Atypical and irregular employment in Southern EU cities: resurgence of an industrial reserve army? Abstract: Labour processes across the EU are restructured in order to facilitate the recovery of profitability. Diminishing wages, extending working time, intensifying work and increasing the industrial reserve army of labour are normal means and outcomes of this restructuring. However, the implementation of these restructuring policies are necessarily uneven within EU regions due to unequal internal power relations and different productive structures. In this frame, this paper studies atypical and irregular employment in crisis-hit cities of Italy, Greece and Spain. Specifically, it focuses on primary as well as secondary material collected from selected capital and port-cities of the three Southern EU countries. The paper discusses the increasing significance of an industrial reserve army, especially in the deprived cities like Thessaloniki and Naples. The paper argues that what is more important than defining the potential groups of workers that belong to the reserve army or its size, is to reveal how this powerful segmenting mechanism is acting in favour of collective capitalist interests. Keywords: Flexible and atypical employment, uneven development, regions, crisis, Greece, Spain, Italy 1. Introduction The implementation of labour flexibilization policies broadly follows the course of capitalist accumulation; especially in the current era of crisis when devalorisation accelerates1. Labour processes across the EU are restructured in order to facilitate the recovery of profitability. Diminishing wages, extending working time, intensifying work and increasing the pools of redundant labour are normal means and outcomes of this restructuring. However, the implementation of these restructuring policies are necessarily uneven within EU regions due to unequal internal power relations and different productive structures. Flexible employment arrangements are as specific to particular localities and time periods, at least as much as devalorisation is sensitive to place and time (Smith, 1986; Gialis and Leontidou, 2014). 1 Economic crises in capitalism are essentially caused by falling profitability. The latter means that accumulated capitals cannot be re-invested sufficiently profitably and thus a situation of overaccumulation occurs. This signifies that accumulated capitals are greater than those that can profitably re-invested under the given social and technical conditions (Barnett, 1998). The solution to the overaccumulation crisis is the ‘destruction’ of part of the accumulated capitals which is termed as devalorisation. For an overaccumulation crisis to be surpassed capitalism has to reinvigorate the mechanisms counteracting falling profitability. One crucial such mechanism is the increased exploitation of labour. The flexibilisation of labour is a powerful mechanism of increasing labour exploitation and at the same time reducing labour costs (Mavroudeas, 2014). In this frame, this paper studies atypical and irregular employment in crisis-hit cities of Italy, Greece and Spain. Specifically, it focuses on primary as well as secondary material collected from selected capital and port-cities of the three Southern EU countries. The paper discusses the increasing significance of an industrial reserve army, especially in the deprived cities like Thessaloniki and Naples. Its floating part is comprised of all those who lost their jobs due to costs reductions. Its latent part is either directly or indirectly pictured in the reproduction of solo selfemployment. Finally, the stagnant part comprises all of the poor and underpaid atypical forms. The paper discusses these categories while argues that what is more important than defining the potential groups of workers that belong to the reserve army or its size, is to reveal how this powerful segmenting mechanism is acting in favour of collective capitalist interests. It does so by dividing workers while making those who still have a typical job more frightened and dispensable than in the precrisis period (Gialis and Herod, 2014). 2. Relations of production in capitalism Wage labour is the founding relationship of the capitalist mode of production. However, the forms and the conditions under which wage labour is performed are not static but they change during subsequent historical periods. The greater part of the 20th century had been dominated by the belief that developed capitalism is associated with a more or less fixed framework for employment. This belief has been rightfully questioned since the eruption of the global capitalist structural crisis2 of 1973. The course of the last century, when seen retrospectively, reveals that the predominance of fixed employment was but a short period in the long history of capitalism. Full-time, permanent employment, often seen as a byproduct of capitalism’s sophistication, actually came at high cost for the working class, and only after fierce struggle. It is often disregarded that flexible and precarious forms of employment never ceased to exist as they are a powerful tool in the hands of the capitalist class in order to ‘discipline’ labour and to extract more surplus-value from it. Capital has always a strong incentive to pay workers the least possible, have them work longer and more intensively and bear