COOPERATION VERSUS NON-COOPERATION IN CLEANING OF AN INTERNATIONAL WATER BODY WITH STOCHASTIC ENVIRONMENTAL DAMAGE : THE CASE OF THE BALTIC SEA Ing-Marie Gren2,3 and Henk Folmer1 This paper develops a simple model that accounts for uncertainty in degradation of water quality from emission from countries surrounding an international waterbody. Theoretical analysis of the cooperative and noncooperative solutions shows that the inclusion of risk and risk aversion can either increase or decrease the differences between the two solution concepts. An application to the Baltic Sea shows that the higher risk aversion, the larger abatement and the smaller the net benefits of abatement. This result was found to hold for both the cooperative and the noncooperative solution, though less for the latter than for the former. Key words: international water pollution, stochastic damage, cooperation, noncooperation, Baltic Sea JEL classification: D61, Q25 1. Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm, e-mail: ing@beijer.kva.se 2. Department of Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Uppsala, email: Ing-Marie.Gren@ekon.slu.se 3. Prof. Henk Folmer, Department of Economics, Wageningen University, e-mail: Henk.Folmer@alg.SNNK.WAU.NL 1 1. Introduction Like for many sea and lake common properties, the use of Baltic Sea as a nitrogen sink has been one of the most important reasons for the current ecological damages from eutrophication. Damages occur if either of the growth limiting nutrients, nitrogen or phosphorus, increase. This implies higher production of algae, which, when decomposed, demand oxygen. The resulting decrease in oxygen may then generate sea bottom areas with reduced biological life. Furthermore, there is a change in the composition of fish species. In the case of the Baltic Sea, decreases in the production of commercial fish species have occurred frequently and there are large sea bottom areas without life (Wulff and Niemi, 1992). It is regarded that excessive loads of nitrogen is the main source of damages from eutrophication of the Baltic Sea Another feature of the Baltic Sea is that it is bordered by nine countries - Finland, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Russia, Poland, Germany, Denmark, and Sweden. Each of these countries contributes to the eutrophication of the Baltic. This implies that effective and efficient nitrogen reduction requires joint action. Unilateral abatement efforts or actions by a few of these countries are likely to be insufficient to reduce eutrophication because the emissions produced by the individual countries are small proportions of total emissions. Moreover, efficiency requires that the marginal abatement costs are the same across the polluting countries, which implies that policy coordination is required for the states bordering the Baltic Sea. (For further details see amongst others Folmer and de Zeeuw (2000).) The early concern for the ecological conditions of the Baltic Sea has resulted in a lot of natural science research. The 20 years period of this kind of research has generated much data on biological conditions of parts of the Sea and nutrient transports between different water basins [see e.g. Edler (1979), Granéli et al. (1990), Larsson et al. (1985), Wulff et al. (1990), and Wulff and Niemi (1992)]. Furthermore, cost benefit analyses of improvement of the Sea corresponding to its ‘healthy’ conditions prevailing prior to the 1960s, have been carried out [Markowska and Zylics (1996), Söderqvist (1996) and (1998), and Gren (2001)]. However, in spite of these studies, difficulties remain with respect to the development of an effective and efficient abatement scheme and its implementation. These difficulties relate to amongst others uncertainty inherent to nitrogen pollution and international cooperation. 2 In much of the economic literature on water management, pollution abatement has been analysed within a deterministic framework [see for instance Johnsson et al. (1991), Helfand and House (1995), Wu and Segerson (1995), and Gren (2001)]. However, environmental damages from water pollution (like virtually any other damages from pollution) are characterised by conditions of uncertainty. For nitrogen, uncertainty in the water recipient and its catchment region is related to: -the diffusion of pollutants in the drainage basins to the coastal water; -coastal and marine transports of the deposited nitrogen and -ecological damages from the remaining nitrogen. Adequate abatement of environmental damages caused by stochastic pollution thus requires consideration of the probability distribution of pollution loads to the recipient. (See amongst others, Malik et al., 1993; McSweeny and Shortle, 1990; Shortle, 1990; Mapp et al., 1994; Byström et al., 2000.) These studies show that pollution abatement allocation and costs are affected by the introduction of reliability constraints in addition to a standard deterministic pollution constraint. There is a large literature, mainly theoretical, with the focus on efficient provision of an international environmental public good [see e.g., Barrett (1990), Mäler (1991) and (1993), Hoel (1992), and Kaitala et al.(1995), Folmer and van Mouche (2000), Gren (2001), and Folmer and van Mouche (2002).]