STRATEGIC RENTS AND TRANSACTION COSTS IN THE THEORY OF THE FIRM Josef Windsperger Center for Business Studies University of Vienna Brünner Str. 72 A-1210 Vienna Austria Tel.: 00431-4277-38180 Fax: 00431-4277-38174 E-mail: josef.windsperger@univie.ac.at Vienna, October 2003 Abstract: The objective of this paper is first to explain the existence of the firm as knowledgecreating institution by developing a strategic efficiency criterion. Starting from Connor and Prahalad’s view, we critically comment on the resource-based theory of the firm and show that a strategic efficiency criterion is missing in the previous literature. Second, we show that the existence of the firm as a knowledge-creating and knowledgeexploiting governance structure can be only explained by combining transaction cost and resource-based reasoning because rent-yielding resources and capabilities are closely intertwined with asset specifity and transaction costs. Finally, we argue that ‘economizing is more fundamental than strategizing’ (Williamson) because the transaction cost theory of the firm can be established in a zero strategic rent world, but a strategic theory cannot be formulated in a zero transaction cost world. Key-words: Transaction Cost, Rents, Strategic Theory, Resource-based Theory. STRATEGIC RENTS AND TRANSACTION COSTS IN THE THEORY OF THE FIRM 1. Introduction During the last decade the theory of the firm has made important progress. On the one hand, contractual approaches of the firm have reached a new stage of development through the new property rights theory (Grossmann and Hart 1986, Hart and Moore 1990, Hart 1995). In addition, the application of the transaction cost theory was very successful in economics, law, organization and marketing (Rindfleisch and Heide 1997, Anderson 1996, Macher and Boerner 2001). On the other hand, an alternative paradigm has been evolving since the 1980-ies - the strategic theory of the firm (Wernerfelt 1984, Rumelt 1984, Connor 1991, Barney 1991, Mahoney and Pandian 1992, Grant 1996, Kogut and Zander 1996, Teece et al. 1997, Barney et al. 2001, Priem and Butler 2001, Nickerson and Zenger 2001). Based on Penrose's resource-based theory (Penrose 1959) and Porter's activity-based approach (Porter 1980, 1985), the strategic theory of the firm investigates the influence of the market structure and internal resources and capabilities on the firm strategy and organization. Hence it tries to explain the efficient strategystructure relationship. However, previous literature in the strategic theory of the firm has not incorporated a strategic efficiency criterion to evaluate the competitive advantage of organizational modes. Strategic efficiency refers to the realization of sustainable competitive advantages as strategic rents of the firm. Depending on the origin of competitive advantage, different strategic rents can be realized. If the competitive advantage primarily results from monopolistic advantages, as argued by Porter (1980, 1985), the strategic choice depends on the generation of monopolistic rents. If the competitive advantage is primarily based on knowledge advantages due to 1 specific resources, capabilities and competencies, Ricardian and Schumpeterian rents can be realized (Peteraf 1993, Winter 1987). Starting from Wernerfelt (1984), Winter (1987) and Barney (1991), Kogut and Zander (1992, 1996) as well as Connor and Prahalad (1996) presented a resource-based view of the firm. The firm is less a contractual network economising on transaction costs but more a rent-yielding bundle of resources and capabilities. They differentiate their approach from the transaction cost theory by emphazising that knowledge-based advantages do not require the assumption of opportunism to explain the existence of the firm. As Kogot and Zander formulated, firms exist because of their „higher order organizing principles“ (1992, p. 384). Under the resource-based view this means that knowledge-based competitive advantages can be more easily created when specific and tacit resources are internally combined to build up organizational capabilities and core competencies (Grant 1991, 1996). This view is also compatible with Nickerson and Zenger’s knowledge-based theory of governance choice. Nickerson and Zenger (2001) developed a theory of alignment that predicts under which problem-solving conditions market supplants hierarchy as knowledge formation mechanism. Their theory can be summarized by the following proposition: The governance mechanism as knowledge formation mechanism depends on the complexity and decomposability of problems. The more complex and non-decomposable the organizational problems, the higher is the tendency toward hierarchy as consensus-based system. On the other hand, Nickerson and Zenger’s theory does not include a knowledge-based efficiency criterion for the governance choice. To summarize the previous literature we may conclude, that the main difficulty of the existing resource-based