as much of the costs of their social reproduction as possible. Flexible and precarious forms of employment not only facilitate directly these aims but they also pressurize indirectly fixed forms of employment to follow the same path (Gialis and Leontidou, 2014, Mavroudeas, 2014). Capitalism, after the heavy-handed restructuring that accompanied the 2nd World War entered a ‘Golden era’ (1950—1973) (Lipietz, 1987). During this era and because of the increased socio-political weight of labour it conceded an increase of the part of fixed employment. This concession did not hinder capital accumulation as the war had created ample space for increased accumulation and had boosted technical progress and labour productivity. Thus, for a lengthy approximately 25years period increased fixed employment co-existed with vigorous capital A structural crisis is one that signifies the exhaustion of capitalism’s historically specific structure and dictates the need for its reorganization. Only then can capital accumulation proceed again vigorously and smoothly (Mavroudeas, 2014). 2 accumulation. However, once this spree met its social and technical barriers falling profitability and the resulting overaccumulation re-emerged (Barnett, 1998). The global crisis of 1973 was the expression of this conundrum. The eruption of the crisis led to a prolonged period of capitalist restructuring, that is of heuristical attempts by capitalism to re-configure itself in a new sustainable form. This shift was associated from the mid-1980s and onwards with neo-liberalism. An essential part of the neoliberal policies is the attack on workers’ rights and the flexibilisation and precariousness of employment is a powerful mechanism for this. From the end of the 1990s capitalism moved from ‘national neo-liberalism’ to unleashed internationalization of capital (or ‘globalisation’). The latter, coupled with laboursaving technological changes, increased international competition that pressurized wages and stable forms of employment (Lipietz, 1987; Harvey, 2014). 3. The industrial reserve army The profit motive (that is the quest for increased profits) defines the modus operandi of capitalism. However, at the same time this quest carries with it the seeds of disaster as the continuous increase of profits leads ultimately to overaccumulation (as the search for extra profits by individual capitals sets in motion the tendency of the rate of profit to fall). To put in a nutshell, for Marxism it is the system’s very success that leads to its failure. In order to combat falling profitability, capitalists must activate counteracting economic mechanisms (Marx, 2004). The increase of workers’ exploitation (expressed by the rate of surplus-value) is a major counteracting mechanism (Marx, 2005). Labour flexibility is a prominent measure for increasing exploitation. have to extract the highest possible rate of surplus value from their workers Consequently, labour flexibility was always a historical pursuit of capital (Bruno, 1979; Buzar, 2008). Of course, there exist historical variations, that is flexibility is stronger during specific epochs and weaker during others. After the eruption of the 1973 crisis flexibility became one of the main instruments of capitalist restructuring. As (Marx, 2004, ch.25:3) argues “there must be the possibility of throwing great masses of men suddenly on the decisive points without injury to the scale of production in other spheres. Overpopulation supplies these masses”. This surplus labour is what we characterise as flexible labour today: a surplus population of workers who have no equivalent rights and benefits as of those working full-time. Unlike what would be logical at a first reading, the absolute size of this labour reserve and capital accumulation are directly proportional. Furthermore, the reserve’s mass expands faster than that of the actively employed labour force (McIntyre, 2011). “The greater the social wealth, the functioning capital, the extent and energy of its growth, and therefore also the greater the absolute mass of the proletariat and the productivity of its labour, the greater is the industrial reserve army” (Marx, 2004: 798). The industrial reserve army is not a malfunction of capitalism but an ordinary and predictable process (McIntyre, 2011). The reason for this is that the expansion of capital and labour reserve share the same cause: the progressive devaluation of capital. In periods of capital accumulation, if the organic composition of capital stayed stable, it would be legitimate to assume that the demand for labour-power would increase. But this is a non-realistic hypothesis, since accumulation favors constant capital over variable; this happens because capital expands based on an increasing productivity, and a crucial part of this is labour-power exploitation. This increasing exploitation of labour-power is expressed through the progressive devaluation of capital. Since capital expansion is based on the increasing exploitation of variable capital and is enhanced by emphasizing variable capital, the demand for labour-power falls behind the rate of accumulation. Therefore, the same elements producing capital accumulation also expand the surplus laboring population (McIntyre, 2011). Consequently, periods of crisis do not reveal novel patterns in the expansion of these surplus