The Economic Sociology of Responsibility Accounting: A Field Study in a Chinese State-Owned Enterprise ChunLei Yang Sven Modell* Manchester Business School University of Manchester *Corresponding author Address: Manchester Business School University of Manchester Crawford House Booth Street West Manchester M15 6PB United Kingdom E-mail: Sven.Modell@mbs.ac.uk 28 May, 2012 Acknowledgements: The research informing this paper was funded by the Swedish Research Council. The paper was partly completed whilst the second author was a Visiting Professor at the University of Sydney (2011). Earlier versions of the paper were presented at research seminars at the Universities of Sydney, Southampton and Cardiff and the 2012 MASOP workshop at London School of Economics. We thank Chris Chapman, Silvia Jordan, Kari Lukka, David Marginson, Martin Messner, Yuval Millo, Keith Robson, Will Seal, Wim van der Stede and Jason Xiao for their comments on earlier drafts. 1 The Economic Sociology of Responsibility Accounting: A Field Study in a Chinese State-Owned Enterprise Abstract Research on responsibility accounting has been dominated by functionalist perspectives of which many subscribe to economics-based approaches, such as agency theory. By contrast, little is known about the social and political dynamics associated with the development of systems for this purpose and how the social gets implicated in the economic as notions of responsibility accounting diffuse across different socio-economic contexts. This paper addresses this knowledge gap through a historically informed field study in a state-owned enterprise (SOE) in the People’s Republic of China. In doing so, we mobilize an analytical framework grounded in economic sociology and seek some rapprochement between diverse schools of thought within this body of research. Insights from classical versions of economic sociology emphasising the social embeddedness of economic behaviour are combined with more recent advances concentrating on the performative, or strongly constitutive, roles of accounting and the theories in which it is embedded. In contrast to much accounting research in the latter vein, we demonstrate how the use of responsibility accounting to frame economic behaviour became entangled with a broader range of socially embedded contingencies and how the interplay between such contingencies and emerging systems of responsibility accounting shaped the constitutive roles of the latter. This addresses concerns that the performative tradition in economic sociology might bracket the influence of the broader socio-economic environment in examining the constitutive roles of accounting. We discuss the implications for future research on responsibility accounting and how it is implicated in processes of organizational change. 2 The Economic Sociology of Responsibility Accounting: A Field Study in a Chinese State-Owned Enterprise Introduction The concept of responsibility accounting has long constituted the bedrock of management control in hierarchically structured organizations and continues to attract considerable research interest (e.g., Frow et al., 2005; Rowe et al., 2008; Simons, 2005). Research on this topic has been dominated by functionalist approaches of which many subscribe to economics-based theorizing. Notable conceptual and analytical advances have been made by agency theorists seeking optimal modes of contracting (e.g., Antle and Demski, 1988; Baiman and Noel, 1985; Demski and Sappington, 1989; Melumad et al., 1992). Empirical evidence supporting agency theory postulates has also accumulated and sheds further light on the economics of designing systems of responsibility accounting under specific structural and environmental conditions (e.g., Bushman et al., 1995; Merchant, 1987, 1989; Ugras, 1994). Similar to much economics-based research on accounting, however, these advances explicitly or implicitly assume a state of equilibrium and pay hardly any attention to the social and political dynamics implicated in the process of changing systems of responsibility accounting. Whilst recent research on the role of responsibility accounting in processes of organizational change affirms its powerful influence on economic behaviour, it also underlines the merits of widening the examination of this topic to include insights from a broader range of social theories (see Rowe et al., 2008). Yet much remains to know about how the social gets implicated in the economic as notions of responsibility accounting diffuse across different socio-economic contexts. Our understanding of how responsibility accounting evolves and shapes economic behaviour beyond traditional capitalist enterprises is especially limited and would seem to warrant a research perspective that recognises the broader social premises influencing systems for this purpose (cf. Berry et al., 1985; Bloomfield et al., 1992; Modell and Lee, 2001). The present paper addresses this issue through a historically informed field study in a state-owned enterprise (SOE) in the People’s Republic of China (PRC) and draws on diverse strands within economic sociology to develop an explanatory framework. More specifically, we ask how changing systems of responsibility accounting interact with their broader, socio-economic context and how this interplay shapes economic behaviour. To address this research question we combine insights from classical versions of economic sociology emphasising the social embeddedness of economic behaviour (Granovetter, 1985; Polanyi, 1944; Zukin and DiMaggio, 1990) with more recent advances concentrating on the performative, or strongly constitutive, roles of calculative devices and the theories in which they are embedded (Callon, 1998a, 1998b). Whilst these perspectives have been positioned as alternative or competing schools of thought within economic sociology (see Fligstein and Dauter, 2007; Fourcade, 2007; Miller, 2002), we demonstrate how a novel system of responsibility accounting partly inspired by agency theoretic rationales became entangled with embedded governance and control practices and how this conditioned its constitutive effects on economic behaviour. This leads us to elaborate on how insights from classical economic sociology may enrich emerging accounting research situated within the performative tradition and how such rapprochement may enhance our 3 understanding of how accounting is implicated in the shaping of economic behaviour. As such, our study advances an alternative theorization of how responsibility accounting affects economic behaviour to the economics-based perspective permeating much research on the topic. We also contribute to the sparse literature on how systems of responsibility accounting are implicated in processes of organizational change. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. We start by introducing economic sociology and offering a tentative discussion of how the different schools of thought within this broad research tradition can be brought together in examining the notion of responsibility accounting. We then introduce the research setting and describe the methods employed. Our empirical analysis then traces the development of responsibility accounting in Chinese SOEs in general as well as in our field study site over a period of nearly 30 years. We close the paper with a concluding discussion summarizing our key findings and contributions. An Economic Sociology Perspective on Responsibility Accounting Economic sociologists have long recognised the socially embedded nature of behaviour in markets and other spheres of economic life (Granovetter, 1985; Polanyi, 1944).1 The sources of such embeddedness have variously been ascribed to structural, political, cultural and cognitive mechanisms that evolve over time and imbue economic behaviour with context-specific norms and meanings (Dacin et al., 1999; Zukin and DiMaggio, 1990). Such a view of embeddedness is amply represented in the accounting literature and is notably manifest in studies of how extant socioeconomic premises condition evolving accounting practices (e.g., Modell and Wiesel, 2008; Neu, 1992; Neu and Simmons, 1996). In contradistinction to this classical view of embeddedness as a “naturally” occurring phenomenon in response to historical contingencies, Callon (1998a) invoked a view of economic behaviour as constituted by the very theories and calculative devices that economists employ. In other words, economic theories and models do not only represent but also shape economic realities and thus play important performative roles. This performative perspective has inspired a burgeoning research programme centred on the idea of economization (see Caliskan and Callon, 2009, 2010) which has gradually found its way into the accounting literature (e.g., Christensen and Skærbæk, 2004; Millo and MacKenzie, 2009; Skærbæk and Tryggestad, 2010; Vollmer, 2007). Even though the insight that calculative devices play an important constitutive role was long anticipated by sociologically informed accounting scholars (Burchell et al., 1980; Miller, 1994, 2007), closer engagement with the performative tradition in economic sociology may refine our understanding of how such devices shape specific types of economic behaviour (Vollmer et al., 2009). We draw some inspiration from this research programme but also seek some rapprochement with classical versions of economic sociology in examining the evolution of responsibility accounting. Of particular relevance for our analysis of the constitutive role of responsibility accounting is Callon’s (1998b) discussion of framing and overflowing. 1 See Krippner and Alvarez (2007) for an extended discussion and comparison of Polanyian and Granovetterian approaches to embeddedness. 4 Drawing on Goffman (1971), Callon (1998b) mobilised the notion of frames as a metaphor for the boundaries established around social interactions in order to imbue them with a temporary degree of stability and predictability. Such framing implies that the world surrounding the focal interactions and relationships is momentarily bracketed. Even though such bracketing does not sever the links between the framed relationships and the larger social context in which they are embedded, it entails an element of disentanglement whereby the influence of the broader context can be controlled. This disentanglement is attributable to the strongly constitutive effects that frames often exercise on human cognition and behaviour. By framing what counts as effective or legitimate forms of behaviour some actors will assume the power to shape social interactions and relationships such that these ideals are achieved. Calculative devices such as those embedded in accounting arguably play a powerful role as frames in that they render economic behaviour controllable and at least partly disentangled from the wider socio-economic context that otherwise conditions it (Callon, 1998a; Gill, 2008; Miller, 1998). However, as demonstrated by a growing number of empirical studies accounting is not a panacea to this end and continuously generates overflows that need to be managed through additional framing efforts (e.g., Christensen and Skærbæk, 2004; Skærbæk, 2009; Skærbæk and Tryggestad, 2010). Callon (1998b) offered the notion of overflows as a sociological revision of the economist’s concept of externalities, or the tendency of economic orders to produce negative and positive consequences that go beyond the intended functions of particular contractual arrangements. In distinguishing the notion of overflows from that of externalities, however, Callon (1998b) departs from a view of such consequences as accidental and exceptional circumstances and argues that they should rather be viewed as constituted by the very attempts to frame economic behaviour. In other words, overflows are an unavoidable consequence of any framing of economic behaviour. Frames are always imperfect social arrangements and often require substantial investments to be maintained. As overflows occur, interactions and relationships need to be re-framed to establish new social orders within which they can be contained. Framing is thus a recursive process fuelled by the overflows that it generates. However, radical re-framing is only likely to take place in specific situations which Callon (1998b, p. 260) labels “hot”. In “hot” situations extant frames become strongly contested as diverse actors draw attention to overflows as a means of questioning prevailing social arrangements. But overflows can also persist over extended periods of time without triggering radical re-framing if situations remain “cold”. In “cold” situations framing is a less contested endeavour and is swiftly achieved as actors reach some agreement on the adequate means of ordering interactions and relationships and bracketing them from the surrounding environment. Callon’s (1998b) discussion of framing and overflowing provides a powerful analytical lens for examining how tendencies towards socio-economic order and disorder are in constant interaction and create an intricate web of change dynamics. Nevertheless, it has been criticised for under-playing the extent to which the broader socio-economic environment influences attempts to frame economic behaviour. A particularly forceful critique was provided by Miller (2002) who charged that Callon presents an overly sanguine view of the possibilities of disentangling particular interactions and relationships from the surrounding world. Economic transactions and contracting, he argues, are always conditioned by a broader set of historically contingent relationships and norms than those contained within the frame. This, in 5 turn, requires us to pay more careful attention to the historical processes causing particular forms of behaviour to be entangled with their broader, socio-economic context and how such entanglements contribute to perpetuate overflows rather than assuming that they may be momentarily controlled through some framing efforts. To further our understanding of such entanglements Miller (2002) called for a return to classical economic sociology based on Polanyi’s (1944) view of markets and other spheres of economic life as embedded in a much broader social system than that envisaged by Callon. However, other commentators have moderated this critique and have cautioned against over-stating the differences between classical economic sociology and the performative tradition (e.g., Fligstein and Dauter, 2007; Fourcade, 2007; MacKenzie, 2006; MacKenzie and Millo, 2003). Similarly, in the accounting literature, Vollmer et al. (2009) called for some rapprochement between the performative view and extant research into accounting as a socially embedded practice. With respect to responsibility accounting, such rapprochement may be accomplished by re-interpreting the design of concomitant performance contracts as an attempt to frame financial obligations whilst examining how the broader socio-economic context continuously conditions such framing efforts. Traditional notions of responsibility accounting refer to the structuring of organizations into hierarchies of financial responsibility centres with varying degrees of autonomy with the ultimate objective of aligning the interests of owners and managers. The design of systems for this purpose is often conceived of as a matter of matching the comprehensiveness of performance contracts with adequate delegation of decision-making rights through a degree of decentralization (McNally, 1980; Modell and Lee, 2001). Contract comprehensiveness refers to the range of performance aspects included in the responsibility assigned to managers. Highly aggregate, financial performance measures, such as various profit metrics, are more comprehensive than less aggregate revenue and cost measures, but are also more sensitive to a broader range of uncontrollable factors attributable to environmental disturbances which may reduce managerial motivation and performance (Merchant, 2006). To enhance controllability and reduce the risk of such dysfunctional effects comprehensive performance contracts often need to be accompanied by a significant degree of decentralization (McNally, 1980; Modell and Lee, 2001; Simons, 2005). From