-£19.0 and -£14.8 respectively). However, GDP per capita becomes positive in the long term (£4.9) due to rising and accelerating health benefits (from reduced disease burdens of several chronic diseases). The accumulation of healthcare savings in terms of both new and recurrent cases averted grows over time, and this leads to increased capital accumulation and increased household income levels in the long term. 14 Figure 2. Health benefits and net (non-health) welfare costs (billion £) 120,000 100,000 80,000 Health benefits 60,000 Net scenario costs 40,000 20,000 0 Healthy Diet Active Travel Home Energy Figure 3. Health and Efficiency benefits and gross welfare costs (billion £) 120,000 100,000 80,000 Health benefits 60,000 Efficiency benefits 40,000 Net scenario costs 20,000 0 Healthy Diet Active Travel Home Energy The active travel intervention naturally reduces domestic production of transport equipment and fossil fuels (Figure 1). As a result, there is a knock-on effect causing a decline in the fossil fuel extraction sector. Re-allocation of consumer demand away from private transportation means that private consumers increase spending elsewhere. This leads to increased production and leakage of GHG emissions to those other sectors. It should also be highlighted that this intervention would be likely to yield an increase for the cycle industry (a transmission mechanism which has not been explicitly included in the model). The home insulation scenario requires significant reallocation of investment to the construction sector. This introduces distortions in the economy and crowds out investment which could be used productively in other sectors. By itself, crowding-out of productive investment leads to a £49bn GDP loss over 20 years (Table 2). However, home insulation efficiency gains (£24.4bn) and health benefits (£500mn) contribute positively, and thereby allows for around 50% self-financing of the 2011-30 15 programme (Figure 3). The self-financing rate is expected to be even higher, if account is taken of health effects and efficiency gains beyond 2030 after the programme of investment has ceased. This again demonstrates how efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements (through introduction of new technologies) are crucial for GHG interventions to be cost-effective. The GDP per capita effects of the home insulation scenario are initially positive (£2.0) as relatively cheap investment in the initial phases yields proportionally high gains in efficiency. In addition the mental health impacts of this scenario brings immediate gains to those affected, reducing healthcare savings and increasing productive labour supply (but by relatively small amounts). In the medium and long terms, GDP per capita effects, however, become negative (-£20.3 and -£46.4 respectively). The positive short term effects of a policy to, initially, reap low-hanging fruits therefore raises the question of what level of investment should be considered optimum.10 The combined GHG scenario amalgamates the economic effects to produce an aggregate UK economy-wide cost of £132bn. Dominating this income loss are the inefficiencies and distortion effects of the demand-constraining mitigation interventions and investment costs, which together constitute a £200bn cost to society (Table 1). Clearly, the £100bn GDP loss from demand-constrained mitigation in the healthy diet scenario plays a significant part (but, again, this welfare loss could possibly be reduced through e.g. changes in consumers’ attitudes towards fruit and vegetables). The £63bn efficiency-enhancement effects, to some extent, counter these negative impacts. Similarly, the health co-benefits contribute welfare gains of £20.8bn and so play an important part in further lowering the macroeconomic cost of implementation of these scenarios. Overall the GDP per capita effects are negative and fairly consistent over time (-£96, -£114 and -£110 in the short, medium and long terms), which is not surprising since GHG interventions are expected to be costly and since the health-related (and welfare-enhancing) population expansion necessarily lowers the denominator of GDP per capita. Again, it should be highlighted that proper evaluation of GHG policies with significant health effects requires a holistic evaluation approach. Table 4. Breakeven Calculations (million £; NPV in 2010 prices) Individual Scenarios III. Housing IIA. Cleaner Cars Insulation Potential Investment Costs1 ΔPotential Investment decomposition - marginal effects Efficiency-enhancing mitigation (productivity gain) Health co-benefits Combined Scenario (IIA + III) 142,155 26,143 168,453 141,999 25,651 167,810 158 493 650 NB: 1 Net Present Value over 2011-2030 (million £ in 2010 prices) 5.2 Breakeven Simulations The breakeven simulations of the cleaner cars and home insulation scenarios indicates that health cobenefits and, especially, productivity gains allows for substantial self-financing for these efficiencyenhancing mitigation initiatives. Table 4 shows that the home insulation scenario remains costeffective as long as investment costs are kept below £26bn, while the similar figure for the cleaner 10 Please note that the issue of choosing the optimal level of insulation and ventilation investment is separate from the issue discussed above (and the motivation for the breakeven methodology) about uncertainty surrounding insulation and ventilation investment costs of achieving a given energy efficiency improvement. 