Economic policy, employers’ strategies and changes in working conditions in the current crisis in Spain Josep Banyuls (Universitat de Valencia and Institut d’Estudis del Treball) Albert Recio (Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona and Institut d’Estudis del Treball) 1. Introduction Every crisis involves a transformation of the economic and social structure. The current recession has been very intense according to the standard measures of economic performance. Job destruction has been very high in some countries, social inequalities have increased dramatically and the quality of employment has declined. However, in addition to these quantitative changes, it is important to address the qualitative changes to the existing model. Every change involves breaks and continuity: some features of the previous model are left behind, while others continue and may even be reinforced. The changes have a temporal cadence that goes far beyond the moment of crisis in which they occur. To analyse the transformations that have taken place in employment during the current crisis in order to explore future trends, we feel that two basic and interrelated aspects must be considered: first, the characteristics of the production model in a broad sense, including business structure, production specialization and strategic business options; and, second, the employment model, including government regulation of labour, the structure of collective bargaining and labour policies of companies. In this context of analysis, public policy is especially important and has an impact on three levels: in the dynamics of the public sector as an employer; in its effect on the production structure (e.g. through R&D, competitiveness, and education policies); and in its effect on business management and labour relations through labour legislation. Taking into account these aspects, the aim of this paper is to analyse the changes that have occurred in the Spanish economy during the current crisis, considering not only the period of strong job destruction but also the brief phase of job creation in recent months. The analysis is fragile to some extent because the period considered is very short, but the paper’s aim is to explore, albeit tentatively, any trends that seem to indicate a qualitative change and a change of model and to assess their impact on employment quality. In this paper we will first address the basic features of the Spanish employment model in recent years. Second, we will analyse the most important changes during the crisis. Third, we will explore the emerging features of employment quality in the recent period of growth in employment. Finally, we will present some conclusions. 1 2. The basic features of the Spanish employment model in the years of growth In the years before the current crisis, Spain was an example of a successful country with high rates of growth and job creation. However, the model showed significant interconnected weaknesses (Banyuls et al 2009, Banyuls and Recio 2012). One of the main problems of the Spanish labour market is production specialization. The strong growth in the boom years occurred in only a few activities. More than half of the jobs created between 1994 and 2007 were concentrated in the sectors of construction (17.9%), 1 real estate and business services (16.6%), retail and repair (12.8%), and hospitality (8.2%); manufacturing accounted for another 7.9%. These are all labour-intensive, low-value-added sectors with a low technological level and a low level of investment in R&D. With this composition and the type of sectoral development, the weaknesses are evident: growth is concentrated in a few sectors related to construction and tourism, industry shows weak international penetration, and there are few advanced tertiary activities. All of these characteristics favour poor employment quality and more reactive business management practices. The other main feature of the production model in this period is the predominance of competitive business strategies based on reducing labour costs, which led to the spread of precarious conditions of employment. Temporary employment remained at very high levels (above 30% of temporary employment rate) throughout the entire period of expansion, associated with a quantitative and reactive labour management based on flexibility. Wages decreased in importance in the distribution of income (Consejo Económico y Social 2013) and the quality of employment deteriorated in general (Prieto et al 2011). The public sector played a key role in shaping the weaknesses of the growth model before and during the crisis. In comparison with European standards, Spain has always been a country with a weak welfare state. During the boom years, strong growth made the provision of public services compatible with low tax collection without too much financial stress. There were even years of surplus. A modest welfare state and the decision to take the “Third Way” made this balance possible (Miguelez and Recio 2010). But the crisis put an end to this model. Compared with the Eurozone average, the fall in income in Spain has been very pronounced and the increase in spending has been very sharp, so the need for financing has soared. The underlying problem of these trends is the low development of the public sector and the limits that this involves. First, our welfare state and public service model continues to depend partly on informal and private provision, satisfying needs but favouring poor employment conditions. Second, the sustainability of the model depends on reducing costs. A good example of this is the continuing deterioration of employment conditions in public services in recent years, even before the application of austerity policies. Finally, a weak public sector is less able to manage crisis situations. These limits are found in 1 In parenthesis, the contribution of these sectors to job creation in the 1994-2007 period. 