WHO DEFECTS? Defection Cascades from a Ruling Party and the Case of United Russia 2008-121 Henry E. Hale, George Washington University, hhale@gwu.edu Timothy J. Colton, Harvard University, tcolton@fas.harvard.edu Draft with Colton comments: December 29, 2013 Word Count: 12,309 What factors govern mass support for the dominant party in a hybrid political regime that combines elements of authoritarianism and democracy? In particular, what causes individual citizens to cease supporting the ruling party? A burgeoning literature broadly agrees that political parties are the linchpin of non-democratic regimes’ survival (Brownlee 2007; Geddes 1999; Huntington 1968; Svolik 2012; Way 2005). Other work has found that public support can be crucial to the ruling party’s ability to stabilize the regime (Magaloni 2006; McFaul 2005).2 The support we have in mind involves not only a heartfelt preference for this regime over all alternatives but also what Kuran (1991, 1995) has called “preference falsification.” The preference falsifier is someone who secretly dislikes a dominant party but out of concern for personal safety or career prospects refrains from openly opposing it and sometimes even champions it in social situations where one is not sure everyone shares the critical attitude. Systematic preference falsification is widely believed to be central to the survival chances of non-democratic ruling parties. But research has also shown that it can rapidly come unraveled as people withdraw this form of support in a cascading process, bringing down whole regimes with stunning speed and finality (Kuran 1995; Lohmann 1994; Wedeen 2002; Yurchak 2006). If anyone doubts the power of such dynamics, they need only look to the stunning collapse of Eastern Europe’s communist party governments in 1989 or the unexpected downfall of regime after regime in the 2011 Arab Spring (Brown 2013; Kuran 1991; 2011; Patel 2011). We use the term defection to refer to such withdrawals of support--be it heartfelt or preference falsification-from a nondemocratic regime or its ruling party. The process of cascading defections--including whether it will go far enough to bring down a regime--hinges on individuals’ preferences and thresholds. But we know remarkably little about what drives variation in these preferences and thresholds. Why would some people who once supported a ruling party shift to opposing it, and why would some be quicker to do so than others? Work focusing on preference falsification have concentrated on the larger dynamic and its theoretical underpinnings, leaving underdeveloped theory on who precisely gets swept up in these regime defection cascades and how (Kuran 1991, 1995; Lohmann 1994; Pfaff 2006).3 A 1 The surveys on which this article is based were funded principally by the National Council for Eurasian and East European Research (NCEEER) under authority of two Title VIII grants from the U.S. government and supplemental funding by the latter. The views expressed here are solely those of the authors and are not the responsibility of the U.S. government, the NCEEER, or any other person or entity. The authors thank Ellen Carnaghan, Thomas Remington, and participants in the Political Economy Seminar of the Higher School of Economics and New Economic School in Moscow for comments on earlier drafts. 2 Most research on non-democratic regime survival emphasizes the elite sources of these parties’ strength (e.g., Levitsky and Way 2010; Reuter and Remington 2009; Smyth, Wilkening, & Urasova 2007), 3 As one recent example, many early accounts have argued that regime defection cascades were key to bringing down Egypt’s Hosni Mubarak and his ruling National Democratic Party, but they say almost nothing about the 1 host of theories explain the defection of elites (e.g., Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2005; Hale 2005; Slater 2010; Svolik 2012), but these do not afford us much leverage on the vast bulk of regime supporters, who do not control major economic or political assets. Some important work tracks macro-level trends in public opinion leading up to a ruling party’s downfall (Magaloni 2006). But without being able to observe the dispositions of the same individuals both before and after, such studies cannot tell us which specific people at the micro level are actually doing the defecting and why. Other scholarship examines what kinds of individuals participate in uprisings or anti-regime protests (Beissinger 2011, 2013; Javeline 2003; Smyth 2013). This is not the question at hand for us. We are interested not in who protests, but in who goes from a situation of supporting a regime to withdrawing that support, whether or not they turn out in the streets. And in any case, it is not enough to ask people after a regime defection cascade whether they were long-time opposition activists or recent converts to the cause. Research into preference falsification dynamics finds that some people can be expected to misrepresent their own prior positions after the fact, with erstwhile regime supporters now associating themselves with the winning side and denying that they had ever sincerely or insincerely backed the old authorities (Kuran 1991; Kuran and Sunstein 1999). In the present paper, we introduce several theoretical propositions on how defection from ruling parties is likely to occur and spread at the individual level, and then present an empirical strategy capable of overcoming many of the difficulties just described. The strategy--to our knowledge unique in the literature--is to employ an original panel survey that measures the same individuals’ support for one hybrid regime’s dominant party first at the peak of its dominance and then again just after the party suffered its most severe political crisis since its founding, one where a great deal of anecdotal evidence suggests that somewhat of a cascade of defections took place among regime supporters in the broader population. The context is Russia, where Vladimir Putin’s United Russia Party went from almost unquestioned dominance in 2008 to a major drop in support and an unprecedented tsunami of protest that shook the regime and forced it into a series of concessions in late 2011 and early 2012.4 On this basis, we find that--contrary to a popular wisdom--defection from dominant parties tends to spread more by geographic community than virtual community and tends to be driven more by cynicism about democracy than faith in it. In addition, such waves first tend to sweep up party supporters based on their individual psychological mobility, low confidence in their own party’s future, and a host of contingent personal reactions to regime actions and changes in personal fortune that may have little to do with the authorities. We also find that the regime’s creation of “virtual parties” can be a significant buttress to the stability of nondemocratic regimes. Many Russiandefectors opted to go to one of these rather than to the most unwavering opposition parties, though the true opposition parties picked up those defectors who had deep-down been most dissatisfied with Putin prior to their defection. Thus while spreading Internet access and democratic values may be important for other reasons, faith in their ability to bring down sophisticated nondemocratic regimes may be misplaced at the same time that the power of demography, geography, and contingency may be underestimated. Defection from a Dominant Party: Theory and Expectations micro-level patterns that brought some citizens into open opposition to the regime and not others, or about what structure this spread might have had apart from taking the form of a cascade (Kuran 2011; Patel 2012). 4 Many of the concessions proved to be temporary or were later scaled down, but this rollback occurred mainly after our survey was conducted. 2 In this section, we address the need for theory on precisely how defection spreads across a dominant party’s supporters in the broader population, developing a set of theoretical propositions with testable implications. Since support can take two forms, heartfelt support and preference falsification, we proceed by examining each, beginning with the latter. Since some of the relevant literature does not distinguish between ruling party and regime, and since ruling parties are tightly connected to the regimes they support, we sometimes use the term regime defection cascades with the understanding that defection from a ruling party is typically part of such a cascade. The classic example of someone falsifying their preferences for a dominant party in a non-democratic regime is the greengrocer in Havel’s famous 1978 essay “The Power of the Powerless.” He displays a communist propaganda sign in his shop window despite not believing in it, thereby contributing to the overall sense of permanence of the regime, which in a selffulfilling prophesy then actually makes the regime more stable since others sense that challenging it is futile (Havel 1992). As Kuran (1989, 1991, 1995) shows formally in a series of seminal publications, however, this same logic also explains how such support can disappear suddenly and rapidly once enough people learn how enough other people feel. This preference de-falsification tends to occur in what Lohmann (1994) dubbed “informational cascades”: The first individuals’ expressions of their opposition embolden others to do the same by providing information that others share their actual preferences, with this emboldening effect becoming more powerful the more people join in. Kuran (1991, 1995) also makes the important observation that such cascades involve not only the revelation of preferences that were