theories lies in the missing efficiency 2 criterion to evaluate the governance mode as knowledge creation mechanism. Starting from this gap in the literature, the primary objective of our paper is to develop a strategic efficiency criterion and to use this concept to explain the existence of the firm as knowledge-creating institution. Furthermore, we develop an integrative view of the firm and show that the existence of the firm as knowledge-creating and knowledge exploiting mechanism is inseparably intertwined with strategic rents and transaction costs. This simultaneity issue has not been featured in previous resource-based theories of the firm, except Madhok’s discussion of the alignment hypothesis (Madhok 2002). The paper is organized as follows: Section two criticizes Connor and Prahalad's resource-based view of the firm and develops a resource-based theory of the firm by incorporating strategic rents as efficiency criterion to evaluate the governance modes. In section three we show that the transaction cost theory of the firm can be constructed without assuming that the transactors have heterogeneous resources and capabilities. Section four presents an integrative approach by combining the transaction cost and resource-based view. Finally, we argue that a strategic theory of the firm cannot be formulated without transaction costs, but a transaction cost theory of the firm can be established in a zero strategic rent world. 2. Resource-based Theory of the Firm 2. 1. Connor and Prahalad's View Connor and Prahalad’s theory (Connor and Prahalad 1996) is the most sophisticated version of the resource-based theory developed in the last years. In the following, we 3 summarize and criticize their view. Their resource-based approach of the firm is based on the knowledge substitution and flexibility effect of the organizational mode: (a) Knowledge substitution effect: If Y (as supplier) and Z (as final goods producer) have certain resources and capabilities, both have two possibilities to influence the other‘s actions: Firm organization and market contracting. The knowledge substitution effect exists when one party (in Connor and Prahalad’s case Z) directs the action of the other party (Y). Hence it refers to the hierarchical mode of coordination. Under this mode, Z can require Y to act according to Z’s judgement. This effect results in a competitive advantage if Z has a specific knowledge base that cannot be internalized by market contracts. In this case, internal organization better enables knowledge creation without full knowledge absorption. This is compatible with Demsetz' view that „[d]irection substitutes for education“ (1991, p. 172). The greater the initial difference in knowledge due to higher skills and capabilities, the larger the knowledge substitution effect. (b) Flexibility effect: „The flexibility effect accounts for the relative cost, under the two organizational modes, of altering the parties’duties and responsibilities on an ongoing basis, in order to incorporate learning or unexpected opportunities...“ (Connor and Prahalad, p. 486). Hence it refers to the dynamic capabilities of the firm. The more dynamic and competitive the environment, the more often changes in skills, duties and responsibilities are required favouring the firm organization, because under market contracting it will be difficult to provide for unanticipated acquisition of new knowledge. However, the flexibility advantage of firm organization only exists if it is assumed that Z has higher learning or knowledge-upgrading capabilities than Y. This 4 flexibility effect is compatible with Langlois’s concept of dynamic transaction costs as learning costs (Langlois 1992). Which resource-based predictions can be derived from Connor and Prahalad's approach? According to Connor and Prahalad, the firm existence is more likely, the higher the knowledge substitution and flexibility advantages are. Consequently, the firm will arise as knowledge-creating institution if the net value of the knowledge substitution and flexibility is higher than under market contracting. Connor and Prahalad’s approach can be criticized as follows: First, the main critics refers to the missing knowledge-based (resource-based) efficiency criterion: They compare the organizational modes according to the knowledge substitution and flexibility effects without explicitly incorporating a strategic efficiency criterion. Oliver Williamson (1999) also criticized this point, but he does not propose a solution. Hodgson proposes a dynamic efficiency criterion for the resource- or competence-based theories. Dynamic efficiency refers to „learning and innovations“ (Hodgson 1998, p. 188). This is an important starting point to distinguish transaction cost and resource-based approaches. However, Hodgson does not operationalize this efficiency concept. Second, as already criticized by Foss (1996), Connor and Prahalad assume that the knowledge substitution and flexibility effects are primarily realized under firm organization. This need not be the case. For instance, as shown by Argyres (1996), market contracting may result in strategic advantages if the supplier has higher organizational capabilities. 