. However, only a few of these studies contain empirical analyses of concrete international environmental concerns [e.g Mäler (1991) and (1993), Kaitala et al. (1995), and Gren (2001)]. Except for Gren (2001), common to these case studies is their application to environmental damages from sulphur emissions under deterministic conditions. To our best knowledge, however, there exist no case studies relating to stochastic pollutants and international water bodies.1 Another important feature of this paper is that it makes use of benefit data, based on estimated willingness to pay for an improved Baltic Sea. This is in contrast to most other international studies, which overcome the problem of lacking information on the benefits of pollution reduction by assuming revealed preferences. The assumption adopted is then that 1 We observe that this study is inspired by Gren (2001), the main differences being the consideration of a stochastic rather than a deterministic pollutant, and the simplification made by disregarding transboundary air pollution of nitrogen oxides and ammonium. 3 marginal environmental damage equals marginal abatement cost at the actual level of abatement (see amongst others Kaitala et al (1995) for an example) . The paper is organised as follows. First, in section 2 we present the theoretical model underlying the case study. We discuss the non-cooperative or Nash solution as well as the cooperative solution to transboundary pollution in a stochastic framework. Next the case study relating to the Baltic Sea is presented in sections 3 and 4. Section 3 presents the data ant the assumptions whereas in section 4 the main results are discussed. The paper ends with a brief summary and discussion of the results. 2. Uncertainty, the Nash equilibrium and the full cooperative solution Consider N countries denoted by subscripts j=1, 2, …., N. Let E be the set of country j's emissions with elements ej. Country j's gross benefit function reads as Bj=Bj(ej) , j= 1,2,…, N (1) We assume that Bj is continuous, twice continuously differentiable, that B'j>0 and B"j<0. Let Q be the set of country j's depositions with elements qj. Deposition at receptor j is given by N q j T jiei q j , (2) i 1 Where q j , are background depositions, Tji are the transportation coefficients, i.e. the proportion of pollution generated in country i and deposited in country j. Damages from emissions in country j, Dj, depend on depositions and ecological functioning at the receptor. In order to take uncertainty into account, depositions at each receptor j are regarded stochastic. We assume that Dj is continuous, twice continuously differentiable with respect to emissions and that Dj'>0 and Dj">0. Taking (1) and (3) together net benefits in country j, πj, are given by j B j (e j ) D j ( q j ) (3) 4 We assume that for each region the following expected utility function is maximised E (U j ( j )) E U ( B j (e j ) D j (q j )) (4) where U'>0, and U"≤0. In order to relate expected profits to risk, as measured by the variance in profits, we specify a quadratic utility function as follows U j j b j 2j (5) Equation (5) implies that the larger bj, the higher risk aversion. Moreover, for bj =0 we have risk neutrality. The restriction (1-2bjπj)>0 is imposed due to the assumption of U’>0. Expected utility for (5) is EU j E j bE( 2j ) (6) where E(π2j)=(E(πj))2+Var(πj), which gives E(Uj ) as EU j E j b ( E( j )) 2 Var( j ) (7) Since Bj(ej) is assumed deterministic, Var(πj)=σj2 is N N i 1 i 1 2j Var ( j ) Var ( D j ) Var (q j ) Var (Tij ei ) (Var (Tijei ) 2Cov(Tijei , T jie j )) (8) Depending on the signs of the covariances, country j’s risk may be larger or lower than the sum of the variances in the countries’ depositions of pollutants at recipient j. For negative covariances, country j’s risk is reduced, and can, in the extreme case, approach zero. If the N countries behave non-cooperatively, country j maximizes (7) with respect to its own emissions, taking emissions from other countries and background depositions as given. 5 Formally, the Nash-equilibrium emission vector Q jN is found by differentiating (7) with respect to ej, which gives U j e j (1 2b j E j ) E ( B T jj D ) b j ' j ' j 2j e j 0 (9) It follows from (9) that when the variance is increasing (decreasing) in ej, emission is lower (higher) under risk aversion than under risk neutrality.2 In contrast to (9), in the case of the full co-operative approach country j does not only take its own marginal benefits and marginal damage into account but the marginal damage of its emissions in other countries as well. The co-operative solution implies that ΣjEUj ≡EU is maximized, which gives 2j N EU 2 (1 2b j E j ) E ( B 'j T jj D 'j ) b j (1 2bi E i )T ji EDi' bi i 0 e j e j i j e j (10) If the last term within brackets of (10) is positive, as in the case of multiplicative uncertainty, then emissions for each country are lower than under the Nash solution (9).3 The role of variance in (10) is similar to that in (9). Another difference between the Nash and the cooperative solution is that the latter offers an additional instrument for the allocation of risk. 4 This can be seen from (10), which can be written as N N i i (1 2b j E j )( B'j T ji EDi' ) bi i2 e j (11) For a multiplicative specification of uncertainty such as Var(Tjjej)=(Tjjejj)2Var(εj), the variance is increasing in emissions: ∂Var(Tjjejεj)/∂ej=2(Tjjej)Var(εj )>0 where represents a stochastic error term. Hence, emissions are lower under risk aversion than under risk neutrality in the case of a multiplicative specification. 3 For details about the relationship between the Nash equilibrium and the full cooperative solution see Folmer and van Mouche (2000) and Folmer and van Mouche (2002). 