previously held privately, but the transformation of preferences and a new kind of preference falsification: Some people who were actually ambivalent under the old regime are likely after its demise to present themselves as its die-hard opponents under the influence of the exciting and dramatic cascade process and the disgracing of the previous authorities.5 These theories of regime defection cascades generally concur that patterns of individual dispositions in a society are absolutely crucial to how far such cascades will go and whether they will ultimately bring down a ruling party or regime. Everything depends on individuals’ thresholds for defection. As Granovetter (1978, 1424-5) points out in a seminal paper, if one person’s defection triggers a second, and a third requires that two others defect first, and so on and so on, then the initial person’s defection triggers a chain reaction that can bring everyone out onto the streets. But just raise the third person’s threshold by one, and the cascade of defections never gets beyond the first two people. For this reason, an implication of preference falsification theory is that it is very important for scholars to study what dispositions tend to give people higher or lower thresholds for defection from ruling parties, and it is arguably most important to understand thresholds up until the point where defections become considered a threat to a regime. Curiously, these theorists have not yet seriously attempted to build a theory of individual thresholds. Kuran (1991, pp.21-22) goes the furthest, noting that individual characteristics are at least as important as major structural changes in determining whether an availability cascade takes place and how far it goes. When it comes to what individual characteristics these are, however, he is rather agnostic other than pointing out the obvious: disapproval of the regime. He implies that other individual-level dispositions that drive the unraveling of preference falsification may be peculiar to each case and not generalizable. 5 On this phenomenon more generally in a context other than regimes, see Kuran and Sunstein 1999. 3 What we can propose here is a somewhat bolder effort in the direction that Kuran has pioneered. In fact, these theories of regime defection cascades do lead to several testable propositions that we label as follows. Expectations. Individuals who have less faith in the future of their own dominant party can be expected to have lower thresholds for defection. They will thus likely be among the earlier rather than the later participants in the cascade. Community. Since it is information that this theory holds is causing the cascade, we would expect individuals who are more connected than others to be more susceptible to the cascade. Here we might single out geographic community (in particular, living in large, densely populated cities) and virtual community (connections through access to specific media that can be expected to convey the information). The Internet, and in particular social media, are frequently singled out as vital sources of information independent of non-democratic regimes, so we should expect those who have the most access to it to be among the earlier defectors from a dominant party. Disgruntlement. If people are falsifying their preferences, then we can also follow Kuran in assuming that those who harbor the deepest “real” dissatisfaction are likely to have the lowest thresholds for defection. Since we cannot know from talking to such people who they are (by definition, they falsify their preferences), we can nevertheless examine other factors that are typically sources of discontent with a regime. In particular, we would expect people who have long been suffering economically to have the lowest thresholds for defecting (Treisman 2011). Likewise, those who have long harbored positions on major issues that are at odds with positions they think the ruling party holds are also likely to have lower thresholds for defection. Investment. Since preference de-falsification is a product of expected cost-benefit calculations, it should also be subject to influence by variation in other potential costs and benefits. Thus we would expect those individuals who are likely to have the least personal psychological (or other) investment in the existing regime to have the lowest thresholds for withdrawing that support. While this can vary by context, this would provide grounds for expecting that youth are likely to be among the earlier defectors since they should be most cognitively mobile. In addition, members of social groups favored by the old regime are likely, ceteris paribus, to be among the later rather than earlier defectors. Of course, partisan attachments are also an important form of cognitive investment in a ruling party, so we would expect a ruling party’s partisans to defect later or never rather than earlier. Democracy. Much of the literature on regime defection cascades treats them as democratic episodes, processes by which underlying “real” mass preferences make themselves felt on a regime, producing a change that can be thought of largely as an expression of the popular will. Surely the association of regime defection cascades with democracy is influenced by the fact that this theory gained particular prominence with the fall of communism, which did in some instances result in democracy (Kuran 1991; Lohmann 1994; Pfaff 2006). By these lights, we would expect that ruling party supporters who also harbor more democratic attitudes would tend to have lower thresholds for defection. 4 Of course, not all defection can be expected to reflect preference de-falsification. Instead, another proposition we advance is that regime defection cascades should also reflect some measure of actual change in those views that had previously underpinned support for the ruling party. At least two forms of this phenomenon are likely to be significant. Contingent Regime Gaffes. We cannot treat the regime as static. A ruling party is perfectly capable of taking contingent actions that attract or repel supporters. It would thus make sense if observed defection cascades came after concrete actions to which supporters happened to react negatively. Pocketbook Deterioration. It is also possible that regardless of regime actions, third variables could change that tend to generate support for the ruling party. Perhaps most noteworthy here is the economy. Individuals whose personal economic fortunes have deteriorated might be expected to subsequently downgrade their level of support for the rulers. Thus we also offer one general proposition emerging out of the preceding: Combination of Defection Processes. Waves of defection from a ruling party can typically be expected to feature the withdrawal of heartfelt support and the cascading reversal of preference falsification, in some complex combination, except in the harshest regimes where heartfelt support is almost entirely nonexistent even before defections begin (expected to be quite rare). We leave for further research theory into when each element will likely dominate the other as this is beyond the scope of what we can test here. The Case of United Russia’s Crisis 2011-12: A Panel Survey A panel survey can be a unique tool for empirically testing theories of defection from ruling parties. By interviewing the very same individuals both before a defection cascade and after it, we gain true measures of levels of support (in the sense discussed above) at each point in time that can be compared. Their attitudes and behavior at the two points in time can be systematically compared, allowing us to identify precisely who has defected, who has not, and who might have actually gone against the grain and joined the ruling party in its hour of weakness--a process we cannot rule out entirely. It is justified to argue that these are “true” measures of support because the act of telling a survey researcher who appears at one’s door that one supports the ruling party is itself a form of support. While we cannot tell if this support is heartfelt or preference falsification, either way it is precisely what we are interested in studying. A panel survey thus provides quite direct measures of whether individuals support a ruling party or not both before and after a cascade, enabling us to tell who defects and to test theories as to which individual traits influence defection.6 Russia between 2008 and 2012 presents a strong context for such analysis because: (a) it is widely agreed to be a nondemocratic regime featuring a dominant party, Vladimir Putin’s United Russia Party; (b) this party went from a high water mark of support to a much lower level in precisely this period; (c) observer accounts provide masses of anecdotal evidence there was a 6 Of course, ideally we would have a running measure that could pinpoint exactly when the changes occurred, but since regime defection cascades are widely argued to be highly unpredictable by their very nature and since such surveys are by their nature expensive to conduct, such data are unlikely to be widely available. 