16 cars scenario is £142bn. The results also indicate that health co-benefits accounts for £150-£500 million or less than one per cent of gross benefits, indicating that these scenarios mainly provides economic gains from efficiency improvements. Home insulation and ventilation investment costs will, as demonstrated in the previous section, most likely exceed benefits and thereby be cost-ineffective. However, since all investment costs are incurred during the programme period 2011-2030, while health and (energy) efficiency gains will persist for the lifetime of the housing improvements, longer term gains are likely to be greater. This is all the more so since the adoption of conservative health estimates for the programme period means that longer term health co-benefits are likely to be significantly greater. Hence, with possible breakeven costs of £26bn alone over the 20 year programme period, the UK home insulation and ventilation programme may well be cost-effective over the very long term. The cleaner cars scenario is even more likely to be cost-effective. A UK network for electric cars is yet to be developed and hybrid cars remain comparatively costly. Furthermore, while relatively small and efficient fossil fuel-based vehicles are currently less costly to acquire and maintain for the average car buyer, traffic jumps may be seen in connection with adoption of efficient transportation modes. Nevertheless, the implementation of the cleaner cars scenario may well be attained through a general change in attitudes towards hybrid and smaller fossil fuel-based vehicles at little additional or possibly even at lower (investment and maintenance) costs to car owners. This is all the more likely as the hybrid car technology is likely to become cheaper and more accessible for the average car buyer over time. With an overall (additional) breakeven investment cost estimated at £142bn over the initial 20 year period, the UK cleaner cars scenario is therefore very likely to be cost-effective. 6 Conclusion The UK has committed itself through the adoption of the 2008 Climate Change Act, to reduce GHG emissions by 80% in 2050 from a 1990 baseline. Preliminary estimates suggest that UK emissions have been reduced by around 25% in 2010. Nevertheless, a number of new mitigation initiatives are needed in order to achieve the intermediate 50% reduction target in 2030 and the final 80% reduction target in 2050. This study constructed a single-country Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model to assess UK GHG initiatives, which can help to achieve the 50% reduction target in 2030. Focus is on initiatives with important health benefits. We analysed three scenarios (healthy diet, active travel, and home insulation) with a standard methodology for impact assessment based on an extended methodology for measuring health effects, and found that health benefits significantly contributes to lowering society’s costs of implementation. Net macroeconomic costs were reduced by 14% for three scenarios combined. Furthermore, health co-benefits covered 60% of net society costs for the active travel scenario. This shows that health externalities may, in some instances, be sufficiently important to decide whether specific GHG scenarios are cost-effective or not. We showed that demand-constraining mitigation interventions may be very costly to implement, while mitigation scenarios with efficiency-enhancing elements are less costly and may even prove beneficial to the economy over the very long term (beyond our time horizon). The high cost of demand-constraining interventions was exemplified by the healthy diet scenario (with a focus on economic instruments: fat tax). However, we noted that induced changes in consumer preferences 17 may significantly lower society costs of implementation. We also noted that health co-benefits and efficiency gains for existing technologies are relatively closely associated with demand-constraining interventions, and that accounting for these benefits may significantly reduce the cost of demandconstraining interventions. The active travel scenario provides an example, where high efficiency gains and health co-benefits lowers the gross cost of demand-constraining transport interventions (with a focus on economic instruments: road tax) by 80%. While demand-constraining interventions, based on economic tax-instruments, may be accompanied by significant efficiency gains and health co-benefits, the results also show that cost-effectiveness typically requires efficiency-improvements based on the introduction of new technologies. This was evident from the home insulation scenario where energy efficiency gains from improved insulation and