4 We observe that if only one abatement measure is available for each country, then there is no portfolio choice for the Nash solution. The cooperative solution on the other hand does allow for a choice of different abatement levels in different countries and thus does offer a portfolio choice. For an application of efficient portfolio choice of risky biodiversity assets, see Xepapadeas (2001). 2 6 The left-hand side reflects the utility from a marginal change in expected net return, which consists of the marginal gross return from emissions in country j minus the costs of marginal environmental damages in all countries from the marginal change in country j’s emissions. The right hand side shows the impact on utility in all countries from an increase in risk associated with a marginal change in j’s emission. The efficient allocation of risky emissions between any two countries, j and k, thus occurs where N N (1 2b j E j )( B T ji ED ) ' j ' i i N (1 2bk E k )( B Tki ED ) ' k ' i i bi i i2 e j i2 b i i e k N (12) That is, the efficient allocation of risk between countries is determined by the equality of the ratio of utility from expected net returns and the ratio of marginal utility of risk (see e.g. Elton and Gruber, 1991). If the utility function is the same for all countries, (12) reveals that the emission level of a country with relatively high marginal impact on risk, should be relatively low. 3. Benefits, costs, and risk estimates of nitrogen load changes In this section we describe the data requirements to apply the theoretical framework outlined in the previous section to determine the full cooperative and the non-cooperative solution to the reduction of nitrogen emissions in the Baltic Sea taking into account the stochastic nature of depositions at each receptor. The empirical analysis requires data on the costs and benefits of emission reductions per country or region bordering the Baltic Sea. By emission reduction we mean decreases in nitrogen loads in the coastal waters. This means that estimation of the costs of nitrogen load reductions requires information on nitrogen transports in the drainage basins because during transport part of the emissions is transformed into harmless nitrogen gas. Finally, information is needed on nitrogen transports in the Baltic because emissions entering the sea at one location are dispersed over several regions. The above mentioned data requirements have implications for the regional division of the drainage basins. Particularly, data is needed on both economic parameters as well as on nitrogen transport. Since data on costs and benefits of abatement are available on another spatial scale than hydrological and biogeochemial information, the regional division of the 7 Baltic Sea drainage basin used here is based on the least common denominator for both types of data sets (see Elofsson 2000 for further details). This has resulted in 19 different drainage basins with different nitrogen transport parameters.5 The benefits from nitrogen emission reduction are derived from Gren (2001), which transfers benefit estimates of an improvement of the Baltic Sea in Poland and Sweden to the other Baltic S ea countries [Söderqvist (1996), (1998), and Markowska and Zylics (1996)]. In order to obtain benefit estimates for the entire drainage basin, the Swedish results were transferred to Finland, Germany, and Denmark and the Polish results to Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania and Russia. The transfer mechanism applied was GDP per capita.6 The valuation scenario used was a change from the current status of the Baltic Sea to ecological conditions corresponding to those prevailing in the 1960s before the large increase in the nutrient loads took place (Wulf and Niemi, 1992). From the benefit transfer analysis it follows that in total the 80 million inhabitants of the Baltic Sea drainage basin would be willing to pay 31,000 millions SEK for this change in ecological conditions of the Baltic Sea (1 Euro=9.31 SEK, July 9, 2001).7 The calculation of efficient nitrogen abatement under the cooperative and Nash solutions requires amongst others information on the relationship between damage and nitrogen load. We start by observing that we assume a linear damage function which implies constant marginal damage. In terms of abatement this implies constant marginal benefits of abatement. According to Wulff and Niemi (1992), the above mentioned ecological change in the valuation scenario would require a total nitrogen reduction of at least 50 per cent, which corresponds to 550 000 tons of N (Gren et al 1997). A constant marginal benefit estimate is then obtained by dividing the estimated total willingness to pay of SEK 31,000 millions by the 550 000 tons of N. The calculated uniform marginal benefit of reduction is then equal to 62/kg N. Thus, a nitrogen emission decrease by 1 kg to the Baltic Sea implies a value increase of SEK 62 for all countries. 5 For a map see Figure A1 in the appendix That is, the estimates for e.g. Estonia are the estimates available for Poland, after correction for the difference in GDP per capita between both countries. For details see Söderqvist (2000) and Markowska and Zylics (2000). 