5 strong cascading aspects of these defections. United Russia was arguably at the peak of its dominance after winning an outright two-thirds majority (enough to amend the constitution on its own) in the December 2007 Duma elections and then claiming victory in the presidential contest, as its nominee Dmitry Medvedev handily dispatched of all rivals in the March 2008 election (his patron Putin had made room for him by shifting to become prime minister). By fall 2011, however, the party’s standing in the polls had noticeably declined. A crystallizing moment, by some accounts, was Medvedev’s announcement on September 24, 2011, that he was sacrificing his own political ambitions to allow Putin to return to the presidency and the accompanying statement that this had in fact been planned long ago--seemingly casting much of Medvedev’s own presidency as a charade and voters as dupes (Hale 2011b).7 The pre-election decline in support translated into a stunning drop of even its official vote count to below 50 percent in the December 2011 Duma election, revealing the regime either to have been unable or unwilling to “save” the party from its poor result by fraud. Nevertheless, there was considerable public evidence that fraud had kept United Russia’s result from being even worse. In this context, initially small efforts at protest shocked almost all observers (even their organizers8) when they resulted in tens of thousands of people turning up in Moscow’s streets in two major rallies and accompanying events in other cities--the largest such manifestations since the early 1990s. Reports from the scene related euphoria in what seemed to be a sudden public revelation of widespread dissatisfaction with United Russia (and even the regime itself), with a large number of former preference falsifiers now joining the opposition.9 This included many media personalities and other public figures who had before been content to hide any dissatisfaction with the regime in order to make their careers but who now suddenly decided to take a stand. For example, the well-known writer Grigorii Chkhartishvili (pen name Boris Akunin) said in a 2012 interview that he had been somewhat dissatisfied with the regime since Putin was elected to office but had generally stayed out of politics until these events began. He then described his defection from a form of preference falsification to the protest movement in terms that Kuran himself could hardly have improved upon: I considered my “rebelliousness” like a strictly personal gesticulation, not having any social significance. But in December (2011), I saw that around me there had suddenly appeared very many who thought like me. And this was already something serious. Serious enough to make possible putting aside all personal projects. 10 The authorities were stunned as Moscow protests reached over 100,000 people by some accounts. Showing signs of panic, the authorities felt they could not repress such large crowds in this moment of weakness and responded instead with some makeshift liberalizing reforms designed to placate the protesters. This included relaxing the media environment, even allowing on the main television stations some opposition voices that had long been absent except where portrayed in a negative light. The Kremlin then remobilized, conducting a massive campaign to rebuild support for Vladimir Putin and his return to the presidency in the March 2012 election, a campaign that included downplaying the United Russia Party, though he still accepted its nomination. These actions, which still left the fundamental controls on the election process intact 7 Though this event was not obviously reflected in the polls that immediately followed (Sonin 2012). The New Times, December 12, 2011, pp.2-7. 9 See coverage by The New Times and Vedomosti, for example. 10 Boris Akunin (Grigorii Chkhartishvili), interview, “Putinskii period vkhodit v final’nuiu fazu,” The New Times, February 20, 2012, p.6. 8 6 , indeed let the protest movement’s steam largely blow out and allowed Putin to recover his support. By the time of his reelection victory, United Russia’s ratings had recovered somewhat too, far behind its 2008 levels but still comfortably ahead of all rival parties even by the most independent surveys. Nevertheless, many were still predicting the party’s continued decline at this time (e.g., Kommersant 2012). What apparently happened in 2011-12, then, is at a minimum a significant wave of defection from United Russia and, by many anecdotal accounts, a cascading process of preference de-falsification that the regime was ultimately able to staunch through limited tactical concessions and a countermobilization that built on strong genuine support that the regime had long been believed to hold among certain large segments of the population. This case, then, would seem to provide an excellent chance to study who among a party’s supporters at the peak of its dominance were the first to abandon it and to have maintained their withdrawal of support. We were able to measure the “before” and “after” levels of support (broadly defined as above) through the Russian Election Studies (RES) series of surveys of voting-age subjects that the present authors regularly conduct right after Russian federal election cycles with the Moscow-based Demoscope survey research organization. Crucially, the spring 2008 and spring 2012 surveys included a panel component, asking the same set of voters each time many questions pertinent to both the parliamentary elections (held in December 2007 and 2011) and the presidential elections (held in March 2008 and 2012).11 This survey thus captured the high water mark of the United Russia Party’s dominance in March-May 2008 and spanned the party’s 2011-12 nadir, with the second wave coming in April-May 2012, just after Putin’s and United Russia’s ratings had begun to recover. Our panel consists of 661 people whom we were able to reinterview in 2012 from the original 2008 sample of 1,130. Naturally, the set of successfully reinterviewed people cannot be considered nationally representative of the adult population in 2012. For one thing, it will exclude people who were too young to be polled in 2008 but who were adults by 2012. Some older people will likely have passed away during the four intervening years, though others will have aged. It may be that other variables of interest are also under- or overrepresented in the sample. To get a better sense of how severe this issue is, we test whether any of the factors that interest us as possible correlates of dominant party defection are indeed correlated with selection into the sample. Table 1 reports the findings using a logit model, with the dependent variable being whether a respondent drops out of the sample and coefficients reported as odds ratios to give a basic sense of how strong any such relationships are. While a discussion of what the different variables included are will be presented below when we discuss our model and findings, here it is sufficient to note that only two variables of 11 The surveys, as with all RES surveys, are based on a multistage area probability sample designed to be nationally representative for Russia by Mikhail Kosolapov of the Russian Academy of Sciences’ Institute of Sociology and Michael Swafford of the George Washington University in consultation with Steve Heeringa of the University of Michigan. The first wave discussed in the present paper included 1,130 respondents and was taken March 18 - May 8, 2008. Of these respondents, 661 were successfully reinterviewed in 2012 during the period April 1 - May 18, 2012. These 661 were supplemented during the same period by another 1,021 respondents to compose a nationally representative sample for 2012 consisting of 1,682 respondents. Demoscope is highly reputable and oriented to academic studies, conducting each of the RES surveys since 1995 as well as surveys for noted scholars such as Donna Bahry and James Gibson, whose findings have been published in the field’s leading journals. All RES surveys have been co-led by Timothy Colton, with Hale co-leading the effort for the three most recent election cycles (2003-04, 2008, and 2012). These data, which will enable replication and other studies, are being prepared for general release to scholars in the near future. 7 primary interest are statistically significantly (using 95 percent confidence intervals) correlated with dropping out of the sample between 2008 and 2012. Those living in larger urban communities and men are more likely to drop out. Presumably, this is because they are more mobile populations in the Russian context. While we will provide reason to expect both variables to be related to defection from a ruling party, the concept of mobility is not part of this logic. Thus we do not expect this slightly patterned sample attrition to significantly impact our findings even for these two variables other than potentially to reduce the chances we find them significant since we have fewer datapoints on them to analyze. To confirm, we ran the main regression analysis reported below with a Heckman probit selection model, which models the attrition process as well as the equation of primary interest. This exercise resulted in no substantial change in our findings, including the significance of community size and gender.12 Table 1. Correlates of Dropping Out of the Panel 2008-12 (N/S = not significant) Odds 95% Conf. More/Less Variable Ratio Interval Likely to Drop Out Larger size of community (quintiles) 2008 1.56* 1.01 - 2.40 More Likely Education 2008 0.91 0.80 - 1.04 N/S Russian 2008 0.99 0.47 - 2.11 N/S Age 2008 0.99 0.98 - 1.00 N/S Orthodox 2008 1.11 0.67 - 1.85 N/S Woman 2008 0.68** 0.51 - 0.90 Less Likely Gained materially from 2000s 2008 0.93 0.76 - 1.13 N/S On the political right 2008 0.97 0.85 - 1.11 N/S “Democracy” good for Russia 2008 1.05 0.78 - 1.43 N/S Left-right stance differs from United Russia’s 2008 0.99 0.90 - 1.09 N/S United Russia Partisan 2008 0.92 0.60 - 1.41 N/S Approval of Putin Performance 2008 0.88 0.71 - 1.10 N/S Internet user 2008 1.33 0.90 - 1.99 N/S Internet most important news source 2008 0.92 0.21 - 4.12 N/S REN-TV news viewer 2008 0.75 0.50 - 