ventilation lowered gross society costs by 50%. Moreover, the cleaner cars scenario (assessed by the breakeven methodology) indicated that efficiency-improvements from a switch to a smaller and more fuel-efficient car stock would carry a significant breakeven investment cost of >£140bn during 2011-2030. Overall, we find that efficiency-enhancing elements (based on new technologies) are likely to be crucial for the cost-effectiveness of GHG interventions. Nevertheless, efficiency-enhancing elements (based on existing technologies) and health co-benefits has the potential to significantly lower the costs of demand-constraining GHG interventions. Furthermore, demand-constraining interventions may, in some cases, be associated with strongly welfare increasing improvements in health outcomes (longevity and life quality) – welfare improvements which tend to have a negative economic impact through increased dependency ratios. A more holistic and all-inclusive approach to impact assessment (accounting for health co-benefits and going beyond economic outcomes) may therefore make demand-constraining interventions, if not cost-effective, relatively attractive It should also be noted that we find evidence of significant health co-benefits, in spite of our relatively conservative assumptions of our approach. First, we only account for health effects during our 20 year time horizon (2011-2030). However, health co-benefits may continue to increase beyond the 20 year time horizon due to long lag periods between the implementation of the policy and the health effects such as Alzheimers disease and cancer. Underestimation of health effects is likely to be especially pronounced in the home insulation scenario, where realistic phasing-in of the investment programme occurs over a 20 year period. Health effects associated with interventions during the final years of the programme therefore contribute little (or nothing) towards the health co-benefits. We may also have underestimated some of the individual health co-benefits. For example, we conservatively assumed that depression was only reduced for one year by improved home insulation and warmer homes. Overall, it may be concluded that the political feasibility of specific GHG initiatives is likely to rest critically on whether they include efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements (of new and/or existing technologies) and important health co-benefits. 18 Annex A: SAM/CGE methodology and health effects A.1 Macroeconomic CGE model The economy-wide dynamically-recursive Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model, used in this study, was based on the ‘IFPRI standard model’ (Löfgren, Lee Harris and Robinson 2002). This is a well-known and widely applied comparative static, single country, open economy, multi-sector CGE model, which has recently been used in health and trade-related applications by some of the authors (Smith, Keogh-Brown et al. 2009; Lock, Smith et al. 2010, Jensen, Robinson and Tarp 2010). The model accounts for different types of agents including producers/enterprises, private households, the government sector and the foreign sector. The model is a neo-classical model based on the fundamental principles of profit-maximization among producers and utility maximization among households. Production is specified as a Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) function of aggregate intermediate input demand (individual commodity input demands are determined by a Leontief specification) and aggregate factor input demand (individual factor input demands are determined by a CES specification). Trade between domestic and foreign agents is specified as a function of relative prices (determined by the real exchange rate), based on an Armington CES specification on the import side and a Constant Elasticity of Transformation (CET) specification on the export side. The standard model specification was, furthermore, expanded to account for household production of transport services and heating services. Household production was in each case determined by a Leontief specification.11,12 Based on this setup, the fuel efficiency (cleaner cars/active travel) and heating efficiency (home energy) improvements were modelled as changes to the Leontief input parameters for respectively fossil fuel and private energy input use. A standard neo-classical model closure is used in all simulations, implying that flexible prices are clearing all goods and factor markets and that a flexible real exchange rate is clearing the current account of the balance of payments. In addition, the counterfactual projections are based on a balanced macro closure (fixed government demand-to-absorption ratio) which ensures a (relatively) unchanged composition of absorption (private and government consumption vs. investment) over the projection period. Furthermore, all simulations are based on a revenue-neutral government budget closure (endogenous household tax rate) which ensures that changes in individual government revenue components (e.g. due to the introduction of a fat tax or road pricing