ATTACHMENT G COMPARATIVE PERFORMANCE OF OTHER OPTIONS THE BASE CASE (STATUS QUO) Over time, current efforts under the base case would result in modest growth in packaging recycling and an incremental reduction in litter. However, the base case does not include action to address current market failures which limit the recycling and litter reduction opportunities being exploited, especially away from home. The base case does not address increasing fragmentation in jurisdictional approaches as it does not seek commitment to a strengthened national approach. This risks a patchwork of packaging regulations continuing to develop across Australia with associated costs to businesses and the economy. OPTION 1—NATIONAL PACKAGING WASTE STRATEGY Option 1 partially addresses increasing fragmentation in jurisdictional approaches through improved government coordination. However, it does this weakly due to the low scale of investment and outcomes delivered, which are unlikely to stop jurisdictions from implementing additional measures driven by community and stakeholder expectations. Arguably, some of the opportunities the option forecasts are already being pursued through government collaboration, potentially reducing the scale of additional outcomes that it may deliver. Because it is funded by government revenue, which does not provide a price signal to consumers, option 1 may not be a strong mechanism for boosting incentives to recycle and prevent litter. Option 1 does not address the identified market failures as strongly as other options due to its low level of investment, which would leave many opportunities to address market impediments unexploited. OPTIONS 2A-D—CO-REGULATION UNDER PRODUCT STEWARDSHIP ACT Co-regulatory arrangements operating under new regulations made under the Product Stewardship Act (PS Act) would undertake recycling and litter actions on behalf of industry members and would have strong incentives to achieve outcomes at least cost. The regulations would set tightly defined targets for additional recycling to ensure delivery. The trade-off is that a complex compliance monitoring framework is required. Therefore, although co-regulatory arrangements operate cost-effectively these options would increase government administration costs over the base case. Because option 2a transfers current arrangements under this new framework, it involves increased administration costs to manage current levels of effort. At the same time, option 2a seeks only a modest increase in industry investment and the recycling rate, which is assumed to result from the strengthened enforceability of the regulated targets. This would leave many opportunities to address market impediments unexploited and is why it has a low Net Present Value. Options 2b and 2d aim to achieve more ambitious targets and outcomes than option 2a, with greater levels of investment. However, 2b’s sub-target for beverage container recycling and 2d’s high overall target for beverage container recycling reduce the cost-effectiveness of these approaches. Three quarters of beverage containers sold in Australia are made of glass and therefore co-regulatory arrangements would be forced to invest heavily in glass recycling, with low market return and limited impact on environmental externalities (see Chapter 7). The focus on collecting beverage containers also limits opportunities to leverage co-benefits and value from the recycling of other packaging materials. These options therefore have a negative Net Present Value representing an overall cost to the economy and cannot be recommended for implementation. Option 2c has a relatively high positive Net Present Value and overcomes the disadvantage of having a beverage container sub-target because it also proposes the greatest recycling target for all packaging materials. This push to recycle high volumes of the other materials compensates for the glass recycling by exploiting more opportunities than options 2b and 2d and delivering higher recyclate value overall. However, the cost-effectiveness per tonne of recycling is lower than in options 1, 2a and 2e. Regulated targets are a less flexible mechanism than the preferred option, and largely define the achievement of outcomes as chasing the recycling tonnage target. Finally, the ambitious outcomes sought by option 2c are likely to approach the known limits of recycling under current approaches, and the sensitivity and risk analysis identified that overall it carries a risk of projected outcomes not being achieved. While these options would address increasing fragmentation in jurisdictional approaches by introducing consistent national regulations, options 2b, c and d increase the funding required from the packaged goods industry to pay membership fees to co-regulatory arrangements to address market failures and improve recycling and litter reduction substantially more than required by the preferred option, for a largely similar result. It is assumed that this cost would be at least partly passed on to and impact consumers. OPTION 3—MANDATORY ADVANCE DISPOSAL FEE Option 3 has a relatively high positive Net Present Value and was modelled to seek the same additional recycling and litter reduction outcomes as option 2c, but through a different regulatory mechanism. The advance disposal fee would be collected from industry based on tonnes of packaging brought to market and invested by government to fund recycling and litter initiatives. Overall, this option has similar strengths and weaknesses to option 2c. It invests in more opportunities to achieve the greater outcomes, but with a lower cost-effectiveness per tonne than other options. There is also the same overall level of risk as in option 2c that the ambitious outcomes may not be achieved. The primary impact of this option on business is to substantially increase the funding required from packaging manufacturers and importers to pay the advance disposal fee. It is assumed that this cost would be at least partly passed on to and impact consumers. This option addresses increasing fragmentation in jurisdictional approaches by introducing a consistent national regulatory framework in the form of taxation (collection of fees). OPTION 4—CONTAINER DEPOSIT SCHEME The CDS options modelled in option 4 all impose substantially negative net costs to the economy and cannot be recommended for implementation. Although the introduction of new CDS options would deliver high beverage container recycling rates and overall the greatest litter reduction due to high rates of beverage container litter collection, this comes at an unsustainable cost. This cost is driven by the roll-out of parallel, purpose-built infrastructure that diverts recyclate from existing kerbside systems and must do so by handling and accounting for each unit—billions of beverage containers per year. In addition, the recycling outcomes are lower than other options such as 2c and 3 as they are constrained by focusing on beverage containers rather than all packaging types. This remains true even taking into account the estimated co-benefits, which are generally lower in options 4a and 4b than the preferred option due to use of Reverse Vending Machines which can only take beverage containers. Option 4c is projected to achieve co-benefits on par with the preferred option, based on the performance of the SA scheme’s more diverse manual collection points. Option 4 would address increasing fragmentation in jurisdictional approaches by introducing consistent national regulations. However additional measures and costs are likely to be required for options 4a and 4b in particular to harmonise with the existing South Australian and Northern Territory schemes to form a national approach.