1.13 N/S Radio news listener 2008 0.66 0.39 - 1.10 N/S N=1,130. * Statistically significant at the 5% level. ** Statistically significant at the 1% level Defecting from United Russia We adopt as our chief measure of support whether a respondent said that they voted for United Russia in a given election. Readers are reminded that we are not interested here in whether respondents who said they cast a ballot for the party actually did so; instead, we are interested in broadly defined support that includes both heartfelt support and preference falsification. A statement to an interviewer that one voted for United Russia even when one did not actually do so is nevertheless a form of support for the party, albeit of the preference 12 The more data-taxing Heckman probit results are not presented here, but are available upon request, and instead we report the more easily interpretable logit findings. The variables we included for the estimation of selection were community size, gender, and whether a respondent reported having children living with them at home, which is likely to be strongly correlated with mobility but not with defection. The estimated value of rho is -.57, where a value of 1 indicates no selection effects on the results whatsoever. Nevertheless, only the variable capturing education levels (not one of primary interest) drops out of the 95-percent confidence range when the switch is made from logit to Heckman probit, but the drop is slight, moving just to 94.1 percent confidence from a level of 97.6 percent not using the Heckman probit technique. 8 falsification variety. Reading the results in this light, our survey registers a net decline in United Russia support amongst the population between 2008 and 2012. As Table 2 illustrates, such dominant party supporters constituted 45 percent of the population in 2008 and just 40 in 2012. This change gets reduced somewhat when we move from the whole survey population to the set of respondents in the panel, those who were successfully reinterviewed. In the panel, 51 percent claimed to have voted for United Russia in 2008 and 49 percent in 2012. Of course, the figures here for 2012 reflect not only United Russia’s losses relative to 2008, which anecdotal evidence suggests were significant, but also new supporters that the party managed to bring in on the coattails of Putin’s “comeback” presidential election campaign in the first part of 2012. Since the 2008 United Russia supporters in our panel are our population of interest, Table 3 provides more information about their dispositions as of 2008. Table 2. Percentage of United Russia Supporters in 2008 and 2012 (Shares Saying They Voted for United Russia in 2007 and 2011) In Whole Survey In Panel 45 51 In 2008 Survey 40 49 In 2012 Survey Table 3. Profile of United Russia’s 2008 Supporters in the Panel From Moscow and St. Petersburg Specialized secondary or higher education Ethnic Russian Orthodox Female Average age Reported their family’s personally gaining from 2000s reforms Mean position on left-right scale (0=left, 5=center, 10=right) Mean position attributed to United Russia Party on same left-right scale Supported continuing, deepening market reform Thought democracy is at least a fairly good fit for Russia Transitional partisans of United Russia (Colton 2000) Approved of Putin’s performance as president Used the Internet Considered the Internet their primary news source Watched news on state-controlled First Channel Watched news on the more independent REN-TV Listened to news on radio 5% 75% 79% 78% 62% 46 34% 6.1 7.8 66% 64% 48% 77% 24% 2% 87% 21% 23% We the panel down into four categories with respect to whether respondents claim to have voted for United Russia in 2007 and/or 2011. These are summarized in Table 4. We dub loyalists those individuals, comprising about a third of our panel, who both times claim to have cast their ballots for Russia’s dominant party. We call oppositionists those who would not say in either wave of the survey that they voted for it, a category making up another third of the panel respondents. The category that interests us most here is the defectors: those who claimed in 2008 to have voted for United Russia in 2007, but told survey researchers in 2012 that they had not done so in 2011. About 17 percent of our panel falls into this category. This is slightly more than the 15 percent turning up in the category of joiners, those who did not support United Russia in 2008 but wound up supporting it in our 2012 survey. 9 Table 4. Patterns of Self-Reported Voting for United Russia (percentage of panel, n=661) Defectors (support 2008, no support 2012) 17 Loyalists (support in 2008 & 2012) 34 Joiners (no support 2008, support 2012) 15 Oppositionists (no support 2008 & 2012) 34 Where did the defectors say they went in 2012 and where did the joiners come from? Tables 5 and 6 indicate that in both cases, a plurality moved in or out of the category of selfdeclared nonvoters. Some 44 percent of defectors said that they did not vote at all in 2011, while 39 percent of joiners had said in 2008 that they did not cast a ballot in the 2007 Duma election. A tenth of defectors and a fifth of joiners moved in and out (respectively) of the category of those unable or unwilling to venture a response, which Carnaghan (1996) finds can indicate a form of apathy or withdrawal. When defectors did say they went to the polls in 2011, they tended most often to support A Just Russia, which observers typically consider a loyal opposition party (March 2009) but which did take a sharply critical line against the Kremlin and United Russia in 2011 (Hale 2011b). The LDPR, which captured 8 percent of our defectors’ self-reported votes, is also widely regarded as a loyal opposition party, though one interpreted as regularly capturing protest votes due to its leader Vladimir Zhirinovsky’s fiery rhetoric. The more clearly opposition Communist Party and Yabloko Party got 14 percent and 3 percent of defectors’ self-reported votes, respectively, and another 1 percent claimed to have spoiled their ballots. About two-fifths of joiners came from other parties, mostly A Just Russia and the KPRF. Table 5. For Which Parties Did Defectors Say They Voted in 2012? Party Percent of Defectors (n=108) A Just Russia 19 LDPR 8 Communist Party 14 Yabloko 3 Right Cause 1 Spoiled ballot 1 Did not vote 44 Hard to say/refuse 10 Table 6. For Which Parties Did Joiners Say They Voted in 2008? Party Percent of Joiners (n=97) Agrarian Party 2 Civic Force 0.1 Democratic Party 1 Communist Party 18 LDPR 4 A Just Russia 11 Patriots of Russia 1 Yabloko 1 Spoiled ballot 3 Did not vote 39 Hard to say/refuse 19 10 Analysis As noted above, the data tell us that about a third of respondents in our panel switched either to or from supporting United Russia, with the share of defectors being a bit larger than the share of joiners. One possibility is that this movement reflects standard measurement error that is typical of any survey: surveys are imperfect measures of true dispositions that can be thrown off by t imperfect question wording, interviewer effects, and respondents’ own awareness or mood on a given day (Green, Palmquist, & Schickler 2002). Because such factors are random with respect to the important variables in our study, if this were the only explanation for the difference between the two waves in our panel survey, we should not find theoretically interesting variables to be systematically correlated with defection from (or joining) United Russia. As the tables below make clear, this is not the case; instead, we seem to be dealing with nonrandom changes in support for United Russia between 2008 and 2012. To study patterns of defection, we start with the entire set of 516 respondents in our 2008 survey who originally said that year they had cast a ballot for United Russia in the December 2007 Duma elections. Of these, 334 were successfully reinterviewed in the 2012 wave of the RES. Among this set, we created a dummy variable coded 1 for those who defected in 2012 and 0 for those who did not. This is our primary dependent variable, and since it is binary, it is appropriate to use the well-established logit model. Following Miller and Shanks (1996) and Colton (2000), we report the magnitude of the “effects” as total effects since these are highly intuitive.13 A total effect is the change in likelihood of defection that would be generated by an otherwise average individual (someone who has the median score on all other relevant variables) moving from the lowest value of a given factor to the highest value. The analysis proceeds in four main steps. First, we consider the overall pattern of defection we find in the data using only predictors from 2008, where we have the most confidence that we are free of endogeneity concerns. Second, we test those parts of the theory elaborated above that can only be evaluated with data gathered in 2012. Third, we explore the determinants of different patterns of defection, considering why some defect by moving to true opposition parties while others simply decide not to vote. And fourth, we present an analysis of patterns among those who began in 2008 as non-supporters of United Russia but in 2012 joined it, going against the overall flow overall but likely responding to state authorities’ comeback effort in early 2012. For the sake of presentation, we discuss the specific measures we use for the different propositions as we present the results, referring readers to an appendix for the specific wording of the survey questions utilized. Predicting Defection in 2012 with Only 2008 Measures Table 7 presents the findings and a summary interpretation of the correlates of mass defection from United Russia between 2008 and 2012. We begin by considering only those theories we can test with independent variables measured in 2008 so as to minimize problems of endogeneity. That is, since the defection occurred only after the 2008 survey was taken but all independent variables come from 2008 survey, it cannot be the case that the act of defection influenced any of the values of the independent variables. These findings are presented in the Regression 1 column of Table 7. 