populations, but affect the temporary fluctuations of their mass, exacerbating the impact of capital devaluation, without in any case being a fundamental cause of their growth (Marx, 2004). Thus, the industrial reserve army of labour is always present in capitalism. What changes from period to period is its size. Furthermore, workers that are thrown into unemployment (that is become members of this industrial reserve of labour) do not cease – at least to a great extent – to be part of the working class. The industrial reserve of labour and the active working population are communicating vessels. Every unemployed worker, who retains his working capacity, has a chance of being recruited by capital again. Therefore, the unemployed, according to Marxist theory, are also integral part of the working class (Peet, 1975, Clark, 1980). The industrial reserve army is divided by Marx in three categories: the floating, stagnant and latent. The floating part consists of workers working short periods of time and then turning jobless again, depending on the oscillations of the industrial production cycle. The latent part comprises this agricultural population that is on the point of passing over into the urban and manufacturing proletariat. Flows of labour force from rural areas to urban centers, preceding rapid urbanization processes, for example in China, are signs of a latent surplus labour force. The stagnant part includes all those employed under extremely irregular conditions; namely, the marginal sections of atypical and undeclared employment. Those provide capital with an “inexhaustible reservoir of disposable labour-power” as they work the longest and paid the less. It comes from the redundant forces of – mainly decadent sectors of – industry and agriculture and its mass takes up most of the industrial reserve army (Marx, 2004; Grover and Piggott, 2005). As it has been made clear already, the increase in industrial reserve army’s mass goes hand in hand with capitalist accumulation. But the process of reserve’s expansion is a complex one and shows important oscillations, due to the factors pushing its relative size up or down. More specifically, those factors tending to diminish the relative size of surplus population are the following. Firstly, the increased demand for labour which leads to an augmentation of absolute employment as capital accumulates. Secondly, those workers employed outside the dominant circuit of capital; in other words, those employed outside capitalism’s set of relations of production. Thirdly, capital’s increased need for reproductive labor (e.g. staff for personal service). On the other hand, we have these factors tending to exacerbate the “problem” of the industrial reserve army; technological breakthroughs, exponentially growing population as capitalism evolves due to an abrupt decrease in death rates (which balances out falling birth rates in the global north) and new sources of wage labour created by capital expansion (McIntyre, 2011) (for example the latent part of the reserve army which is “freed from the means of production” and “is forced to rely on wage labor to survive) (Marx, 2004). If our hypothesis concerned a closed economy, the factors decreasing the relative size of surplus labour population would outweigh those increasing it, mainly because the latter would meet their limits. Technological advances may not be labour saving in all cases but rather capital saving. Moreover, some scholars support that there is no proof that technological innovation causes absolute decline in the demand for wage labour (McIntyre, 2011). Also, falling birth rates in the global north would dry out the source of new young workers. Most importantly, this latent part of the surplus labor force would eventually disappear as an entire labor market of a region submits under the capitalist mode of production. In the long run, for a closed economy, capitalist accumulation would produce increased demand for labour, wherein a problematic supply of labour should lead to shrinking surplus laboring populations and upward pressures on wages (McIntyre, 2011). However, those tendencies created within the context of a closed economy can be easily outweighed by an open capitalist economy. Even in the case of zero capital export, an open market economy can spur surplus laboring populations. Firstly by increasing the size of the population whose small size manufacturing activity cannot compete with industrial products, secondly by creating (partially in consequence of the previous point) inbound flows of migrant labor and thirdly by connecting to the capitalist circuit, through market exchange, a “wide range of producers who do not employ wage labor”. This spectrum of producers can be connected to formal economy by exchange, even though it is “not characterized by capitalist relations of production”. These relations include “slavery, sharecropping, encomienda, tenancy, indentured servitude, long-term labor contracts, and debt peonage” (McIntyre, 2011, p. 1492-93). If we count in the possibility of capital export, the ability of surplus populations creation increases dramatically. Summarily, and as has been pointed out above, the same forces enhancing the expansion of capital do favor the increase of the relative size of the surplus labour army. It should be highlighted that, the industrial