ECONOMIC AND ECOLOGICAL ANALYSIS OF THE CAPE HATTERAS AREA CLOSURE IN THE ATLANTIC BLUEFIN TUNA FISHERY by Megan Ware Dr. Pat Halpin, Advisor Dr. Andre Boustany, Advisor April 21, 2015 Masters project submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Master of Environmental Management degree in the Nicholas School of the Environment of Duke University EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Fisheries are a common property resource and, as a result, are often overexploited because short-term economic gains are considered over long-term societal costs. An archetypical example of this depletion is in the Atlantic bluefin tuna fishery. Atlantic bluefin tuna are a highly migratory species whose quality meat and large size make them a valuable economic resource. In the 1960’s, the catch of Atlantic bluefin tuna increased dramatically, with 30,000 tons caught in the Eastern Atlantic and 18,000 tons caught in the Western Atlantic. This rapid growth in the fishery was made possible by improvements in fishing methodology and technology as well as increased demand from the Japanese sushi market. However, this high level of fishing was unsustainable and, by 1980, populations declined. In response to these depleted populations, quotas were established for the stock. In the US, the current annual Atlantic bluefin tuna quota is 1018 tons and is apportioned among different gear types. However, enforcement of this quota is difficult. The longline sector is continually exceeding its allotment and the number of dead discards is often greater than the allocation of catch. Amendment 7 to the 2006 Consolidated Atlantic Highly Migratory Species Fishery Management Plan represents an effort by NOAA Fisheries to address the management deficiencies in the Atlantic bluefin tuna fishery. One aspect of the Amendment is to create a seasonal area closure in the longline fishery off the coast of Cape Hatteras, NC. This management measure is expected to produce ecological benefits for the species but also economic costs for fishermen. Therefore, the objective of this Master’s Project was to: 1) identify the ecological impact of the closure on bluefin tuna and associated species including yellowfin tuna, bigeye tuna, and swordfish; 2) model the redistribution of displaced fishing effort; and 3) understand if the area closure is in an effective and equitable location. Data on the Atlantic bluefin tuna longline fishery were obtained from Dr. Andre Boustany. Information in the dataset included the date, location, number of sets, number of hooks, and the number of fish caught per species. Data were imported into ArcGIS and catch per unit effort (CPUE) was calculated by dividing the number of interactions by the number of hooks. The redistribution of displaced fishing effort was mapped by assuming fishermen want to maximize returns and minimize costs. Expected revenue for each set was calculated by multiplying the monthly average price per species by the number of individuals caught. The travel costs from four major ports in North Carolina (Hatteras, Morehead City, Ocracoke, and Wanchese) were calculated by plotting the Euclidean distance and multiplying this by $1.02, a pelagic longline travel cost estimate from Strand (2004). Expected profit was then calculated by subtracting travel costs from revenue. The ecological benefits of the area closure were determined by calculating the number of bluefin tuna, yellowfin tuna, bigeye tuna, and swordfish impacted by the area closure and comparing this to the proportion and magnitude of catch in the location where effort is expected to redistribute. Results showed that while the area closure is in a location with a high number of bluefin tuna interactions, it does not have a high CPUE. Instead, areas of high CPUE migrate up and down the coast mimicking the migration patterns of the species. This means the area closure does not maximize ecological benefits and the burden of conservation is not equally distributed among fishermen. Based on profit calculations, displaced fishermen are expected to redistribute their fishing effort south to waters off of the North Carolina/South Carolina border. This southern region was 1 predicted for all fishermen regardless of their port of origin. Profit in this southern region was slightly higher than in the area closure; however, the standard deviation of revenue was also higher. Regression analysis confirmed fishermen prefer areas with both large and stable returns. Moderate ecological benefits in the bluefin tuna pelagic longline fishery are expected as a result of the area closure. The annual number of bluefin tuna protected by the area closure is predicted to be roughly 600 individuals. While this represents less than 1% of total yields for the species, it accounts for 74% of dead discards. As a result, the area closure will move the fishery towards quota compliance but it will not ensure complete observance will quota regulations. Furthermore, the area closure is not expected to rebuild stocks of bluefin tuna. In total, the area closure is not expected to ensure quota compliance. The short-coming of this initiative is in large part due to the fact that a stationary area closure does not account for the complexities associated with managing a highly migratory species. Instead, dynamic management measures should be considered as a way to mirror the broad-scale movement of the species. While this type of management requires enhanced levels of education and enforcement, it would mean protection is provided to the stock at the time and location it is most needed, ensuring the largest ecological benefit to the species. 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS Executive Summary……………………………………………………………………………...1 List of Acronyms ………………………………………………………………………………...4 Introduction………………………………………………………………………………………5 I. II. III. IV. V. The Atlantic Bluefin Tuna Fishery……………………………………………………5 Current Management of the Fishery…………………………………………………..6 Problems with the Recovery of the Species………………………………………..….8 The Area Closure………………….………………………………………………......9 Objectives of Project…………………………………………………………………12 Methods………………………………………………………………………………………….12 I. II. III. IV. V. Data…………………………………………………………………………………..12 CPUE………………………………………………………………………………...13 Cost, Revenue, and Profit……………………………………………………...…….13 Effort Redistribution………………………………………………………………....14 Ecology………………………………………………………………………………15 Results…………………………………………………………………………………………...16 I. II. III. CPUE………………………………………………………………………………...16 Redistribution of Fishing Effort……………………………………………………...18 Ecological Benefits…………………………………………………………………..22 Discussion……………………………………………………………………………………….24 I. II. III. IV. V. Economic and Ecological Implications……………………………………………...24 Significant Difference Between the Area Closure and Patch 11………………….....26 Comparison to Amendment 7………………………………………………………..27 Discussion of No-Take Zones………………………………………………………..27 Limitations of Project………………………………………………………………..28 Recommendations…………………………………………..……………………………….….29 Acknowledgements……………………………………………………………………………..33 References…………………………………..…………………………………………………...34 Appendix..………………..……………………………………………………………………...37 3 LIST OF ACCRONYMS ABFT – Atlantic Bluefin Tuna ICCAT – International Commission for the Conservation of Atlantic Tuna TAC – Total Allowable Catch MSA – Magnuson-Stevens Act ATCA – Atlantic Tunas Convention Act CPUE – Catch Per Unit Effort YFT – Yellowfin Tuna BET – Bigeye Tuna SWO – Swordfish MPA – Marine Protected Area DMA – Dynamic Management Area 4 INTRODUCTION I. The Atlantic Bluefin Tuna Fishery Fisheries are a common-property resource; without regulations, anyone is permitted to access and use the stocks. As a result, fish populations are often over-exploited because individuals consider personal gains rather than costs to society. Specifically, individuals consider the personal benefit of catching one more fish rather than the consequences of extracting a resource at a higher rate than it can be replenished. This depletion of a common pool resource, termed the ‘Tragedy of the Commons’1, is shown to occur in fisheries worldwide. An archetypal example of a depleted common pool resource is the Atlantic bluefin tuna (ABFT). Inhabiting the entire North Atlantic and adjoining waters such as the Mediterranean Sea, ABFT have one of the widest geographical distributions of any species.2 This large distribution is made possible by their fast swimming speed and the fact that ABFT can maintain their body temperature in both cold (3o C) and warm (30o C) ocean temperatures.3 Tagging data show ABFT follow an extensive migration pattern throughout the year. Along the East Coast of the United States, ABFT winter off of the coast of the Carolinas; however, during the summer, the species migrates to waters near New England and Canada4. Due to this extensive seasonal movement, ABFT are characterized as a highly migratory species. Tagging data have also revealed there are two separate populations of ABFT: the eastern stock and the western stock. 