a framing perspective, such matching of contract comprehensiveness and decentralization may be seen as an attempt to contain overflows (ie. dysfunctional effects) and is notably captured by the emphasis traditionally placed on the controllability principle, or the notion that managers should only be held responsible for events and financial line items that they can control. Adherence to the controllability principle may be interpreted as an attempt to disentangle performance contracts from their wider socio-economic context by isolating responsibility centres from environmental disturbances and thereby enhance the predictability of economic behaviour (cf. Kilmann, 1983). This may explain its persistence as a normative ideal for the design of systems of responsibility accounting (see Ugras, 1994) despite the emergence of theoretical and empirical work qualifying this view (e.g., Burkert et al., 2011; Choudhury, 1986; Merchant, 1987, 1989; Giraud et al,, 2008) and long-standing evidence of the difficulties in applying it in complex organizations (e.g., McNally, 1980; Otley, 1990; Vancil, 1979). However, the existence of such evidence casts doubt on the very idea that performance contracts can be disentangled from their socio-economic context (cf. Miller, 2002) and prompts us to explore the change dynamics resulting from the interactions between 6 environmental disturbances and the overflows generated by particular performance contracts in greater detail. As noted in the introductory section of this paper, the literature on responsibility accounting offers few insights into such change dynamics (see Rowe et al., 2008). Consistent with the performative tradition in economic sociology, however, we need to consider how theoretical rationales for responsibility accounting become implicated in the process of change through their capacity to frame economic behaviour. Of particular relevance to our analysis is the frame provided by agency theorists for resolving the issue of aligning the interests of owners and managers. Agency theorists typically conceive of this as a matter of designing systems that mitigate agency problems, or the propensity of self-interested agents (managers) to exploit private information and shirk their responsibilities (see Baiman, 1990; Eisenhardt, 1989). Similar to the view of responsibility accounting outlined in the foregoing, this can arguably be accomplished by making some trade-offs between reliance on (1) relatively comprehensive performance contracts that incentivize the agent to take adequate, decentralized actions and (2) less comprehensive contracts within a more centralized structure that facilitates performance monitoring (see e.g., Moers, 2006). Contrary to the emphasis traditionally placed on the controllability principle, however, agency theorists have relaxed this ideal by arguing that inclusion of uncontrollable line items in more comprehensive performance contracts may address specific agency problems, such as excessive risk aversion (Demski, 1976), lacking attention to long-term capacity costs (Baiman and Noel, 1985), collusion among agents (Suh, 1987) and inefficient coordination of intra-organizational interdependencies (Bushman et al., 1995; Suh, 1988). Such arguments may fill an important constitutive role in so far as agency theory is invoked to frame the notion of responsibility accounting. The constitutive influence of agency theory on especially Anglo-American discourses on corporate governance and control is widely documented (see e.g., Roberts, 2001; Seal, 2006; Shapiro, 2005) and has arguably been salient in reforms in transitional economies such as the PRC (see e.g., Clarke, 2003; Lau et al., 2007; Wong, 2005). It would thus seem appropriate to take such discourses as a point of departure for our analysis of responsibility accounting whilst recognising how they interact with the broader, socio-economic context in which Chinese SOEs are embedded. Research Setting and Methods State-owned enterprises in the PRC have been subject to a series of governance reforms as part of the country’s transition towards a socialist market economy since 1978. The history of such reforms is relatively well-documented (e.g., Hassard et al., 1999, 2007; Hussain and Zhuang, 1997; Steinfeld, 1998) as is the concomitant adoption of management accounting techniques (e.g., Chow et al., 2007; Firth, 1996; O’Connor et al., 2004; Wu et al., 2007). However, there is still a dearth of deeper, theoretically informed case studies exploring the evolution of management accounting practices in individual SOEs (see Duh et al., 2008). The present study takes advantage of prior research on SOE reforms whilst deepening the analysis of the development of responsibility accounting through a historically informed field study in MetalCo (a pseudonym); a leading company in the non-ferrous mining and metal manufacturing 7 industry. The choice of such a research approach is consistent with the need to examine the how the interplay between emerging notions of responsibility accounting and their broader, socio-economic context shapes economic behaviour over time (cf. Dacin et al., 1999). The field study in MetalCo was part of a larger, ongoing research programme entailing data collection at multiple levels of analysis in the Chinese SOE sector (see Appendix). The present paper primarily builds on data solicited from the corporate headquarters of MetalCo in BeiJing and its main production unit (HN). MetalCo was formed in 2001 as part of the broader movement of consolidating Chinese SOEs into larger, internationally competitive entities (cf. Hassard et al., 2010) and incorporates six, previously independent production units (henceforth referred to as “branches”). Since its inception, it has been part-privatised through listings on Chinese and overseas stock markets although central government has retained a controlling ownership stake. The HN branch was formed in 1958 and is the largest and oldest production unit. Its production facilities are located in central China and are structured into seventeen sub-units of which ten are operational and seven administrative departments. Figure 1 provides an overview of its internal structure at the time of our field research. [Insert Figure 1 here] Access to HN and MetalCo headquarters was negotiated through personal contacts of the principal investigator who is a native Chinese. The decision to primarily focus on the relationship between these entities rather than broadening the study to other branches was prompted by the opportunity to collect rich, longitudinal data for a historically informed analysis that both precedes and follows the formation of MetalCo. Doing so was deemed necessary to develop a thorough understanding of how organization-specific as well as more general, historical contingencies have shaped the interplay between embedded control practices and emerging notions of responsibility accounting over time. Yet, despite this trade-off with the breadth of data collection, important insights into the more general incidence of certain types of economic behaviour emanating from this interplay were derived from the data obtained from corporate headquarters. The field study comprised four annual site visits between 2008 and 2011, each lasting several weeks, during which the principal investigator conducted a series of formal interviews at both corporate headquarters and in HN and engaged in extensive informal conversations and observations. In between the site visits, we maintained regular contacts with key informants (mostly via electronic mail) to validate emerging interpretations and follow ongoing developments. In total, over 80 semi-structured interviews and extended conversations with a broad range of mostly managerial staff were conducted during the site visits (see Appendix). The majority of the interviewees had spent their entire careers with HN and/or MetalCo. Key informants in HN, such as the Party Secretary-General, the Assistant Director and the Head and Deputy Head of the Accounting Department had served the branch for over two decades. Interviews were initially relatively open-ended to gain thorough insights into the development of broader control practices over time, but became increasingly focused on issues pertaining to responsibility accounting in the subsequent phases of the field work. Given the sensitivity of many issues covered in the interviews (e.g, the propensity for 8 various types of illicit behaviour) we refrained from tape recording them and rather documented them by taking extensive notes which were transcribed as soon as possible after each interview occasion. Interview data were subject to open-ended and thematic coding throughout the process of data collection and emerging patterns were systematically contrasted with other data sources. Periodic informal sessions with key informants were also organised to validate emerging interpretations. The more specific analysis informing the present paper primarily relies on a combination of oral histories extracted from our interviews and archival data documenting the history of HN and MetalCo. The latter data source included over sixty semi-official company records, hundreds of internal memos and more than twenty internal research reports documenting company-specific developments as well as broader industry trends. Oral histories have the advantage of adding candour to archival data, but entail potential reliability and validity threats associated with the fallibility of human memory (Hoffman, 1974). We sought to address such threats through repeated interviews with several informants, selection of interviewees representing diverse perspectives and systematic comparisons with archival data (Collins and Bloom, 1991; Hoffman, 1974). Repeated interviews were used as a means of checking the consistency of interviewee accounts as well as deepening the analysis of themes emerging as particularly significant in earlier interviews. We also sought to contrast the views of individuals representing different managerial perspectives within HN and corporate headquarters. As far as possible, we crosschecked our analysis of interview data with archival data for consistency and relevance whilst probing into patterns emerging in one or the other data source as data collection progressed. Whilst the case narrative does not aspire to providing a complete or “objective” representation of developments within HN and MetalCo (cf. Hammond and Sikka, 1996), we believe that these analytical procedures at least reduce the risk of bias associated with mainly relying on one, dominant data source in historically informed field research. We divide the ensuing empirical analysis into two main parts with slightly different foci. To enhance our understanding of how embedded control practices and specific forms of economic behaviour have conditioned the evolution of systems of responsibility accounting, we first describe the historical development of such systems in Chinese SOEs and HN prior to the formation of MetalCo. This is followed by an examination of more recent reforms and the system of responsibility accounting emerging after the formation of MetalCo across three analytically distinct phases. Embedded Control Practices and Early Reforms of Chinese SOEs From the Work Unit System to the Contract Responsibility System The emergence of notions of responsibility accounting in Chinese SOEs occurred in a socio-economic context that was long averse to Western accounting concepts as a result of the Maoist ideology dominating the country after 1949 and exercising a lingering influence after the initiation of market-orientated reforms in 1978 (Ezzamel et al., 2007). Prior to 1978, SOEs were primarily governed through the so-called work unit system which was a product of Soviet central planning and entailed a combination of highly centralized decision-making and relatively weak and 9 incomprehensive financial performance contracts. The system functioned through administrative commands whereby resources and information flowed hierarchically between central planners and SOEs. The former controlled key decisions pertaining to pricing, personnel issues, resource allocation and investments and intervened extensively in operational decision-making (Hassard et al., 2007; Steinfeld, 1998) whilst the economic responsibility of SOEs was largely confined to meeting nonfinancial production targets (Chow et al., 2007). Notions of economic efficiency were rather inconsequential as surpluses were remitted to the State and losses were absorbed into the state budget (Hassard et al., 2007; Skousen and Yang, 1988). Whilst some experiments with more elaborate systems for resource and cost allocation within SOEs were initiated in the early 1960s, they did not have much of a lasting impact as a result of being overtaken by the turmoil of the Cultural Revolution from 1966 (Chow et al., 2007; Scapens and Hou, 1995). Hence for an extended period of time SOEs largely operated without any real sense of having a financial bottom line or any clear notion of delegating financial responsibilities for management control. Instead, governance and control practices growing firmly embedded between 1949 and 1978 mainly relied on the so-called mass-line principle, which evolved into a key vehicle of furthering economic progress whilst ensuring ideological and political conformity. At one level, the mass-line principle required government officials to stay in touch with the popular sentiment of the masses through regular inspection of work places. At another level, it called for voluntarism on the part of the masses, urging them to exercise will power to overcome material odds and further economic progress. The mass-line principle left a distinct imprint on SOE management and enabled centralized decision-making and authoritarian leadership to be combined with mass mobilization aimed at energizing radical political activities (Lieberthal, 2004). Such mobilization was also underpinned by the practice of “political learning” exercised through seminars to study official documents, engage in organized selfcriticism and criticism of colleagues (Unger and Chan 2007). Conforming to such practices was pivotal for SOE management to gain recognition and furthering career progression through the nurturing of political connections. In addition, the standing of management was contingent on other, socially embedded ideals, such as the deeply ingrained Confucian notion of mutual dependence between superiors and subordinates requiring managers to possess high moral standards and take people’s interests to heart to command the respect of the masses (Shi, 2009). Consistent with such notions of reciprocity, the work unit system was based on the premise that organizational performance relies more on individuals fulfilling their moral obligations vis-à-vis one another than on formal financial incentives (Yang, 2008; Yang and Zhou, 1999). The incentives of SOE management under work-unit governance thus became entangled with a complex mix of social mechanisms although enhanced economic performance was expected to accrue from such mechanisms. The mass-line principle prompted SOEs to equate financial goals and production targets with actions undertaken in the name of revolutionary ideology (Mitter, 2004). Mandates for cost reduction were typically based on moral and political appeals to “saving for the nation” rather than explicit financial incentives. However, the efficacy of the framing of economic incentives within such social mechanisms gradually diminished as the masses became increasingly accustomed and indifferent to periodic campaigns. This produced persistent overflows, such as waste, data manipulation, pilfering and a widespread lack of attention to economic efficiency, collectively referred to the “SOE 10 illness”. The centralized decision-making structures and frequent political interventions proved largely ineffective in containing such overflows as they did not eliminate the private information of SOEs regarding investment needs and production capacity (Steinfeld, 1998). The ever-increasing production targets incorporated in central plans fostered the managerial “wisdom” of inflating