2 the management of aggregate demand, in income policies, and in the measures aimed at mitigating the negative effects of the crisis. These regressive trends that directly affect employment quality have been strengthened by changes in the labour legislation. Reform after reform, the dynamics of the labour market has been one of increasing precariousness, facilitating a growth model of low wages, in which labour relations voided of content focus mainly on pay bargaining (Pérez Infante 2011). With the benefit of hindsight, the years before the crisis saw the gradual formation of a labour relations model in which the social dialogue and the role of trade unions declined. The crisis reinforced this dynamic and the 2012 labour reform put an end to the model of industrial relations that had been established in the 1980 Workers’ Statute. As we will see below, the reforms resulted in more vulnerable employment conditions and in a significant increase in managerial prerogatives and job insecurity. 3. Sectoral change from 2008 The crisis led to an intense destruction of employment and, together with Greece, Spain was the country with the highest number of job losses within the EU. This trend in employment is largely explained by the characteristics of the production structure that had been established in the period of expansion and subsequent collapse. The activities that had driven growth were precisely those that collapsed rapidly, and it is this fragility of the production structure (rather than labour regulation as has conventionally been argued) that explains the strong impact of the crisis in Spain in terms of employment (Table 1). However, it is interesting to note some aspects of the changes in employment during the crisis. The crisis can be divided into three distinct periods. The first was between the first quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2011, a period in which the austerity policies had not yet been conclusively applied. Job destruction was high in the activities that had been the main drivers of growth (construction, retail and hospitality) and also in industry. Two factors explain this trend: the decline in activities directly related to construction and the decline in the sectors that most suffered the fall in international demand. This was the case in the automotive sector and some other sectors with a high level of exports. Other activities in recession were agriculture, other services (mainly personal services), and financial activities (affected by the restructuring of banks). However, some jobs were also created. Expansionary policies applied in the early years of the crisis allowed an increase in employment in activities related to the public sector: public administration, health and social services, and education. The second period covers the years 2011 to 2013, when austerity policies were applied with greater intensity and job flexibility was increased by two labour reforms. Job destruction continued in the same sectors as in the previous period, but with slight changes: the car industry was no longer a jobdestroying sector and falling industrial employment was now due more to the internal recessive dynamics of the construction sector than to developments in the external sector. However, the most significant change that occurred in 3 this second phase of the crisis was that the austerity policies led to heavy job losses in the public sector (Recio 2013). The role of containment that public employment played in the early years of the crisis came to an end and the public sector became one of the drivers of job destruction. The few jobs created were in other services (personal services) and agriculture. Table 1. Change in employment by economic activity in Spain, period 2008Q1-2015Q1 2008Q1-2011Q1 Economic activity 2011Q1-2014Q1 2014Q1-2015Q1 (000) in % (000) in % (000) in % -2193,8 -10,6 -1475,6 -8,0 504,2 3,0 Agriculture, forestry and fishing -92,1 -10,6 31,1 4,0 -91,7 -11,3 Mining and quarrying -10,5 -19,6 -9,5 -22,0 -5,2 -15,5 Manufacturing -776,4 -25,0 -266,3 -11,4 114,9 5,6 7,8 10,7 8,8 10,9 10,3 11,5 Total Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply Water supply; sewerage, waste management and remediation activities Construction Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles 5,1 4,4 -13,2 -10,9 22,5 20,9 -1180,1 -44,0 -557,3 -37,2 118,5 12,6 -285,6 -8,8 -130,4 -4,4 83,7 3,0 Transportation and storage -40,9 -4,3 -79,6 -8,7 -9,4 -1,1 Accommodation and food service activities -81,4 -5,8 -55,8 -4,2 87,1 6,9 J Information and communication -20,4 -3,8 -20,7 -4,0 7,9 1,6 Financial and insurance activities -54,6 -10,4 -7,3 -1,6 -18,8 -4,1 Real estate activities -28,8 -23,4 1,8 1,9 6,2 6,5 Professional, scientific and technical activities -44,1 -4,9 -34,8 -4,1 61,2 7,4 Administrative and support service activities Public administration and defence; compulsory social security -3,7 -0,4 -61,1 -6,6 43,7 5,1 223,1 17,9 -184,7 -12,6 48,5 3,8 Education 55,8 4,7 -45,7 -3,7 -10 -0,8 Human health and social work activities 218,3 18,1 -25,2 -1,8 14 1,0 Arts, entertainment and recreation 40,7 13,9 -4 -1,2 18,4 5,6 Other service activities Activities of households as employers; undifferentiated goods- and services-producing activities of households for own use -74,9 -16,9 31,2 8,5 6,1 1,5 Activities of extraterritorial organisations and bodies -52,6 -7,1 -52 -7,5 -3,7 -0,6 1,3 59,1 -0,9 -25,7 0 0,0 Source: Own calculation from LFS The third period began in the first months of 2014, when a timid recovery began to be seen in the Spanish economy. Although jobs are still being destroyed in some sectors, such as agriculture (due to its age-old tendency to lose jobs and perhaps also to seasonal factors in the period analysed) and financial activities (still being restructured), in the vast majority of sectors employment has increased (see Table 1). The first question that we can ask is whether the crisis has led to a significant sectoral reorganization and the adjustment has laid the foundations for a new production model. If so, in the expansive phase employment growth could be expected to take place in different activities than those of the pre-crisis expansionary phase. The analysis of the data does not support this hypothesis. Quite the opposite: although the period under consideration is brief, the strong concentration of job creation in a few activities suggests a return to 4 the previous model, with no signs of a major transformation. However, some points should be noted. The first feature to note is that the traditional sectors that were the basis of growth are still present in this new phase of growth. For example, there has been strong job creation in the construction, hospitality and retail sectors. Other sectors in which jobs are being created—and which could contain new activities—are industry, professional activities, administrative activities and public administration. 2 In industry, job creation focuses primarily on the manufacture of vehicles and metal products. There is therefore no significant growth of new activities. The only noteworthy feature is a slight increase in employment in the pharmaceutical and food industries. With regard to professional activities, job creation is mainly concentrated in three areas: legal and accounting activities; head office activities, business consultancy and management; and technical architecture and engineering services, testing and technical analysis. Administrative activities are occupations related partly to office work but above all to gardening and security. Finally, in the public administration much of the increase in employment is due to the political cycle and the proximity of elections rather than to a commitment to recover employment in the public sector. Overall, there do not appear to have been any significant structural changes indicative of a profound transformation of the production structure, as was to be expected because no industrial policies with this aim have been implemented (also difficult to apply within the current European political framework). This absence of change in the production structure means that wage moderation and flexible employment continue to be the basis of competitiveness in Spain, whereas more inclusive proposals targeting greater labour integration and better employment conditions have not been fostered. 4. Quantitative flexibility: a change of model? One of the features of the Spanish labour market has been the high rate of temporary employment. Orthodox economists consider that the cause lies in excessively rigid job protection measures, which encourage companies to recruit on temporary contracts to avoid the high costs of dismissal. These economists consider that the ease of use of temporary employment could explain both the high volatility of employment in Spain and its great elasticity against fluctuations in economic activity. They also consider that temporary employment operates alongside excessively rigid standards of protection for permanent workers, resulting in a dual labour market: some workers are permanently stable, whereas others bear the full cost of the employment adjustment (Dolado et al 2002). In our point of view this is an overly simplistic view that holds only when the data are analysed in aggregate. Disaggregated by sectors and case studies, a more complex reality emerges. First, the use of temporary employment varies 2 The contribution of these activities to employment growth from the first quarter of 2014 to the first quarter of 2015 is as follows: Construction 18%, industry 18%, hospitality 14%, retail 13%, professional activities 10%, public administration 8%, administrative activities 7%. 5 greatly between sectors of the Spanish economy (Table 2), and a large part of the temporary employment is in the large sectors that employ a high volume of temporary labour (construction and tourism). Second, permanent contracts are not immune to the situation of the economic cycle. In situations of prolonged depression, stable employment decreases significantly. In fact, in the 1991-94 crisis net job destruction only took place in stable employment. Third, the public sector has played an important role in recent years in generating temporary employment. In particular, the government has applied neoliberal policies aimed at weakening the large education and health sectors, either by making public employment more unstable or through outsourcing. Finally, the uncertainty and instability of some activities significantly favours the use of temporary contracts. Table 2. Temporary employment rate (in %) by economic activity in Spain 2008Q1 2011Q1 2014Q1 30,0 24,6 23,1 Total 60,7 58,4 66,6 Agriculture, forestry and fishing 14,4 11,8 13,6 Mining and quarrying 22,0 16,9 17,1 Manufacturing 18,0 13,0 14,3 Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply Water supply; sewerage, waste management and remediation activities Construction Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles Transportation and storage Accommodation