5 Third, Connor and Prahalad present a comparison of the resource-based theory with the transaction cost approach as the opportunism-dependent approach (Connor and Prahalad, p. 489). The problem of this comparison is that they do not specify the conditions under which the predictions are possible. The restriction of the transaction cost theory to the opportunism-based view as a reference theory cannot be justified, because transaction cost theory is more than the opportunism-based view. This comparison neglects the information processing view of the firm as an important component of transaction cost theory because – as already argued by Coase 1937, McManus 1972, and Casson 1994 – bounded rationality is sufficient to move from market to hierarchy due to information cost savings. In a world of bounded rationality/zero opportunism the firm exists as an information processing mechanism due to high market coordination costs. The extent of information processing advantage of the firm depends on the degree of environmental uncertainty. If high environmental uncertainty exists, frequently new information arises resulting in high search, bargaining and adjustment costs under market contracting. In this case, the firm organization may lower the coordination costs by installing a higher information processing capacity. 2.2. A Resource-based Approach of the Firm Starting from the Connor and Prahalad’s approach we develop a resource-based theory of the firm by incorporating strategic rents as efficiency criterion to evaluate the organization modes. As discussed in section 3.1., Connor and Prahalad developed a knowledge-based approach for the existence of the firm. They argue that the firm’s existence can be explained on the basis of the transactor’s knowledge advantages 6 resulting from firm-specific resources and dynamic capabilities. The first refers to the knowledge substitution effect and the latter to the flexibility effect under changing environmental conditions. In the following, we argue that knowledge substitution and flexibility effects are only relevant for a resource based theory of the firm, when they are closely related to the rent-generating potential of organizational mode. As argued by Barney (1991), Amit and Schoemaker (1993) and Alvarez and Busenitz (2001), the firm's resources, capabilities and competencies (as strategic assets) may generate a sustainable competitive advantage if rarity, imperfect imitability and nonsubstitutability exist. Under this resource-based view of the firm, strategic rents (including Ricardian and Schumpeterian rents) are the efficiency criteria to evaluate the firm’s competitive advantage. Ricardian rents result from knowledge advantage due to differences in existing firm-specific resources and "static capabilities" (Fujimoto 1998, p. 17), and Schumpeterian rents result from knowledge creation due to differences in dynamic or innovation capabilities (Teece et al. 1997, Penrose 1959, p. 85). This organizational learning refers to the knowledge-leveraging capabilities to strengthen the firm’s competitive advantage in the future. This concept of strategic rents is also compatible with Putterman’s “information rents” (1995, p. 379), but Putterman does not differentiate between rents due to static and dynamic capabilities. In the following, we show that the resource-based theory explains the firm as knowledge-creating institution due to its higher strategic efficiency, compared to market contracting. We differentiate between two strategic criteria: Ricardian rents (RR) due to static resource advantages and Schumpeterian rents (SR) due to dynamic capabilities 7 (innovation capabilities) advantages. The results of the comparison of the rentgenerating effect of the firm organization and market contracting are summarized in figure 1. Based on Connor and Prahalad’s analysis, we use Y as supplier and Z as buyer (final goods producer) and investigate the strategic efficiency of the organizational modes from Z’s point of view. We differentiate four cases: Insert Figure 1 (1) The firm organization results from Z’s static resource advantages and Z's more efficient organizational learning due to its higher innovation capabilities. Thus Z can realize both higher Ricardian and Schumpeterian rents by internal bundling of resources and capabilities. (2) In this situation, the firm organization arises if Z's Schumpeterian rents due to its higher innovation capabilities are not compensated by Z's static resource disadvantage. (3) The firm organization will arise if Z's Ricardian rents due to its static resource advantages exceed the lower Schumpeterian rents (higher learning costs) due to Z's lower innovation or dynamic capabilities compared to Y. (4) Market contracting