investment requests and keeping slack resources in reserve instead of putting them to productive use. Such data manipulation and other forms of “irregular behaviour”2, such as asset stripping, were reinforced by the mutual dependence culture as resources were channeled into so-called “private treasuries” to fund unofficial pay-rises and staff benefits to strengthen the social ties between superiors and subordinates (see Hassard et al., 2007; Steinfeld 1998). The economic efficiency of SOEs also suffered from their extensive obligations to cater for their work force as well as local communities “from the cradle to the grave” by providing a broad range of social services in addition to their core operations (Hassard et al., 1999, 2007). The emergence of market-orientated SOE reforms from the early 1980s entailed a gradual re-framing of financial responsibilities and managerial incentives within increasingly comprehensive performance contracts without eliminating many of the performance problems outlined in the foregoing. This development started with the launch of the Contract Responsibility System (CRS), which transformed SOEs into “profit centres” and allowed them to retain a share of their surplus for discretionary investments and incentivization of staff to engage in more “entrepreneurial” behaviour aimed at improving financial performance (Scapens and Hou, 1995; Skousen and Yang, 1988). The CRS also entailed emerging notions of responsibility accounting as financial performance targets were cascaded to operating units forming the basis for hierarchies of cost and profit centres (Chow et al., 2007; Scapens and Hou, 1995). The reform marked a first step towards transforming SOEs into independent legal entities in an attempt to support emerging efforts to decentralize decision-making authority. However, the implementation of the reform followed a cautious and incremental path, partly as a result of lingering concerns with the risk of jeopardizing achievement of the broader, social objectives of SOEs. The extensive social welfare obligations of many SOEs remained intact. Central government and the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) were also reluctant to relinquish control over major personnel-related decisions, such as staffing levels, to ensure that efficiencyenhancing measures were not pursued at the expense of social order and stability. The possibilities of SOEs to improve financial performance through lay-offs were thus limited and central government continued to intervene in a broad range of operatinglevel decisions (Chen et al., 1997; Hassard et al., 1999; Hussain and Zhuang, 1997). The managerial incentives to improve financial performance were also limited by “soft” budgetary constraints and the effective bankruptcy protection still enjoyed by many SOEs (Hussain and Zhuang, 1997; Scapens and Meng, 1993; Skousen and Yang, 1988). The incentives of SOE managers under the CRS regime thus continued to be entangled with a complex mix of social mechanisms constraining their ability to prioritise financial performance improvements over achievement of wider, social and political objectives. The CRS reform also failed to contain many of the overflows occurring during the pre-reform era. Indeed, the decentralization of decision-making 2 A direct translation of a Chinese term signifying non-compliance with the goals of higher authorities. 11 authority increased the opportunities for SOE management to engage in “irregular behaviour” (Hussain and Jian, 1999; Lee, 1993) and resulted in widespread prioritization of staff benefits over investments in new production technology (Cheung and Xing, 1994; Hassard et al., 1999). In the long run, this cemented a state of under-investment and loss of competitiveness. To conceal the full economic implications of under-investment some SOEs were able to negotiate favourable profit contracts by cultivating political contacts. This reduced the transparency of the contracting process (Hassard et al., 1999; 2007; Steinfeld, 1998) and fostered widespread manipulation of accounting data (Cheung and Xing, 1994). Such practices were also facilitated by a general lack of transparency of SOE accounts and the proclivity of central government officials to accept falsification of accounts to conceal losses (Chen et al., 1997; Steinfeld, 1998). This weakened the incentives to prioritize financial performance improvements and contributed to a gradual decline in the aggregate performance of SOEs. Although there is some evidence of productivity gains in the 1980s these were unevenly distributed across SOEs (Groves et al., 1994; Shirley and Xu, 2001) and did not translate into sustainable improvements in profitability. From the late 1980s, SOE losses increased (Hussain and Zhuang, 1997; Nee, 1992) and by the mid-1990s the sector had grown heavily dependent on state loans (Lee, 2001). Developments in the HN Branch Prior to 2001 Developments in HN throughout the 1980s and 90s mirrored the development of emerging SOE reforms relatively closely. In the mid-1980s, the branch introduced a formal system of responsibility accounting which remained largely intact until the formation of MetalCo in 2001. The government-sanctioned profit sharing scheme, allowing the company to retain ten per cent of its profit, was disaggregated into profit targets for each individual member of staff and production units were transformed into cost centres. This was accompanied by extensive delegation of decision-making rights from central government affording the company considerable discretion in pricing, supply chain management, determination of wages, recruitment and investments as well as less constrained access to the market.3 Decentralization was also carried further within the organization as 22 categories of operational decisions were delegated to the managers of refinery lines whilst functions such as sales, finance and personnel remained centralized. The CRS reform also allowed the company to abolish life-time employment in the early 1990s and initiate some lay-offs and streamlining of production processes. Similar to many other SOEs, however, these measures did not lead to any sustained improvements in financial performance.4 According to the former Finance Director, HN was a heavy loss-maker throughout most of the 1980s and 90s (although official company accounts might show a different picture) and it was only in 1998 that the company was turned around to become genuinely profitable. Important reasons for these lingering performance problems were the extensive social welfare obligations of HN and a strongly embedded mutual dependence culture being reinforced by its location in a remote, rural part of China where few alternative 3 The implementation of a dual-track price system allowed SOEs to sell their outputs above the planned quota at market prices. 4 Although no reliable quantitative performance data for HN could be found in company archives, our informants recollected a history of perpetual neglect of financial performance. 12 employment opportunities have traditionally been available. Being “cut out from all civilization”5 staff and local residents developed a strong sense of community and solidarity. To strengthen social ties and comply with the expectations of nurturing mutual dependence managers engaged in extensive “irregular behaviour” to create resources for unauthorized pay rises and staff benefits. Whilst company archives show that senior management repeatedly condemned such practices, our interviewees did not shy away from discussing how they were entangled with the politically embedded incentives of managers to maintain social stability. For instance, the Deputy Head of the Office of HN explained: “Private treasury is more or less a historical constant… In the same way that the objective of SOEs is not straightforward profit creation, our managers are not singleminded economic actors. For an economic decision to be executed, it must first be politically correct. No matter what reforms say, there are people to be fed. You can’t just ignore them, can you? Especially for a company of this kind of size having a harmonious and unified work force has tremendous social and political impact. If they are unhappy, they can cause a great deal of social unrest which would reflect extremely badly on the managerial board. Our bosses all have political ambitions of one kind or another. They certainly can’t afford to make such political mistakes.” ( interview with the deputy Head of Office of HN, 2008) For similar reasons, control practices within the branch continued to be characterized by a pronounced “average culture” entailing systematic efforts to smooth out subordinates’ performance evaluation scores to avoid social conflict and embarrassment. The system of responsibility accounting also proved largely ineffectual as a means of enhancing cost control and curbing tendencies towards “irregular behaviour”. The lack of cost awareness was notably manifest in the “adjustments” of financial results routinely undertaken in conjunction with performance evaluation. According to several of our informants, such adjustments and overspending of departmental budgets could easily be explained away with reference to external, uncontrollable circumstances. Consequently, financial control practices were seen as little more than paper work with hardly any binding effects on departmental spending decisions. According to the former Head of Accounting and Finance: “Throughout the 1990s, the fundamental control mechanism was never one based on accounting numbers, but on the personal likings and disliking of the head of the company…the [accounting] targets were soft and negotiable… meeting or missing the cost targets was merely a side issue that no one took seriously”. (interview with the former Head of Accounting and Finance of HN, 2010) Similar to many other SOEs, managers also took the decentralization of decisionmaking rights embedded in the CRS as a “golden opportunity” for providing unauthorized staff benefits. For instance, the Assistant Director recalled the 1990s as a period when: “Irregular behaviour was blown out of all proportion thanks to the freedom. Data manipulation, in particular, was so rampant that God knows how many books were 5 Interview with the Party-Secretary General of HN, 2010. 13 kept. The opportunities for corruption, as you can imagine, were plentiful…people were busy getting rich, few really cared about company performance.”(interview with the Assistant Director of HN, 2008) The chief editor of the official company history between 1988 and 2008, the Head of the Office, agreed that that the practice of manipulating accounting data peaked in the 1990s: “The situation prior to 2000 was quite appalling. The books had no credibility, cash spending was very much at the headman’s whim and financial planning was practically non-existent, budgeting was inconsequential …account falsification was very much a routine operation.” (interview with the Head of Office of HN, 2009) However, incentivization of staff through “irregular behaviour” and creation of “private treasuries” did not produce any sustainable solution to other, long-standing problems encapsulated in the “SOE illness”. Prior to the CRS reform, company archives revealed a tendency for the organization to oscillate between rather extreme forms of “stagnation” as a result of managers and staff refraining from performanceenhancing actions and “anarchy” emanating from a loss of control over “irregular behaviour” such as data manipulation and asset stripping. Such pendulum swings continued throughout the 1980s and most of the 1990s. According to the Party Secretary-General of HN: “Tackling the SOE illness is a long and ardous process, an extremely complex project involving many impossible trade-offs. Since the 1960s we have been trying to find a healthy balance between anarchy and stagnation so that operations can proceed “normally”; but we always come back to ground zero…we are not unique in this— there are some larger, structural issues at play, and I do not think individual managers can come up with a satisfactory answer to the problem.” (interview with the Party Secretary-General of HN, 2009) A particularly serious incident reinforcing the tendencies towards “stagnation” took place in 1996 when HN, attracted by a significant price discount, acquired a heavily depreciated refinery line from Eastern Europe. The line never passed trial production tests and caused a three-year disruption of production which allegedly brought the company to the brink of bankruptcy. Conversely, “irregular behavior” was widely seen as crucial in reversing this situation. Branch managers and staff unanimously interpreted the turn-around of HN in 1998 as entailing “intelligent” adoption of such behaviour as a new, “entrepreneurial” Managing Director set up a “private treasury” to incentivize staff to cut costs and improve production efficiency. However, the tendencies for such behavior to deteriorate into “anarchy” were arguably avoided as senior management took a highly hands-on approach to finance and personnel matters and closely monitored operations through daily inspections of the refinery lines. These measures proved relatively effective in overcoming the tendencies towards “stagnation” previously plaguing the company and by 2000 HN had established itself as the largest domestic supplier in its industry. The Development of Responsibility Accounting in MetalCo 14 The Modern Enterprise Systems Reform and the Formation of MetalCo From the mid-1990s, the poor financial performance of SOEs prompted a new wave of reforms which resulted in some re-framing of governance and control practices around the so-called Modern Enterprise System (MES). To support the emerging policies of consolidating SOEs into larger and more competitive entities through mergers and acquisitions and privatization through stock market listings and formation of joint ventures, corporate governance reforms drawing considerable inspiration from “best practices” from the West were initiated under the banner of nurturing a “scientific” approach to management (Clarke, 2003; Wong, 2005). The MES reform evolved as an explicit attempt to overcome the problems of lingering government intervention and politically embedded incentives detracting from financial performance and aimed at establishing SOEs as more independent entities governed by boards of directors primarily responsible to shareholders. Important policy advice underpinning this development was provided by the World Bank and Chinese economists trained in the West and entailed notable elements of neo-liberal market economics thinking (Hassard et al., 2007; Steinfeld, 1998). Reports published by the World Bank in the 1990s made explicit and repeated references to agency theory as a basis for justifying reforms and especially drew attention to the need to improve the alignment of the interests of owners and managers and address the problem of information asymmetries. Solutions prescribed to this end included the clarification of property rights and lines of authority, improved quality of information for monitoring corporate performance and a better balance between managerial autonomy and accountability for financial results (see e.g., World Bank, 1995, 1996, 1997). At one level, the MES reform may thus be seen as a relatively forceful attempt to disentangle corporate governance and control from socially embedded practices that previously generated overflows detracting from financial performance. However, since the late 1990s the salience of agency theoretic arguments and other manifestations of “Western” corporate governance discourses has decreased as a result of the diminishing influence of the World Bank on policy development and the growth in domestic institutional capacity to oversee SOE reforms (Nolan, 2005). This marked the starting point of a more pragmatic phase in the MES reform where notable steps were taken to strengthen the monitoring of SOE performance whilst adjustments were made to reconcile it with long-standing political and social concerns. An important step in this development was the formation of the Chinese State Assets Supervision and Administration Committee (SASAC) as a governing body for central SOEs in 2003.6 Apart for being charged with safeguarding the value of state assets and promoting continued management reforms the SASAC assumed relatively complete responsibility for a range of strategic decisions, such as the scope of SOE activities, personnel policies and investments, that were previously dispersed across different government departments. However, it has also been entrusted with controlling political and social performance aspects, such as those of ensuring that safety and environmental standards are met and preventing any tendencies towards social unrest and instability. The political pressures on SOEs to control such performance aspects has increased as the more extensive lay-offs following the MES 6 Central SOEs are distinct from local SOEs in that the former are centrally controlled and administered whereas the latter are controlled and managed by local authorities. 