13 We calculate them using the software CLARIFY with Stata. CLARIFY generates estimates of total effects from highly opaque logit (and multinomial logit) coefficients through a stochastic simulation technique (King, Tomz, and Wittenberg 2000; and Tomz, Wittenberg, and King 2003). 11 Table 7. Correlates of Defecting from United Russia 2008-2012 (among panel respondents who reported voting for United Russia in 2008, logit model, total effects [percent] with 95-percent confidence interval, N=334) 1. 2. Total Effect Total Effect Interpretation* Variable (95% conf.) (95% conf.) (N/S = not significant) Larger community size (quintiles) 2008 41 36 Defection more likely (23, 58) (18, 54) Education 2008 -16 -10 N/S (-36, 4) (-32, 10) Russian 2008 13 12 Defection more likely (5, 22) (4, 21) Age 2008 -27 -22 Defection less likely (-46, -8) (-41, -2) Orthodox 2008 3 1 N/S (-10, 13) (-13, 11) Woman -14 -12 Defection less likely (-25, -4) (-23, -1) Gained from 2000s 2008 0 -3 N/S (-18, 19) (-20, 14) On the political right 2008 -11 13 N/S (-12, 31) (-11, 34) Democracy good for Russia 2008 -33 -31 Defection less likely (-58, -10) (-57, -7) Diverges from United Russia on left-right 46 51 Defection more likely (14, 72) (18, 75) United Russia partisan 2008 0 0 N/S (-9, 8) (-9, 10) Approves Putin 2008 -26 -18 (Defection less likely) t (-56, -1) (-48, 6) Internet user 2008 -4 -6 N/S (-14, 7) (-15, 4) Internet is main news source 2008 16 5 N/S (-14, 57) (-18, 49) REN-TV news watcher 2008 4 2 N/S (-7, 16) (-8, 14) Radio news listener 2008 6 9 N/S (-4, 20) (-2, 23) Negative reaction to September 24 41 Defection more likely (18, 64) Other party has chance to win in 10 years 11 Defection more likely v (0, 24) Own family’s situation better in last year -32 Defection less likely (-56, -7) * Statistical significance threshold: 5% level. t Statistically significant at the 5.1% level in the logit analysis in regression analysis 1, but the CLARIFY stochastic simulation estimate of the total effects rules out a null effect with 95 percent confidence. Not significant in equation 2 by either measure. v Comfortably statistically significant at the 4.4% level in the logit analysis, but the CLARIFY stochastic simulation estimations of the total effects just barely do not rule out a null effect with 95 percent confidence. 12 One of the most striking findings concerns community effects: Defection appears to spread far more by physical geography than by virtual society despite the attention frequently given to the Internet by analysts. Not a single pattern of media usage in 2008 is correlated with defection in 2012: United Russia supporters who watched more independent television news, got news from the radio, or relied primarily on the Internet for news in 2008 were no more or less likely to abandon their party four years later than anyone else. On the other hand, we find a very large effect for community size: United Russia supporters who lived in the largest cities were 41 percent more likely than those living in the smallest communities to jump party ship. This supports the analysis of Russian geographers and sociologists who have argued that there is a large divide politically between Russia’s largest cities and the rest of the country (Gudkov 2012; Zubarevich 2011). That said, contrary to some accounts, we found nothing special about Moscow and St. Petersburg in this regard; this wave of defection was more about larger urban areas generally.14 We also find strong confirmation for the argument that defection cascades are likely first to sweep up people whose underlying views had been in disagreement with the ruling party but who had been its supporters nevertheless. We tested this in several ways. Initially, we asked them in 2008 simply whether they approved of the activity of Vladimir Putin as president, Putin having headed United Russia’s party list in the 2011 parliamentary election. As Regression 1 in Table 7 reveals, people who had approved of his performance in 2008 were 26 percent less likely to defect when 2012 rolled around, though this effect was on the verge of our 5-percent statistical significance threshold. More impressive is the finding from a second measure we constructed more directly for this purpose: By asking respondents in 2008 where they placed themselves on an 11-point scale ranging from the far political left (0) to the far political right (10) and then asking them where they placed thought the United Russia Party stood on this same scale, we were able to construct an index capturing the distance between their self-positioning and the ruling party’s perceived position.15 This disagreement in political orientation turns out to be a very strong predictor of defection: Those whose policy views diverged completely from the ruling party’s on this scale in 2008 were an impressive 46 percentage points more likely to defect in 2012 than were those who had been in agreement with it. And what mattered is precisely disagreement with the ruling party rather than left-right self-placement itself; one’s own left-right positioning in 2008 does not afford us significant leverage on predicting who will defect in 2012. This pattern of underlying disgruntlement-driven defection did not appear to extend to selfreported “pocketbook” considerations, however: Individuals who reported in 2008 having done more poorly in material economic terms as a result of the Putin-era reforms were no more likely to defect in 2012 than others. The panel study also finds that personal investment in a ruling party influences who defects first, though in some counterintuitive ways. Consistent with expectations is that younger people, who are expected to have less psychological investment in party-supportive behavior, are more likely to defect and, conversely, older people, more dependent on the regime economically, are less likely to defect: The oldest were 27 percent less likely to defect than the youngest. 14 That is, when we included a variable coding whether a respondent lived in Moscow or St. Petersburg, it had no significant effect if the community size variable was also included. This result is robust and available upon request. 15 We coded as 0 (reflecting no distance) individuals who could not place either themselves or United Russia on this scale because we are interested in people who definitely declared in 2008 a difference in policy positioning between themselves and the party they supported. 13 Two other findings on personal investments might at first seem surprising. One is that self-identified ethnic Russians turn out to be 13 percent more likely to defect than ethnic minorities, which should be unexpected for those seeing Russian nationalism as a key source of Putin’s support. Careful prior survey research, however, has found that such a view is misguided, and that Putin and United Russia have in fact not tended to draw significantly on Russian nationalism (Colton and Hale 2009, 486). Moreover, the finding that ethnic Russians are actually more likely to defect makes perfect sense keeping in mind that many ethnic minorities in Russia have long been found to be a core source of official votes and support for United Russia. Importantly, this support is to a significant degree institutionalized and enforced by strong political machines based in autonomous ethnic republics that are often highly dependent on the central authorities (Hale 2003, 2006; Zimmerman 2009; Zubarevich 2011). This finding thus indicates that these sorts of personal investments in a ruling party tend to slow defection. Also remarkable is a negative finding, the robust insignificance of partisan identification in retarding defection. Those 48 percent of 2008 United Russia supporters who displayed the strongest personal attachments to it turned out to be no more loyal than the others in 2012 when the party hit a crisis.16 Thus while United Russia has been building up partisans since its founding in the early 2000s, this would appear to be providing it with cold comfort at best. Perhaps most surprising for those who interpret regime defection cascades in the framework of democratization (which would appear to be most) is the following sturdy result: Those United Russia supporters who averred in 2008 that a “democratic system” is a “very good” fit for Russia were 33 percent less likely to defect from the party in 2012 than were those who had thought it was a “very bad” fit. This finding is robust to many different combinations of other variables in the equation, and so cannot easily be dismissed as an artifact of the uncertainty that all regression analyses involve. As it turns out, the RES allows us to rule out a number of different possibilities and check consistency with various attempts to explain the result away. For one thing, the 2008 survey asked respondents to state in their own words what they meant by democracy, and a coding of the responses found that the United Russia loyalists in our sample did not have any more non-standard definitions of democracy than did others--in fact, they were more likely than others to define democracy much as Western researchers do.17 We also