scheme) will not affect the relative size of the government sector in the economy. A.2 Macroeconomic data base and CGE model calibration The CGE model for the UK economy was calibrated on the basis of a 2004 social accounting matrix (SAM) dataset taken from the GTAP database v7 (Narayanan and Walmsley 2008). The basic dataset 11 Since production of private transportation and heating services does not constitute a standard industrial production sector, it was necessary to specify separate household production sectors for each of these private services. A Leontief production function was chosen based on the assumption of proportional input use. Furthermore, profit-maximization was invoked based on the standard separability assumption for household production and consumption decisions, and a standard equilibrium condition was implemented as part of the general equilibrium framework. 12 A more sophisticated specification of household production of transport services have previously been applied within a CGE model, to study how taxation of work journeys (akin to our road pricing scheme) may affect labour supply decisions (Berg 2007). This type of specification was outside the scope the current paper. 19 was aggregated to 17 production activities and 17 retail commodities covering both agricultural, industry and service sectors (including health). A further five retail commodities were created specifically to allow for analysing abatement technologies in household production of heating services and transport services. These five commodities included two heating-related commodities (“heating services” and “private energy” inputs), and three transport-related commodities (“private transport services” as well as “private fuel” and “other private transport” inputs). Value breakdowns were based on the UK Office for National Statistics Family Spending Survey 2004-5. A.3 Assessment methodology Two types of assessment methodologies are applied to evaluate the cost-effectiveness of policy scenarios: (1) a standard methodology, and (2) a breakeven methodology. The standard methodology is based on standard factor accumulation and standard calculation of macroeconomic aggregates such as GDP. This methodology will be used to assess the three main scenarios (I), (II), and (III). In contrast, the breakeven methodology calculates the maximum non-productive investment costs, which are consistent with an unchanged NPV value of GDP over the 20 year simulation horizon (20112030). The methodology is targeted at policy scenarios with an investment element (where actual investment costs are eliminated, and potential investment financing is calculated). The breakeven methodology is therefore only applied to assess the cleaner cars (IIa) and home energy (III) scenarios. The breakeven methodology is especially useful for our purposes, since it allows us to highlight the beneficial effects of efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements and health externalities. An understanding of the accumulation of factor stocks is central to understanding the economic impact of GHG emission reduction strategies. GHG strategies have direct consequences for annual spending on investment and capital accumulation. E.g. efficiency-enhancing abatement technologies may increase productivity and thereby raise value creation and investment, while non-productive investment in housing may lead to crowding-out and lower investment. Reduced capital accumulation leads, ceteris paribus, to reduced future value creation and welfare. This mechanism has been used by many economists to argue that GHG emission reduction strategies may entail a trade-off between GHG emission reductions and (future) welfare gains. This argument does not, however, take account of (1) the possibility of employing efficiency-enhancing abatement technologies (which may reduce GHG emissions at no cost or even increase productivity and welfare) and (2) the possibility that beneficial (health) externalities may reduce the economic costs of policy implementation. A.4 Health effects For each disease, detailed age- and gender-specific calculations of disease burdens, including Years of healthy Life lost due to Disability (YLD) and Years of Life Lost (YLL) were used to calculate implied changes to UK healthcare costs, UK labour supplies, and UK social security transfers. Gender and age-specific health effects were determined by the WHO comparative risk assessment approach (Woodcock et al. 2009; Friel et al. 2009; Wilkinson et al. 2009), and distributed over the 20 year horizon (Smith et al. 2012). The resulting dynamic patterns of health effects, including YLDs and YLLs, were used to derive (1) changes in the effective labour force (based on reduced YLD and YLL for the working age population corrected for gender-specific labour market participation rates), and (2) changes in social security transfers including reduced labour market benefits (based on reduced YLD for the working age population) and increased pension payments (based on reduced YLL for the old-age population). Furthermore, changes in healthcare