and food service activities J Information and communication Financial and insurance activities Real estate activities Professional, scientific and technical activities Administrative and support service activities Public administration and defence; compulsory social security Education Human health and social work activities Arts, entertainment and recreation Other service activities Activities of households as employers; undifferentiated goods- and services-producing activities of households for own use Activities of extraterritorial organisations and bodies 2015Q1 23,6 59,8 15,0 18,8 12,1 21,4 51,2 15,7 40,8 10,4 33,3 14,9 38,7 24,1 22,1 36,2 20,9 11,6 16,8 23,7 29,7 17,1 17,2 33,0 19,2 8,5 13,6 19,8 26,4 19,3 20,0 36,8 18,9 6,3 12,8 18,9 21,1 19,6 18,7 34,2 18,2 8,5 18,6 18,4 22,6 22,0 28,9 31,5 37,1 27,2 20,4 25,8 28,4 34,0 24,6 14,9 24,4 24,8 31,1 20,2 17,6 24,9 25,4 31,9 25,5 37,4 nd 33,5 nd 25,1 nd 24,6 nd Source: Own calculation from LFS During the crisis, temporary employment has shown a cyclical pattern. In the first phase there was a sharp reduction, largely because of the heavy job losses in construction and because industrial enterprises reduced temporary employment as a means of making a short-term adjustment. As this first adjustment is coming to an end, temporary employment is flourishing again (Figure 1), despite the fact that the two labour reforms of the period (2010 and 2012) made it easier and less expensive to dismiss employees on open-ended contracts. In part, this “recovery” of temporary employment can be explained by the increased activity in the sectors in which it is most common. In fact, there is some structural inertia (Toharia 2005), and in sectors in which temporary employment has been high, it is again increasing rapidly. Furthermore, the crisis 6 has led enterprises and the public sector to use types of recruitment aimed at limiting the use of labour, and this translates into short-term contracts. Figure 1. Changes in employment, permanent and fix term contracts and part time work (2005Q1=100) 140.0 120.0 100.0 80.0 Total employment Permanent contracts 60.0 Fix term contracts 40.0 Part time work 20.0 0.0 The most significant change has occurred in part-time employment (Figure 1), traditionally considered uncommon in the Spanish labour market, although there are indications that this is partly because informal employment (e.g. domestic cleaning, elderly care, etc., usually done informally by women and mostly part-time) has been undervalued. It is now an expanding form of employment and during the crisis it has shown strong growth, largely because companies have tried to reduce working time and minimize labour costs. Some sectoral studies (Castillo 2013; Moreno et al 2014) also note that parttime employment is used as a mechanism to force an increase in work rates by combining short-term contracts with stipulation of the tasks to be done, leading to an intensification of the rate. The growth of these jobs is often associated with outsourcing of activities to service companies or temporary employment agencies (very common, for example, in cleaning and hospitality). There is also evidence that this type of contract is being used as a way to avoid paying taxes and social contributions. In fact, it is fairly common for workers on a part-time contract to be actually working full time. All of this makes part-time work ideal for generating working poor and increasing the precariousness of employment (Blazquez and Moral 2013; Recio et al 2015). Various aspects of the development of part-time contracts are noteworthy. The first is that most people with part-time jobs—including the women who make up the majority of part-time workers—are in this situation because they cannot find full-time jobs (Table 3). In addition, as the importance of this form of employment has increased, the proportion of involuntary part-time workers has also increased. This situation can be explained by a combination 7 of several factors. First, there is no public income supplement system to compensate for low wages in current income and in future pension entitlements. Second, the crisis of male employment directly affects working class household income, and the part-time income of the members of the household is insufficient. Third, cultural changes in Spanish society mean that a growing percentage of women aspire to financial independence that is not guaranteed by the part-time employment model (largely a simple variation of the Victorian family model). Therefore, part of the unemployment is camouflaged by growing underemployment, which may involve workers who were previously in full-time formal employment. Table 3. Part time employment over total employment and involuntary part time work (people working part time because they do not found a full time employment) in Spain % part time employment over total employment Involuntary part time work Period Total Male Female Total Male Female 2005 12,6 4,8 24,2 32,3 30,3 32,9 2006 12,0 4,5 22,9 32,7 32,5 32,7 2007 11,8 4,3 22,4 32,3 31,4 32,6 2008 11,8 4,2 22,2 33,6 30,7 34,4 2009 12,7 4,8 22,8 42,7 46,5 41,6 2010 13,2 5,5 23,1 49,7 54,0 48,3 2011 13,9 6,1 23,4 53,5 60,3 51,4 2012 14,7 6,7 24,2 56,4 62,6 54,4 2013 16,1 8,2 25,6 62,3 66,6 60,7 2014 16,4 8,2 26,1 63,4 69,3 61,1 Source: Own calculation from LFS. Second quarter of each year The second noteworthy aspect is the strong increase in part-time employment among men. This dynamic suggests that new ways of managing quantitative labour flexibility may be emerging, in which labour costs are reduced by adjusting contracts closely to the time needed for the activity. The evolution of part-time employment by sectors (Table 4) shows a significant increase in tertiary activities and also in sectors in which this form of employment was formerly unusual (e.g. construction and industry, both very masculinized). Also noteworthy is the increase in activities with a strong presence of the public sector, such as education and health. Finally, it should be noted that the increase in part-time employment is also occurring in the sectors in which temporary employment is increasing significantly. The combination of these two forms of flexibility makes the conditions of employment even more precarious. 