15 reform have enhanced the risk of labour conflicts (Hassard et al., 2008) and are notably manifest in the performance monitoring practices forming a cornerstone of the SASAC’s governance of SOEs. The system partly relies on league tables based on the ranking of SOEs along five grades across such indicators as total profits, return on investment and a selection of operating-level measures capturing industry-specific characteristics. However, the performance contracts embedded in the league tables are part of a broader and highly complex system for managing the performance of SOEs. For instance, some SOEs are given “policy allowances” whereby financial performance can partly be traded off for undertaking government-sanctioned tasks partly aimed at upholding social stability. Individual SOEs may also face degrading in the league tables if such tasks are overlooked. In addition, the personnel controls of central government and the CCP remain loosely coupled to these performance monitoring practices in that the former take a broader range of social and political aspects into account and grant these actors considerable discretion in the appointment, promotion and dismissal of senior SOE managers. Hence political constraints continue to exercise an important influence on control practices (cf. O’Connor et al., 2006) and managerial incentives are not entirely disentangled from long-standing social and political concerns. The formation of MetalCo as a central SOE was a direct outcome of the MES reform and was heralded as an integral part of the process of “furthering industry consolidation, curtail the SOE illness and improve the financial performance of SOEs”.7 Heeding the call of the CCP and central government to develop more internationally competitive SOEs, MetalCo was to embark on an aggressive strategy of expansion through national and international mergers and acquisitions. This strategy received forceful support from central government through preferential policies and interventions granting the company access to favourable prices for key inputs such as electricity and loans from China’s major commercial banks. Central government also intervened to ensure that national mergers and acquisitions received the backing of local governments. In addition, MetalCo was singled out as a “flagship” of continued SOE reforms pivoting on the nurturing of “scientific management” practices. As explicated in the ensuing case narrative, this entailed the introduction of a new management control system based on a notion of responsibility accounting partly inspired by agency theoretic ideals and mirroring the SASAC’s ambition to strengthen performance monitoring. The Rise of the “MetalCo Model” and Emerging Overflows (2001-2004) The new management control system came to be known as the “MetalCo Model” and was primarily devised by a newly appointed Chief Financial Officer (CFO) who had previously headed a large European company. Albeit a native Chinese he had no prior experience of Chinese SOEs. His appointment was viewed as a politically significant manifestation of the ambition to improve the financial performance of SOEs and he was given a clear mandate to pursue the modernizing agenda embedded in the MES reform and work towards facilitating the listing of MetalCo on international stock markets. Despite being the only “outsider” on the senior management team, he was granted considerable authority and was widely seen as the “real” executive head of 7 Extract from company publicity material. 16 the management board. He enjoyed the whole-hearted support of the Chairman of MetalCo who repeatedly appealed to branch managers to: “… offer unreserved support for Comrade NN’s work. The reform is crucial to building the competitiveness of MetalCo. The task [of making MetalCo an internationally competitive company] is of great economic and political importance.” (Extract from Chairman’s speech at the annual conference of MetalCo, 2003, 2004) The system of responsibility accounting underpinning the “MetalCo Model” relied on a return to centralized performance monitoring rather than managerial incentives linked to more comprehensive financial performance contracts although it was heralded as epitomizing a spirit of merit-based performance management. To tighten control of the newly incorporated SOEs, branches were transformed into cost centres in charge of direct branch costs and were to be subjected to tight cash management and budgetary control (framed in terms of “total budgetary control”). However, there were no attempts to render performance contracts more comprehensive through allocation of uncontrollable corporate overheads and the re-framing of financial responsibilities were accompanied by a withdrawal of decision-making rights from the branches across a range of key operating areas. In early 2002, the authorization of operating budgets, capital investments, research and development and repair and maintenance budgets was centralized to headquarters. This was followed by centralization of most of the personnel, production planning, sales and purchasing functions over the following years. To further the ability of headquarters to monitor branch performance a decision to implement an enterprise resource planning system (supplied by SAP) was also made in 2004. Whilst the matching of centralized decision-making with less comprehensive performance contracts may be seen as an attempt to adhere to the controllability principle (cf. McNally, 1980), the CFO espoused a “non-negotiable” approach to the tendencies towards routine adjustments for allegedly uncontrollable factors in performance evaluation. A similar approach was adopted with respect to other types of behaviour presumably detracting from the emphasis on shareholder interests. To justify this position and the return to centralized performance monitoring, explicit support was derived from the imperatives of agency theory. For instance, in his keynote address during a corporate-wide training seminar for senior accounting staff, the CFO explained: “… ultimately we need to deliver shareholder value. We can only achieve that through profit maximisation. That is why we need to build a modern corporate governance structure. A modern corporate governance structure is based on agency thinking. Western agency theory argues that a company is a network of performance contracts between layers of managements. It is concerned with the design of these contracts and the division of the responsibility between different levels of the business. For example, in MetalCo headquarters has headquarters’ agendas, branches have branches’ agendas. How do you coordinate these agendas so that we are moving in the same direction? Centralisation is the most suitable way to regulate the relationship between the headquarters and the branches, to optimise resource allocation, and to standardise financial and operational practices.” (Extract from CFO speech, 2004) 17 A similar emphasis on heightened managerial attention to financial control permeated the CFO’s speeches and memoranda throughout the early years of the “MetalCo Model”. Of particular concern in this regard was the persistent emphasis on centralized performance monitoring as an antidote to “irregular behaviour”, such as the creation of “private treasuries” through data manipulation. This was accompanied by concerted efforts to disentangle responsibility accounting from “old” SOE practices. For instance, in a memorandum to branch managers about a year after the launch of the “MetalCo Model” the CFO rebuked them for their continued entanglement in embedded mindsets and practices and for being slow in complying with the new, shareholder-focused reform agenda: “Some branch managers conflated the [MetalCo] Model with old central planning and assumed they could get away with their old behaviour. This is a gross misunderstanding. Last year’s budgeting was a disaster ... instead of thinking on behalf of MetalCo, many branches stood in opposition to headquarters and engaged in extensive gaming, adding layers and layers of “water” to their resource claims. … These problems are underpinned by the old SOE style of thinking. But we are not an old SOE anymore. We are a consolidated, integrated, listed modern enterprise. We need to be aware of and remove the old mentality to become market oriented, to embrace the mission of profit maximisation for our shareholders. …. I must remind everybody that the rule of the game has changed, the business context has changed and our thinking and mode of management must change accordingly. We are no longer self-serving work units, we work for our investors, or we will be voted out.” (CFO memorandum, 2003) Similarly, in a speech to branch managers around the same time, he concluded: “I stress once more that you are no longer an old SOE. You need to live up to the reputation of a listed modern enterprise. I want every one attending this meeting to achieve the same level of thinking, adjust their attitude and act as managers of a market-oriented, global modern enterprise.” (CFO, 2003, senior branch financial managers training seminar) However, despite these efforts to disentangle financial control from “old” SOE practices,, the notion of responsibility accounting was not isolated from broader control practices requiring branch managers to take wider, social concerns into consideration. Following the requirement of the SASAC to use league tables similar to those governing central SOEs for management control, branch performance was compiled annually into corporate league tables based on a weighted average of a range of financial, operational and political performance indicators. Even though the weight attached to financial indicators grew increasingly dominant over the coming decade, branches were required to meet targets for social stability and compliance with other political directives issued by headquarters to be included in the league tables and avoid embarrassment and negative career implications. Another manifestation of the continued entanglement of financial control with socially embedded practices was evident in the mechanisms employed to build organizational commitment to the “MetalCo Model”. Even though the league tables were complemented with an incentive system giving branches the discretion to allocate 40 per cent of their salary budgets as performance-related pay to departments 18 and individuals, these efforts relied less on performance-based, financial incentives than tried-and-tested methods reminiscent of the mass-line principle. The model was rolled out across the branches with an intensity similar to the political campaigns of the pre-reform era. For three years after its inception, branches were required to devote their weekly political learning seminars to the “MetalCo Model” and branch accounting personnel, in particular, were urged to “broaden their horizons, take into heart the collective interest of MetalCo and follow headquarters’ commands whenever it is in conflict with local decisions”.8 Measures were also taken to replace “non-conformists” with “loyalists” through internal transfers and a company-wide personnel rotation scheme was set up to train high-performing employees at headquarters. Such political pressures for conformance were reinforced by the external acclaim bestowed on MetalCo and its new control practices. In 2003, the SASAC singled out MetalCo as a role model for “scientific management”, praising it for its “clear vision, solidarity and strong leadership”.9 A year later, the company rose to the top ten in the league table for central SOEs and the press referred to “the MetalCo phenomenon” to capture the public’s imagination. Within MetalCo, this fostered an atmosphere of ostensible enthusiasm and strengthened the framing of the “MetalCo Model” as a vehicle of improved control. Even though some of our interviewees claimed to have harboured personal misgivings about the efficacy of the model from an early stage, there was widespread recognition that questioning the reform might have negative career implications. The Assistant Director of HN succinctly captured the attitude of several of his colleagues at the time: “Questioning [the economic feasibility of] the model is to question headquarters, that is to say the government’s political agenda, which would be very career limiting… it is hard to say which kind of mistake [questioning the model on economic or political grounds] is graver, at the end of the day they are the same… given that centralisation is politically correct, it must also be economically right no matter what you think.” (interview with the Assistant Director of HN, 2010) The implementation of the “MetalCo Model” thus relied heavily of political incentives partly grounded in embedded practices originating in the pre-reform era. Initially, this framing seemed to produce relatively powerful constitutive effects supporting the emerging reform agenda. Consistent with the intentions of the CFO, there were signs of a reduced incidence of “irregular behaviour” and propensity for routine adjustments of performance evaluation for uncontrollable factors to avoid financial scrutiny. Branch managers generally agreed that the system of responsibility accounting brought control practices into a new era of regulation. Looking back at the development over the past twenty years, the Head of Budgeting of HN acknowledged that: “Centralisation led to a more disciplined managerial regime. That fact is beyond dispute... Previously our annual budget was treated like a joke and adjustments were made all the time. Since incorporation …we have taken annual budgeting more seriously and been doing our best to produce more accurate plans. Financial management was modernised as a result” (interview with the Head of Budgeting of HN, 2008) 8 9 internal memo, 2003. Excerpt form SASAC report, 2003. 