5 The eastern stock is estimated to have a spawning stock biomass (the population capable of reproducing) between 439,000- 647,000 tons and originates in the Mediterranean Sea.6 The western stock is much smaller, with a spawning stock biomass between 22,000 - 33,000 tons, and originates in the Gulf of Mexico.7 While an individual returns to its spawning site to reproduce, ABFT migrate and forage throughout the entire Atlantic Ocean.8 In fact, the ranges of the eastern and western stocks overlap up to 47%.9 This means a fisherman who catches an ABFT off the US coast has up to a 50% chance of catching a fish which was spawned on the opposite side of the Atlantic. The impressive size and high quality meat of ABFT makes them a valuable economic resource. Dating back to the Phoenicians in 1200 BC, ABFT captured the attention of fishermen due to their impressive length (>3m) and weight (up to 670kg).10 While ABFT were historically caught with beach seines and hand lines, during the 1950s and 1960s fishing technology 5 transitioned to purse seines and longlines.11 This change in methodology increased the number of hooks in the water, the number of ABFT caught as bycatch, and mortality in the fishery.12 Other technological changes included improvements in sonar which made fishermen more effective at locating tuna, and improved on-board storage, which allowed fishermen to extend their number of days at sea.13 At the same time demand for bluefin tuna increased largely as the result of the immense growth in the Japanese sushi market and the ability to quickly fly tuna from the Atlantic to Tokyo.14 This escalation in demand raised the prices of bluefin tuna, increasing the profitability of the fishery and providing fishermen the incentive to invest in larger and more powerful boats.15 Together, these changes expanded the area of the ocean which was economically viable for tuna exploitation.16 As a result, landings of ABFT increased dramatically in the early 1960’s, with roughly 30,000 tons caught annually in the East Atlantic.17 In the West Atlantic, 18,000 tons of ABFT were caught in 1964, 18 times the catch reported four years previous.18 High landings continued until the late 1960s when the capacity of the fleet exceeded the productivity of the fishery.19 By 1980, the spawning stock biomass of the western ABFT dropped to just 15% of its pre-exploitation level.20 A similar collapse was seen in the spawning stock biomass of the eastern population during the 1970s.21 These low population levels continue today as the West Atlantic stock is at just 36% of its already overfished 1970 levels.22 II. Current Management of the Fishery ABFT are currently managed by the International Commission for the Conservation of Atlantic Tuna (ICCAT). Established in 1969, this intergovernmental organization was created in recognition of the fact that tuna are highly migratory and do not obey national or international boundaries23. The mission of ICCAT is to promote “the conservation of tuna and tuna-like species in the Atlantic and its adjacent seas”.24 To achieve this goal, member nations of ICCAT provide annual catch and effort data from their national tuna fisheries.25 This information serves as the basis of ICCAT’s scientific reports and is used to facilitate management schemes among member nations.26 Currently, ICCAT oversees the broad geographic range of ABFT by dividing the stock into two management zones: the western stock and the eastern stock.27 The management boundary separating these two populations is the 45o W meridian in the North Atlantic Ocean.28 While this method may provide a simplified management system, it does not 6 match the ecological nature of ABFT since the species migrates between both sides of the Atlantic Ocean.29 This has significant implications for the validity of stock assessments and projections on the recovery of the two populations.30 The ineffectiveness of ICAAT’s management scheme is amplified by the fact that ICAAT has no legitimate enforcement power over the member nations.31 As a result, issues with over-capitalization of the fishery and illegal, unintended, and unreported fishing are continuing to plague the ABFT fishery.32 In response to the continued depletion of the ABFT, ICCAT imposed catch quotas in 1982.33 The theory behind quotas is that, by limiting effort in the fishery, scientific data can be used to direct the optimal harvest of a species. Specifically, data can be used to determine a sustainable total allowable catch (TAC) and this amount can be divided into shares, or quotas, among participants in the fishery. In the West Atlantic, TACs have remained relatively stable, ranging between 1750 and 2700 tons.34 Contrastingly, in the East Atlantic, TACs have been appreciably high even in the face of scientific data which challenges their long-term sustainability.35 This discrepancy between the management of the two populations continues today as the 2014 West Atlantic quota was set at 1750 metric tons while the East Atlantic quota was 13,500 tons.36 The implications of this mismanagement are severe given there is significant mixing between the two populations and large yields in the East Atlantic can negatively impact the western stock. The United States is a major participant in the West Atlantic bluefin tuna fishery. Between 2011 and 2014, the annual US baseline quota for ABFT was 1018 tons, roughly 53% of the TAC for the West Atlantic catch.37 This quota is managed by NOAA Fisheries and is broken down by gear type as seen in Table 1. The “Reserve” category is set aside for scientific research and can be used to account for dead discards, thereby providing flexibility in the management of the fishery.38 7 Table 1: Distribution of US ABFT quota among gear types.39 Gear Type Percentage of US ABFT Quota 47.1% General (Commercial fishermen who use rodand-reel) Harpoon Purse Seine Longline Trap Angling (includes recreational fishermen) Reserve III. 3.9% 18.6% 8.1% 0.1% 19.7% 2.5% Problems with the Recovery of the Species Recently, the distribution of ABFT quota among gear types in the US received significant criticism. The longline category is repeatedly exceeding its subquota, which is 8.1% of the TAC.40 This is forcing NOAA Fisheries to rely on unharvested quota from other sectors or to ‘borrow’ quota from the Reserve category in order to meet yearly catches.41 Another issue is that, while yields in the fishery have remained fairly stable due to extensive management measures, the western stock remains well below its 1960 levels.42 In fact, the stock has been considered overfished since 1997.43 This means that while the collapse of the fishery may be halted, the western stock of ABFT has yet to recover. Several management changes by ICCAT are also precipitating the need for change in the US ABFT fishery. The first is that, when US quotas were first established in 1999, only landings were included in this figure; dead discards were accounted for separately.44 However, in 2006, ICCAT changed its recommendations requiring dead discards to be counted within each country’s annual quota.45 This issue came to a head in 2011 when the annual quota for the longline sector was insufficient to cover dead discards and yields. Specifically, the quota from the longline sector was 82.45 tons and estimates of dead discards exceeded 134.81 tons.46 Secondly, the amount of unharvested quota which can be rolled over each year has been reduced by ICCAT from 100%, to 50%, to the current 10%.47 This minimizes the flexibility of NOAA Fisheries to respond to high yields in the longline fishery. Finally, ICCAT recently adopted a 8 more ecologically conservative approach to qualifying and quantifying dead discards, causing the estimate of dead discards in the fishery to increase.48 The inefficiency in the ABFT fishery is of concern because it means NOAA Fisheries is failing to meet the