reserve army is practically nonerasable in capitalism; it is a precondition of the capitalist mode of production (Bruno, 1979). This fact is related to four (4) important dimensions highlighted below: Firstly, the redundant labour force is used for staffing emerging or rapidly developing sectors of the economy, without this mobilization bearing negative impact in other established spheres of production. Simply put, unemployment and underemployment renders the labour force more flexible to fluctuations caused by shifting demand patterns in the market or by technological breakthroughs which change the mode of production substantially. This need for more flexible responses to shifting demand may have been an imperative of the post- 1973 crisis era and a seemingly logical justification of the expansion of flexible employment, but it was highlighted some two centuries ago by Herman Merivale (1841, 1842), professor of political economy. “[S]uppose that, on the occasion of some of these crises, the nation were to rouse itself to the effort of getting rid by emigration of some hundreds of thousands of superfluous arms, what would be the consequence? That, at the first returning demand for labour, there would be a deficiency. However rapid reproduction may be, it takes, at all events, the space of a generation to replace the loss of adult labour. Now, the profits of our manufacturers depend mainly on the power of making use of the prosperous moment when demand is brisk, and thus compensating themselves for the interval during which it is slack. [...] They must have hands ready by them, they must be able to increase the activity of their operations when required, and to slacken it again, according to the state of the market, or they cannot possibly maintain that pre-eminence in the race of competition on which the wealth of the country is founded.” (Merivale, 1841:146) This sudden mobilization of workers does not only concern periods of crises, but regular phases of the industrial cycle. Amid crises though, the role of the industrial reserve labour, in conjunction with new technologies, is crucial. Kondratiev drew that connection when writing that crises in capitalism occur in a periodic fashion (Barnett, 1998). Capitalism overcomes those crises through technological advances. Therefore, emerging sectors need a bulk of labour force immediately, and not at the expense of other up and running sectors. Secondly, the industrial reserve army has been used to keep the aspirations of the active part of the labour force low (that is as a disciplining mechanism). “The function of this reserve is to supply the labour-power required for future expansion of capital while acting as a dead weight upon the aspirations of those already employed as they struggle to improve rates of remuneration and working conditions” (Harvey, 2014:110). Capital imposes the active part of the labour force unto direct competition to this reserve army and reaps numerous benefits. While being disheartened, the labour force tends to overwork, further increasing the relative size of surplus labour, has fewer claims – even in times of prosperity –, and is willing to bear the costs of its own reproduction uncomplainingly; all in all it stays docile and disciplined. For all those reasons, it is very convenient for capital to create and sustain such a surplus population. In cases where this reserve does not exist, capital has to create it by gaining access to underused or unused labour markets, such as those of China, Asia and Africa (Harvey, 2014). If we follow the General Law of Capitalist Accumulation inversely, we will see that higher the share of the industrial reserve army, higher the official pauperism. And as the industrial reserve army’s share expands, capital accumulates. Keeping the active part’s aspirations low is therefore suggested to be a key factor in the accumulation process. Thirdly, through the industrial reserve army, capital manages to “detour” the law of supply and demand of labour and regulates wages in an alternate fashion. Instead of following the ratio of supply and demand for labour, capital affects wages in formal economy through comparison to adjacent countries and the informal economy. The key here is to understand how the industrial reserve lives when unemployed. When reserves come from rural regions, when losing their “urban” work return to their home place and live as they have traditionally done. This particularly is a paradigm we encounter a lot in Greece during the last six years, even though these flows of deurbanization do not fall out of the circuit of the capitalist mode of production. When migrant labourers from adjacent countries lose their job, they return to their country of origin (e.g. Mexicans in the US, Albanians in Greece). The previous two examples (migrant and formerly rural labour) obviously do not apply for entire families which migrate to urban areas. The active members of those engage with the rising informal economies and sustain life on marginal terms (Wilson & Keil, 2008). The stagnant part of the reserve army, when unemployed usually makes a living however possible in the urban slums (Harvey, 2014). Specifically in the European South, family income sustains multiple members when unemployed or underemployed. This way a reserve army reproduces itself at its own expense practically, while