19 This view was shared by other members of HN management: “Total budgetary control was effective in that it indeed curtailed irregular behaviour and gave our financial management a more scientific outlook.” (interview with the Assistant Director of HN, 2008) “The CFO made huge efforts to reinforce financial and operational discipline … The SAP system is the culmination of all his reforms. SAP made branch activities highly visible, so most of the ‘behind-the-scene activities’ just had to stop. We could hardly change the layout of our monthly reports let alone cooking the books…this is not to say [the latter] was impossible… but because it involved so much hassle and so little gain, the practice was indeed scaled down quite a lot.” (interview with the Deputy Head of Office of HN, 2008) However, the continued entanglement of the “MetalCo Model” with political incentives soon produced overflows with detrimental consequences for financial performance at the branch level. Only a few years after the introduction of the model, new signs of the familiar tendencies towards “stagnation” began to emerge as branch managers became more pre-occupied with being seen to conform to political directives than taking “entrepreneurial” initiatives to improve financial performance. The Head of HN’s Human Resource department, who also headed the Performance Evaluation Committee, described the emerging situation as follows: “[Control] practices became open to all kinds of political influence and human factors…the truly capable people are leaving. The rest of our managers talk and behave like bureaucrats, pre-occupied with taking orders and instructions from above.” (interview with the Head of Human Resource of HN, 2008 ) He further observed: Managers, myself included, are primarily driven by the prospects of promotion and status. Economic incentives do not matter much and economic performance is just one of the many reference points for promotion decisions… There are a great deal of similarities to the system used by the government departments in the sense that the Party controls the personnel, decisions are often made behind closed doors and there is much scope for discretionary judgment. (interview with the Head of Human Resource of HN, 2009) A first, major sign of the lack of attention to financial performance aspects was the spread of “irresponsible purchasing” practices across several of the branches. Whilst rooted in the emerging lack of “entrepreneurial” behaviour, these practices may also be understood as an overflow stemming from the centralization of purchasing decisions. Although the “MetalCo Model” vested formal power over purchasing in corporate headquarters it soon became clear that it had neither sufficient information nor the necessary local network contacts to single-handedly manage the complex supply chain. Centralized purchasing decisions consequently became dependant on “purchasing requests” from the branches. However, the latter had few incentives to economise on purchasing due to the return to relatively incomprehensive, financial performance contracts preventing them from retaining any surplus. The resultant lack 20 of attention to efficient purchasing routines caused considerable frustration on the part of headquarters. In 2005, the CFO openly condemned the lack of cost consciousness amongst branch managers during the annual performance review: “We all know that grade 6 [ore] is perfectly adequate…then why did some branches insist headquarters provide them with grade 7?...One particular branch even requested headquarters to provide them with XX [a key chemical for refinery] at the laboratory standard… What kind of attitude lay behind such requests? Where is your cost awareness?”(CFO speech at the internal annual performance review of MetalCo, 2005) The incentives for staff to engage in more “entrepreneurial” behaviour were also weakened by the removal of “private treasuries” from the branches. Although the CFO insisted that the official performance-related pay budget accounting for 40 per cent of the salary budget was motivational, our interviewees in HN indicated that the unofficial forms of payment previously available could amount to as much as 100 and even 150 per cent of formal pay. Thus, the Head of Budgeting at HN recalled: “Completely eliminating hidden treasuries was bound to backfire as it was our main source of incentives, especially since headquarters was not prepared to make up for it by increasing the formal salary budget.” (interview with the Head of Budgeting of HN, 2010) However, the weakening of financial incentives was not only due the removal of “private treasuries”, but also the difficulties in reconciling the official system of performance-related pay with the strongly embedded “average culture” at the branch level. Two of our informants within HN explained: “The designer clearly has no idea of the reality of SOEs where you need to save people’s face and cannot differentiate their performance scores to create big pay gaps. If you do, you get a bad name for yourself and your window might be smashed at night.”(interview with the Head of Human Resource of HN, 2009) “After modification and adjustment the performance scores never differ much and we all get more or less the same performance related pay…this may sound strange to you, but the workforce has lived and worked together for three generations since the late 1950s…people are very conscious of saving each other’s face. It is just not possible to create huge pay gaps.” (interview with the Head of the Salary Office of HN, 2009) These problems of reconciling performance-related pay with the “average culture” testify to the difficulties in radically re-framing relationships at the branch level such that novel control practices are disentangled from their broader, socio-economic context. As explicated below, such problems of disentangling the “MetalCo Model” from embedded practices became increasingly salient over the coming years and contributed to perpetuate a range of overflows. Re-Framing of the “MetalCo Model” and Continued Overflows (2004-2008) 21 The emerging signs of “stagnation” prompted some modifications of the “MetalCo Model” between 2004 and 2005. However, a number of factors prevented the situation from getting “hot” and triggering more radical re-framing of responsibility accounting at this stage. MetalCo maintained its strong performance in the central SOE league tables and continued to be hailed as a beacon of reform by the SASAC. This positive image was reinforced by its successful strategy of international expansion and attraction of foreign investors, which helped it secure a cherished position as a Fortune 500 company in 2007. These achievements gained the CFO a considerable amount of official praise, including the award of “CFO of the Year” in 2005, and his position within MetalCo remained unchallenged. He continued to enjoy the full support of the Chairman and the management board and was able to push ahead with his reform agenda. Hence the modifications of the “MetalCo Model” were relatively marginal and were implemented without any major disputes. Even though the CFO redefined the financial responsibility of branches from constituting “production centres” to “profit-conscious cost centres” and introduced a market-based transfer pricing system to compile profit metrics, such as Return on Investment, for performance evaluation this was not accompanied by any increase in the budget for performance-related pay or any substantial delegation of decision-making rights. In 2005, headquarters recognised the need to decentralise purchasing decisions and allowed about 40 per cent of supplies to be organised at the branch level. However, decentralization never went beyond the purchasing function. The implementation of the enterprise resource planning system also progressed according to plan and was fully operational in 2006. Not surprisingly, this re-framing of the “MetalCo Model” did not strengthen the incentives to engage in more “entrepreneurial” behaviour or assume more complete responsibility for financial performance. In so far as one of the main overflows motivating the re-framing was concerned (ie. the problem of “irresponsible purchasing”), the situation continued to deteriorate. Even though branches regained some of their authority over purchasing decision, the preceding wave of centralisation and removal of “private treasuries” had inflicted considerable damage on local supply networks and the branches’ ability to nurture critical relationships with local political authorities. Taken together, this considerably weakened their competitive position visà-vis budding, private sector refineries. According to the former Head of Accounting and Finance of HN, local governments had a natural inclination to discriminate against SOEs in favour of private sector refineries in important areas, such as the price of electricity and the logistics necessary to ensure reliable supplies of raw materials, due to tax reasons.10 Elaborating on the consequences of the removal of “private treasuries” he explained: “We used to have excellent informal relationships with local authorities and many issues were negotiable…. But now we can no longer afford presents and entertainment, which is exactly what the headquarters wanted. But dealing with officials at the official level is much more costly for the business…The private refineries are extremely generous at giving gifts…why do they do that? It pays off…we are clean so we lose out. What I am saying is that the headquarters’ idealism 10 Only 30 per cent of the corporate tax on SOE profits goes to local government in comparison with 100 per cent of that of private sector companies. Boosting the profits of the latter thus benefits local government. 22 has a lot to answer for our present rise in total costs.”(interview with the former Head of Accounting and Finance of HN, 2010) The Head of Purchasing of HN confirmed these problems and described the performance consequences of the lack of control over the supply chain: “HN was only 26 per cent self-sufficient [in raw materials supply]. It has been a real struggle to rebuild the supply network. Now we have to rely on less credible mining companies and operate with sub-standard raw materials. This is causing a lot of efficiency issues. We should not be held responsible for missing the cost target because it was the headquarters’ fault in the first place.” (interview with the Head of Purchasing of HN, 2011) The re-framing of responsibility accounting also failed to provide adequate resources to incentivize staff. Faced with such difficulties, branches sought alternative, illicit ways of enhancing their financial discretion and ability to provide staff benefits. This included a return to practices prevailing in SOEs prior to 1978, such as submission of inflated investment requests. However, such practices were forcefully rebutted by the CFO and the branches largely seem to have failed to restore their capacity to create “private treasuries”. For instance, in 2005 financial managers from all branches were summoned to BeiJing to account for their failure to monitor capital investments: “Headquarters encourages technological upgrade. However, I have noticed that some of the investment requests were made without any reference to the market and were motivated not by the profitability of MetalCo but the need to polish their own performance reports. Worse still, some investment requests were ostensibly inflated. Headquarters is not blind...Again I ask financial managers to take into heart the interest of MetalCo and carefully consider the financial consequences of your investment requests. Is it economic? Can it deliver? …As I have stressed before, you are appointed by the headquarters. You need to keep professional distance from the local influences and stay loyal to headquarters’ agenda even if that involves offending the branch directors.” (CFO speech at the special meeting, 2005) Nevertheless, financial managers continued to manipulate financial data to help branches meet their financial targets and were arguably under considerable pressure to do so as a result of the socially embedded expectations to comply with the communal ethos at the branch level. Rather than confronting their superiors, financial managers in HN paid lip-service to headquarters’ directives whilst continuing to collude in data manipulation. As the Head of Accounting and Finance of HN confessed: “Yes, I was appointed by the CFO and I was supposed to act more independently on behalf of headquarters. But this is extremely difficult because HN is where my roots are - not BeiJing. I have worked here for twenty-five years and I would like to retire in a decent respectful way (as a devoted manager of the branch). Besides my salary is paid through the branch budget, so is my wife, my daughter and everybody else in the department. I am morally obliged to look after the branch…The CFO does not understand that…[hence] his ideal [of total control over local finance by emphasising the independence of the branch financial managers] just won’t work” (interview with the Head of Accounting and Finance of HN, 2009) 23 These findings show how the entanglement of branch managers in social relationships at the local level continued to detract from compliance with the “MetalCo Model” and contributed to the generation of overflows. Such overflows were made possible by emerging opportunities to manipulate performance data embedded in the enterprise resource planning system. At HN, this was achieved by delaying data entries and postponing and even falsifying purchasing information in collusion with local suppliers. Such practices were said to have helped HN meet its financial targets and avoid taking the bottom position in the corporate league table. Collusion between the branches also occurred through what headquarters called “passive aggression” as they collectively refrained from following the templates for data entry in the enterprise resource planning system. The resultant problems of information overload caused considerable concern on the part of the CFO: “Last month branches sent us over 600 spreadsheets without making any effort to sort or analyse the data. The lack of managerial initiatives is shocking...I can see a dangerous trend forming where managers adopt a minimum approach to their work…this is disgraceful… Headquarters’ capacity is limited and you must not pass all responsibilities to headquarters.” (CFO memorandum, 2006) The attempts to avoid closer scrutiny through collusion were particularly noticeable in HN and another branch with a similar history of carrying extensive social responsibilities. These social responsibilities prevented them from radically climbing the corporate league table but also provided a pretext detracting from the pressures to improve financial performance. The assistant of the Chairman of MetalCo described the general attitude to performance improvements in the two branches as “broken glasses which couldn’t care less if smashed again”. Instead of taking forceful actions to improve financial performance, the managers of the two branches repeatedly exchanged and manipulated performance data in such a way that they could take turns in occupying the bottom position of the corporate league tables and avoid “public humiliation”.11 To the researchers, the Head of Finance at HN made no secret of such practices and blamed it on headquarters’ tendency to push the branches too far to achieve “mission impossible”. The CFO’s response to these enduring problems of disentangling financial control from embedded, social obligations was to persist in his emphasis on the “MetalCo Model” as a “non-negotiable” frame but increasingly resorting to tried-and-tested methods, such as mass mobilization and moral persuasion, to enhance managerial commitment. Internal memoranda exchanged between headquarters and HN since 2005 showed the former making increasing use of moral and political appeals to reinforce managers’ attention to financial performance aspects through “selfsacrifice”, “solidarity” and “collectivism”. This was accompanied by recurring political campaigns to encourage branch managers to take the “MetalCo Model” to heart. Whilst this reinforced the political incentives of managers to be seen as complying with the corporate reform agenda it largely failed to address their loyalty to the branches and foster more deep-seated commitment to change. In HN, this continued entanglement of branch managers in social relationships detracting from financial performance was notably manifest in a reversal to a prevalent “excuse 11 Headquarters ruled that if a branch stayed at the bottom of the league table for three consecutive quarters, then the branch director would receive a public reprimand and be required to offer a personal apology to headquarters. 