considered whether this result reflected the fact that we were coding “don’t know” and “refuse” answers as average responses (see Carnaghan 1996), but dropping them changed neither the significance nor the sign of the coefficient. Instead, this finding appears to reflect that at least part of United Russia’s fall in support involved the departure of anti-democratic people from its ranks in greater measure than that of the democrats who had been in its ranks as of 2008. Nearly a fifth of United Russia supporters in 2008 who supported democracy did defect, but a much greater proportion of “authoritarians” bolted the party in its moment of crisis, mostly moving to other parties with dubious democratic credentials (like the Communists, Vladimir Zhirinovsky’s LDPR, and A Just Russia) or to the ranks of self-reported non-voters. And among United Russia supporters in 2008 who said The measure reported in Tables 7 is Colton’s (2000) standard “transitional partisanship,” which records as a party’s “partisan” anyone who names that party (without being given a list) when asked if there is any party they would call “my party” or if there is at least one that “more than the others reflects your interests, views, and concerns.” This negative finding holds even when other measures of partisanship are used, including what Hale (2006) has called “hard core transitional partisanship” and a very different measure of partisanship drawing from social psychology and used productively by Green, Palmquist, and Schickler (2002) in Western contexts. 17 On how Russian understandings of “democracy” sometimes differ from Western ones, see Carnaghan 2007; Hale 2011a; Levada Center 2006; Rose, Mishler, & Munro 2006. See also Smyth (forthcoming).. 16 14 unequivocally that democracy was a good fit for Russia, only 4 percent said at the same time that they would prioritize democracy over economic growth and only a quarter would privilege it over a strong state, with these figures being even lower for those less confident in their support for democracy. In short, it would appear that United Russia’s 2008 democracy supporters were not systematically driven by any personal democratic awakening. Instead, the party’s more antidemocratic backers were among those quickest to leave the apparently sinking ship. Perhaps, somewhat ironically, they were concerned that United Russia was weakening as a nondemocratic force as pro-democracy protests and sentiments appeared to be in ascendancy. Defection cascades from a dominant party, therefore, appear not to be about democratic awakening--at least, when it comes to those who can be expected to cut bait first. Expectations, Contingency, and Pocketbooks: 2012 Measures Some of the theoretical expectations discussed above can only be studied with measures included in our survey solely in the 2012 wave, so in a second model we added a set of such variables. While we now must wrestle with questions about whether the act of defection might have caused (instead of be caused by) the dispositions we find associated it, the fact that we are only looking here for correlations that are derived from theory adds confidence that significant relationships, when found, actually do reflect at least some cause and not just effect. These findings are reported as Regression 2 in Table 7. At the outset, we observe that addition of these new variables does not substantially change any of the main findings from the 2008 variables discussed above except the significance of approving Putin’s performance. Turning to hypotheses that have not yet been tested, Regression 2 allows us to confirm that United Russia supporters who calculated that another party registered at the time had a chance of coming to power in the next ten years were 11 percent more likely than others to have defected.18 This is firmly in line with theories of preference de-falsification, since the informational cascades they describe hinge on beliefs about whether individuals’ actions are likely to be punished or rewarded in the future. The 2012 RES also confirms that people who reported their family’s economic fortunes had gotten much worse over the preceding dozen months were an impressive 32 percent more likely to defect than were those who reported doing much better. Finally, we find confirmation that contingent regime gaffes can promote defection, alienating former supporters. In particular, we test here whether negative reactions to the September 24, 2011, “switcheroo” announcement gaffe is associated with defection from United Russia. It turns out that 2008-vintage United Russia supporters who reported in 2012 being “offended” by the announcement were 41 percent more likely to have defected by 2012 than are those who expressed “satisfaction” with the announcement. Since some readers are likely to find the negative results on the Internet’s influence surprising and wonder whether 2008 was too early to capture the most politically important Internet usage patterns for 2011-12, we also tried adding to Regression 2 several Internet-related variables created from 2012 survey responses. In particular, we tested whether defection was correlated with self-reported internet use for any purpose, use of the Internet as one’s primary source of news, and engagement with social networks like Facebook or the popular Russian Odnoklassniki (“Classmates”) or vKontakte (inContact). The results are in each case The importance of expectations as to the future prospects of the ruling party and other parties’ could in principle have been tested with 2008 data if we had asked the right question in the survey that year, but even if we had, expectations are not expected to be stable like most of the other dispositions discussed above, thus in practice they need to be measured much closer to the actual act of defection. 18 15 insignificant, not even close.19 These negative findings hold even when we employ finer-grained measures, detecting no statistically significant evidence that those who reported using various social media (either lumped together or separated into Facebook, Odnoklassniki, and vKontakte) in 2012 were any more likely to defect than anyone else. Defection from a ruling party, whether or not this is unlike street protest, does not appear to be about the Internet. Explaining Different Kinds of Defection While the main story is that summarized in Table 7, our study also finds some important nuances in the precise form defection took. As summarized in Table 5, some defectors said they voted for another party, while others declared that they did not vote at all. Table 8 thus goes a step beyond Regression 2 in Table 7, reporting results from a multinomial logit analysis that tells us what variables are correlated with different sorts of defection. We divide defection up into three categories.20 The first is a shift to supporting the two Russian parties on the ballot in 2011 that were widely regarded as true opposition parties, the Communist Party and the Yabloko Party. The second category consists of supporting parties other than United Russia that were on the ballot but that are widely regarded as “virtual parties,” either having been created with Kremlin assistance or working in relatively close concert with the authorities, even though some were in quite sharp opposition to United Russia during the 2011 campaign (Hale 2011b; March 2009; Wilson 2005).21 We include in the third category everyone who does not report that they voted for a party, which Table 5 indicates is mainly people who said they did not vote.22 The fourth category, used as the baseline in the multinomial logit analysis, is the set of people who did not defect, sticking with United Russia through its time of crisis. For ease of interpretation, only effects estimated with at least 95-percent statistical confidence are reported in Table 8. Even though the multinomial logit approach is more taxing on the data, it is worth noting that the variables found to be significant in Table 7 generally remain significant here, testifying to their robustness. What is of primary interest here, though, is the set of factors that distinguish different forms of defection rather than those that make defection generally more or less likely, so we focus on this set here. One noteworthy finding confirms that expectations about other parties’ future prospects matter: Those 2008 United Russia supporters who thought in 2012 that a party other than the ruling party had a chance to come to power in the next decade tended not to drop out of politics but instead to defect to one of these alternative parties, with a 3 percent greater chance of moving to a real opposition party and a 12 percent greater probability of shifting to a virtual opposition party, compared with otherwise typical individuals. 19 These findings are not reported here due to the insignificance, but are available upon request. Since multinomial logit is taxing on data, we do not have enough observations to allow for a finer-grained analysis, with more than three categories. 21 These include A Just Russia, the LDPR, Pravoe Delo (Right Cause), and Patriots of Russia. 