being constantly available to capital. All the previous lead to the creation of a “benchmark of poverty”, which is substantially lower than actually the average one, as we can easily realize by looking at the term of “poverty line”. What happens is that capital defines a cost of living which is directly influenced by the reality of the informal sector, however forming a lower bound for the formal sector, since workers of those marginal layers can be easily recruited (Harris, 1993). Last but not least, the industrial reserve labour, is not only used to “detour” the law of supply and demand of labour, but also to distort it. It is commonly believed that wages rise while capital accumulates, the increase in wages stimulate a faster reproduction of labour until the supply of labour exceeds the demand. Then wages fall and the aforementioned process takes place inversely. Falling wages and a more intense exploitation of the labour force accelerates accumulation, until a time comes again when supply of labour is less than the demand. This line of thought is based on the fact that in capitalism, labour-power is bought and sold like any other commodity. However, as it happens, there are elements distorting this fine balance achieved by supply and demand correlation. One serious drawback of this argument is that it overlooks the emigration of labour between sectors and the crucial reason why the reserve is necessary (to man emerging sectors). Marx fiercely attacked his contemporary political economists (like Ricardo) for that in this process, they only saw “the local oscillation of the labour-market in a particular sphere of production […], only the phenomena accompanying the distribution of the working population into the different spheres of outlay of capital, according to its varying needs” (Marx, 2004, ch. 25:3). He reached the remarkable assumption that the relative surplus population is the pivot upon which the law of demand and supply of labour works, as it “confines the field of action of this law within the limits absolutely convenient to the activity of exploitation and to the domination of capital” (Harvey, 2014). Concluding, capital works on “both sides at the same time”. When accumulation increases the demand for labour, supply is augmented by gaining access to unused sources of labour. Simultaneously, the very existence of reserve labour, forces those working to increase their productivity, to overwork. This way, capital makes “the supply of labour, to a certain extent, independent of the supply of laborers” (Marx, 2004, ch. 25:3). The circulation of labour-power as a commodity in this sense – as “artificial” as it may be – expresses the hegemony of capital. 4. Capitalist crisis and progressive devaluation of capital We saw earlier that economic crises do not alter the patterns of industrial reserve army fluctuation but just exacerbate its temporal oscillations. Here we will see how economic crises relate to labour. Value is a central concept in capitalism as the surplus product (which is the source of profit for the capitalist class) is extracted and realized in the form of surplus-value. This process manifests the capital - labour relationship in the capitalist mode of production. Furthermore, value is the “social expression” of human labour. The very notion of value though, implies the possibility of crisis (Smith, 1986). There are three sets of processes regarding accretion or diminution of value (Marx, 1974, 2004, 2005): appreciation/depreciation, which occurs only in the price sphere, valorisation/devalorisation, which is about the movement of value inherent in the creation and circulation of capital and revaluation/devaluation, which occurs solely in the value sphere. What is of importance for this paper, is the last set of processes: revaluation/devaluation. In contrast to the previous two sets, this does not concern a mere increase or decrease in price (like appreciation/depreciation), but an absolute augmentation or destruction of value. Devaluation takes place when the general capital of a sector of production or a whole region of the global economy goes through a generalized loss of value. Devaluation is a “historically dominant process”, unlike revaluation, and is conduced by two main sources: progressive and periodic devaluation (Smith, 1986). The first one, simply put, is an inherent tendency and results from the necessity of perpetual increase in the productiveness of labour. The second one, periodic devaluation, is the abrupt devaluation taking place amid crises and affects all forms of capital (commodity, money, productive capital). As mentioned above, the possibility of crisis is implied in the constitution of the structure of value. Devalorization, the interruption in the movement of value (inherent in the creation and circulation of capital) merely implies the possibility of crisis. The realization of crisis is about the progressive devaluation of capital. Wage labourers and jobs lost Metropolitan Area Region Total in thousands 2008 Total in thousands 2011 Total in thousands 2013 jobs lost 20082011 jobs lost (%) 2008 wage labour jobs lost 20112013 jobs lost (%) 2011 wage labour Attica Cen. Macedonia Athens 1389.0 1201.4 1013.6 187.6 13.5% 187.8 15.6% Thessaloniki Madrid Madrid Cataluña Barcelona Lazio Rome 471.5 2694.0 2967.1 1720.3 1212.9 399.0 2499.7 