24 culture” in conjunction with performance evaluation. So called “historical” and allegedly uncontrollable factors associated with the branch’s extensive social obligations were frequently invoked to counter criticisms of poor financial performance. This stood in marked contrast to the CFO’s intentions. However, by the time our fieldwork started, the managerial consensus in HN was that the model had “hit the wall” and that “the CFO had turned into a UFO” as the Deputy Head of the Office of HN put it in a candid exchange with us. Similarly, junior accounting staff in HN saw the idea of “profit conscious cost centres” as just another headquarters command to be obeyed but being of little practical significance. Such superficial commitment led to increasing frustration on the part of the CFO. His internal speech in 2007 revealed a rare occasion of admitting to having failed to address emerging overflows and appealing to the branches for enhanced cooperation: Having reviewed the accounting work across branches, I am far from satisfied…headquarters invested so much in merit based performance measurement system and yet branches take it as a joke … The lack of commitment is shocking … I am disheartened to see branch financial managers fail to internalise total budgetary control and take it as an assignment instead. ... I am also disappointed to see branches so lacking in cost consciousness. …[and] branch financial managers still engage in practices that they should not. Why is that? I have stressed before that financial managers must take instructions from the rules and headquarters, not your managing directors. Unfortunately that is not the case ... Yes I agree that there might be some structural issues and I understand that some branches felt let down by headquarters. I hope we can open up to each other and discuss your concerns more openly. Whatever doubts you may have can be resolved, but we need to sit down and listen to each other. Creating a healthy managerial environment is not a one-sided exercise but requires input from headquarters and the branches. (CFO speech at the internal annual review of the accounting work of MetalCo, 2007)) However, the CFO’s attempts to disentangle financial control from the wider, social obligations of the branches were counteracted by the propensity of the management board to tacitly accept the attribution of poor financial performance to such “historical factors”. For instance, the assistant to the chairman of MetalCo remarked: “The board is not unaware of the excuse culture. The CFO, in particular, detests this type of behaviour, but he can hardly argue against “historical factors”. Besides, the branch and the headquarters alike must both fill socio-political responsibilities. There can be nothing worse than an up-rise in a [geographically isolated] place like HN, which would immediately terminate their careers.” (interview with the assistant to the chairman of MetalCo, 2008) Similarly, the Head of the Office of HN described how the costs of providing for “unofficial staff” put tremendous financial strain on the branch whilst simultaneously offering opportunities for management to shirk financial responsibilities: “Headquarters formulates and imposes universal cost targets across all branches. But these targets do not affect us in any real sense because we both [branches and headquarters] know that “historical factors” cannot be ignored. No one can afford the [political] cost of ignoring these “historical factors”… even the MetalCo Model has to allow for them. The economic and social responsibilities can only co-exist in 25 harmony in times of extraordinarily good markets.” (interview with the Head of Office of HN, 2008) Hence a range of overflows detracting from financial performance continued to prevail as a result of the entanglement of responsibility accounting with the broader, socio-economic context in which the “MetalCo Model” was implemented. However, the situation remained relatively “cold” for an extended period of time and did not prompt any radical re-framing despite emerging evidence of the wider performance implications of such overflows. In particular, the continuous problems of securing reliable supplies of raw materials contributed to a significant loss in domestic market share for MetalCo’s key products. From enjoying a near monopoly position at its foundation MetalCo’s market share gradually decreased to below 40 per cent in 2008. Yet, at the corporate level, such performance problems were long over-shadowed by the success of the state-backed, international growth strategy and a booming international commodity market. From 2001 to 2007, MetalCo’s assets grew fivefold. Over the same time period, corporate profits soared by over 1,000 per cent and the company continued to occupy a prominent position in the central SOE league tables. As explicated below, however, this trend was abruptly reversed in 2008, which turned the situation “hot” and prompted a relatively radical re-framing of control practices. The Waning of the “MetalCo Model” (2008-2011) From 2008, a series of external events began to take their toll on MetalCo’s performance and its standing as a leading example of SOE reform. Following an abrupt market downturn, the industry as a whole entered into a severe depression in the last quarter of 2008. The price of MetalCo’s main product dropped by nearly 50 per cent and continued to fluctuate erratically throughout the following years. However, the branches failed to respond in a timely fashion to the market turmoil. For instance, at the end of 2008 HN was still operating at full capacity in spite of the plummeting demand whilst a neighbouring private sector competitor had temporarily suspended production. Similar performance problems emerged across the other branches and caused MetalCo to incur heavy losses. In early 2009, the company faced a severe liquidity crisis. This coincided with a setback in its global expansion strategy in the form of a highly publicized failure to acquire a major international competitor for which the Chairman had to offer official apologies. These events tarnished MetalCo’s reputation and its position in the central SOE league table dropped significantly. The deteriorating performance of MetalCo also weakened the position of the CFO and put heat into the process of re-framing control practices over the coming years. From having enjoyed unanimous support from the management board and important external actors, such as the SASAC, the appointment of a new Chairman in early 2009 drastically changed this situation. The CFO gradually lost much of his influence and was first relegated to the “backbench” and eventually resigned at the end of 2010 claiming health reasons. Whilst ostensibly in charge up till that point, the Assistant to the Chairman of MetalCo intimated that the fate of the CFO was finally sealed by the growing concerns that he would face litigation from overseas investors for failing to curb the extensive manipulation of financial data over the preceding years. 26 With its chief architect and champion being marginalised, the “MetalCo Model” became increasingly contested and ultimately discredited. Although the model officially remained the backbone of management control, the new Chairman took personal charge and launched a series of campaigns which “looked just like the Cultural Revolution”.12 These campaigns superseded any formal performance contracts embedded in the “MetalCo Model” and were aimed at more direct and forceful management intervention to mobilize staff into action. Internal memoranda produced after 2008 made liberal use of political slogans such as those frequently used as a means of mass mobilization during the pre-reform era, whilst much less emphasis was placed on the “MetalCo Model” as a symbol of reform and progress. Instead, forceful interventions by corporate management were justified under the pretext that “radical situations require radical measures” and were accompanied by appeals to “the will power of the masses against all material odds”.13 In 2009, the first of a series of corporate-wide cost-saving campaign was initiated based on the following motivation: “MetalCo is in a deep crisis—we are to confront a battle of life and death. I instruct all branch managers to take personal responsibility to break even and remove any waste and inefficiency in the production process….should slack, either in attitude or action, be noticed, we will change posts immediately.”(chairman speech at the internal annual conference of MetalCo, 2009) This re-framing of management control practices around tried-and-tested methods of mass mobilization had some constitutive effects on economic behaviour as branch managers scurried to comply with the new corporate agenda. In HN, this became manifest in a flurry of activity to avoid reprisals for non-conformity. A special TV channel was set up to boost staff morale and a list of hundreds of cost saving initiatives was drawn up. A particularly drastic measure involved sending managers to the operational front line to engage in hands-on work and to impress the sense of urgency on the work force. However, losses continued to accumulate. At the end of 2009, MetalCo dropped to the bottom of the central SOE league table and faced the threats of stock market delisting and asset consolidation by the State. This prompted a new wave of cost-cutting campaigns whose efficacy proved relatively short-lived and which failed to produce sustained improvements in financial performance. In 2010, less than a third of all branches met their performance targets and HN continued to be the worst performer in the corporate league table. In an alleged state of “panic”14 more radical measures followed. The Chairman ordered all functional areas to reduce their head count by 30 per cent and cut the salaries of remaining staff by 30 per cent. However, HN in particular struggled to comply with this initiative due its heavy social responsibilities and its Managing Director was subsequently replaced by the head of the best performing branch who initiated a new cost-cutting campaign. Around the time our field work ended in 2011 hundreds of proposals for cost savings had recently been received whilst steps were also taken to check tendencies towards social unrest. Nevertheless, this re-framing of control practices around the idea of mass mobilization did not imply a complete disentanglement from the use of responsibility accounting as a means of improving financial control. The cost-cutting campaigns 12 Interview with the Deputy Head of Office of HN, 2009. Memo issued by the chairman of MetalCo, 2009. 14 Interview with the Assistant Director of HN, 2010 13 27 were combined with an element of “measured delegation” and at least a notional return to more comprehensive financial performance contracts to contain some of the major overflows emerging over the preceding years. Towards the end of 2009, seven business sectors were created under headquarters with considerable decision-making autonomy in areas such as sales, finance, investments and purchasing. The business sectors were to be held accountable to headquarters for profits and return on investment and were placed in direct charge of the branches which were, in turn, redefined as “cost as well as profit centres”. To resolve the lingering problems of inefficient purchasing routines, purchasing decisions were fully devolved to branch managers although they were expected to coordinate these decisions with headquarters. However, these initiatives were accompanied by measures aimed at strengthening headquarters’ control and disentangling financial control from embedded, local relationships reinforcing the tendencies of financial managers to collude in the manipulation of performance data. To this end, eight “branch CFOs” directly reporting to headquarters were appointed. The “branch CFOs” were instructed to work closely with other branch managers in coordinating performance management, investment appraisals and business development decisions and were also entrusted with direct responsibility for special cash budgets designated to the rebuilding local supply networks. However, our interviews in HN suggest that the reframing of financial responsibilities and reporting lines made little difference. The view of the Head of Office of HN was representative: “Previously we reported to headquarters; presently we report to section leaders as well as headquarters. Given our current financial performance headquarters couldn’t possibly let go of direct control. Restructuring makes no difference to the way branches operate but merely adds another layer of bureaucracy. Our last two investment proposals were refuted, clearly proving my point…We will always be at the bottom of the food chain.” (interview with the Head of Office of HN, 2010) This observation was confirmed by internal correspondence and memoranda issued in 2010 and 2011 suggesting that no substantive changes in the lines of reporting or clarification of the financial responsibility of the branches materialized from the restructuring of MetalCo. Rather, it was officially acknowledged that the revised system of responsibility accounting gave rise to new overflows, such as coordination problems stemming from a lack of communication across various hierarchical levels, and perpetuated extant ones, such as the tendency of production managers to resort to some “excuse culture” by systematically explaining away inefficiencies with reference to uncontrollable factors.15 Neither did the re-framing of financial responsibilities entirely curtail data manipulation. For instance, in an informal conversation in the summer of 2010 branch managers boasted about ways in which they tried to make HN “break even” by “massaging” inventory figures. They further suggested that a truly competent manager must find ways to “beat” the enterprise resource planning system by manipulating data entries. The new CFO of MetalCo also confirmed that such problems of data manipulation continued to be of more general concern across the corporation: “The enterprise resource planning system has failed to deliver true and timely reports. … In 2010, we have found several cases of branches keeping private 15 Internal memo issued by the CFO, 2011. 28 treasuries, hiding profits, falsifying expenditures and stripping assets.” (CFO speech at the internal annual review of the accounting work of MetalCo, 2011) The unfolding development of the notion of responsibility accounting in MetalCo thus failed to provide a more stable or orderly frame supporting the recurring cost-cutting campaigns. Indeed, there were even signs of these campaigns reinforcing rather than resolving the problems of data manipulation, or as the Deputy Head of Accounting at HN explained: “We budgeted for a loss of 700 million for this year but this was turned down [by headquarters], then reduced to 500 million, which was turned down again, it went down further to 350 million, which was still unacceptable. It was finally agreed that this year our loss would be 60 million. How could this be possible? This left people with no alternative than to cook the books.” (interview with the Head of Budgeting, 2010) Neither did the re-framing of financial responsibilities and decision-making rights produce any lasting improvements in so far as purchasing was concerned. The delegation of purchasing decisions to the branches largely failed to enhance the efficiency and transparency of purchasing practices and corruption and collusion between supply-chain managers and suppliers flourished under the pretence of competitive tendering.16 Headquarters was so alarmed by these continuing overflows that it decided to re-centralize all purchasing decisions except for the acquisition of metal ore in early 2011. Hence at the time our field work ended the system of responsibility accounting was again in a state of flux without any managerial consensus as to how to resolve such long-standing problems being forthcoming. In other words, the situation surrounding the framing of responsibility remained relatively “hot” and showed few signs of settling around more stable social arrangements to contain overflows. Concluding Discussion We began this paper by raising the issue of how the notion of responsibility accounting shapes economic behaviour and developing an analytical framework grounded in economic sociology as an alternative to the agency theoretic approaches informing much research on this topic. Our field study in a Chinese SOE sheds further light on this issue by illuminating how the evolution of responsibility accounting is conditioned by broader socio-economic contingencies and how the interplay between such contingencies and emerging systems of responsibility accounting shapes the constitutive roles of the latter. As explicated below, this provides for some rapprochement between classical versions of economic sociology and more recent advances within the performative tradition. Consistent with accounting research inspired by classical versions of economic sociology (e.g., Modell and Wiesel, 2008; Neu, 1992; Neu and Simmons, 1996), our analysis demonstrates how systems of responsibility accounting evolving both prior to and after the formation of MetalCo were reconciled with long-standing, socially 16 Internal annual review of the accounting work of MetalCo, 2010. 