is more efficient from Z’s strategic point of view, because Z can leverage its resources and capabilities by acquiring and exploiting Y’s static resource and innovation capabilities advantage. Consequently, the firm will arise as a knowledge-creating institution (Nonaka et al. 2000), if the sum of Ricardian and Schumpeterian rents from internal bundling of resources and capabilities are higher than under market contracting. Therefore, a 8 resource-based explanation of the existence of the firm is only possible if the rentyielding potential of resources under internal organization is higher than under market contracting. The resource-based theory can be summarized by the following proposition: The firm organization (F) as a knowledge creating institution is more efficient than market contracting (M), if the knowledge-based rents (Ricardian and Schumpeterian rents) under internal organization exceed the rents under market contracting (RF – RM > 0). 3. A Transaction Cost View of the Firm Compared with the resource-based theory, the transaction costs approach does not require heterogeneous resources and capabilities of the transactors to explain the firm’s existence and organization (Barney and Hesterley 1996). Under given transactionspecifity and frequency, environmental uncertainty and opportunism influence the organizational mode (Williamson 1975, 1985). Transaction costs, due to environmental uncertainty, are coordination costs consisting of search, information processing and adjustment costs, and transaction costs, due to opportunism (behavioral uncertainty), are motivation costs resulting from adverse selection, moral hazard and hold-up. Based on transaction costs as coordination efficiency criterion, we show that transaction costs differences can explain the firm as knowledge-exploiting institution, due to its information processing and incentive effects, without recourse to heterogeneous resources and capabilities. 9 We differentiate between two transaction cost criteria: Coordination and motivation costs According to the transaction cost theory (Williamson 1975), coordination cost savings of the firm organization are higher, the higher the uncertainty is. The results of the comparision are summarized in figure 2. Insert Figure 2 (1) Under low environmental uncertainty, market contracting results in low transaction costs because Z already has the relevant knowledge to conclude a relatively complete contract. (2) Under high environmental uncertainty, high market coordination costs as search, information processing and adjustment costs arise because market contracts must be frequently adjusted to new information. On the other hand, Y does not behave opportunistically and is willing to adjust its plans to new relevant knowledge. Consequently, under internal organization Z can realize coordination cost advantages, if the savings of market transaction cost exceed the higher setup-costs of internal organization structure. (3) Under low environmental uncertainty and opportunism, market contracting results in relatively low coordination and motivation costs. Although Z behaves opportunistically, moral hazard, adverse selection and hold-up behavior can be easily detected in this situation. Thus Z may realize coordination and motivation cost advantages under market contracting. (4) Under high environmental uncertainty and opportunism, the firm organization will arise as a knowledge-exploiting institution. High uncertainty results in information asymmetry between Y and Z, hence in high market transaction costs. In addition, 10 high environmental uncertainty increases Y‘s tendency toward opportunistic behavior and hence Z‘s motivation costs, because information selection and manipulation cannot be easily detected. Consequently, in a world of bounded rationality and opportunism the firm existence can be explained by transaction cost differences without recourse to heterogenous resources and capabilities of the transactors. The transaction cost view of the existence of the firm can be summarized by the following proposition: The firm organization as a coordination mechanism (knowledge-exploiting institution) is more efficient than market contracting, if the transaction costs under market contracting exceeds the transaction costs under internal organization. 4. An Integrative View Finally, we show that the existence of the firm as institutional entity requires an integrative view of the firm by combining the resource-based and the transaction cost theory, because transaction costs incurred in the exchange of resources are not independent of the rent-generating effects of resources and capabilities (Madhok and Talmann 1998, p. 327). Hence the question to ask is, which relationship exists between transaction costs and strategic rents? 