7 It is interesting to note that after adjustment for differences in GDP per capita WTP in Sweden and Poland were approximately the same. 6 8 In the context of nitrogen reduction measures we distinguish between direct abatement measures and land use measures. The former include: increased nutrient cleaning capacity at sewage treatment plants, catalysts in cars and ships, scrubbers in stationary combustion sources, and reductions in the use of fertilisers and manure in agriculture. Land use measures include: change in spreading time of manure from autumn to spring, cultivation of so called catch crops such as energy forests and ley grass, and creation of wetlands.8 Calculations of nitrogen abatement costs are based on econometric estimates for sewage treatment plants, fertiliser reductions, reduction in nitrogen oxides from reduced use of gas and oil, and wetland creation (for details, see Gren et al, 1997, and references therein). Abatement costs of all other measures are obtained from engineering data. Marginal reduction costs have been obtained from Gren et al. (1997a) and are presented in Table 1. The marginal costs refer to the cost of a unit nitrogen reduction to the coastal waters. The marginal costs vary according to type of abatement measures used and abatement level, as well as the location of abatement measures. Measures implemented remote from the coastal zones have smaller impacts, and hence, higher costs for achieving a unit reduction at the coastal waters. Hence, the variation in marginal abatement costs in Table 1. The impact of location on marginal abatement costs is explained by the nature of nitrogen transport in the Baltic Sea catchments. In order to relate nitrogen emissions from sources in the catchment areas to loads in the coastal waters, data is needed on nitrogen transformation during transport from the source to the coastal waters. These transports are determined by hydrological, climatic, and biogeochemical conditions, and vary for the 19 regions of the Baltic Sea catchment. A simplification is made, however, by assuming a linear relationship between emission generation at the source and deposition in the own coastal waters. That is, for each source a constant fraction, less than unity, of upstream emissions was assumed to reach the coastal water. The smaller load to the coast than emissions at the source is mainly due to the transformation of nitrogen into harmless nitrogen gas during transport. The magnitude of the fractions of emission reaching the coastal loads is determined by climatic and biogeochemical parameters and differ for different regions of the Baltic Sea. For a further description of the derivation of the transport parameters, see Elofsson in this issue. 8 Change of spreading time from autumn to spring implies less leaching due to the fact that, in spring, the crops are growing making use of the nutrients. Catch crops refer to certain grass crops which are sown at the same time as ordinary spring crops but start to grow, thereby making use of remaining nutrients in the soil, when the ordinary crop is harvested. 9 Based on these assumptions, calculated emissions to the coastal waters are as presented in Table 1. It follows that in total almost 900 thousand kton of N is deposited at the Baltic Sea coasts from the nine countries bordering the Baltic Sea9. Poland is the largest emitter, accounting for about 27 per cent of total emissions. Latvia and Sweden account for approximately 14 per cent each. In addition to information on transport in the drainage basin information is needed on the dispersion of pollution among countries , i.e. the matrix of transport coefficients T. The dispersion matrix is determined by several factors such as vertical circulation, temperature, and salinity in different parts of the Sea, and total inflow to the Sea of oxygen supply (see Wulff et al 2001 for further details). The depositions on the own coast of a country’s nitrogen emission depends on these factors and also on the vegetation in coastal regions. The more vegetation, the higher is the damage from oxygen depletion on the own coast.10 Data on transport coefficients are obtained from large scale modelling exercises for the Baltic Sea (Wulff and Niemi (1992) and Gren (2001) for further details). However, these modelling results give no information on transport among countries but among Baltic Sea basins. Therefore, we assume that transports coefficients are the same for regions sharing the same Baltic Sea basin. (See the transport matrix in Appendix 1.) Table 1 shows the impact on the own coast from the region’s emission, and also total deposition including transports from other regions. In order to take risk into account we assume a quadratic utility function. Numerical operationalization of risk, (i.e. the variance), is obtained by means of coefficients of variations of nutrient concentration ratios measured at river mouths along the Baltic Sea coasts (Stålnacke, 2000). In order to simplify the numerical optimisation, co-variances among concentration ratios at different locations are disregarded. The reason is that the variance-covariance matrix is not positive semi-definite. Depending on the magnitude of the co-variances the marginal impact of a risk reducing abatement measure as expressed by eqs. (10) and (12) is either increased or decreased. As shown by Elofsson in this issue, inclusion of covariation increases overall risk. The coefficients of variation are displayed in Table 1. 9 The total load is higher due to emissions of nitrogen oxides from countries outside the Baltic Sea drainage basin. 