22 This also includes people who spoiled their ballots, found it hard to say, or declared support for a nonexistent party (a very rare volunteered response) which for our purposes also constitute forms of defection but not to any particular party registered at the time. 20 16 Table 8. Correlates of Different forms of Defecting from United Russia 2008-2012 (reporting only effects estimated with at least 95-percent confidence, multinomial logit model, total effects [percent], N=334) ‘Real’ ‘Virtual’ Opposition Opposition Non-Voting No Variable Party Party Defection Larger community size (quintiles) 2008 32 -37 (13, 53) (-57, -17) Education 2008 Russian 2008 3 (1, 7) * (-) Age 2008 -19 (-36, -4) 23 (4, 44) Orthodox 2008 Woman * (-) * (+) -16 (-45, -1) 33 (8, 62) -55 (-80, -19) Gained from 2000s 2008 On the political right 2008 8 (1, 28) Democracy good for Russia 2008 Diverges from United Russia on left-right United Russia partisan 2008 Approves Putin 2008 -21 (-65, -1) Internet user 2008 Internet is main news source 2008 REN-TV news watcher 2008 Radio news listener 2008 Negative reaction to September 24 Other party has chance to win in 10 years 3 (0.45, 12) Own family’s situation better in last year 14 (1, 42) 12 (3, 29) -12 (-33, -1) 26 (4, 53) -44 (-68, -18) 30 (6, 56) * Statistically significant at the 5-percent level in a regression with only the variables measured in 2008. (-) = negative correlation, (+) = positive correlation. Of special interest are variables associated with defection to a true opposition party since this is arguably the strongest form of defection. Table 8 shows that only a handful of factors tended to drive 2008 United Russia supporters to such lengths. One is ideology: people who 17 consider themselves to be on the far political right were 8 percent more likely to defect to a real opposition party than typical individuals who happened to be on the far political left. A stronger factor, however, was their attitude toward Putin’s performance in presidential office as of 2008: those who most disapproved tended with a total effect of 21 percent to defect to the Communists or Yabloko but did not stand out for any other form of defection. This also indicates that other forms of defection were preferred by people who were a bit softer in their attitude toward Putin. United Russia supporters who defected to a virtual opposition party tended to stand out for being ethnically Russian (3 percent total effect), having a negative reaction to the September 24 “switcheroo” announcement (14 percent total effect), and having suffered a decline in material fortunes during the twelve months prior to being interviewed. This is quite in keeping with the common view that such parties, especially the LDPR and A Just Russia, tend to pick up protest votes and also emphasize Russian nationalist themes (Hale 2006; Laruelle **). It is also interesting that precisely these parties tended to attract United Russia defectors who had the least democratic attitudes, not the most; the other categories of defection do not stand out on the democracy variable. Since parties in this category have some of the most dubious democratic credentials--especially the LDPR, which has perhaps most openly flirted with advocating a dictatorial style of rule under the charismatic Zhirinovsky--this tends to confirm the interpretation given above that regime defection cascades are not actually about democratic views, but can actually reflect the most authoritarian members abandoning political ship. There is somewhat weaker evidence that younger and male United Russia supporters from 2008 tended to defect to these parties, though youth also stood out for declaring themselves alienated from the political process. A “non-voting” option also tended to be preferred by those who lived in larger communities as opposed to smaller ones (a total effect of 32 percent) and those who reacted most negatively to the “switcheroo” announcement. Patterns among United Russia Joiners Just to make sure that defectors from United Russia are not being replaced by virtually identical joiners, a pattern that might suggest we are only witnessing some kind of structured fluctuation in and out of party support instead of patterned defection, we also conducted an analysis of the 327 people in our panel who were not United Russia supporters in 2008 to see who had joined United Russia by 2012. Remarkably, our central finding is the statistical insignificance of almost all of the variables considered in our analysis of defection presented above. The only variable observed in 2008 that turns out to have been a good predictor of which non-supporters of United Russia would become its supporters in 2012 was whether respondents approved of Putin’s performance in office as president. People who fully approved of Putin but were not United Russia supporters in 2008 were 40 percent more likely than others to be pulled into the ruling party’s orbit by 2012. This strongly suggests that while defection is highly patterned in the ways anticipated by theory, the people that the party was able to regain were drawn primarily by personal attachments to Putin himself. This makes a great deal of sense in the context of Russian events. As was discussed above, after suffering a large wave of defection reflected in official voting results and tracking polls, the party’s recovery came on the heels of Putin’s comeback in the 2012 presidential campaign where his personal status as father of the nation was emphasized and United Russia’s qualities as a party deemphasized, though he did still run as the party’s nominee. This conclusion is reinforced when we include the 2012 variables in the equation just as we did in our study of defection. Approval of Putin remains the only significant variable from 2008, and 18 among the 2012 variables, we find only that non-supporters of United Russia who reacted negatively to the September 24 “switcheroo” announcement were 59 percent less likely to be joiners than others while those who thought another party had a chance to come to power in the next ten years were 11 percent less likely to fall into this category. Thus while the party’s net support in spring 2012 looked on the surface not too dissimilar to spring 2008, the losses from the defection wave were being compensated for by attracting a different sort of person, primarily those drawn to Putin’s personality but who had not earlier been party supporters.23 Conclusion Our unique panel survey data spanning a limited but significant cascade in defection from the ruling United Russia Party between 2008 and 2012 provides significant leverage in starting to develop theory as to the behavioral micro-foundations of how non-democratic regimes lose support. Understanding such defection is essential for understanding authoritarian endurance, revolution, and regime dynamics because ruling parties are widely considered a critical source of regime stability and since the withdrawal of support for them (particularly in the form of unraveling preference falsification) has been widely linked to their regimes’ collapse. Our study finds that such defections, while often linked in the public imagination to social media and the emergence of democratic values, in fact has little to do with either. Ruling party defectors in Russia did not stand out for any particular kind of media use, and actually turned out to be among the more authoritarian elements of the party’s initial support base. This suggests that defection is more about hard-headed, rational calculations of political futures and that these calculations are much more influenced by what people see and hear in their physical environments than what they read or watch online. Indeed, defection was far more likely among those who lived in the largest cities and thought that opposition parties had a real chance of coming to power in the coming decade. Disgruntlement with the regime was also a powerful predictor of defection: United Russia supporters who nevertheless in 2008 reported liking Putin less and being in disagreement on policy issues with their party were much more likely to defect when the party hit a crisis in 2011-12, as where those who reported that their families had suffered materially over the past year and who were most put off by a major regime gaffe in autumn 2011. The regime certainly had its defenses, on which our analysis also sheds light. For one thing, both Putin and his party retained substantial approval ratings despite the unexpected sharp drop in support, and this mattered in the end: the primary factor driving defectors into the most die-hard opposition camp was underlying dissatisfaction with Putin’s performance as president, so the fact that most were in fact satisfied provided a sort of backstop for the regime. And the regime’s creation of a set of virtual parties, entities that trumpeted opposition rhetoric but retained close ties with (and potentially being in subordination to) the rulers, also helped ease the impact of the defection wave: Most defectors who chose an alternative party actually went over to these parties rather than to the true opposition, probably representing a more psychologically comfortable move for those who our survey revealed were not entirely dissatisfied with Putin themselves. We thus gain insight not only into how defection cascades spread, but also into how 23 As the vast majority of variables are insignificant, tables for these regressions are not reported here due to space considerations, though they are available upon request from the authors. In one version of the analysis, we find that people who relied on the Internet as their primary news source in 2008 were significantly less likely to join than otherwise median respondents, but this effect was unstable, and in any case, only about 2 percent of the population fell into this category so even if it were significant, it could explain at best only a small share of joiners. 