4.1. Asset Specifity, Transaction Costs and Rents The mediating factor between transaction costs and rents is asset specifity. Asset specifity is an important theoretical concept both in the resource-based and in the transaction cost theory. But many authors do not differentiate between firm specifity, on 11 the one hand, and transaction specifity, on the other hand. In order to be able to explain the relationship between transaction costs and strategic rents, we have to distinguish the two forms of asset specifity: (I) Transaction-specifity: The concept of transaction-specifity is based on the transaction cost theory developed by Klein et al. (1978) and Williamson (1979). An asset is transaction-specific when it realizes a quasi rent (QR), which refers to the higher value of the transaction compared to the best alternative. Two cases can be distinguished (Anderson and Weitz 1992, Buvik and John 2000, Wathne and Heide 2000): (a) Asymmetric specific investments: If the transaction-specific investments of the supplier are high and of the buyer are low, the opportunism risk is high because the buyer may appropriate the supplier's quasi-rents under unilateral dependency. (b) Symmetric specific investments: When both partners invest into relationship-specific assets, bilateral dependency mitigates the opportunism risk because both can realize high quasi-rents. Consequently, the following propositions between transactionspecifity and transaction costs can be derived: If asymmetric specific investments exist, the quasi-rents of the more dependent party are exposed to the hold-up risk by the less dependent party, hence transaction costs rise with transaction-specifity (e.g., Anderson 1988). If symmetric specific investments exist, both parties can realize high quasi rents under the current relationship, hence transaction costs decline with transaction-specifity due to the incentive effect of bilateral dependency (e.g., Dyer 1997). (II) Firm-specifity: The concept of firm-specifity is based on the resource-based view of the firm (Wernerfelt 1984, Barney 1991, Connor 1991, Amit and Schoemaker 1993). Strategic assets as resources, capabilities and competencies are firm-specific because they are difficult to transfer and imitate due to high transaction costs. 12 Consequently, sustainability of competitive advantage is closely intertwined with high transaction costs. Now we can answer the question regarding the relationship between asset specifity, transaction costs and strategic rents. Two cases can be distinguished: If the assets of one party (buyer) are firm-specific and generate strategic rents (R) but do not require transaction-specific investments of the other party (supplier), high transaction costs may arise due to the hold-up behavior of the less dependent party. On the other hand, if the buyer‘s assets are firm-specific and require transaction-specific investments of the supplier, high relationship-specific rents arise under "idiosyncratic investments" (Jap 1999, p. 471, Bensaou, Anderson 1999). In this case, the buyer realizes high strategic rents (R) due to its firm-specific resources and capabilities, and the supplier realizes high quasi-rents (QR) due to the transaction-specifity of its investments. For instance, as argued by Asanuma 1989, Dyer and Singh 1998, Kalwani and Narayandas 1995, Nishiguchi and Brookfield 1995 and Helper and Sako 1995, the close relationship between Japanese automobile suppliers and producers is characterized by high relationship-specific assets that result from the dynamics of firm-specific and transaction-specific investments. The change of assets specifity during the relationship life-cycle can be explained as follows (Asanuma 1989, Jap and Ganesan 2000, Dyer et al. 1998) (see figure 3): We assume that the producer (buyer) realizes a competitive advantage (strategic rents) due to its capabilities in the design and production of automobiles. These firm-specific assets require transaction-specific investments by the supplier (1). Over time these transaction-specific investments trigger a capabilityupgrading and knowledge leverage effect for the supplier (2). Conversely, the high firm- 13 specifity of the supplier's resources and capabilities results in transaction-specific investments by the producer (3) which may lead to a knowledge leverage effect for the producer (4) and hence to an increase in strategic rents (as Schumpeterian rents). Insert Figure 3 Consequently, strategic rents and transaction costs are closely intertwined with asset specifity. In order to explain the existence of the firm as knowledge creating and knowledge exploiting institution the transaction cost and resource-based theory have to be combined. The results of the theory development are depicted in figure 4; thereby we assume a medium degree of environmental uncertainty. We differentiate four cases: Insert Figure 4 (1) The buyer’s (Z’s) high rent-yielding resources and innovation capabilities show a high degree of firm-specifity. In addition, the probability of opportunistic behavior is high if the supplier (Y) has not to undertake transaction-specific investments resulting in high