8 Table 4. Part time employment over total employment by economic activity in Spain 2008Q1 2011Q1 2014Q1 2015Q1 11,8 13,9 16,2 16,3 Total 9,2 9,3 9,9 8,7 Agriculture, forestry and fishing 1,5 3,9 1,8 2,8 Mining and quarrying 4,2 4,7 6,0 5,8 Manufacturing 3,3 2,7 4,3 2,4 Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply Water supply; sewerage, waste management and remediation activities Construction Wholesale and retail trade; repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles Transportation and storage Accommodation and food service activities J Information and communication Financial and insurance activities Real estate activities Professional, scientific and technical activities Administrative and support service activities Public administration and defence; compulsory social security Education Human health and social work activities Arts, entertainment and recreation Other service activities Activities of households as employers; undifferentiated goods- and services-producing activities of households for own use Activities of extraterritorial organisations and bodies 5,4 2,7 5,5 5,2 9,6 6,3 6,5 7,4 13,6 6,4 18,1 8,2 6,0 14,9 10,7 26,4 4,3 19,4 11,7 27,8 15,9 14,8 7,3 24,0 8,2 5,8 11,7 11,6 28,8 4,9 18,7 14,4 29,2 20,8 17,4 8,4 29,2 8,0 5,1 17,5 14,1 31,7 4,8 22,0 16,5 32,4 21,0 17,9 8,3 27,3 7,4 6,7 20,7 12,4 30,7 5,3 23,0 17,0 32,1 21,9 51,0 nd 49,0 nd 50,9 nd nd 54,4 Source: Own calculation from LFS. 5. Changes in collective bargaining The 2012 labour reform is undoubtedly the most radical of the many that have been implemented in Spain. Some of the measures taken follow the line initiated in previous reforms: making dismissal easier and less expensive, and increasing managerial prerogatives on work organization and wage setting. However, the transformation has been most radical in the field of collective bargaining (Pérez 2013). The model previous to the reform had long provided a floor of social rights to millions of workers, despite the low level of union membership and the predominance of small businesses in the employment structure. The Spanish collective bargaining system is complex, with agreements at enterprise level and at sector level. The former are usually predominant in large companies where there is greater trade union organization. Sectoral agreements (which may be national, regional or provincial, according to the sector) cover most small companies, even those in which there is no union representation (Fina et al 2001). This is because the Spanish laws recognize trade union representativeness on the basis of the trade union elections of the companies in each sector rather than on the basis of affiliation. Elections usually occur only in companies with more than 50 or 100 employees, but the results obtained in these companies affect the representativeness throughout the sector. The large trade unions have thus negotiated agreements covering the working conditions of all companies in 9 the sector, regardless of the representation that they have at company level. In addition, the labour laws include a clause on “ultraactivity”, which presupposes that, on expiry of a collective agreement (usually negotiated for periods of 1-3 years), its conditions are maintained until a new agreement is signed. In fact, this mechanism was designed to encourage the adoption of previous agreements as a basis for bargaining. The new labour reform is attempting to destroy this whole mechanism in various ways: it encourages companies to stop applying all or some of the conditions of the agreement if they can allege economic reasons; it give priority to the enterprise agreement rather than the sectoral agreement; allows a negotiating mechanism with employee representation elected without union guarantees; and it reduces “ultraactivity” to one year. After a year the agreement is extinguished, and it is uncertain what rules should apply. The law provides that a similar agreement should be applied, but it is not clear what will happen in the case of enterprise agreements and specific sectors, for which there is no similar agreement. Some companies have decided that only the basic rules of the Workers’ Statute need to be applied, so they have cut pay to the level of the minimum wage. Figure 2. Colective agreements trend 14000 12000 10000 8000 6000 4000 2000 0 Number of collective agreements in force Number of employees covered by collective agreements (000) In many cases employers have used the rules strategically to curb collective bargaining in the hope that, when the old agreement expires, the bargaining conditions will be more favourable to them. According to official figures, the first effect of this policy has been the dramatic decline in the number of workers covered by collective agreements (Figure 2). There is as yet insufficient empirical evidence to know what has happened to the working conditions of those not covered by an agreement. Social conflict is increasingly moving into the courts, which have often determined that, though the agreements have expired, the individual workers still retain their rights and wages. Collective regulation of the agreement is thus transferred to individual rights. The situation of these workers is frozen but, because their rights are individual, a new type of discrimination arises: companies may change the conditions of employment of new employees at their discretion. 