standards of the Magnuson-Stevens Act (MSA). The MSA is the foremost piece of legislation governing the management of fisheries in the US. The law outlines standards which all fisheries must meet, including minimizing bycatch, managing a species to its optimal harvest, and rebuilding overfished stocks.49 Furthermore, as a member state of ICCAT, the US must abide by the Atlantic Tunas Convention Act (ATCA) and enact regulations which carry out the recommendations of the international organization.50 These regulations include minimizing dead discards to the extent practicable and supporting the efforts of the stock rebuilding program.51 Data from the US ABFT fishery show these requirements are not being met. Specifically, while some gear categories are exceeding their subquotas, others are failing to reach their limit. This shows the fishery is not being optimally managed. Additionally, the large number of dead discards, especially in the longline sector, illustrates bycatch is not being minimized in the fishery. Finally, the fact that the species is still considered overfished means regulations are failing to rebuild the stock. IV. The Area Closure In an effort to address these deficiencies within the fishery, NOAA Fisheries undertook a comprehensive review of ABFT management and the quota system. In 2012, the Highly Migratory Species Advisory Panel began the scoping process to assess challenges within the fishery and potential changes which could be made.52 In August 2013, NOAA Fisheries published the Draft Amendment 7 to the 2006 Consolidated Atlantic Highly Migratory Species Fishery Management Plan53, a document outlining specific actions which could be taken in the fishery to meet MSA and ICCAT requirements. The Final Amendment 7 proposal was released in August 2014 and the Final Rule was issued on December 1, 2014.54 Some of the management strategies outlined in the Amendment include reallocating quota among gear types, implementing area closures, enhancing monitoring, and creating individual bluefin quotas in the longline fishery.55 One management measure of specific relevance to North Carolina fishermen is the implementation of a seasonal gear restriction off of Cape Hatteras.56 As seen in Figure 1, the area was chosen because it has a high number of ABFT interactions relative to the surrounding area.57 9 This area closure will prohibit the use of longline gear from December to April; however, select longline fishermen will be permitted access to the area closure based upon previous compliance with the Pelagic Observer Program, low historic bluefin tuna interactions, and superior logbook reporting.58 The overall goal of the area closure is to improve ABFT stocks by reducing the number of vessels in the fishery, decreasing the number of ABFT caught, and eliminating the boats which make up a large portion of total bycatch.59 Figure 1: The location of the Cape Hatteras area closure. The closure will be implemented from December to April and apply to pelagic longline fishing.60 Implementing this type of closure has vast economic and ecological impacts. Therefore, it is important to analyze the location and timing of the area closure and predict impacts to fishermen and the stock. In the Amendment, NOAA Fisheries undertook a rudimentary analysis to understand the ecological and economic impact of the Cape Hatteras area closure. A major 10 assumption in the analysis is fishermen with 75% or more of their hooks in the area closure will exit the fishery; fishermen who have 40-75% of their hooks in the area closure will redistribute 50% of that displaced fishing effort; and fishermen with less than 40% of their hooks in the area closure will redistribute all of their effort in the fishery.61 Based on this assumption, NOAA estimates that, of the thirty-four vessels fishing in the Cape Hatteras area closure, fourteen will be proscribed from fishing in the region based on performance metrics.62 Four of these fourteen vessels will exit the fishery since greater than 75% of their effort is concentrated in the area closure.63 Three vessels will distribute 50% of their effort outside of the area closure.64 This downsize of the fishery will result in 25 fewer ABFT landed each year and 379 fewer ABFT discarded each year.65 Since ABFT are part of a multi-species fishery, other species impacted include swordfish (1344 fewer fish caught/year), bigeye tuna (310 fewer fish caught/year), and yellowfin tuna (862 fewer fish caught/year).66 Economically, the revenue lost in the fishery after accounting for the partial redistributed of effort is estimated at $211,000 per year.67 While NOAA Fisheries estimates the ecological and economic impacts of the closure, there are several methodological concerns. The first is the assumption that fishermen with greater than 50% of their hooks in the gear restricted area will, in part or in total, exit the fishery. Since the ABFT fishery is a lucrative industry with large sunk costs, it is unlikely fishermen will simply leave the fishery. This is especially true considering fishing is often an immense source of pride and community, making many fishermen unwilling to leave their profession even when it is economically rational to do so.68 Secondly, the analysis in the Amendment assumes displaced fishermen will evenly distribute their effort outside of the area closure. However, this is unlikely since fishermen, hoping to maximize profit, will go to the location which has the highest potential revenue and the lowest fuel costs. As a result, redistributed effort will be heterogeneous.69 Finally, the location of the gear restricted area was chosen due to a high concentration of ABFT interactions. However, it can be argued the most effective location for an area closure is one with a high catch per unit effort (CPUE). CPUE is a measure of fish yields relative to fishing effort. Accounting for effort is important because, unlike the number of interactions, it results in an accurate estimate of fish density; the greater the effort spent catching a fish, the smaller the stock in a given area.70 Furthermore, the calculation of CPUE over time can reflect trends in the population size.71 As a result, CPUE is an important indicator to use when locating a potential area closure. Since interactions, not CPUE, were used as the basis of 11 NOAA’s analysis, it is unclear if the area chosen for the seasonal closure is the most effective location to promote the conservation of ABFT. V. Objectives of Project The objective of this Masters Project was threefold. The first was to map CPUE in order to determine if the location of the Cape Hatteras area closure is an effective and equitable location for the conservation of ABFT. Since Figure 1 shows there are high levels of ABFT interactions in the area, a high CPUE would confirm this location has a high stock density and is ideal for increased management. The second objective of this Master’s Project was to analyze the potential environmental benefits of the area closure to ABFT as well as the other species in the fishery. These include swordfish (SWO), bigeye tuna (BET), and yellowfin tuna (YFT). Finally, the third goal of the Project was to predict where displaced fishermen will go given that they are looking to maximize potential revenue and minimize fuel costs. This relocation could have important economic impacts to fishermen and ecological impacts to the multi-species fishery. An overarching objective of this Master’s Project is to inform future decision-making concerning the location and impact of area closures by using this paper as a methodological case study. METHODS I. Data Data from the ABFT longline fishery were obtained from Dr. Andre Boustany. The dataset included the location (latitude and longitude) of 194,288 sets in the fishery between 1992 and 2008. Additional information included the number of hooks per set, the date, and the number of ABFT, YFT, BET and SWO caught per set. The data were imported into ArcGIS 10.2 as a shapefile using the “NAD 1983 StatePlane North Carolina FIPS 3200” projection. The location of the area closure near Cape Hatteras was mapped in ArcGIS using the coordinates provided in Figure 2.8 of the NOAA Amendment (see Figure 1). 