costs were measured on the basis of 20 disease/injury incidence numbers. Details of the methodology for calculating these healthcare costs are provided in Jarrett et al. (2012).13,14 For each illness (with the exception of road traffic injuries) a disease-specific sigmoid curve was used to determine the lag time between the implementation of an intervention and the health benefits (or harms). In the cleaner cars and home energy scenarios, interventions occur gradually over a 20 year period. For these scenarios, the time-lagged health effects and healthcare savings were further staggered to account for the gradual implementation of the interventions. Health harms from increased road traffic injuries (attributable to the increased number of pedestrians/cyclists under the intervention scenarios) were assumed to occur linearly. 13 The reduction in YLDs had not been estimated for several illnesses in the healthy diet (Friel et al 2009) and home energy (Wilkinson et. al. 2009) scenarios. Nevertheless, it was decided to include the reduction in YLDs for diseases for which a reduction in YLLs had been calculated. This was achieved by using ratios of YLLs to YLDs for Europe from the WHO Global Burden of Disease. 14 Detailed healthcare savings were measured for the active travel scenario (Jarrett et al. 2012). Healthcare savings were, subsequently, calculated for the remaining scenarios by applying the active travel healthcare savings per patient to incidence estimates for the same common diseases. 21 Annex B: Policy Scenarios B.1 The healthy diet scenario (Scenario I) Greenhouse gasses are produced throughout the food-system supply chain, including agricultural farming, food distribution, consumption, and waste disposal (Friel et al 2009). The agriculture sector is responsible for 10-12 % of global greenhouse gas emissions (and an additional 6-17% if land use change is included), and livestock-related activities accounts for 80% of agricultural emissions (FAO 2006). Furthermore, increasing demand for meat is expected to raise livestock production in 2030 by 85% above the level in 2000 (World Bank 2008). These numbers indicate that livestock activities are – and will remain – a key contributor to anthropogenic GHG emissions for the foreseeable future. The healthy diet scenario was designed to achieve the sector-specific 50% emissions reduction target for UK agricultural activities in 2030 (Friel et al. 2009). The emissions reduction scenario was developed as a two-pronged strategy: (1) introduction of new abatement technologies, and (2) reduction in livestock activities. Based on estimates of technological change, already in the pipeline, it was estimated that the 50% overall reduction target could only be achieved by an additional 30% reduction target for livestock production, which for the purposes of illustration was assumed to result in a commensurate reduction in consumption (Friel et al. 2009). In this paper, we focus on the health co-benefits of reduced meat and dairy consumption. We therefore decided to target a 30% reduction in demand (rather than output). This was achieved through the introduction of a tax instrument – a socalled ‘fat tax’ – on livestock-related meat and dairy products.15 Health co-benefits stem primarily from improved diets with reduced intakes of saturated fats and cholesterol, which leads to reduced disease burdens of ischaemic heart disease and stroke.16 B.2 The active travel (Scenario II) and cleaner cars (Scenario IIa) scenarios The transport sector accounts for more than a quarter of global anthropogenic GHG emissions. Furthermore, fossil fuels account for 95% of global transport fuel demand, and current trends suggest that emissions from this source will increase by 80% during 2007-2030 (Ribeiro et al. 2007). Within the transport sector, road traffic accounts for three-quarters of global emissions. Road traffic is therefore another key contributor to anthropogenic GHG emissions, which needs to be addressed within an overall UK GHG emission reduction strategy. The active travel and cleaner cars scenarios were originally designed to achieve a combined 60% emissions reduction target for the Greater London area in 2030 (Woodcock et al. 2009). By itself, the active travel scenario was designed to achieve a 38% reduction in GHG emissions through a switch from fossil fuel combustion vehicles to alternative active travel modes including walking and biking. The cleaner cars scenario was, subsequently, developed to achieve an additional 35% reduction in GHG emissions, through a switch to more fuel-efficient lower-carbon-emission vehicles, and thereby reach a combined 60% reduction in GHG emissions. In the policy simulations below, the active travel 15 The decision to specify the policy shock as a 30% reduction in demand rather than production is due to our focus on health effects (which are consistent with a 30% demand reduction for processed meat and dairy products – see Friel et al. 2009). As discussed below, the 30% demand reduction is only accompanied by a 17% reduction in the production of meat and dairy products. Hence, this scenario specification may not fully achieve the GHG emission reduction targets which it was designed to achieve, due to trade-related ‘leakages’. 