hold-up risks for Z. Therefore, both resource-based and transaction cost predictions lead to internal organization by Z. (2) Z has no competitive advantage in resources and capabilities implying a low degree of firm-specifity. On the other hand, transaction costs are high under a high probability of opportunistic behavior. This can be only the case, if one agent (Z or Y) has to undertake high transaction-specific investments resulting in high hold-up risks under unilateral dependency. Firm organization is more efficient than market 14 contracting, because it can more easily process the relevant information and it may mitigate the opportunism risk by creating incentive and control devices. (3) Z‘s rent yielding knowledge-based advantages are high due to the firm-specific resources and capabilities. On the other hand, market transaction costs are low under a low probability of opportunistic behavior. This can be the case if a high degree of bilateral dependency exists, due to high transaction-specific investments by Y. Hence Z’s firm-specific assets are complemented by Y‘s transaction-specific investments. Under this bilateral dependency, market contracting results in low transaction costs. Consequently, the resource-based and transaction cost theories lead to different predictions. The firm organization will arise if the higher rentyielding potential of internal knowledge creation exceeds the transaction cost savings of market contracting. (4) The firm organization cannot realize rent-yielding resource and innovation capabilities advantages. Hence no knowledge leverage effect exists. In addition, transaction costs under market contracting are low because Z and Y undertake low transaction-specific investments. Consequently, market contracting is more efficient than firm organization under the transaction cost view. As a result, the existence of the firm as a knowledge-creating and knowledge–exploiting institution can be explained by combining the transaction cost and resource-based reasoning, because the rent-yielding resources and capabilities are inseparately intertwined with high transaction costs. Under these conditions, the knowledge- or rentgenerating organizational mode cannot be separated from the transaction cost 15 minimizing organizational mode. The existence of the firm as a knowledge-creating and knowledge-exploiting institution can be summarized by the following proposition: The firm organization (F) is more efficient than market contracting (M), if the rent-yielding potential of internal bundling of resources and capabilities exceeds the transaction costs disadvantages, or the transaction cost savings of the firm organization exceed the rent-yielding advantage of market organization (RF – RM > TCF – TCM or TCM – TCF > RM – RF). 4.2. Existence of the Firm and Primacy of the Transaction Cost Explanation Finally, we argue that “economizing is more fundamental than strategizing” (Williamson 1994, p. 362) to explain the existence of the firm as governance mechanism. Although the resource-based theory does not depend on the existence of opportunism, the existence of the firm as a knowledge-creating (or rent-generating) institution requires positive transaction costs. This is compatible with the view of Mahoney (2001) and Foss (2001, 2002) that market frictions (transaction costs) explain sustainable firm-level rents, because transaction costs make the transfer and imitation of resources and capabilities more difficult. A similar view was already presented by Lippman and Rumelt (1982) and Reed and DeFillippi (1990). They suggest that uncertainty and ambiguity regarding which factors are responsible for performance differences between competitors explain the existence of rents. Conversely, if transaction costs are zero, the firm resources are mobile and easily imitable and do not generate sustainable strategic rents. On the other hand, a zero strategic rent world is compatible with a positive transaction cost world. If no strategic rents are generated, due to homogeneous resources and capabilities, the existence of the firm can be only 16 explained by transaction cost differences. As argued in section 4, transaction cost differences result from transaction specifity, transaction frequency, as well as environmental and behavioral uncertainty consequences under firm and market organization. Therefore we may conclude: Contrary to Mahoney’s view (2001, p. 655), market frictions (transaction costs) that explain the existence of the firm as knowledgeexploiting institution (in transaction cost theory) are not always sufficient isolating mechanisms that explain sustainable strategic rents (in resource-based theory). Only when market frictions exist due to firm-specific resources and capabilities, the market frictions are sufficient to explain sustainable strategic rents. From this reasoning we can derive the primacy of transaction cost explanation: If strategic rents are zero, the firm only exists as coordination or knowledge-exploiting governance structure. But if transaction costs are zero, the firm exists neither as knowledge-exploiting nor as knowledge creating-governance structure. 