10 It should be observed that the less vegetation, the larger offshore transport of nitrogen. On the other hand, vegetation in coastal regions takes up part of the nitrogen deposited. Hence, the more vegetation, the higher is the damage from oxygen depletetion on the own coast assumed to be. 10 Table 1: Nitrogen loads, own national impacts per unit of nitrogen load, marginal costs, and coefficient of variation in measured nitrogen concentration. We observe that the coefficients of variation vary between 0.17 and 0.39, being highest for Kaliningrad.11 Finally, we turn to risk attitude. In the expected utility function, the value of the coefficient bj is bounded by the requirement of U’j>0, but can otherwise take any positive value depending on risk attitudes. Unfortunately, there is no information on risk attitudes for the different countries. Therefore, we adopt the following assumptions. First, the case of risk neutrality, bj=0, is used as a reference case. Next, we consider a relatively high and a relatively low value of b: bj=0.001 and bj=0.0001.12 4. Maximum net benefits The program code to calculate the cooperative and nocooperative solutionfollows the structure of the equations presented in Section 2, except for the profit function specified in (3). In order to facilitate the numerical calculations, we solve for the "dual" of (3) which specifies net benefits as benefits from emission abatement minus abatement costs. The optimisation solver used is GAMS (Brooke et al. 1998). Appropriate calculations of the Nash solution would require reaction functions for each country showing responses from other countries on its nitrogen reduction levels. However, this considerably complicates calculations. Therefore, Nash solutions are calculated by assuming other countries' emissions fixed at the uncontrolled level. This implies an underestimation of net benefits from a country’s emission reductions (since other countries’ emission reductions are excluded), and consequently an overestimation of the emission reduction (due to the decreasing utility in net benefits). Table 2: Maximum net benefits (mill SEK per year) and nitrogen reductions ( in %) under cooperative solutions for risk neutrality and risk aversion 11 We observe that relatively large risk may be an important incentive to reduce emission and counteract possible low reduction incentives due to small own marginal benefits. Due to the absence of positive covariances risk is underestimated. 12 We observe that these values for b are arbitrary. We are not aware of any reference values that have been used in empirical research in this aera. 11 The results presented in Table 2 show that there is no change in total nitrogen reductions when b increases from b=0 to b=0.0001. Moreover the reductions are constant for all countries except for Finland, Poland and Estonia. Total net benefits decrease from SEK 18612 million to 16296 million. All countries, except Poland, experience a decrease in net benefits with the highest relative decrease for Estonia (33 %). The reason for the increase in net benefits for Poland is cost savings from less nitrogen abatement. This, in turn, is a result from the larger change in marginal utility of net benefits than in marginal utility of risk at the relatively high Polish abatement level. The opposite is true for Estonia, which also faces relatively low abatement costs A further increase of b to b=0.001 leads to an increase in overall abatement from 45% to 50 %. All countries increase their abatement as compared to when b=0.0001. The increase in b causes substantial decreases in net benefits, which turn into net losses for Denmark and Estonia. Total net benefits drop from SEK18612 million to SK2071 million. Sweden and Estonia experience decreases in net benefits of similar orders of magnitude. These results show that the higher risk aversion, the larger abatement and the smaller net benefits.13 Table 3 displays abatement and maximum net benefits under the Nash solution. We observe that total abatement is constant for an increase of b from b=0 to b=.0001 and only slightly increases when b increases from b=0.0001 to b=0.001. Similar results hold for the individual countries. The most striking result is the increase for Germany from zero abatement for b=0 and b=0.0001 to 13% for b=0.001. Total net benefits as well as net benefits per country decrease slightly when b increases from b=0 to b=0.0001. When b increases further to b=0.001 total net benefits drop from Sk 1755 million to Sk 963 million. For the individual countries the decrease in net benefits is also relatively large. Moreover, for Denmark, Germany and Poland the net benefits turn negative. These results further illustrate, though less clearly, that the higher risk aversion, the larger abatement and the smaller net benefits. Since under the Nash countries only take their own impacts into account, the results are less outspoken. Table 3: Maximum net benefits (mill SEK per year) and nitrogen reductions ( in %) under Nash solutions for risk neutrality and risk aversion 13 The decrease of net benefits is the "price" of risk aversion. 12 Comparison of Table 2 and Table 3 shows the familiar result that under the full cooperative approach total abatement and total net benefits are substantially higher than under the Nash. Similar results hold for the individual countries. An interesting result is that all countries benefit from cooperation and that there are no countries that incur a net loss under cooperation, except Denmark and Estonia for b=0.001. The virtual absence of losses is due to the absence of strong asymmetries in the diffusion of nitrogen emissions in the Baltic and also the assumed uniform marginal benefits of nutrient reduction. An important consequence is that there is no need to compensate countries for their losses and to induce them to accept the co-operative solution when b=0 and b=0.0001. However, the increase in net benefits for Sweden, Germany, Finland, Poland and Russia under the full cooperative solution compared to the Nash is substantially larger than for Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania and Denmark. Therefore, in order to achieve a “fair sharing” of the net benefits from cooperation side payments may be needed. Several fair sharing schemes could be thought of, the most simple one being an equal split between the countries. Other possible schemes are the proportional rule and the Shapley value. Roughly speaking, these redistribution schemes take into account how valuable a country's abatement is to the net benefits of the other countries (e.g. Pham et al., 2001 and the references therein). 