12 II. CPUE CPUE was calculated and mapped in ArcGIS by dividing the total number of interactions for a given species by the total number of hooks in the water for all data between 1992 and 2008. First, data on the number of hooks and the number of interactions per species were converted into raster files (cell size 72000, 72000). If multiple fishing sets occurred in the same raster cell, the sum of the number of hooks and interactions was taken. The Raster Calculator was then used to divide the number of interactions per species by 10,000 hooks. The number of hooks used in the calculation was large so the resulting values of CPUE would not be small decimal numbers. This same procedure was used to calculate CPUE for each of the twelve months. III. Cost Distance, Revenue, and Profit Four major longline fishing ports in North Carolina (Hatteras, Morehead City, Ocracoke, and Wanchese) were identified and their location mapped in ArcGIS.72 Using the Euclidean Distance tool, seaward distances were calculated in miles. Since all four points were located on the coast and the Atlantic Ocean was the focus on the study, there was no concern about avoiding land in this calculation. This prevented the need to use the Cost Distance tool. Distances were then transformed into costs by multiplying the Euclidean Distance raster files by $1.02. This estimate for the cost of fishing per boat mile in North Carolina was obtained from Strand (2004).73 Revenue for each set of hooks was estimated by multiplying the monthly average price per pound of the species by the average weight of the species caught and then multiplying this value by the number of fish caught per set. Monthly data on the total revenue and total poundage caught for each species in the South Atlantic were obtained from NOAA Commercial Fisheries Statistics.74 This allowed for the calculation of the monthly average price per pound for each species. If data were not available for a specific month, then the average price per pound of the previous month served as a proxy. Data on the average weights of ABFT, BET, YFT, and SWO caught in the longline fishery were obtained from catch-at-size data in ICCAT stock assessments.75 These values were then multiplied by the monthly average revenue per pound to get the average revenue per fish caught. The revenue for each species in a single fishing set was calculated by multiplying the monthly average revenue per fish by the number of individuals caught of that species. The 13 revenue values for the four species were then added together to get the total revenue per set. The number of ABFT landed per set (and thus sold for revenue) was limited to two fish to reflect retention limits in the fishery.76 This revenue data were imported into ArcGIS and converted to a raster file. If multiple data points occurred in the same raster cell, the mean of these values was taken. The expected profit for each fishing set was calculated by subtracting the cost-distance for each port from the expected revenue. Therefore, four profits were estimated from a single fishing set to account for different travel costs from each port. These calculations were done in ArcGIS using the Raster Calculator tool. IV. Effort Redistribution In order to compare areas of equal size, locate regions of high profit, and better predict the redistribution of displaced fishing effort, the Southeast Atlantic coast was divided into 18 rectangles similar in size to that of the area closure. This method was based on models developed by Smith & Wilen (2003) in which fishermen choose between an array of locations, or patches, based on expected revenues and travel costs.77 Figure 2 shows the location and size of these patches. Average profits for each patch per port of origin were calculated in ArcGIS by converting profit raster files into shapefiles and using the Statistics tool in the attribute table to calculate the mean. The standard deviation of the average profit was also calculated for each patch. Only data from December to April were used to calculate these average profits since this is when the area closure is to be implemented. This same procedure was repeated to calculate monthly average profits for each patch. 14 Figure 2: An array of 18 patches along the SE Atlantic Coast. This replicated the method used in Smith & Wilen (2003) in which fishermen choose between regions based upon travel costs and expected profit. The blue box is the area closure. A series of regressions were run in STATA to ascertain the respective importance of revenue, economic risk, and travel costs in the fishing location decisions made by fishermen. These regressions analyzed the number of sets in each patch relative to average revenue, the standard deviation of that revenue, and travel costs to the center of the patch. The centroid of each patch was determined using the Calculate Geometry function in the attribute table. All data were used in these regressions. V. Ecology The ecological impacts of the Amendment were assessed by first calculating the average number of ABFT, YFT, BET, and SWO caught within the area closure from December to April. Only data from 2006 to 2008 were used to calculate these averages in order to account for recent population trends. Additionally, the number of ABFT caught within the closure was divided in 15 half to account for the fact that this represents fish from both the western and eastern stocks. The number of individuals caught for each species was then compared to total yield estimates and longline catch data in ICCAT stock assessments.78 ABFT catches impacted by the area closure were also compared to dead discards to assess the potential for quota compliance in the longline fishery. The same methodology was used to assess the number and type of fish caught in patch 11, the area to which most fishing effort is expected to redistribute. Additionally, the relative proportion of each species caught in the fishery was calculated for the area closure and patch 11 to determine if catch in one location is dominated by a specific species. This analysis used data between December and April from all available years. RESULTS I. CPUE Figure 3 maps the CPUE for ABFT caught off the Southeast coast. While CPUE ranges from 0-244 ABFT caught per 10,000 hooks, no clear patterns emerges from the map. Most importantly, CPUE is not appreciably higher in the area closure, denoted by the blue box. This means that although there are a high number of interactions in the area closure, this is largely the result of high fishing effort. 16 Figure 3: The CPUE of ABFT in the South Atlantic for all data between 1992 and 2008. The blue box represents the area closure, illustrating CPUE is not considerably higher in this region. To determine the magnitude and extent of seasonal patterns in the fishery, CPUE was calculated for each month. Figure 4 shows a selection of 8 months which illustrate clear trends in the data. During January and February, CPUE is highest just south of the area closure. This region of high CPUE migrates north into the area closure during March and April. Extensive regions of high CPUE are found in the Mid-Atlantic and New England regions during the month of June and then this area begins to migrate south in the early winter months. These seasonal changes are not surprising given the migration patterns of ABFT up and down the East Coast. 17 Figure 4: Seasonal changes in the location of high CPUE areas. In the late winter, CPUE is highest in the South Atlantic while in the summer and early winter, CPUE is highest in the Mid-Atlantic. II. Redistribution of Fishing Effort The distribution of profits among the 18 patches for fishermen from the four North Carolina ports is shown in Figure 5. The yellow box is the location of the area closure while the green box is the patch with the highest profit and the region to which displaced fishermen are expected to relocate. Profits range from a loss of roughly $400 dollars (fuels costs if nothing is caught) to a gain of $29,000. Importantly, regardless of the port of origin, all fishermen are predicted to relocate to the same patch and this patch is not adjacent to the area closure. 18 Figure 5: Predicted profits of fishermen from the four major fishing ports in North Carolina. The yellow box is the patch with the area closure while the green box is the patch with the highest profit. The star is the location of the port. Profits range from a loss of roughly $400 to a gain of $29,000. Analysis was also undertaken to determine if the relocation of displaced fishermen varied by month. Figure 6 shows the results for fishermen from Wanchese; however, the results were uniform among the four ports. During January, February and April displaced fishermen are predicted to go to patch 11. In December and March, fishermen are predicted to go slightly further south to patch 16. While there is modest seasonal change in the relocation of displaced fishing effort, the overall pattern remains the same: regardless of their port of origin, fishermen will relocate their effort to waters near the North Carolina/South Carolina border. Maps of this monthly analysis for Hatteras, Ocracoke, and Morehead City fishermen can be found in Figures 1-3 of the Appendix. 