16 The healthy diet scenario focuses narrowly on measuring the economic impact of indirect health effects. Hence, the scenario does not account for direct health effects of e.g. reduced local air pollution (which are considered to be of minor importance). 22 and cleaner cars scenarios will be analysed separately. Furthermore, the simulations (and associated health effects) are expanded to cover all major urban centres throughout England and Wales (active travel) and the entire UK (cleaner cars). 17 The cleaner cars scenario is based, solely, on a (UK-wide) 38% fuel efficiency improvement. In contrast, the active travel scenario includes both demand-constraining and efficiency-enhancing mitigation elements: (1) a 41% reduction in urban traffic volumes, which translates into a 15.6% UKwide reduction in traffic volumes. In the policy simulations, this target reduction will be achieved through the introduction of a tax instrument – a ‘road pricing’ tax – on private transport services; and (2) an accompanying reduction in urban congestion, which improves fuel efficiency by 16% for urban car journeys or 6% on a UK-wide basis.18 In the cleaner cars scenario the focus is on replacing the current car pool in urban areas with lowercarbon-emission motor vehicles. Important health effects therefore arise from reduced local air pollution in urban centres.19 In the active travel scenario the switch to active travel modes such as walking and biking leads to increased physical activity, and this has a number of health co-benefits including reduced disease burdens of diabetes, Alzheimers disease, ischaemic heart disease, cerebrovascular disease, depression, etc. However, increased walking and biking also leads to increased numbers of traffic-related injuries which are nevertheless greatly outweighed by the health co-benefits. B.3 The home insulation scenario (Scenario III) Residential and commercial buildings account for 8% of global anthropogenic GHG emissions. In spite of limited growth in emissions, analyses indicate that buildings have the highest potential (among the major sectors of emissions) for mitigation in 2030 (5.3-6.7 GtCO2-eq/year) (IPCC 2007). Within the UK, dwellings account for around 30% of total UK energy consumption, while space heating accounts for around 60% of energy consumption in UK dwellings (DTI 2008). Furthermore, space heating is estimated to account for more than half of total CO2 emissions by UK dwellings (DCLG 2006). Improving the heating and insulation of dwellings is therefore another important policy to implement within an overall UK GHG emission reduction strategy. The ‘home insulation’ scenario was designed with the aim to achieve the sector-specific 50% emissions reduction target for dwellings in 2030 (Wilkinson et al. 2009). The scenario took as point of departure that emissions from dwellings had already been reduced by 9% in 2010 relative to 1990 levels. The target reduction to be achieved was therefore 41% during 2010-2030. The scenario was developed as a four-pronged strategy: (1) fabric improvements (insulation), (2) improved ventilation control, (3) fuel switching (fossil fuel combustion to electricity), and (4) occupant behaviour (in-door temperatures controlled at 18˚C or above). Due to uncertainty regarding fuel switching, this 17 The temporal implementation of the active travel scenario is assumed to occur instantaneously, while the transition to a more environmentally-friendly car stock (cleaner cars) is assumed to occur gradually (efficiencygains are implemented linearly over time horizon, reaching 38% in 2030). 18 The urban congestion impact was not part of the original scenario design (Woodcock et al. 2009). The active travel scenario (combined with the cleaner cars scenario) is therefore likely to bring GHG emission reductions in excess of the targets which it was designed to achieve. 19 While the other scenarios (including active travel) focus narrowly on measuring the importance of indirect health effects, the cleaner cars scenario is the only scenario where the direct health impact of reduced local air pollution is accounted for. As discussed below, the economic impact of reduced local air pollution turns out to be relatively limited. 