5. Summary and conclusions In this paper we have addressed the problem of efficient cleaning of an international water body with stochastic environmental damage. A standard net benefit function was embedded in a quadratic utility function framework which, in its turn, was used to derive the noncooperative outcome or Nash equilibrium emission vector as well as the full cooperative solution. For both outcomes we showed that if risk (measured as variance) is increasing (decreasing) in emissions, the level of emission is decreasing (increasing) under risk aversion relative to risk neutrality. The model was applied to nitrogen reduction in the Baltic See which is surrounded by 9 countries. The application was hampered by data limitations. The benefits from nitrogen reduction per country surrounding the Baltic Sea were obtained by means of benefit transfer which made it possible to circumvent the usual assumption that marginal environmental damage equals marginal abatement costs at the actual levels of pollution abatement. With 13 respect to the transport of pollution from its source to the coastal waters, transformation of nitrogen into harmless nitrogen gas was taken into account. The dispersion of pollution among countries was modelled by means of a dispersion matrix, taking into account several ecological system factors, such as vertical circulation, temperature, salinity and coastal structure. A variety of abatement measures consisting of direct measure and land use measures were used to derive the marginal abatement costs per country. The empirical results for the Baltic Sea confirm the theoretical results mentioned above. In addition to the well-known result that, ceteris paribus, abatement is higher under the cooperative than under the noncooperative approach, we found that the higher risk aversion, the larger abatement and the smaller net benefits. This was found to hold for both approaches, though less for the Nash because in this case countries only take their own impacts into account. Another important result is that for risk neutrality and low risk aversion the net benefits are positive for each country under the full cooperative outcome and the Nash solution (except Germany under low risk aversion). This implies first of all a major incentive for nitrogen abatement: no country will incur a loss from cleaning up its act. However, the net benefits under the full cooperative approach strongly outweigh the net benefits under the Nash which makes the former preferable to the latter. Although no country will incur a loss under the former, some countries will benefit more than others which may necessitate the implementation of a redistribution scheme of the increase of the net benefits due to cooperation. It is important to note that these estimates are sensitive to several assumptions. For example, sensitivity analysis in Gren et al. (1997) shows that total costs of nitrogen may double when a reduced capacity of low cost measures is assumed. Another crucial assumption concerns the linkage of nitrogen reductions to benefits as measured in monetary terms. Moreover, diversifying the (assumed) constant marginal benefits may further impact on the results including the differences between the cooperative and Nash solution (seeGren, 2001). Recall also the arbitrary measurement of marine nitrogen transports between countries. A change in these transport parameters might result in considerable changes in allocations of nitrogen reductions and net benefits. Another strong assumption relates to the shape of the utility function and, in particular, the influence of risk on utility. Except for restrictions imposed by positive marginal utility from damage reductions, we could not find any support 14 in the literature for the values of the parameter b. Since our results indicate significant implications of differences in risk attitudes, this is a fruitful area of further research. The results are, by all likelihood, not only affected by difficulties of measuring included parameters, but also by excluded factors. One such factor is the negligence of all other environmental benefits than those associated with eutrophication reductions in the Baltic Sea. For example, the construction of wetlands implies further environmental benefits by the provision of biodiversity and may also contribute to recreational values. The inclusions of such “extra” environmental benefits would increase nitrogen reductions for all regions where these benefits are positive. Another important issue is related to the concept of cost of nitrogen reductions applied in this study. It would be more appropriate to include not only the direct costs of the reduction activities, but also their general equilibrium impacts. As shown in Johannesson and Randås (1996), structural impacts of nitrogen reduction policies can be large but the net impact on GDP is small. Further, costs of enforcing nitrogen reduction are not included. Since there are large differences in institutions affecting environmental policies among the countries, enforcement costs are likely to differ much, being highest in the Baltic states and Poland (Eckerberg et al., 1996). The inclusion of enforcement costs would thus effect, not only total net benefits, but also the allocation of nitrogen reductions among countries. References Barrett, S. (1990). Global environmental problems. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 8(1):68-79. Brooke, A., Kendrick, D., & Meeraus, A. 1998. GAMS. A user's guide.San Francisco: The Scientific Press Byström, O., Andersson, H., and I-M. Gren, 2000.Economic criteria for restoration of wetlands under uncertainty. Ecological Economics 35:35-45 .Eckerberg, K., Gren, I-M, and T. Söderqvist, (1996). Policies for combatting water pollution of the Baltic Sea: Perspectives from economics and political science. Proceedings from a workshop September 27-28, Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, Stockholm. 15 Edler, L. (Ed.), (1979). Recommendations for marine biological studies i the Baltic Sea. Phytoplankton and chlorophyll. Baltic marine Biologists Publications 5:1-35. Elofsson, K. (2000). Cost effective reductions of stochastic nitrogen and phosphorous loads to the Baltic Sea. Working Paper Series No. 6, Department of Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Uppsala. Elton, E.J., and M. J. Gruber (1991). Modern portfolio theory and investment analysis. 4th edition, John Wiley & Sons, IncNew York Folmer, H. and A. de Zeeuw (2000). International environmental problems and policy. In: H. Folmer and H.L. Gabel (eds). Principles of Environmental and Resource Economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Folmer, H. and P. van Mouche (2000). Transboundary pollution and international cooperation. In: T. Tietenberg and H. Folmer (eds) The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2000/2001. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. Folmer H. and P. van Mouche (2002). The acid rain game: a formal and mathematically rigorous analysis. Working paper. Department of General Economics. Wageningen University. Granéli, E., Wallström, K., Larsson, U., Granéli, W. and R. Elmgren (1990). Nutrient Limitation of primary production in the Baltic sea area. Ambio 19:142-151. Gren, I-M, Jannke, P. and K. Elofsson, (1997). Cost-effective nutrient reductions to the Baltic Sea. Environmental and Resource Economics 10(4):341-362. Gren, I-M.,(2001). International versus national actions against nitrogen pollution of the Baltic Sea. Environmental and Resource Economics, 20(1):41-59. Helfand, G.E., and B. W. House. (1995). Regulating nonpoint source pollution under heterogenous conditions. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77:1024-1032. Hoel, M., (1992). International environment conventions: The case of uniform reductions of emissions. Environmental and Resource Economics 2:141-159. Johanesson, Å. and P. Randås, (1996). Economic impacts of reducing nitrogen emissions into the Baltic Sea. Paper presented at the EAERE VII conference, Lissabon, June, 1996. Johnson, S.L., R.M. Adams, and G.M. Perry. (1991). The on farm costs of reducing groundwater pollution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73:1063-1073 Kaitala, V., Mäler, K-G. and H. Tulkens, (1995). The acid rain game as a resource allocation process with an application to the international cooperation among Finland, Russia and Estonia. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97(2): 325-343. Larson, U., Hobro, R. and F. Wulff, (1985). Eutrophication and the Baltic Sea – Causes and consequences. Ambio 14:9-14. Malik, A.S., Letson, D., & Crutchfield, S.R. (1993). Point/Nonpoint Source Trading of Pollution Abatement: Choosing the 16 Right Trading Ratio. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75, 959-967. Mapp, H.P., Bernardo, D.J. Sabbagh, G.J. Geleta, S., and K.B. Watkins. (1994). Economic and environmental impacts of limiting nitrogen use to protect water quality: A stochastic regional analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76: 889903. Markowska, A.. and T. Zylicz, (1996).Costing an international public good: The case of The Baltic Sea. The European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. The Seventh Annual Conference, Lisbon, Portugal. McSweeny, W.T. & Shortle, J.S. (1990). Probabilistic Cost Effectiveness in Agricultural Nonpoint Pollution Control. Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics 22, 95-104. Mäler, K-G., (1991). International environmental problems. In D. Helm (ed.), Economic policy towards the environment, Blackwell, Oxford. Mäler, K-G., (1993). The acid rain game II. Beijer Discussion Papers Series No. 32, Beijer International Institute of Ecological Economics, Stockholm, Sweden. Pham, Do, K.H., Folmer, H. and H. Norde (2001). Transboundary fishery management: a game theoretic approach. Working paper. Center, Tilburg University. Shortle, J. (1990). The allocative efficiency implications of water pollution abatement cost comparisons. Water Resources Research 26, 793-797. Söderqvist, T. (1996). Contingent valuation of a less eutrophicated Baltic Sea. Beijer Discussion Papers Series No. 88, Stockholm, Sweden. Söderqvist, T. (1998). Why give up money for the Baltic Sea? Motives for people’s willingness (or reluctance) to pay. Environmental and Resource Economics 12: 249254. Wu, J., and K. Segerson. (1995). The impacts of policies and land characteristics on potential ground water pollution in Wisconsin. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77:1033-1047. Wulff, F., and A. Niemi (1992). Priorities for the Restoration of the Baltic Sea - A Scientific Perspective., Ambio 2:193-195. Wulff, F., A., Stigebrandt, and L., Rahm, (1990). Nutrient Dynamics of the Baltic Sea., Ambio 3:126-133. Wulff, F., Bonsdorff, E., Gren I-M., Johansson, S, and Stigebrandt, A, (2001). Giving advice on cost effective measures for a cleaner Baltic Sea: a challenge to science. Ambio, in press Xepapadeas, A. (2001). Biodiversity and risk. In Dasgupta, P. Kriström B. Essays in honor of Karl-Göran Mäler. Edward Elgar, London. Forthcoming 17 Table 1: Nitrogen loads, own national impacts per unit of nitrogen load, marginal costs, and coefficient of variation in measured nitrogen concentration. Nitrogen National Deposition Marginal costs Coefficient Regions emission own impact, on coast, , of variation 1000 kton Tjj iTijeI SEK1/kg N N, ej reduction Finland Bothnian Bay Bothnian Sea Gulf of Finland Sweden: 31 25 19 0.2 0.2 0.3 42 42 47 0 – 1677 0 – 1968 0 – 3645 0.21 0.25 0.24 Bothnian Bay Bothnian Sea North Baltic Proper South Baltic Proper Sound Kattegat Denmark 19 33 20 0.2 0.2 0.3 42 42 46 0 – 1516 0 – 1780 0 – 1404 0.17 0.20 0.27 18 0.3 45 0 – 1404 0.35 7 39 85 0.3 0.3 0.3 42 42 70 0 – 703 0 – 421 0 – 986 0.33 0.21 0.25 Germany 37 0.3 52 0 – 2977 0.20 Vistula Oder Polish coast Lithuania 145 84 28 60 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.15 54 48 43 46 0 –2233 0 – 2232 0 – 1116 0 – 715 0.29 0.27 0.18 0.16 Latvia 131 0.15 52 0 – 818 0.20 Estonia 59 0.15 65 0 – 838 0.18 90 20 952 0.3 0.15 58 43 9212 0 – 528 0 – 747 0 – 2 977 0.17 0.39 Poland: Russia: S:t Petersburg Kaliningrad Total Sources: Elofsson (2000), Gren et al (1997), and Gren (2001) 1) 1 Euro = 9.3 SEK (July 9, 2001) 2) Total deposition is lower than total emission since part of emission from Denmark and Kattegatt enters Skagerack 18 Table 2: Maximum net benefits (mill SEK per year) and nitrogen reductions ( in %) under cooperative solutions for risk neutrality and risk aversion Country b=0 b=0.0001 b=0.001 Red. Red. Red. Denmark 35 981 35 841 41 -72 Finland 36 2870 37 2568 43 419 Germany 33 1143 33 998 51 155 Poland 48 1267 46 1435 47 289 Sweden 33 6041 33 5318 47 764 Estonia 47 1781 59 1164 63 -23 Latvia 58 1066 58 940 61 162 Lithuania 57 986 57 881 60 204 Russia 43 2475 43 2147 49 172 Total 45 18612 45 16296 50 2071 Table 3: Maximum net benefits (mill SEK per year) and nitrogen reductions ( in %) under Nash solutions for risk neutrality and risk aversion Country b=0 b=0.0001 B=0.001 Red. Red. Red. Denmark 11 129 11 114 11 Finland 23 185 23 179 23 Germany 0 0 0 -2 13 Poland 5 48 4 39 4 Sweden 16 249 15 237 17 Estonia 46 282 46 274 46 Latvia 44 481 44 455 44 Lithuania 6 21 6 20 6 Russia 35 464 35 439 37 Total 21 1859 21 1755 22 -12 131 -16 -38 137 197 231 17 316 963 19 Appendix: Table Table A1: Matrice of transport coefficients among Baltic Sea catchments DENMARK FIBB FIBS FIFV GERMANY VIST ODER POLCOS SEBB SEBS SEBANO SEBAP SESO SEKA ESTONIA LATVIA LITHUANIA SUKAL SUPET DENMARK FIBB FIBS FIFV GERMANY VIST ODER POLCOS SEBB SEBS SEBANO SEBAP SESO SEKA ESTONIA LATVIA LITHUANIA SUKAL SUPET DENMARK FIBB 0.3 0 0.01 0.3 0.01 0.3 0.01 0 0.05 0 0.03 0 0.03 0 0.03 0 0.01 0.2 0.01 0.2 0.03 0 0.03 0 0.03 0 0.10 0 0.02 0 0.03 0 0.03 0 0.03 0 0.01 0 FIBS 0 0.3 0.3 0 0 0 0 0 0.2 0.2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 FIFV 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.3 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.2 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.2 GERMANY 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.3 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.03 VIST 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.15 0.06 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 ODER POLCOS 0.06 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.15 0.06 0.06 0.15 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 SEBB SEBS SEBANO SEBAP SESO SEKA ESTONIA 0 0.2 0.2 0 0 0 0 0 0.3 0.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.2 0.2 0 0 0 0 0 0.3 0.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.3 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.3 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.3 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.03 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0 0 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.3 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.1 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.15 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.1 20 LATVIA DENMARK FIBB FIBS FIFV GERMANY VIST ODER POLCOS SEBB SEBS SEBANO SEBAP SESO SEKA ESTONIA LATVIA LITHUANIA SUKAL SUPET 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.06 0.15 0.06 0.06 0.04 LITHUANIA 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.15 0.06 0.04 SUKAL SUPET 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.15 0.04 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.2 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.2 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.3; Baltic Proper: Denmark, Germany, Vistula (Vist), Oder, Polish coast (Polcos), North Baltic Proper (Sebano), South Baltic Proper (Sebap), Swedish sound (Seso), Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Kaliningrad (Sukal). Bothnian Bay: Finnish and Swedish Bothnian Bay (Fibb and Sebb) Bothnian Sea: Finnish and Swedish Bothnian Sea (Fibs and Sebs) Gulf of Finland: Finland (Fifv), S:t Petersburg, (Supet), and Estonia Kattegatt: Sweden (Seka) and Denmark 21 Fig.A1 The Baltic Sea Drainage Basin..