5. Conclusion The paper focuses on the role strategic rents and transaction costs in the theory of the firm. Resources, capabilities and competencies are the building blocks of a strategic theory of the firm. According to Barney, they generate competitive advantage when rarity, imperfect imitability, and nonsubstitutability exist. Based on this view, Connor and Prahalad developed a resource-based theory of the firm by trying to show that the firm can realize a competitive advantage by internal bundling of resources and capabilities. Starting from Connor and Prahalad‘ s view, we developed a resource-based theory by explicitly incorporating a strategic efficiency criterion. Strategic efficiency is operationalized by the concept of strategic rents, consisting of Ricardian and Schumpeterian rents. Ricardian rents result from static resource advantages and 17 Schumpeterian rents from innovation or dynamic capability advantages. Only if the organization of resources and capabilities influence strategic rents, rents can serve as efficiency criterion in a resource-based theory of the firm. We have shown that the firm as a knowledge-creating institution may arise, if strategic rents under internal organization exceed the rents under market contracting. However, to explain the firm as a knowledge-creating and knowledge-exploiting institution the transaction cost and resource-based views must be integrated because strategic rents as resource-based advantages are closely related to transaction costs. Finally we argued that a primacy of transaction cost explanation exists. A transaction cost theory of the firm can be formulated in a zero strategic rent world, but a strategic theory of the firm organization cannot be established in a zero transaction cost world. References Alvarez, S. A., L. W. Busenitz (2001), The Entrepreneuship of Resource-based Theory, Journal of Management, 27, 755 – 775. Amit, R., P. J. H. Schoemaker (1993). Strategic Assets and Organizational Rent, Strategic Management Journal, 14, 33 - 46. Anderson, E. (1988). Transaction Costs as Determinants of Opportunism in Integrated and Independent Sales Forces, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9, 247 – 264. Anderson, E., B. Weitz (1992). The Use of Pledges To Build and Sustain Commitment in Distribution Channels, Journal of Marketing Research, 24, 18 – 34. Anderson, E. (1996). Transaction Cost Analysis and Marketing, in: J. Groenewegen (ed.) Transaction Cost Economics and Beyond, Boston, 65 - 83. Argyres, N. (1996). Evidence on the Role of Firm Capabilities in Vertical Integration Decision, Strategic Management Journal, 17, 129 - 150. Asanuma, B. (1989), Manufacturer-Supplier Relationships in Japan and the Concept of Relation-Specific Skills, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 3, 1 30. Barney, J. (1991). Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage, Journal of Management, 17, 99 - 120. Barney, J., W. Hesterly (1996). Organizational Economics: Understanding the Relationship between Organizations and Economic Analysis, in: S. R. Clegg, C. Hardy, W. R. Nord (eds.), Handbook of Organization Studies, London, 115 - 147. Barney, J., M. Wright, D. J. Ketchen (2001). The Resource-base View of the Firm: Ten years after 1991, Journal of Management, 27, 625 – 41. 18 Bensaou, M., E. Anderson (1999). Buyer-Supplier Relations in Industrial Markets: When Do Buyers Risk Making Idiosyncratic Investments? Organization Science, 10, 460 - 481. Buvik, A., G. John (2000), When does Vertical Coordination Improve Industrial Purchasing Relationships? Journal of Marketing, 64, 52 - 64. Cantillon, H. (1964 [1755]), Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en Général, New York. Casson, M. (1994). Why are Firms Hierarchical? Journal of Economics of Business, 1, 47 - 76. Coase, R. H. (1937). The Nature of the Firm, Economica, IV, 386 - 405. Connor, K. R. (1991). A Historical Comparison of Resource-based Theory and Five Schools of Thought within Industrial Organization Economics: Do W Have a New Theory of the Firm, Journal of Management, 17, 121 - 154. Connor, K. R., C. K. Prahalad (1996). A Resourc-based Theory of the Firm: Knowledge versus Opportunism, Organization Science, 7, 5, 477 -501. Demsetz, H. (1991). The Theory of the Firm Revisited, in: O. E. Williamson, S. G. Winter (eds.), The Nature of the Firm, New York, 159 - 178. Dyer, J. H. (1996). Specialized Supplier Networks as a Source of Competitive Advantage: Evidence from the Auto Industry, Strategic Management Journal, 17, 271 291. Dyer, J. H. (1997). Effective Interfirm Collaboration: How Firms Minimize Transaction Costs and Maximize Transaction Value, Strategic Management Journal, 18, 535 - 556. Dyer, J. H., D. S. Cho, W. Chu (1998), Strategic Supplier Segmentation: A Model for Managing