7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 1000 0 años employees collective agreements 10 The transformation of the collective bargaining model has led to a reduction in pay. Aggregated data of the survey on wage costs do not allow for an accurate assessment because they are influenced by the composition effect 3 (changes in the structure of employment by occupation and sector) and seasonality. The survey on pay structure provides more detailed information, but the last year available is 2012, so the effects of the latest labour reform cannot be assessed (Table 5). Table 5. Wage distribution in Spain 2008-2012 2008 2009 2010 2011 All average 21883,42 22511,47 22790,2 22899,35 median 18244,4 18803,28 19017,09 19303,51 Women average 18910,62 19502,02 19735,22 19767,59 median 15886,02 16433,14 16536,1 16796,41 Men average 24203,33 25001,05 25479,74 25667,89 median 20057,56 20730,71 21206,99 21487,99 Source: Wage structure survey, INE 2012 22726,44 19040,98 19537,33 16524,51 25682,05 21425,14 Nevertheless, there is a clear trend towards wage decline. There has also been an increase in the number of employed persons who fail to earn the annual minimum wage (because of the proliferation of part-time and/or shortterm jobs) and in the already high proportion of people with less than twice the minimum wage (Figure 3). These findings indicate the predominance of a low-pay market (and agricultural wages, always low, are not included in these figures). Figure 3. % of workers according to their incomes related to the Minimum Wage 3 For example, a report by the Studies Service of the Spanish Central Bank shows that an alleged increase in labour costs at the beginning of the crisis was due only to the change in the composition of employment: the highest proportion of jobs destroyed were low-pay jobs, so the average wage cost of those who kept their jobs rose (Puente and Galán 2014). 11 6. Unemployment and poverty The effects of the crisis go far beyond employment and have their most visible impact in the strong increase in unemployment. Much time will be needed to compensate for the enormous number of jobs lost in the seven years of crisis, two long periods of recession, and adjustment policies that themselves caused the second recession. In fact, part of the decline in unemployment is due to a reduction in the labour supply from mid-2012. This reduction is explained by a new migratory flow (foreign workers returning to their country and young people seeking employment abroad), something that had not taken place in Spain since the early 1970s, and by the “discouraged worker” effect, by which unemployed workers are statistically converted into inactive workers. The other face of unemployment is increasing inequality and poverty that have raised dramatically (Fundación Foessa 2013) (Tabla 6). Table 6. People in risk of poverty or social exclusion (Strategy Europa 2020) 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 29,2 Total 24,7 26,1 26,7 27,2 27,3 29,4 Men 23,8 25,5 26,1 27,3 27,9 28,9 women 25,6 26,7 27,4 27,2 26,7 Source: Living conditions survey Unemployment always involves a loss of income, just as part-time employment involves low income. Preventing workers in these situations from falling into poverty depends not only on the labour market but also on the social protection system. Countries with high rates of part-time employment, such as Denmark, Sweden and the Netherlands, have low rates of poverty thanks to relatively generous family support policies. The same applies to unemployment. This is not the case in Spain in either of the two fields: the family protection system is 12 very weak and the unemployment protection system is insufficient to guarantee income to the long-term unemployed (Addabbo et al 2012). The Spanish unemployment protection system consists of two levels: contributory benefit and welfare benefit. Contributory benefit marks the right of entry to the entire system. To receive this benefit, workers must have contributed for at least six months, which excludes persons entering the labour market for the first time or returning to it, and those who have had short-term jobs. The period of benefit varies according to the number of monthly contributions, but the maximum is 24 months after 48 monthly contributions. The amount of benefit is based on the value of the contribution (the base salary). It is initially 80% of the base salary (with a maximum of 1.7 times the minimum wage) and decreases in each six-month period to reach 50% in the last period. When this mechanism has been exhausted, welfare benefits can be obtained by people with special personal characteristics (people over 45, with family responsibilities, with low income, etc.) and for a maximum period of 11 months (except for persons over 55, who are in fact considered to be outside the labour market). Persistent unemployment has reached such a high level that in 2010 a new type of benefit, integration income, was created for persons who have been unemployed for over a year without benefit and with specific characteristics. They receive 11 months’ benefit in exchange for agreeing to carry out an integration plan designed by the employment services. There is also a separate scheme for seasonal agricultural workers in southern Spain. These three types of welfare