19 Figure 6: The predicted profit for fishermen from Wanchese for each month of the area closure. The yellow box represents the location of the closure while the green box is the patch with the highest profit. The winter profit is an average of profits between December and April. The winter average profit and associated standard deviation for each patch and port of origin is shown in Tables 2-5. The red highlighted row (patch 4) is the location of the area closure and the green highlighted row (patch 11) is where displaced fishermen are predicted to relocate. Interestingly, patch 11 has a higher average profit than patch 4 for all ports. This begs the question why fishermen are not already relocating to this area. Importantly, Tables 2-5 also show that patch 11 has one of the highest standard deviations meaning profit in this location varies considerably. It may be fishermen are considering economic risk when deciding where to fish. 20 Tables 2 & 3: Average profit and standard deviation for Wanchese and Hatteras fishermen. The patch 4 is the location of the area closure while patch 11 is the region with the highest profit. Patch 11 also has a high standard deviation, a measure of economic risk. Tables 4 & 5: Average profit and standard deviation for Ocracoke and Morehead City fishermen. The patch 4 is the location of the area closure while patch 11 is the region with the highest profit . Patch 11 also has a high standard deviation, a measure of economic risk. 21 Results from regressions run to ascertain the respective importance of revenue, economic risk, and travels costs in the location choices of fishermen are shown in Table 6. Revenue had a positive coefficient and was significant at the 0.05 level for the ports of Wanchese and Hatteras. Standard deviation had a negative coefficient and was significant at the 0.05 level for all ports, with p-values ranging from 0.009 to 0.024. Travel costs had negative coefficients and were not significant. R-Squared values for the four ports ranged between 0.426 and 0.3578. Table 6: Regression results for each port when number of sets is a function of revenue, standard deviation of that revenue, and travel costs. Standard deviation was significant at the 0.05 level for all of the ports, revenue was significant for half of the ports and travel costs were not significant for any of the ports. Port Wanchese Ocracoke Morehead City Hatteras III. Variable Revenue SD Travel Cost Revenue SD Travel Cost Revenue SD Travel Cost Revenue SD Travel Cost Coefficient 3.26 -0.31 -10.42 3.42 -0.32 -11.11 3.12 -0.28 -6.35 3.49 -0.33 -11.39 P-Value 0.025 0.009 0.338 0.057 0.024 0.43 0.061 0.017 0.604 0.047 0.021 0.374 R-Squared 0.426 0.3998 0.3578 0.4145 Ecological Benefits The annual number of ABFT caught in the area closure averaged over the three most recent years of data is shown in Table 7. In total, the annual catch of ABFT is expected to be reduced by roughly 600 individuals. Using an average catch- at-size of 150kg, this is equal to roughly 99 tons of ABFT. The percentage of total ABFT yields impacted by the proposal is shown in the fourth and fifth columns of Table 7. These percentages are all less than 1% of current catches for the eastern and western stocks. Table 7 also shows the percentage of longline catch impacted by the area closure. While the closure accounts for less than 1% of longline catches in the eastern stock, the impact to the western stock ranges up to 3%. Importantly, since some fishermen will be able to fish in the area closure due to high levels of logbook compliance, the reduction in catch and the percentages are likely smaller than those shown in Table 7. 22 Table 7: Number of ABFT affected by the area closure and the relative proportion of this number to total yields and current longline catches. The total number of ABFT per month is divided in half to account for the presence of eastern and western stocks. Month December January February March April # ABFT 96 31 93 165 217 Eastern Western ABFT ABFT 48 48 15 15 46 46 83 83 109 109 % Eastern Yields 0.0488% 0.0156% 0.0473% 0.0844% 0.1107% % Western Yields 0.4386% 0.1406% 0.4249% 0.7580% 0.9949% % Eastern Longline 0.356% 0.114% 0.345% 0.616% 0.809% % Western Longline 1.352% 0.433% 1.309% 2.336% 3.066% Since ABFT are a part of a multispecies fishery, the area closure may also have ecological ramifications for SWO, YFT, and BET. Table 8 shows the annual number of SWO, YFT, and BET caught in the area closure, averaged over the three most recent years of data. SWO are the most common species caught in this region; however, catch in the area closure accounts for less than 1% of their total yields. Similar trends exist for the YFT and the BET. The impacts of the area closure on longline catches of each species are also shown in Table 8. Again, these values are all less than 1%. Table 8: The catch of YFT, BET, and SWO which will be impacted by the area closure. The relative proportions of these numbers to total yields and current longline catches for each species are also shown. Month # YFT December January February March April 652 617 204 92 221 % YFT Yields 0.0105% 0.0100% 0.0033% 0.0015% 0.0036% % YFT # BET Longline 0.0588% 260 0.0556% 226 0.0184% 44 0.0083% 32 0.0199% 65 % BET Yields 0.0243% 0.0211% 0.0041% 0.0030% 0.0060% % BET Longline 0.0476% 0.0413% 0.0081% 0.0058% 0.0253% # SWO 906 552 602 280 297 % SWO Yields 0.3396% 0.1958% 0.2324% 0.1048% 0.1112% % SWO Longline 0.355% 0.204% 0.243% 0.109% 0.116% It is expected that much of the fishing effort displaced by the area closure will redistribute to patch 11. Figure 7 compares the fishing patterns in the two regions. From the graphs it is clear SWO make up a much larger portion of the catch in patch 11 than in the area closure (70% vs. 54%). Additionally, ABFT do not make up a measurable portion of catch in patch 11 whereas they account for 4% of catches in the area closure. Another observation is that the magnitude of catch in the area closure is much higher than in patch 11. This does not mean profit should be necessarily higher in the area closure since revenue is largely dependent on the 23 density of the catches. Instead it means the amount of fishing in patch 11 is significantly less than in the area closure. Patch 11 Catch Dec.-Apr. Area Closure Catch Dec.-Apr. 4% 0% 13% 0% BFT (12) BFT (2481) 30% BET (21) BET (7920) 54% 29% 70% YFT (17843) YFT (5934) SWO (14095) SWO (32404) Figure 7: Proportion and number of catch for the four species in the area closure and patch 11. DISCUSSION I. Economic and Ecological Implications As seen in Figure 3, the area closure is not in a region with a high CPUE. This calls into question the effectiveness of the area closure since high amounts of effort may be causing the large number of interactions seen in Figure 1 rather than a high population density. Monthly analysis of CPUE shows areas of high CPUE migrate up and down the coast, following the migration patterns of ABFT. Figure 4 shows that during March and April, the areas of highest CPUE are, in fact, in the area closure. This suggests there could be large ecological value to the management measure during these two months. However, as the summer progresses, the highest CPUE is found in the Mid-Atlantic and New England regions. By January, ABFT CPUE is highest just south of the area closure. The observation that regions of high CPUE seasonally migrate is important for two reasons. The first is that while an area closure may prove effective for a month or two, there is no single location which is optimal for a long-term closure. This suggests stationary area closures are not ideal to protect non-spawning grounds in the fishery. Secondly, given the fact that CPUE can be just as high off New England as it can be off of Cape Hatteras, the implementation of an area closure in just one of these locations means the burden of conservation is not equally distributed among fishermen. Moreover, while