2705.2 1744.2 1136.4 330.4 2384.5 2527.5 1705.6 1149.3 72.5 194.3 261.9 -23.8 76.5 15.4% 7.2% 8.8% -1.4% 6.3% 68.6 115.2 177.7 38.6 -12.9 17.2% 4.6% 6.6% 2.2% -1.1% Campania Naples Table 1: Estimating the floating part of the industrial reserve army: wage labourers and jobs lost, 2008-2013 Temporary workers that could not find a permanent job Region Metropolitan Area Attica Total in thousands 2008 Total in thousands 2011 Total in thousands 2013 Change (%) 2008-11 Change (%) 2011-13 % of wage labour 2008 % of wage labour 2011 % of wage labour 2013 Athens 86,4 88,7 37,2 2,7% -58,1% 6,2% 7,4% 3,7% Cen. Macedonia Thessaloniki 43,2 34,4 30,2 -20,2% -12,3% 9,2% 8,6% 9,1% Madrid Madrid 391,9 410,0 321,8 4,6% -21,5% 14,5% 16,4% 13,5% Cataluña Barcelona 489,8 462,9 435,4 -5,5% -5,9% 16,5% 17,1% 17,2% Lazio Rome 128,9 137,7 143,5 6,8% 4,2% 7,5% 7,9% 8,4% Naples 134,5 134,6 148,8 0,1% 10,5% 11,1% 11,8% 12,9% Campania Table 2: Estimating the stagnant part of the industrial reserve army: temporary workers that could not find a permanent job, 2008-2013 Solo self-employment Region Metropolitan Area Total in thousands 2008 Total in thousands 2011 Total in thousands 2013 change 20082011 change (%) 2008-2011 change 20112013 change (%) 2011-2013 Attica Cen. Macedonia Athens 114,0 85,8 80,1 -28,2 -24,8% -5,7 -6,6% Thessaloniki 72,7 56,8 40,3 -15,9 -21,9% -16,5 -29,0% Madrid Madrid 127,6 110,4 96,1 -17,2 -13,5% -14,3 -13,0% Cataluña Barcelona 204,6 154,6 138,8 -50,0 -24,5% -15,7 -10,2% Lazio Rome 108,8 120,0 123,0 11,1 10,2% 3,0 2,5% Naples 116,8 101,7 106,5 -15,0 -12,9% 4,7 4,7% Campania Table 3: Estimating the latent part of the industrial reserve army: solo self-employed persons, 2008-2013 Unemployed persons and new unemployed Region Metropolitan Area Total in thousands 2008 Total in thousands 2011 Total in thousands 2013 new unemployed 2008-2011 change (%) 2008-2011 new unemployed 2011-2013 change (%) 2011-2013 Attica Cen. Macedonia Athens 127.5 338.2 527.5 210.7 165.3% 189.3 56.0% Thessaloniki Madrid Madrid Cataluña Barcelona Lazio Rome Campania Naples 70.1 295.0 349.6 182.3 241.9 160.0 564.4 760.0 218.9 288.0 239.0 669.5 893.2 310.0 430.2 89.9 269.4 410.4 36.6 46.1 128.2% 91.3% 117.4% 20.1% 19.1% 79 105.1 133.2 91.1 142.2 49.4% 18.6% 17.5% 41.6% 49.4% Table 4: Estimating the industrial reserve army: unemployed person and new unemployed, 2008-2013 Capital inherently seeks its expansion (because of competition), but it can expand only if the organic composition of capital increases so fast – that it is logical – that labour-power is systematically diminished. Solely the valorization of fixed capital, the technological advances and the instruments of production, cannot sustain a sufficient growth of the organic composition of capital. It is dictated by the need of increasing productivity that variable capital has to be constantly devalued. However, the increase in the organic composition of capital results to a falling rate of profit (Mavroudeas, 2014). Capital moves away from sectors and regions where a falling rate of profit initially appears (Clark, 1980). However, when moving away from its original source, it cannot valorize itself but at the expense of capitals in sectors and regions where, possibly, the rate of profit is also falling due to increasing competition. The generalization of this falling rate of profit “crowds out some capitals, forcing them to be partially or completely idle” (Smith, 1986: 20). What we see here is that progressive devaluation of capital leads to a higher level periodic devaluation and a devalorization of capital (interruption in the circulation of capital). This is the process of over-accumulation (through endless seek for expansion), which consequently leads to the depreciation of commodities in the market. Summarily, progressive devaluation leads to periodic devaluation and devalorization (both described by the process of over-accumulation), which in turn lead to depreciation of capital (Marx, 2005). This chain is somewhat the opposite of the consumptionist theory, where underconsumption/overproduction lower commodity prices and this leads to an interruption of the production process, and eventually a crisis. 5. The industrial reserve army nowadays: the case of crisis-hit Southern EU cities and regions When Marx wrote Capital, employment and relations of production were much different than today. Typical employment in the sense that is meant today (i.e. regulated, long-term employment for five days and a total of forty hours per week) did not exist, as did not atypical employment. Yet, Marx distinguished the active part of the labour force from the reserve army. This paper suggests that, nowadays, the floating group may be comprised of all the unemployed who lost their jobs due to technological advances or were replaced by cheaper labor. The latent group is mainly underemployed labour found in primary sector activities that have been marginalized by intensified industrial production. Lastly, we can trace the stagnant group among those employed under very irregular conditions; precarious and informal employment. These labourers are usually fall under part-time, seasonal and temporary employment norms that are deprived of important security aspects, while being underpaid in comparison to the average wages of the ‘typical’ workers. We also suggest that, defining the