23 component was not counted towards GHG emission reductions (but it was retained for the calculation of health effects). The policy simulations below are based on input data from an environmental home energy model employed by the Department of Energy and Climate Change (DECC 2011). The scenario is based on a 20 year investment programme for home insulation and ventilation, and therefore involves a gradually increasing dynamic 2011-2030 growth path for productivity gains in household production of heating services, supported by a dynamic sequence of unit insulation investment costs. In this way, investment in improved insulation and ventilation is used as a policy instrument to reduce GHG emissions and enhance the production efficiency of private heating services in UK dwellings. Health co-benefits stem from several sources. Insulation of dwellings ensures reasonable in-door temperatures and reduced concentrations of externally produced particulate pollutants, leading to health benefits in the form of reduced disease burdens of cardiovascular disease and depression (temperature) and of cardiopulmonary disease and lung cancers (PM2.5). At the same time, insulation of dwellings also leads to health harms due to higher in-door radon concentrations (which causes lung cancers), increased mould growth (which exacerbates asthma), and increased in-door concentrations of environmental tobacco smoke (a risk factor for cerebrovascular disease and ischaemic heart disease). The latter health effects can be countered by mechanical ventilation with heat recovery (MVHH) and this was assumed to occur in the 20 % of homes that were the most tightly sealed. 24 References Ackerman F, DeCanio SJ, Howarth RB, Sheeran K (2009) Limitations of integrated assessment models of climate change. Climatic Change 95:297-315. Ackerman F, Finlayson IJ (2007) The economics of inaction on climate change:a sensitivity analysis. Climate Policy 6:509-26. ADAS (2009) RMP/5142 Analysis of Policy Instruments for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Agriculture, Forestry and Land Management. ADAS UK Ltd. Ayres RU, Walters J (1991) The greenhouse effect: Damages, costs and abatement. Environmental & Resource Economics 1:237-70. Azar C (1998) Are optimal CO2 emissions really optimal? Environmental and Resource Economics 11:301-15. Berg C (2007) Household transport demand in a CGE-framework. Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics 37:573-97. Bosello F, Roson R, Tol RSJ (2006) Economy-wide estimates of the implications of climate change: Human health. Ecological Economics 58:579-91. Böhringer C, Helm C (2008) On the fair division of greenhouse gas abatement cost. Resource and Energy Economics 30:260-76. Böhringer C, Rutherford TF (2010) The costs of compliance: A CGE assessment of Canada’s policy options under the Kyoto protocol. World Economy 33:177-211. CCC (2009) Advice for Policymakers. Copenhagen Consensus on Climate. Ciscar J-C, Iglesias A, Feyenc L, Szabóa L, van Regemortera D, Amelunge B, Nicholls R, Watkiss P, Christensen OB, Dankersc R, Garrotek L, Goodess CM, Hunt A, Moreno A, Richards J, Soria A (2010) Physical and economic consequences of climate change in Europe. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108:2678-83. Daily GC, Ehrlich PR, Mooney HA, Ehrlich AH (1991) Greenhouse economics: Learn before you leap. Ecological Economics 4:1-10. DCLG (2006) Review of sustainability of existing buildings - energy efficiency of dwellings. Department of Communities and Local Government. UK. DECC (2008) UK Climate Change Act 2008. Chapter 27. Department of Energy and Climate Change. UK. DECC (2011) UK greenhouse gas emissions: performance against emissions reduction targets – 2010 provisional fugures. Department of Energy and Climate Change. UK. Dellink R, Hofkes M, van Ierland E, Verbruggen H (2004) Dynamic modelling of polution abatementin a CGE framework. Economic Modelling 21:965-89. DoT 2012 Statistics. Department of Transport. http://www.dft.gov.uk/statistics. 25 DTI (2008) Energy Consumption in the United Kingdom. Department of Trade and Industry. UK den Elzen MGJ, Hof AF, Beltran AM, Grassi G, Roelfsema M, van Ruijven B, van Vliet, J, van Vuuren DP (2011) The Copenhagen accord: abatement costs and carbon prices from the submissions. Environmental Science and Policy 14:28-39. den Elzen MGJ, Hof AF, Roelfsema M (2011) The emissions gap between the Copenhagen pledges and the 2C climate goal: Options for closing and risks that could widen the gap. Global Environmental Change 21:733-43. den Elzen MGJ, van Vuuren DP, van Vliet J (2010) Postponing emission reductions from 2020 to 2030 increases climate risks and long-term costs. Climatic Change 99:313-20. Dessus S, O'Connor D (2003) Climate policy without tears: CGE-based ancillary benefits estimates for Chile. Environmental & Resource Economics 25:287-317. FAO (2006) Livestock's long shadow - environmental issues and options. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Rome. Fisher-Vanden K, Wing IS (2008) Accounting for quality: Issues with modelling the impact of R&D on economic growth and carbon emissions in developing countries. Energy Economics 30:2771-84. Friel S, Dangour AD, Garnett T, Lock K, Chalabi Z, Roberts I, Butler A, Butler CD, Waage J, McMichael AJ, Haines A (2009) Public health benefits of strategies to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions: food and agriculture. Lancet 374:2016-25. Garbaccio RF, Ho MS, Jorgenson DW (2000) The health benefits of controlling carbon emissions in China. working paper. GLA (2007) Action today to protect tomorrow – The mayor’s climate change action plan. Greater London Authority. UK. Grepperud S, Rasmussen I (2004) A general equilibrium assessment of rebound effects. Energy Economics 26:261-82. Hagem C, Kallbekken S, Mæstad O, Westskog H (2006) Market power with interdependent demand: Sale of emission permits and natural gas from Russia. Environmental and Resource Economics 34:211-27. Haines A, McMichael AJ, Smith KR, Roberts I, Woodcock J, Markandya A, Armstrong BG, Campbell-Lendrum D, Dangour AD, Davies M, Bruce N, Tonne C, Barrett M, Wilkinson P (2009) Public health benefits of strategies to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions: overview and implications for policy makers. The Lancet 374:2104-14. IPCC, various years, Assessment reports of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Jack DW, Kinney PL (2010) Health co-benefits of climate mitigation in urban areas. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 2:172-77. 26 Jarrett J, Woodcock J, Griffiths U, Chalabi Z, Edwards P, Roberts I, Haines A (2012) Projected impact on National Health Service costs of increased active travel in urban England and Wales. submitted to The Lancet. Jensen HT, Robinson S, Tarp F (2010) Measuring agricultural policy bias: General equilibrium analysis of fifteen developing countries. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 92:1136-48. Klepper G, Peterson S (2005) Trading Hot-Air. The influence of permit allocation rules, market power and the US withdrawal from the Kyoto protocol. Environmental & Resource Economics 32:205-27. Li JC (2002) Including the feedback of local health improvement in assessing costs and benefits of GHG reduction. Review of Urban and Regional Studies 14:282-304. Lim, J (2011) Impacts and implications of implementing voluntary greenhouse gas emission reduction targets in major countries and Korea. Energy Policy 39:5086-95. Lock K, Smith RD, Dangour A, Keogh-Brown M, Pigatto G, Hawkes C, Fisjberg R, Chalabi Z (2010) Health, agricultural and economic effects of adopting healthy diet recommendations. The Lancet 376:1699-17. Löfgren H, Harris RL, Robinson S (2002) A standard Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model in GAMS. Microcomputers and Policy Research 5. IFPRI. Washington DC. Maréchal K (2007) The economics of climate change and the change of climate in economics. Energy Policy 35:5181-94. Narayanan B, Walmsley TL (2008) Global trade, assistance and production: The GTAP 7 database. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Neumayer E (1999) Global warming: Discounting is not the issue, but substitutability is. Energy Policy 27:33-43. Nijkamp P, Wang S, Kremers H (2005) Modeling the impacts of international climate change policies in a CGE context: The use of the GTAP-E model. Economic Modelling 22:955-74. Peterson EB, Schleich J, Duscha V (2011) Environmental and economic effects of the Copenhagen pledges and more ambitious emissionreduction targets. Energy Policy 39:3697-3708. Ribeiro SK, Kobayashi S, Beuthe M, Gasca J, Greene D, Lee DS, Muromachi Y, Newton PJ, Plotkin S, Sperling D, Wit R, Zhou PJ (2007) Transport and its infrastructure. IPCC Fourth Assessment Report (AR4), Working Group 3 (WG3), Chapter 5. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Roe GH, Baker MB (2007) Why is climate sensitivity so unpredictable. Science 318:629-32. Smith RD, Keogh-Brown M, Barnett T, Tait J (2009) The economy-wide impact of pandemic influenza on the UK: a computable general equilibrium modelling experiment. British Medical Journal 339: b4571. 27 Smith RD, Keogh-Brown M, Jensen HT, Chalabi Z, Dangour A, Davies M, Edwards P, Garnett T, Givoni M, Griffiths U, Hamilton I, Jarrett J, Roberts I, Wilkinson P, Woodcock J, Haines A (2012) The macroeconomic impact of health co-benefits associated with climate change mitigation strategies. Submitted to the Lancet Stern (2007) The economics of climate change. The Stern Review. Cambridge University Press. 712pp. Telli C, Voyvoda C, Yeldan E (2008) Economics of environmental policy in Turkey: A general equilibrium investigation of the economic evaluation of sectoral emission reduction policies for climate change. Journal of Policy Modeling 30:321-40. TfL 2004 Congestion charging central London – impacts monitoring, second annual report. Transport for London. van den Bergh, JCJM (2004) Optimal climate policy is a utopia: From quantitative to qualitative costbenefit analysis. Ecological Economics 48:385-93. van den Bergh, JCJM (2010) Safe climate policy is affordable – 12 reasons. Climatic Change 101:339-385. Wilkinson P, Smith KR, Davies M, Adair H, Armstrong BG, Barrett M, Bruce N, Haines A, Hamilton I, Oreszczyn T, Ridley I, Tonne C, Chalabi Z (2009) Public health benefits of strategies to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions: household energy. The Lancet 374:1917-29. Woodcock J, Edwards P, Tonne C, Armstrong BG, Ashiru O, Banister D, Beevers S, Chalabi Z, Chowdhury Z, Cohen A, Franco OH, Haines A, Hickman R, Lindsay G, Mittal I, Mohan D, Tiwari G, Woodward A, Roberts I (2009) Public health benefits of strategies to reduce greenhouse-gas emissions: urban land transport. The Lancet 374:1930-43. World Bank (2008) Agriculture for Development. World Development Report 2008. World Bank. 28