North Carolina fishermen are faced with a closure 24 during critical fishing months, no such management restriction is proposed for New England fishermen. This calls into question the equitable nature of the area closure. The estimated profits shown in Figure 5 suggest displaced fishermen, who are looking to maximize returns and minimize costs, will likely redistribute their fishing effort south of the area closure to patch 11. This pattern slightly varies by month as fishermen either move to patch 11 or patch 16. Therefore, contrary to the assumptions made in the NOAA Amendment, effort redistribution is not homogenous but rather congregates around an area of high profit. Furthermore, this redistribution is not adjacent to the area closure meaning fishermen are not expected to merely move to the borders of the closure. Profits between the area closure and patch 11 are comparable, with profits being slightly higher in patch 11. Notably, the standard deviation of revenue is also higher in patch 11. This begs the question whether revenue, economic risk in the form of standard deviation, or travel cost is the most important factor fishermen consider when choosing where to fish. The regression analysis shown in Table 6 shows revenue and the standard deviation of revenue are important factors fishermen consider when choosing where to fish. The coefficients on the regression outputs show that ideally, fishermen prefer areas with high and stable revenue. This is not surprising given that fishermen want to maximize returns and minimize economic risks. Travel costs were never significant in the regression output and do not appear to be a significant factor in choosing where to set hooks. However, only a small fraction of the range of the fishery was analyzed and travel to far away areas may be limited. Other variables which also influence where fishermen decide to set could include proximity to other fishing grounds, typical ocean conditions, and family tradition. This highlights the complexity of predicting the redistribution of displaced fishing effort. Ecologically, the area closure provides moderate benefits to the ABFT pelagic longline fishery. Table 7 shows that the catch of ABFT will be reduced by roughly 600 individuals, or 99 tons. While this represents only a small percentage of total longline catch, it does equal 74% of longline dead discards, which were 134.81 tons in 2011. Importantly, this does not account for all dead discards and means that the area closure will not ensure quota compliance in the longline sector. Moreover, the area closure will not reduce dead discards to within current catch limits and the fishery will not be in strict compliance with NOAA Fisheries or ICCAT. Table 7 also shows the area closure will impact less than 1% of total ABFT yields. Therefore, the closure will 25 not serve to rebuild or improve current stocks in the fishery. Notably, the percentages calculated are likely higher than the ecological benefits which will be accrued for ABFT since select longline fishermen will be allowed to fish in the area closure due to historic compliance with observers and superior logbook compliance. Impacts to BET, YFT, and SWO are expected to be minimal in the multi-species fishery. Table 8 shows affected portions of these species are all less than 1% of longline catches and total yields. Therefore, the ecological benefits accrued by the area closure for these species are not expected to be significant. II. Significant Differences Between the Area Closure and Patch 11 Displaced fishing effort from the area closure is expected to redistribute to patch 11; however, there are significant differences in the fishing patterns of these two locations which could have important ecological and economic impacts. The first difference is that, while average profits in the two regions are similar, the range of profits in patch 11 is much greater. This means there is greater economic risk when fishing in patch 11. Another important disparity is that, as seen in Figure 7, the proportion of species caught in patch 11 is markedly different than those caught in the area closure. Specifically, fishing in patch 11 is characterized by high catches of SWO, with almost no ABFT and BET caught in this region. Finally, the current magnitude of catch in patch 11 is far less than that occurring in the area closure. This means that, when the area closure is implemented, fishing effort in patch 11 will dramatically increase. These differences between the area closure and the location of effort redistribution have important economic and ecological consequences. With large amounts of effort being transferred to a location which currently supports far less fishing, it is unclear what level of catch can be supported. If displaced fishermen are unable to meet their quotas in patch 11, CPUE will drop prompting fishermen to invest in more advanced gear and technology. This effect will be amplified since the economic risk of fishing in patch 11 is greater and fishermen will seek out improved technology to increase the reliability of their catch. While overall catch is hypothetically limited by quotas, overcapitalization in the fishery will likely result in greater levels of bycatch.79 This transfer of fishing effort south of the area closure will also have implications for the species in the fishery. The fact that hardly any ABFT and BET are caught in patch 11 suggests 26 the redistribution of fishing effort may not negate the mild benefits accrued to these species in the area closure. Moreover, the minimal impacts to ABFT and BET populations may be preserved even after the redistribution of fishing effort. Contrastingly, fishing pressure on SWO will likely increase since they make up 70% of catch in patch 11, compared to 54% in the area closure. While this does not pose a current concern since SWO catches are below quota limits, it is an indirect effect of the area closure that should be monitored. 80 It does not appear YFT populations will be significantly impacted by the area closure. Roughly the same percentage (29% vs. 30%) of YFT is caught in both regions and it is likely the relocation of fishing effort further south will nullify any minimal benefits to the stock. III. Comparison to Amendment 7 Rough calculations in Amendment 7 state the economic loss to the fishery will be roughly $211,000.81 This number is largely based on expected exits in the fishery. Contrary to the assumption that fishermen with a majority of sets in the area closure will reduce their fishing effort or completely exit the fishery, Figure 5 suggests patch 11 presents a potentially profitable alternative. Furthermore, given the large sunk cost of a boat, the occupational pride felt by many fishermen, and the lucrative tuna business, it is unlikely many fishermen, if any at all, will leave the fishery. Therefore, economic loss from the consolidation of the fishery is unlikely; however, fishermen’s profits could decrease if patch 11 is unable to sustain the increase in fishing effort. Additionally, overcapitalization of the fishery could increase the costs associated with fishing. The NOAA Amendment also estimates the ecological impact to the four species will be 1344 fewer SWO, 310 fewer BET, 862 fewer YFT, and 401 fewer ABFT caught each year.82 These values all represent impacts to less than 1% of the respective total landings and roughly 2% of ABFT pelagic longline landings. Importantly, NOAA’s estimates are based on effort consolidation since they assume some fishermen will exit fishery.83 As previously stated, this is a flawed assumption so the validity of the specific values must be questioned. IV. Discussion of No-Take Zones The establishment of area closures, no take zones, and marine reserves is a popular management scheme to conserve and preserve fish stocks. It is believed that these protected zones increase fish biodiversity and abundance by eliminating fishing pressure, diminishing 27 bycatch, and removing habitat disturbances.84 Furthermore, these positive impacts are thought to spill-over to adjacent areas as fish move out of the area closure.85 Some studies have found success with this management option. Research at the Mona Island Marine Protected Area (MPA) in the Caribbean found the implementation of a no-take zone resulted in a greater abundance of early life-stage fish within and outside of the MPA.86 Another study at De Hoop Reserve in South Africa found that within 2.5 