29 embedded practices. Rather than forming a powerful mechanism for nurturing sustained improvements in financial performance, the initial system of responsibility accounting introduced in HN evolved into a very lax means of financial control in response to the deeply ingrained expectations to provide unauthorized pay rises and staff benefits and other practices aimed at maintaining social stability. Even though the subsequent system of responsibility accounting underpinning the “MetalCo Model” was designed to curb such tendencies towards adjustment and enhance financial discipline it too relied heavily on socially embedded mechanisms, such as principles of mass mobilization, rather than formal financial incentive schemes devised to align managerial interests with the emerging, shareholder-focused reform agenda. Moreover, the incentives of managers to prioritise financial performance improvements were weakened by the integration of financial performance indicators into league tables that also required them to pay close attention to long-standing political concerns with social stability. As the system of responsibility accounting evolved over the following years it also became clear that socially embedded phenomena, such as the expectations on financial managers to conform to the communal ethos at the branch level and lingering social welfare obligations, continued to constrain its efficacy by perpetuating problems of data manipulation and a lack of fiscal probity. Taken together, these findings show how the use of responsibility accounting to reframe control practices around increasing concerns with enhanced financial performance and shareholder interests continued to be entangled with broader socioeconomic contingencies historically detracting from such goals in Chinese SOEs (Miller, 2002). This is not to deny the constitutive effects of emerging accounting practices. Indeed, the launch of the “MetalCo Model” and the subsequent framing of the notion of responsibility accounting around the need for centralized performance monitoring did re-constitute economic behaviour by removing the possibilities of creating “private treasuries” and gradually generated a range of overflows, such as “irresponsible purchasing” and the creation of novel opportunities for data manipulation (cf. Callon, 1998b). However, in contrast to much accounting research within the performative vein of economic sociology (e.g., Christensen and Skærbæk, 2004; Skærbæk, 2009; Skærbæk and Tryggestad, 2010), we argue that such constitutive effects are not only a result of more or less successful attempts to disentangle economic behaviour from its broader, socio-economic context. Rather, our analysis suggests that both the efforts to re-constitute economic behaviour through the framing of control practices and subsequent overflows can be understood as an outcome of an intricate interplay between emerging and embedded practices. For instance, the initial acceptance of centralized performance monitoring as a new frame relied heavily on its entanglement with political incentives grounded in long-standing principles of mass mobilization whilst the same incentives subsequently bolstered the tendencies towards “stagnation” underpinning the problems of “irresponsible purchasing”. A similar pattern was discernible towards the end of our study as the reframing of control practices around principles of mass mobilization reinforced the incentives to engage in periodic cost cutting campaigns whilst the entanglement of such campaigns with the notion of responsibility accounting cemented extant overflows such as data manipulation to meet financial targets. These findings are indicative of how insights from classical versions of economic sociology may prompt some re-conceptualization of the possibilities of framing 30 economic behaviour and thus enrich the performative tradition. Rather than conceiving of framing as a relatively isolated event aimed at disentangling economic behaviour to render it controllable, it would seem pertinent to recognise how it depends on and is continuously conditioned by a range of embedded practices. Empirical enquiries closely following Callon’s (1998a, 1998b) work have placed considerable emphasis on the theories and specific calculative devices constituting economic behaviour (e.g., Christensen and Skærbæk, 2004; MacKenzie and Millo, 2003; Skærbæk, 2009; Skærbæk and Tryggestad, 2010). By contrast, our findings suggest that economic theories played a less direct, constitutive role and that it was largely superseded by socially embedded practices once specific calculative practices, such as responsibility accounting, were put into practice. Whilst agency theory was explicitly invoked to legitimize the MES reform and the introduction of the “MetalCo Model”, it became much less salient in the subsequent framing of economic behaviour as a result of the reconciliation of responsibility accounting with long-standing political and social concerns. This, in turn, fostered a more complex framing process where key actors, such as the CFO of MetalCo, continuously sought to disentangle financial control from embedded practices whilst such practices continued to condition economic behaviour and emerging overflows. From a Callon-inspired perspective, such outcomes may be seen as a consequence of accounting forming a very incomplete and fragile frame (cf. Christensen and Skærbæk, 2004; Gill, 2008; Skærbæk, 2009). However, given the seemingly intractable task of disentangling responsibility accounting from the broader, socio-economic context of Chinese SOEs, we are more inclined to conceive of framing as a process that inherently draws on and is in constant interaction with elements situated outside the focal frame (cf. Miller, 2002). At the same time, our analysis confirms central tenets of Callon’s (1998b) work in so far as the propensity for more or less radical re-framing is concerned. The system of responsibility accounting devised by the CFO of MetalCo proved remarkably resilient despite escalating overflows and it was only when his position was weakened by exogenous events, such as the market downturn in 2008, that the situation turned sufficiently “hot” for the system to be discredited and control practices to be re-framed around periodic cost-cutting campaigns. This revised conceptualisation of framing has important implications for the notion of responsibility accounting and the theorization of its role in organizations. Much research on this theme has concentrated on the possibilities and merits of adhering to or flouting the controllability principle. We initially suggested that adherence to the controllability principle may be seen as a way of disentangling financial responsibilities from environmental disturbances in an attempt to maintain the stability of control practices. Whilst this is inherently problematic where the framing of responsibility accounting is continuously conditioned by broader, socio-economic contingencies, our analysis provides some insights into how it might be achieved. In MetalCo, allegedly uncontrollable factors continued to be evoked by branch managers to deflect attention from poor financial performance and this “excuse culture” was tacitly accepted as a way of reconciling financial control with long-standing social welfare obligations despite the CFO’s resistance to such practices. This provides an alternative rationale as to why the influence of uncontrollable factors is filtered out of performance evaluation to those generally emphasised in the literature. Empirical accounting research has mainly explained variations in this regard from a motivational perspective with reference to the influence of organizational structures and business environments (e.g., Frow et al., 2005; Giraud et al., 2008; Merchant, 31 1987, 1989) without relaxing the assumption that the ultimate objective of responsibility accounting is that of aligning the interests of managers and shareholders. By contrast, our findings suggest that some uncontrollable factors are at least implicitly excluded from financial performance evaluation to avoid destabilising conflicts with socially embedded priorities competing with pressures for enhanced shareholder orientation. However, it would be fallacious to assume that economic behaviour is controllable merely because a seemingly stable frame has been established through the use of responsibility accounting. As demonstrated by the persistence of the “MetalCo Model” such stability may prevail despite the emergence of a multitude of overflows unless wider changes in the socio-economic environment prompt a radical re-framing of control practices. Our view of responsibility accounting as a device for framing economic behaviour also adds important insights that are generally overlooked in the economics-based literature on the topic. Most importantly, the finding that the use of responsibility accounting to frame economic behaviour is entangled with broader social priorities enhances our understanding of the role of goal conflicts emanating from a broader range of socio-economic objectives being endorsed by dominant stakeholders. Agency theorists have typically paid little attention to such goal conflicts by assuming that dominant stakeholders, or principals, possess relatively stable and consistent preferences (Shapiro, 2005). With respect to responsibility accounting the over-riding preference of the principal is generally seen as being that of profit maximization. However, this is rarely a realistic assumption in organizations that continue to fill wider, socio-economic functions despite being exposed to increasing pressures for enhanced financial performance as is often the case in SOEs in emerging and transitional economies (Shirley and Xu, 1998, 2001). Even though the policy discourse initially underpinning the MES reform echoed much of the agency theoretic concerns with enhanced financial performance and shareholder orientation the governance and control practices subsequently devised by the SASAC and permeating MetalCo reveal a rather more complex reform trajectory where such concerns became entangled with broader, socially embedded priorities and how this continued to detract from financial performance. This observation nuances prior commentaries suggesting that the MES reform followed some Anglo-American corporate governance ideal infused with agency theory in a rather slavish and unreflexive manner (e.g., Clarke, 2003; Wong, 2005). However, it is consistent with the finding that political constraints have continued to exercise an important influence on control practices in SOEs (O’Connor et al., 2006). The economic sociology perspective advanced in this paper also provides a more holistic and dynamic view of how responsibility accounting is implicated in shaping economic behaviour than that normally found in the economics-based literature. Whereas the latter body of research mainly examines specific behavioural consequences, or agency problems, in isolation from each other, our analysis shows how a multitude of overflows are both generated by and condition the continuous development of responsibility accounting. This adds important, complementary insights to recent research showing how responsibility accounting is implicated in organizational change by shaping the socio-cognitive boundaries conditioning economic behaviour (Rowe et al., 2008). In contrast to such advances, our study demonstrates how responsibility accounting interacts with a broader range of socioeconomic contingencies rooted in political reforms unfolding over an extended period 32 of time. However, we believe that future research has much to gain from connecting such macro-level categories to mechanisms operating at a deeper, cognitive level to enhance our understanding of how individual actors conceive of and engage with responsibility accounting. This may foster further, multi-level analyses of how different sources of embeddedness interact in shaping economic behaviour (cf. Dacin et al., 1999). It may also enrich emerging research into how cognitive mechanisms influence individual reactions to key aspects of responsibility accounting, such as variations in adherence to the controllability principle (Burkert et al., 2011), by drawing attention to how such mechanisms are conditioned by the broader socioeconomic environment in which they are embedded. 33 References Antle, R and Demski, J.S. (1988) The controllability principle in responsibility accounting, The Accounting Review, 63, 700-718. Baiman, S. (1990) Agency research in management accounting: a second look, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 15, 341-371. Baiman, S. and Noel, J. (1985) Noncontrollable costs and responsibility accouting, Journal of Accounting Research, 23, 486-501. Berry, A.J., Capps, T., Cooper, D., Ferguson, P., Hopper, T. and Lowe, E.A. (1985) Management control in an area of the NCB: rationales of accounting practices in a public enterprise, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 10, 3-28. Bloomfield, B.P., Coombs, R., Cooper, D.J. and Rea, D. (1992) Machines and maneuvers: responsibility accounting and the construction of hospital information systems, Accounting, Management and Information Technology, 2, 197-219. Burchell, S., Clubb, C., Hopwood, A., Hughes, J. and Nahapiet, J. (1980) The roles of accounting in organizations and society, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 5, 527. Burkert, M., Fischer, F.M. and Schaffer, U. (2011) Application of the controllability principle and managerial performance: the role of role perceptions, Management Accounting Research, 22, 143-159. Bushman, R.M., Indjejikan, R.J. and Smith, A. (1995) Aggregate performance measures in business unit manager compensation: The role of intrafirm interdependencies, Journal of Accounting Research, 35 (Supplement), 101-128. Caliskan, K. and Callon, M. (2009) Economization, part 1: shifting attention from the economy towards processes of economization, Economy and Society, 38, 369-398. Caliskan, K. and Callon, M. (2010) Economization, part 2: a research programme for the study of markets, Economy and Society, 39, 1-32. Callon, M. (1998a) Introduction: the embeddedness of economic markets in economics, in Callon, M. (Ed.) The Laws of the Market, Oxford: Blackwell. Callon, M. (1998b) An essay on framing and overflowing: economic externalities revisited by sociology, in Callon, M. (Ed.) The Laws of the Market, Oxford: Blackwell. Chen, Y, Jubb, P. and Tran, A. (1997) Problems of accounting reform in the People’s Republic of China, International Journal of Accounting, 32, 139-153. Cheung, L.K. and Xing, L. (1994) Management myopia: a by-product of the business contract system in China, Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 11, 125-131. 