industrial reserve army is not reducible to empirically observing and measuring the groups that it is comprised of; rather it has to do with defining how the reserve army is derived from capitalist expansion (i.e. how and where it increases while the organic composition of capital is increasing) (Clark, 1980, Dorre, 2010). We these remarks taken as granted, below an empirical account of the industrial reserve army in contemporary regions of the crisis-hit3 Southern EU is below attempted. As obvious from Table 1 the floating part of the industrial reserve army has largely increased during the crisis period. Thousands of wage-dependent workers lost their jobs across all regions under study, with the exception of the region of Lazio (Rome) which kept its number of employees between 2008 and 2011. The largest reductions are in Greece where for both periods under study almost 15% of jobs in Thessaloniki and Athens where destroyed (see Table 1). Following Greece, but on a less intense pace, Spanish regions suffered a loss that is close to 8% between 20082011 and approximately 5% between 2011 and 2013 (Gialis and Leontidou, 2014; Gialis and Herod, 2014). Table 2 reveals that very precarious atypical jobs, such as involuntary temporary employment, are slightly increasing their share in four out of the six regions, despite they are also highly affected by the crisis. This is an unavoidable results of the fact that certain firms prefer to reduce their permanent labour force and hire more temporaries, while other tend to dismiss more of their temporary workers in order to avoid the (relatively) high costs of permanent personnel compensation. Making temporary workers redundant means that in some regions, such as the Greek ones, the relative share of the stagnant part of the industrial reserve army may decrease, favoring an increment of the share of the floating part. At the same time, solo self-employed persons, such as those that run very small traditional businesses that are thrown out of the market or face bankruptcy highly increase, as revealed from data on this latent part of the industrial reserve army (as in Table 3). All these lead to huge increments of unemployment and thousands of new entrants that enroll in the unemployment lists. There are regions, like the Greek and Spanish ones that have an increase in unemployment that is equal or even larger to 100% between 2008 and 2011. This pace remains extremely high (i.e. close to 50%) for the Greek and the Italian regions between 2011 and 2013 (as in Table 4). 6. Conclusion The significance of the industrial reserve army is increasing across crisis-hit Southern EU, especially in the deprived cities like Thessaloniki and Naples. Its floating part, comprised of all those who lost their jobs due to capital devaluation, bankruptcies and costs reductions, has largely increased leading hundreds of thousands of people to unemployment and precariousness, as seen from the cities 3 GDP data reveal an ongoing devaluation of the economies of Mediterranean EU countries. According to Eurostat’s data between 2008 and 2013, the Greek nominal GDP has been reduced by more than 20%; the Italian and Spanish reductions are modest when compared to the Greek fall (Gialis and Leontidou, 2014). discussed above. Its latent part, either directly or indirectly pictured in the reproduction of solo self-employment, lost much of its capacity, especially in cities like Thessaloniki, yet still retains its dynamism. Finally, the stagnant part, comprised of the poor and underpaid atypical forms, is subjected to controversial trends as it increases in some regions while it is being reduced in others. The crisis and political responses to it are weakening Southern EU’s already disempowered economic status by multiplying public deficit, pushing small entrepreneurship to collapse and prevailing industries to shrink. A clear example is observed in the case of Attica/ Athens and Central Macedonia/ Thessaloniki’s regions, where tertiarization and falling construction affect employment structures; it is also prevalent in Madrid and Barcelona, where tourism and falling industrial production produce labour market dismantling. In all these cases, the further flexibilisation of the labour market is not a way to overcome employment rigidities and generate new job opportunities – as it, it marginalizes more integrated and established atypical employment forms and expands the more fragile ones. The austerity measures and the cuts imposed upon wages and pensions pose a threat on the available family income. This challenges a basic, though divergent from the Northern patterns, welfare pillar of the Southern EU countries. Extended support networks among the family members and kinship are loosened and social security in the urban fabric and abroad is under threat. Economic support of the younger members of the households until their mid-30s, living with parents, taking care of the elderly, combination of formal with informal employment and income sharing along with family duties, are all aspects of an existent pattern that is currently deconstructed, if not destroyed, as support among the members of extended kinship networks cannot be further sustained. The supporting role of the family was in many cases complemented by voluntary and community support and the long-lasting selfemployment or