years of establishing a no-take zone, the CPUE of six species increased.87 While the above research points to tangible benefits of no-take zones, some economists are beginning to question their effectiveness. A review on the methodological approach to evaluating marine reserves found that, while many papers report higher abundances of fish as the result of an area closure, there is no counterfactual to judge the effectiveness of the management plan; there is no comparison to determine what would have happened to the species if a marine reserve had not been implemented.88 Another issue with the evaluation of marine reserves is the simplification of fishermen’s responses to these closures.89 Specifically, many studies assume displaced fishing effort will evenly distribute over the available area.90 However, this assumption can cloud estimates of harvest and egg production, resulting in overly optimist predictions of marine reserves.91 Recent studies are revealing the ecological benefits of no-take zones may be minimal. A study of a marine reserve in the Great Barrier Reef found that 9 years after establishing a marine reserve, there was no increase in total catch levels or catch-rates outside the area closure.92 This refutes the theory that spillovers of adult and juvenile fish will create economic benefits in the fishery.93 Another investigation into the seasonal closure of the Californian sea urchin fishery found that, when changes in the amount and location of effort were accounted for in harvest and recruitment models, the biological effects of the marine reserve were significantly minimized.94 These results support the finding that an area closure off of Cape Hatteras will only produce moderate benefits to ABFT and will not serve to rebuild currently depleted stocks. V. Limitations of Project One of the major limitations of this project was that the dataset did not include ports of departure and arrival, preventing fishing sets from being identified to a specific boat. These missing pieces of data impact travel cost calculations since a boat may not return to the same 28 port from which it departed. Additionally, since it was not possible to identify which hooks were set by the same boat on a single fishing trip, travel between sets was not accounted for in distance calculations. Instead, travel costs to each set were assumed to be from a port. This is not realistic because fishermen will place multiple sets in a region, thereby reducing fuel costs for those subsequent hooks. While travel costs were not found to be significant in the regression analysis, it is unclear if this outcome might change were the data able to support this high level of complexity. Another important limitation is the fact that ecological impact of the area closure on ABFT was based on ICCAT stock assessments. As mentioned in the beginning of this paper, ICCAT currently manages the species by dividing the Atlantic stock into two populations along the 45oW meridian. This simplified management scheme does not account for the intermingling of the eastern and western stocks and limits the validity of population assessments and recovery projections. Thus, the predicted ecological impact of the area closure is based on potentially faulty stock assessments which may obfuscate the true biological effect. RECOMMENDATIONS Analysis shows the ecological benefits of the area closure are limited in the multispecies fishery. While the closure will help the pelagic longline fishery come closer to quota compliance, the management measure is not enough to cover the current number dead discards in the fishery. Furthermore, analysis suggests this area closure will not significantly improve the stock of ABFT or support its recovery. This has important ramifications for NOAA Fisheries since they will continue to fall short of the requirements outlined in the MSA and ATCA. The outputs of project highlight the need to incorporate CPUE into the siting of area closures. The location of the closure in Amendment 7 was chosen because it has a high number of ABFT interactions; however, analysis shows this area does not have a high CPUE. In fact, the calculation of CPUE reveals the highest number of fish caught per hooks in the water moves up and down the coast. This highlights the inequitable nature of the area closure and its ineffectiveness for three out of the five months it is to be implemented. Therefore, future decisions concerning the location of area closures should be made after calculating CPUE. 29 Additionally, this project highlights the importance of realistically predicting the redistribution of displaced fishing effort. The economic and ecological analysis undertaken by NOAA Fisheries was predicated on the assumption that fishermen would exit the fishery and effort would evenly distribute over the remaining areas. However, these assumptions do not accurately reflect the incentives for fishermen to stay in their profession and find the next most profitable location. By incorporating the heterogeneous redistribution of fishing effort into this analysis, the ecological benefits of the area closure are more accurately calculated. Furthermore indirect effects, such as that on SWO, may be identified. This highlights the need to incorporate realistic economic modeling into the analysis of future area closures. A primary challenge in the management of the ABFT is the ecological complexity of the species. Not only is the stock comprised of two distinct populations but ABFT undertake vast migrations throughout the entire North Atlantic. Since stationary area closures do not reflect this complexity, they may be ineffective tools for the management of highly migratory species. One recommendation is that future management schemes reflect the seasonal movement of this species. Figure 4 shows areas of high CPUE migrate up and down the US coast. Therefore, an effective area closure would be one which mirrors this pattern. Figure 8 illustrates the basic concept of a dynamic area closure. In this strategy, the location of the area closure changes seasonally to follow regions of high CPUE. This dynamic management would not only ensure the closure focuses on dense population aggregations but it would equally distribute the burden of conservation among West Atlantic fishermen. 30 Figure 8: A conceptual look at dynamic management in which the location of an area closure moves seasonally to mirror areas of high CPUE. Dynamic management has already been implemented in several regions. NOAA Fisheries implements Dynamic Management Areas (DMAs) in the Northeast to protect right whales from vessel strikes.95 Specifically, right whale observations are monitored and when a certain threshold is met, vessel restrictions go into effect.96 These management measures include reduced vessel speeds and re-routing around the DMA.97 The DMA is an effective management tool to deal with the rather unpredictable occurrence of right whales. Instead of implementing year-round closures which could negatively impact the shipping industry, the DMA allows for management measures to be narrowly tied to the timing and location of right whales.98 This example shows management measures can be created which are directly linked to the need for protection.99 31 Like many resource management initiatives, there are difficulties associated with dynamic fisheries management. First and foremost is the complexity associated with implementing a moving area closure. Unlike a stationary marine reserve, a dynamic management area requires a higher level of fishermen education and enforcement.100 The sheer area which must be covered when implementing this management tool is also greater, especially considering ABFT are found along the entire US East Coast. This broad range and complex management scheme translates into higher costs for compliance.101 Despite these challenges, the potential biological benefits of dynamic fisheries management may be immense, especially for highly migratory species such as ABFT. Further research is needed to fully understand the magnitude of impact this adaptive management scheme can have and to determine what guidelines should be established to ensure its successful implementation. Nonetheless, this project suggests traditional management efforts will not be enough to rebuild ABFT stocks and dynamic fisheries management may be needed to secure healthy tuna stocks. 