34 Choudhury, N. (1986) Responsibility accounting and controllability, Accounting and Business Research, 16, 189-198. Chow, C.W., Duh, R-R and Xiao, J.Z. (2007) Management accounting practices in the People’s Republic of China, in Chapman, C.S., Hopwood, A.G. and Shields, M.D. (eds) Handbook of Management Accounting Research, Oxford: Elsevier. Christensen, M. and Skærbæk, P. (2004) Framing and overflowing of public sector accountability innovations. A comparative study of reporting practices, Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 20, 101-132. Clarke, D.C. (2003) Corporate governance in China: an overview, China Economic Review, 14, 494-507. Collins, M. and Bloom, R. (1991) The role of oral history in accounting, Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 4(4), 23-31. Dacin, T., Ventresca, M.J. and Beal, B.D. (1999) ‘The embeddedness of organizations: dialogue & directions’, Journal of Management, 25, 317-356. Demski, J.S. (1976) Uncertainty and evaluation based on controllable performance, Journal of Accounting Research, Autumn, 230-245. Demski, J.S. and Sappington, D.E.M. (1989) Hierarchical structure and responsibility accounting, Journal of Accounting Research, 27, 40-58. Duh, R-R., Xiao, J.Z. and Chow, C.W. (2008) An overview and assessment of contemporary management accounting research in China, Journal of Management Accounting Research, 20, 129-164. Eisenhardt, K.M. (1989) Agency theory: an assessment and review, Academy of Management Review, 14, 57-74.. Ezzamel, M. Xiao, J.Z. and Pan, A. (2007) Political ideology and accounting regulation in China, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32, 669-700. Firth, M. (1996) The diffusion of managerial accounting procedures in the People’s Republic of China and the influence of foreign partnered joint ventures, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 21, 629-654. Fligstein, N. and Dauter, L. (2007) The sociology of markets, Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 105-128. Fourcade, M. (2007) Theories of markets and theories of society, American Behavioral Scientist, 50, 1015-1034. Frow, N., Marginson, D. and Ogden, S. (2005) Encouraging strategic behaviour while maintaining management control: multi-functional project teams, budgets, and the negotiation of shared accountabilities in contemporary enterprises, Management Accounting Research, 16, 269-292. 35 Giraud, F., Langevin, P. and Mendoza, C. (2008) Justice as a rationale for the controllability principle: a study of managers’ opinions, Management Accounting Research, 19, 32-44. Gill, M. (2008) Rationalization defeats itself: the limits to accounting’s framing of economic life, Socio-Economic Review, 6, 587-609. Goffman, E. (1971) Frame Analysis. An Essay on the Organization of Experience, Chicago: Northeastern University Press. Granovetter, M. (1985) Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481-510. Groves, T., Hong, Y., McMillan, J. and Naughton, B. (1994) Autonomy and incentives in Chinese state enterprises, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 183209. Hammond, T. and Sikka, P. (1996) Radicalizing accounting history: the potential of oral history, Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 9(3), 79-97 Hassard, J., Morris, J., Sheehan, J. and Yuxin, X. (2010) China’s state-owned enterprises: economic reform and organizational restructuring, Journal of Organizational Change Management, 23, 500-516. Hassard, J., Sheehan, J. and Morris, J. (1999) Enterprise reform in post-Deng China, International Studies of Management and Organization, 29(3), 54-83. Hassard, J., Sheehan, J. and Yuxin, X. (2008) Chinese state-enterprise reform: economic transition, labour unrest and worker representation, Capital and Class, 96(3), 31-52. Hassard, J., Sheehan, J., Zhou, M.X., Tong, J.T. and Morris, J. (2007), China’s State Enterprise Reform: from Marx to the Market, New York : Routledge. Hoffman, A.M. (1974) Reliability and validity in oral history, Communications Quarterly, 22, 23-27. Hussain, A. and Jian, C. (1999) Changes in China’s industrial landscape and their implication, International Studies of Management and Organization, 29(3), 5-20 Hussain, A. and Zhuang, J. (1997) Chinese state enterprises and their reform, Asia Pacific Business Review, 3(3), 20-37. Kilmann, R.H. (1983) The costs of organizations structure: dispelling the myths of independent divisions and organization-wide decision making, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 8, 341-357. Krippner, G.R. and Alvarez, A.S. (2007) ‘Embeddedness and the Intellectual Projects of Economic Sociology’, Annual Review of Sociology, 33, 219-240. 36 Lau, C-M., Fan, D.K.K., Young, M.N. and Wu, S. (2007) Corporate governance effectiveness during institutional transition, International Business Review, 16, 425448. Lee, C-W. J. (2001) Financial restructuring of state-owned enterprises in China: the case of Shanghai Sunve Pharmaceutical Corporation, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 26, 673-689. Lee, K. (1993) Property rights and the agency problem in China’s enterprise reform, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 17, 179-194. Lieberthal, K. (2004) Governing China: From Revolution through Reform, New York: W. W. Norton. MacKenzie, D. (2006) An Engine, Not a Camera: How Financial Models Shape Markets, Princeton: Princeton University Press. MacKenzie, D. and Millo, Y. (2003) Constructing a market, perfoming theory: the historical sociology of a financial derivatives exchange, American Journal of Sociology, 109, 1007-1045. McNally, G.M. (1980) Responsibility accounting and organizational control: some perspectives and prospects, Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 7, 165-181. Melumad, N., Mookherjee, D. and Reichelstein, S. (1992) A theory of responsibility centers, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 15, 445-484. Merchant, K.A. (1987) How and why do firms disregard the controllability principle?, in Bruns, W.J and Kaplan, R.S. (eds) Accounting and Management: Field Study Perspectives, Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press. Merchant, K.A. (1989) Rewarding Results: Motivating Profit Center Managers. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press. Merchant, K.A. (2006) Measuring general managers’ performances. Market, accounting and combination-of-measures systems, Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 19, 893-917. Miller, D. (2002) Turning Callon the right way up, Economy and Society, 31, 218233. Miller, P. (1994) Accounting as social and institutional practice: an introduction, in Hopwood, A.G. and Miller, P. (Eds.) Accounting as Social and Institutional Practice, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Miller, P. (1998) The margins of accounting, in Callon, M. (Ed.) The Laws of the Market, Oxford: Blackwell. Miller, P. (2007) Management accounting and sociology, in Chapman, C.S., Hopwood, A.G. and Shields, M.D. (eds) Handbook of Management Accounting Research, Oxford: Elsevier. 37 Millo, Y. and MacKenzie, D. (2009) The usefulness of inaccurate models: towards an understanding of the emergence of financial risk management, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 638-653. Mitter, R (2004), A Bitter Revolution: China's Struggle with the Modern World, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Modell, S. and Lee, A. (2001) ‘Decentralization and reliance on the controllability principle in the public sector’, Financial Accountability and Management, 17: 191218. Modell, S. and Wiesel, F. (2008), ‘Marketization and Performance Measurement in Swedish Central Government: A Comparative Institutionalist Study’, Abacus, 44, 251-283. Moers, F. (2006) Performance measure properties and delegation, The Accounting Review, 81, 897-924. Nee, V. (1992) Organizational dynamics of market transition: hybrid forms, property rights, and mixed economy in China, Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, 1-27. Neu, D. (1992) The social construction of positive choices, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 17, 223-237. Neu, D. and Simmons, C. (1996) Reconsidering the “social” in positive accounting theory: the case of site restoration costs, Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 7, 409435. Nolan, P. (2005) Evaluation of the World Bank's Contribution to Chinese Enterprise Reform, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. O’Connor, N.G., Chow, C.W. and Wu, A. (2004) The adoption of “Western” management accounting/controls in China’s state-owned enterprises during economic transition, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 29, 349-375. O’Connor, N.G., Deng, J. and Luo, Y. (2006) Political constraints, organization design and performance measurement in China’s state-owned enterprises, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 31, 157-177. Otley, D. (1990) Issues in accountability and control: some observations from a study of colliery accountability in the British Coal Corporation, Management Accounting Research, 1, 101-123. Polanyi, K. (1944) The Great Transformation, New York: Rinehart. Roberts, J. (2001) Trust and control in Anglo-American systems of corporate governance: the individualizing and socializing effects of processes of accountability, Human Relations, 54, 1547-1572. 38 Rowe, C., Birnberg, J.G. and Shields, M.D. (2008) Effects of organizational process change on responsibility accounting and managers’ revelation of private knowledge, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 33, 164-198. Scapens, R.W. and Hou, B-L. (1995) The evolution of responsibility accounting systems in China, Research in Accounting in Emerging Economies, 3, 193-211. Scapens, R.W. and Meng, Y. (1993) Management accounting research in China, Management Accounting Research, 4, 321-341. Seal, W. (2006) Management accounting and corporate governance: an institutional interpretation of the agency problem, Management Accounting Research, 17, 389408. Shapiro, S.P. (2005) Agency theory, Annual Review of Sociology, 31, 263-284. Shi, T.J., (2009) Is there an Asian value? Popular understanding of democracy in Asia, in Yang, D.L. and Zhao, L.T. (eds), China's Reforms at 30: Challenges and Prospects, NJ: World Scientific Publishing. Shirley, M.M. and Xu, L.C. (1998) Information, incentives and commitment: an empirical analysis of contracts between government and state enterprises, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 14, 358-378. Shirley, M.M. and Xu, L.C. (2001) Empirical effects of performance contracts: evidence from China, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 17, 168-200. Simons, R. (2005) Levers of Organization Design: How Managers Use Accountability Systems for Greater Performance and Commitment, Boston, Harvard Business School Press. Skærbæk, P. (2009) Public sector auditor identities in making efficiency auditable: the National Audit Office of Denmark as independent auditor and modernizer, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 971-987. Skærbæk, P. and Tryggestad, K. (2010) The role of accounting devices in performing corporate strategy, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 35, 108-124. Skousen, C.K. and Yang, J-L. (1988) Western management accounting and the economic reforms of China, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13, 201-206. Steinfeld, E.S. (1998) Forging Reform in China: The Gate of State-Owned Industry, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Suh, Y (1987) Collusion and noncontrollable cost allocation, Journal of Accounting Research, 25 (Supplement), 22-46. Suh, Y. (1988) Noncontrollable costs and optimal performance measurement, Journal of Accounting Research, 26, 154-168. 39 Ugras, Y.J. (1994) Factors affecting allocation of noncontrollable costs for performance evaluation use: A survey, Advances in Management Accounting, 3, 255278. Unger, J and Chan, A. (2007) Memories and the moral economy of a state-owned enterprise, in Lee, C.K. and Yang, G.B. (eds) Re-envisioning the Chinese Revolution: the Politics and Poetics of Collective Memories in Reforming China, Stanford: Stanford University Press. Vancil, R.F. (1979) Decentralization. Managerial Ambiguity by Design, Homewood: Dow Jones-Irwin. Vollmer, H. (2007) How to do more with numbers. Elementary stakes, framing, keying, and the three-dimensional character of numerical signs, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32, 577-600. Vollmer, H., Mennicken, A. and Preda, A. (2009) Tracking the numbers: across accounting and finance, organizations and markets, Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 619-637. Wong, L. (2005) Corporate governance in China: a lack of critical reflexivity? Advances in Public Interest Accounting, 11, 117-143. World Bank (1995) Meeting the Challenge of Chinese Enterprise Reform, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. World Bank (1996) China - Reform of State-Owned Enterprises, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. World Bank (1997) China's Management of Enterprise Assets: the State as a Shareholder, The World Bank, Washington, D.C. Wu, J., Boateng, A. and Drury, C. (2007) An analysis of the adoption, perceived benefits, and expected future emphasis of western management accounting practices in Chinese SOEs and JVs, International Journal of Accounting, 42, 171-185. Yang, C (2008) The “Chinese” way—performance appraisal and personnel control in Chinese government departments, in Gstraunthaler, T. and Messner, M (eds), Performance in context – Perspectives from management research, Innsbruck, Innsbruck University Press. Yang, X.M. and Zhou, Y.H. (1999). China Unit System, Beijing: China Economic Press. Zukin, S. and DiMaggio, P. (1990) ‘Introduction’, in Zukin C. and DiMaggio, P. (eds) Structures of Capital. The Social Organization of the Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 40 HN Office Refinery Production mgt Power plant 1 Human resource Power plant 2 Equipment & Engery Carbon factory Transport unit Accounting & finance Mainte -nance Engineering & Project mgt. R&D Inf. system Safty & environment Sales Figure 1. Organizational structure of HN around the time of our field work. 41 Inventory mgt Appendix List of interviews List of interviews with governing agencies of SOEs Interviewee Head of Performance Review Division, Performance Bureau, China State Asset Administration Committee (SASAC) Duration (min.) Date 2008 2009 2010 60 11/08/09 45 4/09/09 45 Chief, Performance Bureau., SASAC 2011 6/08/10 60 5/09/11 60 24/09/11 20 6/08/10 30 Deputy Minister, Ministry of Finance 5/09/11 120 4/09/09 30 Deputy Chief, XX Municipal branch of SASAC 5/08/10 90 23/09/11 20 28/09/11 60 10/09/09 50 Chief, SOE performance division, XX municipal Party Committee, 20/09/11 90 2/10/08 45 9/09/09 120 1/8/10 45 4/09/11 60 20/09/11 Subtotal:18 2 4 4 8 2010 2011 List of interviews at MetalCo headquarters Interviewee Assistant to the chairman Duration (min.) 90 Date 2008 2009 22/10/08 7/8/09 90 50 6/ 8/10 17/9/11 Deputy Chief, Accounting and Finance 120 23/10/08 45 7/09/09 60 16/9/11 Secretary of Office 60 6/ 8/10 Staff, Accounting and Finance 120 7/ 8/10 Deputy Director, the ining function 90 7/ 8/10 Deputy Director of Sales 30 8/09/09 42 Head of the Investors’ Relations 45 22/10/08 Deputy Head, SAP team 60 23/10/08 60 5/09/09 Subtotal: 14 4 4 4 2 List of interviews at HNbrach Interviewee Duration (min.) Managing Director 60 Date 2008 35 Party Secretary-General 2009 2010 25/8/09 60 23/8/10 30 2/8/10 45 14/10/08 30 23/8/09 45 2/8/10 30 23/8/10 30 Assistant to the Managing Director Chairman, Disciplinary Committee Head of Sales Head of Office 1/10/11 30 10/9/08 30 1/11/08 60 5/08/09 60 25/8/09 30 11/09/09 120 31/7/10 30 19/7/10 30 3/9/11 60 1/10/11 45 15/10/08 40 17/10/08 90 13/10/08 40 24/8/09 90 24/8/10 90 21/8/10 60 1/8/10 90 Deputy Head of Office 60 2/10/11 14/10/08 40 Head of Human Resource 150 24/8/09 17/10/08 120 27/8/09 50 Head of Accounting and Finance 2011 13/10/08 23/8/10 90 15/10/08 90 17/10/08 120 26/8/09 45 24/8/10 5/10/11 43 Deputy Head Finance of Accounting and 90 15/10/08 45 26/8/09 3/8/10 +lunch 22/8/10 +dinner 90 120 Head of Purchasing 30 3/10/11 Head of XX Mine 40 3/9/11 60 6/9/11 90 4/10/11 60 6/10/11 Former Head of Accounting Finance and 30 16/10/08 90 Tax officer, Accounting and Finance 24/8/10 60 20/10/08 60 16/10/08 60 29/8/09 90 26/8/09 21/8/10 +dinner 60 Head of Budgeting Office, Accounting and Finance 90 16/10/08 4/8/10; lunch 40 60 4/10/10 Chief Finance Officer, the Mining Function 120 3/8/10 Chief Finance Officer, LZ branch 180 21/8/10 Worker, Refinery 2 40 22/8/10 Head of Resource Salary Office, Human 120 20/10/08 150 27/8/09 Staff, Salary Office, Human Resource 45 27/8/09 Chief, Refinery1 120 Chief, Refinery2 Deputy Director, cement factory, 60 28/8/09 60 28/8/09 60 Factory worker, Refinery 2 14/10/08 15/10/08 45 120 SAP team members, IT Dept. 28/8/09 20/10/08 60 31/8/09 Managing Director, private competitor A Whole day 1/8/09 Head of Office, private competitor A Whole day 1/8/09 Whole day 3/9/09 Whole day 3/9/09 Deputy Managing Director, competitor B Production Manager, competitor B Subtotal: 72 private private 20 44 22 19 11 45