income (welfare benefit, the integration income and benefit for agricultural workers) are all of the same amount: 80% of the IPREM (an index of income approved each year by the Government, which is lower than the minimum wage; it is currently €425 per month). All unemployed people who receive some form of benefit may also be called on to carry out unpaid community work. It should also be noted that the Spanish minimum wage has undergone a permanent real depreciation in the last 20 years (except for a slight increase in 2005-2008) and is situated close to the level of relative poverty. All non-contributory benefits are clearly below this rate. Two facts show the lack of generosity of the Spanish system of unemployment protection. The first is its coverage ratio: the percentage of unemployed people who receive benefit. The official figures of coverage show serious shortcomings. The numerator includes all people receiving some form of unemployment benefit. The denominator includes the number of people registered as unemployed in the employment offices. This is a problematic figure. The number of people registered as unemployed does not take into account the unregistered unemployed (especially people who are not entitled to benefit) and, in addition, the unemployment census is adjusted by the employment service with opaque criteria (e.g. it is known that the unemployed who receive training are taken off the register; paradoxically they are counted in the numerator as earners of income but they are not counted in the denominator). We have therefore calculated an index of coverage that includes in the denominator the number of unemployed in the Survey of the Working Population, which is drawn up with a clearer and approved methodology. Both calculations show a common denominator (Figure 4): the sustained fall in the coverage ratio from 2010, indicating that an increasing percentage of 13 unemployed receive no income. The difference is in the level: according to official figures the percentage of unemployed without income is more than 40% of the total, whereas according to our calculation it is more than 50%. A recent study with microdata from the Survey of the Working Population (Negueruela 2015) has shown that the reality is even worse. The reason is that some claimants of benefit are not unemployed in a statistical sense: they are early retirees (people of advanced age, usually over 57, who have lost their jobs in restructuring processes and have been integrated into a scheme that guarantees their income until retirement and allows them to draw the unemployment benefit to which they are entitled). The study estimates that the coverage of benefit for the unemployed was 29.24% in the first quarter of 2015, 9.64 points below the level of 2011. There are also great inequalities based on age (older people enjoy the greatest coverage because they have contributed for a longer time when they lose their jobs and because of the very nature of welfare benefit), sex (men are more protected) and region (regions with higher unemployment such as Murcia, Andalusia and the Canary Islands have significantly lower rates of coverage). Figure 4 Unemployed receving benefits 90 80 70 60 50 AT REG 40 AT EPA 30 20 10 0 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 We should take into account not only the percentage of people receiving benefit but also the number. There is an important difference between contributory benefit and welfare benefit. It is therefore meaningful to determine the percentage of claimants of each type of benefit. In 2010, 60% of unemployed persons entitled to benefit received contributory benefit and 40% received welfare benefit. At the end of 2014 the percentage of contributory benefit had fallen to 41.3% according to the unemployment figures of the employment services. However, if we use the LFS unemployment figures to calculate the number of people receiving contributory benefit, it drops to 18.6, and it could be even lower according to the analysis by Negueruela. Therefore, a large number of Spanish unemployed receive no benefit and many more receive only povertylevel benefit (Table 7). 14 Table 7. Anual net income by person (over 16 years old) in relatioship with the economic activity 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 10.904 Total 11.855 11.835 11.362 11.297 11.068 12.289 Employees 13.365 13.448 13.015 13.028 12.563 7.031 Unemployed 8.743 8.360 8.114 7.792 7.608 13.236 Retired 12.652 12.911 12.368 12.887 13.049 9.476 Other inactive 9.964 9.977 9.611 9.605 9.630 Source: Living conditions survey This leads to two conclusions. The first is that the high Spanish unemployment rate cannot be explained by questions of supply if the vast majority of the unemployed receive no benefits or insufficient benefit. The second is that the benefit system translates unemployment into increased poverty and inequality, as is shown in the deprivation index and the Gini index for Spain. The question is how do people subsist? The answer is strong family solidarity (including even sharing the retirement income of parents), a resurgence of the informal economy (although some of it is more pro-cyclical than cyclical) and the traditional networks of charity, many of them linked to the Catholic Church, which have been reactivated in recent years. 