19 regimes might be able to stop them. Those party supporters with significant investments in the regime were also slow to defect, especially the old and ethnic minorities, though one of our most surprising findings was that the party loyalties United Russia had been building up over the past decade proved no barrier for the defection cascade. Partisanship may still matter, but at a minimum this finding suggests that it may take more time to gel before it can truly shore up a regime’s support. While our findings contribute support for a set of theoretical propositions that should be tested in other environments where possible, they also do constitute something of a warning sign to the subject of our case study, Russia’s regime. While some of the regime’s defenses were working, the ineffectiveness of partisanship bodes ill for its future prospects. Moreover, we found that while United Russia was apparently successful in replacing most of its defectors with new “recruits” by late spring 2012 on the coattails of Putin’s all-out campaign for election to a third presidential term, the new joiners were of a different quality from those that were lost. The newcomers were drawn nearly randomly from the population, not reflecting any of the deep or patterned connections with the electorate that has previously been found to be correlated with support for both the ruling party and its leadership in the past. Instead, they were attracted mainly by approval of Putin’s performance in office. And since performance evaluations are fragile, our study may also have picked up a crucial episode in the deterioration of one of the world’s hitherto most successful non-democratic regimes. Defection from a ruling party in a non-democratic regime, then, appears to be primarily about geographic community rather than virtual community, about rational career-oriented calculations of the future rather than democratic values, and about attitudes toward the party and regime that are subject to fluctuation based on contingent regime gaffes, perceived policy shifts, and the vicissitudes of the economy. While regimes can take some defensive actions, such as the creation of virtual parties and appeal to a charismatic leader, ultimately these are likely to be effective only when the regime itself retains substantial public support through performance. REFERENCES Beissinger, Mark R. 2011. “Mechanisms of Maidan: The Structure of Contingency in the Making of the Orange Revolution,” Mobilization: An International Journal, v.16, no.1, pp.25-43. Beissinger, Mark R. 2013. “The Semblance of Democratic Revolution: Coalitions in Ukraine’s Orange Revolution,” American Political Science Review, v.107, no.3, August, pp.574-92. Brownlee, Jason. 2007. Authoritarianism in the Age of Democratization (New York: Cambridge University Press). Carnaghan, Ellen. 1996. “Alienation, Apathy, or Ambivalence? ‘Don’t Knows’ and Democracy in Russia,” Slavic Review, v.55, no.2, Summer 1996, pp.325-363. Carnaghan, Ellen. 2007. Out of Order: Russian Political Values in an Imperfect World (University Park, Pennsylvania: Pennsylvania State University Press). Colton, Timothy J. 2000. Transitional Citizens: Voters and What Influences Them in the New Russia (Cambridge: Harvard University Press). Colton, Timothy J., and Henry E. Hale. 2009a. “The Putin Vote: Presidential Electorates in a Hybrid Regime,” Slavic Review 68 (3): 473-503. Colton, Timothy J., and Henry E. Hale. 2009b. “What Makes Dominant Parties Dominant in Hybrid Regimes? The Unlikely Importance of Ideas in the Case of United Russia,” paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Association for the Advancement of Slavic Studies, Boston, November 12-15. 20 Geddes, Barbara. 1999. “What Do We Know About Democratization After Twenty Years?” Annual Review of Political Science 2. Granovetter, Mark. 1978. “Threshold Models of Collective Behavior,” American Journal of Sociology, v.83, no.6, May, pp.1420-43. Green, Donald, Bradley Palmquist and Eric Schickler. 2002. Partisan Hearts and Minds (New Haven: Yale University Press). Green, Kenneth F. 2007. Why Dominant Parties Lose: Mexico’s Democratization in Comparative Perspective (New York: Cambridge University Press). Gudkov, Lev. 2012. “Sotsial’nyi kapital i ideologicheskie orientatsii,” Pro et Contra, May-June, pp.6-31. Hale, Henry E. 2003. “Explaining Machine Politics in Russia’s Regions: Economy, Ethnicity, and Legacy,” Post-Soviet Affairs, v.19, no.3, July-September, pp.228-63. Hale, Henry E. 2006. Why Not Parties in Russia? Democracy, Federalism, and the State (NY: Cambridge University Press, 2006). Hale, Henry E. 2011a. “The Myth of Mass Russian Support for Autocracy: Public Opinion Foundations of a Hybrid Regime,” Europe-Asia Studies, v.63, no.8, October 2011, pp.1357-1375 Hale, Henry E. 2011b. “The Putin Machine Sputters: First Impressions of Russia’s 2011 Duma Election,” Russian Analytical Digest, no.106, December 21, 2011, pp.2-5, http://www.css.ethz.ch/publications/pdfs/RAD-106.pdf . Havel, Vaclav. 1992. “The Power of the Powerless,” in Paul Wilson, ed., Open Letters: Selected Writings, 1965-1990 (New York: Vintage Books, 1992). Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press). King, Gary, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg. 2000. “Making the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation” American Journal of Political Science 44 (2): 347-61. Kommersant, April 26, 2012, http://www.kommersant.ru/doc/1924105 , accessed same day Kuran, Timur. 1991. “Now Out of Never: The Element of Surprise in the East European Revolution of 1989,” World Politics, v.44, no.1, October 1991, pp.7-48. Kuran, Timur. 1995. Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social Consequences of Preference Falsification. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Kuran, Timur, and Cass R. Sunstein. 1999. “Availability Cascades and Risk Regulation,” Stanford Law Review, v.51, April, pp.683-768. Kuran Timur. 2011. “The Politics of Revolutionary Surprise,” Project Syndicate, February 8, 2011, http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/the-politics-of-revolutionarysurprise, accessed November 7, 2012. Levada Center. 2006. Obshchestvennoe mnenie 2006, chapter 2, http://www.levada.ru/om2006.html , access date August 9, 2010. Lohmann, Susanne. 1994. “The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989-91,” World Politics, v.47, no.1, October, pp.42-101 Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and Its Demise in Mexico (New York: Cambridge University Press). March, Luke. 2009. “Managing Opposition in a Hybrid Regime: Just Russia and Parastatal Opposition,” Slavic Review, v.68, no.3, Fall, pp.504-27. 21 McFaul, Michael. 2005. “Transitions from Communism,” Journal of Democracy, 2005, **. Miller, Warren E., and J. Merrill Shanks. 1996. The New American Voter (Cambridge: Harvard University Press). Olson, Mancur. 1990. “The Logic of Collective Action in Soviet-type Societies,” Journal of Soviet Nationalities, v.1, Summer. Patel, David Siddhartha. 2012. “Don’t Be Square: Preference Falsification, Diffusion, and the Centrality of Squares in the Arab Revolutions,” paper prepared for delivery at the 2012 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 30 - September 2. Pfaff, Steven. 2006. Exit-Voice Dynamics and the Collapse of East Germany: The Crisis of Leninism and the Revolution of 1989 (Durham: Duke University Press). Reuter, Ora John, and Thomas Remington. 2009. “Dominant Party Regimes and the Commitment Problem: The Case of United Russia,” Comparative Political Studies, v.42, no.4, pp.501-26. Roeder, Philip G. 2007. Where Nation-States Come From: Institutional Change in the Age of Nationalism (Princeton: Princeton University Press). Rose, Richard, William Mishler, and Neil Munro. 2006. Russia Transformed: Developing Popular Support for a New Regime (New York: Cambridge University Press). Sidorenko, Alexey. 2011. “Society and the State on the Internet: A Call for Change,” in Maria Lipman & Nikolay Petrov, eds., Russia in 2020: Scenarios for the Future (Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment) pp.573-92. Slater, Dan. 2010. Ordering Power: Contentious Politics and Authoritarian Leviathans in Southeast Asia (New York: Cambridge University Press). Smyth, Regina. 2013. Draft paper. Smyth, Regina, Brandon Wilkening, and Anna Urasova. 2007. “Engineering Victory: Institutional Reform, Informal Institutions, and the Formation of a Hegemonic Party Regime in the Russian Federation,” Post-Soviet Affairs 23 (2). Sonin, Konstantin. 2011. “Podschety sotsiologov,” http://ksonin.livejournal.com/412894.html, December 16, 00:43, accessed December 18, 2011. Tomz, Michael, Jason Wittenberg, and Gary King. 2003. CLARIFY: Software for Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results, Version 2.1, Stanford University, University of Wisconsin, and Harvard University, January. Available at http://gking.harvard.edu. Treisman, Daniel. 2011. “Presidential Popularity in a Hybrid Regime: Russia under Yeltsin and Putin,” American Journal of Political Science, v.55, no.3, July, pp.590-609. Wedeen, Lisa. 2002. “Conceptualizing Culture: Possibilities for Political Science,” American Political Science Review, v.96, no.4, December 2002, pp.713-28 Yurchak A. 2005. Everything Was Forever, Until It Was No More: The Last Soviet Generation (New York: Oxford University Press). Zakharov, Alexei V. 2008. “Voting in 2007 Russian Legislative Elections: The Role of Putin’s Approval and Ideology,” mimeo, July 1. Zimmerman, William. 2009. “Kabardino-Balkar and Overall Russian Evaluations of Key Religious and Ethnic Identities: A Comparison,” in Marta Zahorska and Ewa Nasalska, eds., Wartosci polityka spolecsenstwo (Warsaw: Scholar) pp.466-74. Zubarevich, Natalia. 2011. “Chetyre Rossii,” Vedomosti.ru, December 30, 00:02, http://www.vedomosti.ru/opinion/news/1467059/chetyre_rossii. 22