micro-entrepreneurship for at least one member of the household (in most cases the husband/ father). These networks of protection are dismantled leading to increased poverty and fragile patterns of social reproduction. Such social dynamics are also prevalent when the huge rates of youth unemployment and the relatively high shares of females/ youngsters that are precariously employed or seek work are examined. The momentum that unemployment is gaining is also an indirect sign of the weak social policies in Southern cities and regions, as in the case of Greece where less than 20% of the almost 1,2 unemployed workers (data for late 2014) are receiving any unemployment benefit. All these changes are encouraging outward mobility of both the natives and the immigrants, and are turning Southern regions from immigrant-hosting to migrantsending labour markets. Within this framework, the industrial reserve army is a powerful segmenting mechanism that is acting in favour of collective capitalist interests. It does so by dividing workers while making those who still have a typical job more frightened and dispensable than in the pre-crisis period. Acknowledgments. This work is part of the “The Southern EU flexicurity project”. The research project “The Southern EU flexicurity project” is implemented within the framework of the Action «Supporting Postdoctoral Researchers» of the Operational Program "Education and Lifelong Learning" (Action’s Beneficiary: General Secretariat for Research and Technology), and is co-financed by the European Social Fund (ESF) and the Greek State (Funding Decision: 11409/31-8-2012). References Barnett, V. (1998). Kondratiev and the dynamics of economic development: long cycles and industrial growth in historical context. Palgrave Macmillan. Bruno, S. (1979). The industrial reserve army, segmentation and the Italian labour market. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 131-151. Clark G. (1980), ‘Capitalism and regional inequality’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers, v.70(2): 226-237. Gialis, S., & Herod, A. (2014). Of steel and strawberries: Greek workers struggle against informal and flexible working arrangements during the crisis. Geoforum, 57, 138-149. Gialis, S., & Leontidou, L. (2014). Antinomies of flexibilization and atypical employment in Mediterranean Europe: Greek, Italian and Spanish regions during the crisis. European Urban and Regional Studies, 0969776414538983. Grover, C., & Piggott, L. (2005). Disabled people, the reserve army of labour and welfare reform. Disability & Society, 20(7), 705-717. Harris, C. (1993). Post-war migration and the industrial reserve army. Inside Babylon: The Caribbean Diaspora in Britain. London: Verso, 7-54. Harvey, D. (2014). Seventeen contradictions and the end of capitalism. Oxford University Press. Lipietz, A. (1987), Mirages and miracles: The crisis of global Fordism, Ed. Verso: London. Marx, K. (1974) Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 2. International Publishers Marx, K. (2004) Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1. Penguin UK Marx, K. (2005) Grundrisse: Foundations of the critique of Political Economy, Vol. 2. Penguin UK Mavroudeas, S. (Ed.). (2014). Greek Capitalism in Crisis: Marxist Analyses. Routledge. McIntyre, M. (2011). Race, surplus population and the Marxist theory of imperialism. Antipode, 43(5), 1489-1515. Merivale, H. (1842). Lectures on Colonization and Colonies. Vol. 2. Longman, Green, Longman and Roberts. Retrieved from http://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/001151530. Merivale, H. (1841). Lectures on Colonization and Colonies. Vol. 1. Longman, Green, Longman and Roberts. Retrieved from http://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/001151530. Peet R. (1975) ‘Inequality and poverty: a Marxist- Geographic theory’, Annals of the Association of American Geographers 65(4): 564-571. Smith N. (1986), ‘The concepts of devaluation, valorization and depreciation in Marx: toward a clarification’, unpublished paper. Wilson, D. and Keil, R. (2008). The real creative class. Social & Cultural Geography, 9(8), 841-847. Short Biographies: Stelios Gialis is a post-doctoral researcher in Hellenic Open University and University of Georgia (joint affiliation) as well as an Assistant Professor of Regional Geography and Development in the University of Aegean, Greece. His research interests include Labour Geography, Regional Development and Flexible work and he has published in various journals like Geoforum, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research and Capitalism, Nature, Socialism. Stavros Mavroudeas is a Professor of Political Economy in the University of Macedonia, Greece. He is the author of ‘The Limits of Regulation: A Critical Analysis of Capitalist Development’, Cheltenham: Edward Elgarand and the editor of ‘Greek capitalism in crisis: Marxist Analyses’ published by Routledge, while he has published in various journals like Review of Radical Political Economics and International Critical Thought. Kostas Gourzis is and Urban and Regional Development Engineer, Dipl. Eng, MSc and an associate researcher in the University of Aegean Greece. His main interests include Labour Geography, Regional Development and Urban restructuring while he has published his work in various conference proceedings and journals.