7. Conclusion: What is the best model for overcoming the crisis? In our first contribution to the analysis of the crisis in Spain (Banyuls and Recio 2012), we presented the changes that we considered key for best overcoming the situation and we also made a forecast of where things could go if these changes were not made. We felt that the most crucial elements affecting the economy and employment in Spain were an inadequate production structure (which led to repeated deficits and foreign debt), insufficient development of the public sector (in terms of welfare and of fostering a change in the type of production), and excessive inequality caused by insufficient public policies and downward pressure on wages in business management policies. (Reducing these inequalities would greatly reduce social suffering and could promote a more cooperative production model, more oriented towards quality and more environmentally sustainable). We also suggested that if these changes were not made, the result could be that, instead of moving towards the Northern European route (which is the aspiration of much of the population), Spain is heading towards the Latin American route of societies with very high inequality and a public sector that is unable to meet the collective needs. After eight years of crisis, hardly anything has been done to deal with the production structure. Furthermore, the current economic recovery continues to focus on sectors that have dominated the national economy in recent years. The development of the public sector and inequality have even worsened as a result of the cuts and structural reforms applied in Spain. These reforms were imposed by the EU leadership in return for the rescue of the Spanish banking 15 system, but were often adopted enthusiastically by local elites. And the results suggest that we are approaching an unacceptable evolution: unbearable employment rates that will continue in time according to all forecasts, growing inequality, poverty, formal underemployment (part-time jobs), informal underemployment, and deterioration of public services, which will be replaced partially by private charities. Informal employment has always been present in Spain but it has perhaps shown the lowest rates of growth, not because there are no people willing to “make a living” (as is patent in the number of garbage scavengers in large cities), but because activities such as street vending are subject to repression. Nevertheless, informal employment may increase in scale if the context does not change. Spain’s problems are common to those of other Southern countries. We therefore think that without a regional approach for Southern Europe the decline will persist, and the current recovery is just a short episode in a general context of crisis. Bibliography References Addabbo T.; García-Fernández, R.; Llorca-Rodríguez, C.; Maccagnan, A. (2012), “Poverty and Unemployment: The Cases of Italy and Spain”, in G. Parodi and D. Sciulli (eds.), Social Exclusion, AIEL, Series inLabour Economics, Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg. Banyuls, J., Recio, A. (2012), “Spain: the nightmare of Mediterranean neoliberalism”, in Lehndorff, S. (ed), A triumph of failed ideas. European models of capitalism in the crisis, Brussels, ETUI:199-216. Banyuls, J.; F. Miguélez; A. Recio; E. Cano and R. Lorente (2009) “The transformation of the Employment System in Spain: Towards a Mediterranean Neoliberalism?”, in G. Bosch, S. Lehndorff and J, Rubery (ed) European Employment Models in Flux, Palgrave Macmillan. Blázquez, M.; Moral, J. (2014): “El empleo a tiempo parcial femenino. “Flexiriesgo” en cinco países europeos”, Revista Internacional del Trabajo, vol 133, nº 2, pp. 299-324. Castillo, J.J. (2013): “Nuevas tendencias de organización en las relaciones laborales en la crisis: trabajar en cliente y trabajar en proyecto”, Anuario de Relaciones Laborales de España 4: 54-66. Consejo Económico y Social (2013), Distribución de la renta en España: desigualdad, cambios estructurales y ciclos, Madrid, CES.(http://www.ces.es/documents/10180/526241/Inf0313.pdf) Dolado, J.; García Serrano, C.; Jimeno, J.F. (2002): “Drawing lessons from the boom of temporary Jobs in Spain” Economic Journal, 112. Fina, L.; González, F.; Pérez J. I. (2001): Negociación colectiva y salarios en España, CES Madrid. Fundación Foessa (2013), Desigualdad y derechos sociales, Madrid: FoessaCáritas. Miguélez, F. and A. Recio, (2010) “The uncertain path from the Mediterranean welfare model in Spain”, in D. Anxo, G. Bosch and J. Rubery (ed) The 16 Welfare State and Life Transitions. A European Perspective, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Moreno, S., Godino, A. y Recio, A. (2014): “Servicios externalizados y condiciones laborales. De la competencia de precios a la presión sobre el tiempo de trabajo”, Sociología del Trabajo, 81: 50-67. Perez Infante, J.I. (2011) “La negociación colectiva y los salarios en España” Cuadernos de Relaciones Laborales vol 21. Pérez, F. (2013), “La contrareforma laboral”, Anuario IET de Trabajo y Relaciones laborales, Vol. 1. Barcelona. (http://revistes.uab.cat/anuarioiet/issue/view/v1) Prieto, C. (coord.), Arnal, M.; Caprile, M.; Potrony, J. (2011), La calidad del empleo en España: Una aproximación teórica y empírica, Madrid, Ministerio de Trabajo e Inmigración. Recio, A (2013) “2012: la segunda recesión” Anuari de l’Institut d’Estudis del Treball Barcelona, IET. (http://revistes.uab.cat/anuarioiet/issue/view/v1) Recio, A., Moreno, S.; Godino, A. (2015): “Out of sight. Dimensions of working time in gendered occupations” in Holgrewe, Ursula, Ramioul, Dominique and Vassil Kirov (ed) Hard times in new jobs Palgrave Macmillan (forthcoming). Toharia, L. (2011): “El debate sobre las reformas necesarias para la economía española: el mercado de trabajo”, Gaceta Sindical nº 17, pp. 201-236. Toharia, L. (dir), (2005), El problema de la temporalidad en España: un diagnóstico, Madrid, Ministerio de Trabajo y Asuntos Sociales. 17