32 ACKOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank my advisors Dr. Andre Boustany and Dr. Pat Halpin for their guidance throughout this project. A special thanks to Andre Boustany for the supplying the data for this research. Finally, I would like to thank Dr. Martin Smith for his expertise in modeling the redistribution of displaced fishing effort. 33 REFERENCES 1 Hardin, G. (1968). The Tragedy of the Commons. Science, 162(3859),1243-1248. Fromentin, J. M. and Powers, J. E. (2005). Atlantic bluefin tuna: population dynamics, ecology, and fisheries management. Fish and Fisheries, 6, 281-306. 3 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 4 Block, B., Teo, S., Walli, A., Boustany, A., Stokebury, M., Farwell, C., Weng, K., Dewar, H., and Williams, T. (2005). Electronic tagging and population structure of Atlantic bluefin tuna. Nature, 434, 1121-1127. 5 Galuardi, B., Royer, F., Golet, W., Logan, J., Neilson, J., and Lutcavage, M. (2010). Complex migration routes of Atlantic bluefin tuna (Thunnus thynnus) question current population structure paradigm. Canadian Journal of Fish Aquatic Science, 67(6), 966-976. 6 ICCAT. (2014). Report of the 2014 Atlantic Bluefin Tuna Stock Assessment Session. Madrid, Spain: September 22 to 27, 2014. 7 ICCAT, 2014. 8 Galuardi et al., 2010. 9 Block et al., 2005. 10 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 11 Ibid. 12 NOAA Fisheries. (August 2014). Final Amendment 7 to the 2006 Consolidated Atlantic Highly Migratory Species Fishery Management Plan. Accessed from http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/sfa/hms/documents/fmp/am7/final_amendment_7_to_the_2006_consolidated_atlantic_hi ghly_migratory_species_fishery_management_plan_8_28_2014_for_web.pdf 13 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 14 Ibid. 15 Ibid. 16 Ibid. 17 Ibid. 18 Bard, Dave. (October 2013). The Story of Atlantic Bluefin Tuna. Pew Environment. Retrieved from http://www.pewenvironment.org/news-room/fact-sheets/the-story-of-atlantic-bluefin-tuna-85899420680 19 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 20 Center for Biological Diversity. (24 May 2010). Petition to List the Atlantic Bluefin Tuna (Thunnus thynnus) as Engandered Under the United States Endangered Species Act. Accessed from http://www.fisheries.noaa.gov/pr/pdfs/species/cbd_bluefintunapetition_5242010.pdf 21 Taylor, N., McAllister, M., Lawson, G., Carruthers, T., and Block, B. (2011). Atlantic Bluefin Tuna: A Novel Multistock Spatial Model for Assessing Population Biomass. PLOSone, doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0027693 22 Bard, 2013. 23 ICCAT. Introduction. Accessed from https://www.iccat.int/en/introduction.htm 24 ICCAT. Introduction. 25 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 26 Ibid. 27 Ibid. 28 Block et al., 2005. 29 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 30 Ibid. 31 Straker, L. (2009). ICCAT: Managing or Documenting? Marine Technology Society Journal, 43(1), 117-126. 32 Straker, 1009. 33 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 34 ICCAT, 2014. 35 The Pew Charitable Trusts. (20 November 2014). “ICCAT Ignores Science and Increases Quota for Atlantic Bluefin Tuna.” The Pew Charitable Trusts News Room. Accessed from http://www.pewtrusts.org/en/about/newsroom/news/2014/11/20/iccat-ignores-science-and-increases-quota-for-atlantic-bluefin-tuna 36 ICCAT, 2014. 37 NOAA Fisheries, 2014. 38 Ibid. 2 34 39 Ibid. Ibid. 41 Ibid. 42 Fromentin and Powers, 2005. 43 NOAA Fisheries, 2014. 44 Ibid. 45 Ibid. 46 Ibid. 47 Ibid. 48 Ibid. 49 NOAA. (Amended 12 January, 2007). Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act. P.L. 94265. 50 Atlantic Tunas Convention Act. (1975). P.L. 94-70. 51 NOAA Fisheries, 2014. 52 Ibid. 53 Ibid. 54 NOAA Fisheries, 2014; 79 FR 71509. 55 NOAA Fisheries, 2014. 56 Ibid. 57 Ibid. 58 Ibid. 59 Ibid. 60 Ibid. 61 Ibid. 62 Ibid. 63 Ibid. 64 Ibid. 65 Ibid. 66 Ibid. 67 Ibid. 68 Daw, T., Cinner, J., McClanahan, T., Brown, K., Stead, S., Graham, N., and Maina, J. (2012). To Fish or Not to Fish: Factors at Multiple Scales Affecting Artisanal Fishers’ Readiness to Exit a Declining Fishery. PLOSone, doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0031460. 69 Smith, M. and Wilen, J. (2003). Economic impacts of marine reserves: the importance of spatial behavior. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46, 183-206. 70 Gulland, J. (1969). Section 4: Effort and Catch Per Unit Effort. In Manual of Methods for Fish Stock Assessment. Fishery Resources and Exploitation Division, FAO. 71 Musick, J and Bonfil, R. (2005) Management techniques for elasmobranch fisheries. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper, 474. 72 McCay, B. and Cieri, M. (April 2000). Fishing Ports of the Mid-Atlantic. Report to the Mid-Atlantic Fishery Management Council. Accessed from http://www.st.nmfs.noaa.gov/st1/econ/cia/McCay_Port_StudyApr2000_Revised.pdf 73 Strand, I. (2004). Spatial Variation in Risk Preferences Among Atlantic and Gulf of Mexico Pelagic Longline Fishermen. Marine Resources Economics, 19, 145-160. 74 NOAA. Office of Science and Technology. Commercial Fisheries Statistics: Commercial Landings. Accessed from http://www.st.nmfs.noaa.gov/commercial-fisheries/ 75 ICCAT, 2014; ICCAT. (2010). Report of the 2010 ICCAT Bigeye Tuna Stock Assessment Session. Pasaia, Gipuzkoa, Spain: July 5 to 9, 2010; ICCAT. (2011). Report of the 2011 ICCAT Yellowfin Tuna Stock Assessment Session. San Sebastian, Spain: September 5 to 12, 2011; ICCAT. (2013). Report of the 2013 Atlantic Swordfish Stock Assessment Session. Olhao, Portugal: September 2 to 10, 2013. 76 50 CFR 635.23. Retention Limits for BFT. 77 Smith and Wilen, 2003. 78 ICCAT 2014; ICCAT 2010; ICCAT 2011; ICCAT 2013. 79 Alverson, D., Freeberg, M., Murawski, S., and Pope, J. (1994). Part IV: Policy, Solutions, and Conclusions. In A global assessment of fisheries bycatch and discards. FAO Fisheries Technical Paper. No. 339. Rome, FAO. 40 35 80 ICCAT 2013. NOAA Fisheries, 2014. 82 Ibid. 83 Ibid. 84 Dugan, J., and Davis, G. (1993). Applications of Marine Refugia to Coastal Fisheries Management. Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, 50, 2029-2042. 85 Mateos-Molina, D., Scharer-Umpierre, M., Appeldoorn, R., and Garcia-Charton, J. (2014). Measuring the effectiveness of a Caribbean oceanic island no-take zone with an asymmetrical BACI approach. Fisheries Research, 150, 1-10. 86 Mateos-Molina et al., 2014. 87 Bennett, B. and Attwood, C. (1991). Evidence for recovery of a surf-zone fish assemblage following the establishment of a marine resource on the southern coast of South Africa. Marine Ecology Progress Series, 52, 173181. 88 Smith, M., Zhang, J., and Coleman, F. (2006). Effectiveness of marine reserves for large-scale fisheries management. Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Science, 63, 153-164. 89 Smith, M., and Wilen, J. (2003). Economic impacts of marine reserves: the importance of spatial behavior. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46, 183-206. 90 Smith and Wilen, 2003. 91 Ibid. 92 Fletcher, W., Kearney, R., Wise, B., and Nash, W. In press. Large-scale expansion of no-take closures within the Great Barrier Reef has not enhanced fishery production. Ecological Applications, http://dx.doi.org/10.1890/141427.1 93 Fletcher et al., in press. 94 Smith and Wilen, 2003. 95 NOAA Fisheries. (2004). Dynamic Management Areas. [White paper]. Retrieved from http://www.greateratlantic.fisheries.noaa.gov/shipstrike/news/DMAs_July_2004.pdf 96 NOAA Fisheries, 2004. 97 Ibid. 98 Ibid. 99 Ibid. 100 Freestone, D., Varmer, O., Bennett, M., Wilhelm, A., Beuttler, T., Ardon, J., Maxwell, S., and Morrison, K. (2014). Place-based Dynamic Management of Large-Scale Ocean Places: Papahanaumokuakea and the Sargasso Sea. Stanford Environmental Law Journal, 33(2), 191-248. 101 Freestone et al., 2014. 81 36 APPENDIX Figure 1A: The predicted profit for fishermen from Hatteras for each month of the closure. The yellow box represents the location of the area closure while the green box is the patch with the highest profit . 37 Figure 2A: The predicted profit for fishermen from Ocracoke for each month of the closure. The yellow box represents the location of the area closure while the green box is the patch with the highest profit. 38 Figure 3A: The predicted profit for fishermen from Morehead City for each month of the closure. The yellow box represents the location of the area closure while the green box is the patch with the highest profit. 39