Suppliers in the 21st Century. In: G. Hamel et al. (eds.), Strategic Flexibility: Managing in a Turbulent Environment, London, 257 - 278. Dyer, J. H., H. Singh (1998). The Relational View: Cooperative Strategy and Sources of Interorganizational Competitive Advantage, Academy of Management Review, 23, 660 679. Foss, N. J. (1996). Knowledge-based Approaches to the Theory of the Firm: Some Critical Comments, Organization Science, 7, 5, 470 - 476. Foss, N. J. (2001). Strategy, Bargaining, and Economic Organization: Some Thoughts on the Transaction Cost Fondation of Firm Strategy, in P. Joffre (ed.), Transaction Cost Economics: Points of View from the Strategy Field, Paris. Foss, N. J. (2002), The Strategy and Transaction Cost Nexus: Past Debates, Central Questions, and Future Research Possibilities, LINK, Copenhagen Business School, March 2002. Fujimoto, T. (1998). Reinterpreting the Resource-Capability View of the Firm: A Case of the Development-Production Systems of the Japanese Auto-Makers, in: A. D. Chandler, P. Hagström, O. Sölvell (eds.). The Dynamic Firm, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 15 - 44. Grant, R. M. (1991). The Resource-based Theory of Competitive Advantage: Implication for Strategy Formulation, California Management Review, 33, 114 - 135. Grant, R. M. (1996). Prospering in Dynamically-Competitive Environments: Organizational Capability as Knowledge Integration, Organization Science, 7, 375 387. Grossman, S., O. Hart (1986). The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691- 719. Hart, O. (1995). Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure, Oxford. 19 Hart, O., J.Moore (1990). Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1119 - 1158. Helper, S. R., M. Sako (1995). Supplier Relations in Japan and the United States: Are they converging? Sloan Management Review, Spring, 77 – 84. Hodgson, G. M. (1998). Competence and Contract in the Theory of the Firm, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 35, 179 - 201. Jap, S. D. (1999), Pie-Expansion Efforts: Collaboration Processes in Buyer-Supplier Relationships, Journal of Marketing Research, 36, 461 - 475. Jap, S. D., S. Ganesan (2000), Control Mechanisms and the Relationship Life Cycle: Implications for safeguarding Specific Investments and Developing Commitment, Journal of Marketing Research, 37, 227 - 245. Kaldor, N. (1934). The Equilibrium of the Firm, Economic Journal, March, 60 - 76. Kalwani, M. U., N. Narayandas (1995), Long-Term Manufacturer-Supplier Relationships: Do They Pay off for Supplier Firms? Journal of Marketing, 59, 1 - 16. Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and Entrepreneurship, Chicago. Klein, B., R. A. Crawford, A.A. Alchian. (1978), Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process, Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 297 - 326. Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, New York. Kogut, B., U. Zander (1992). Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the Replication of Technology, Organization Science, 3, 383 - 397. Kogut B., U. Zander (1996). What Firms Do? Coordination, Identity, and Learning, Organization Science, 7, 5, 502 - 518. Langlois, R. N. (1992). Transaction-Cost Economics in Real Time, Industrial and Corporate Change, 1, 99 - 127. Laseter, T. (1998), Balanced Sourcing: Cooperation and Competition in Supplier Relationsships, San Francisco. Lippman, S. A., Richard P. Rumelt (1982). Uncertain imitability: An analysis of interfirm differences in efficiency under competition, Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 418-438. Macher, J., C. R. Boerner (2001). Transaction Cost Economics: An Assessment of Empirical Research in the Social Sciences, Working Paper, Georgetown University. Madhok, A. (2002), Reassesing the Fundamentals and Beyond: Ronald Coase, the Transaction Cost and Ressource-based Theories of the Firm and the Institutional Structure of Production, Strategic Management Journal, 23, 535 – 550. Madhok, A. S. B. Tallmann (1998). Resource, Transactions and Rents: Managing Value Through Interfirm Collaborative Relationships, Organization Science, 9, 326 - 339. Mahoney, J. T. (2001). A Resource-based Theory of Sustainable Rents, Journal of Management, 27, 651 – 650. Mahoney, J. T., J.R. Pandian (1992), The Resouce-based View within the Conversation of Strategic Management, Strategic Management Journal, 13, 363 – 380. Makadok, R. (2001). Toward a Synthesis of the Resource-based and DynamicCapability View of Rents, Strategic Management Journal, 22, 387 – 401. March, J.G. (1991), Exploration and Exploitation in Organizaitonal Learning, Organization Science, 1, 71 – 87. 20 McManus, J. C. (1972). The Theory of International Firm, in:G. Paquet (ed.), The Multinational Firm and the Nation State, Collier, 66 - 93. Mody, A. (1993). Learning Through Alliances, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 20, 151 - 170. Nickerson, J.A., T.R. Zenger (2001), A Knowledge-based Theory of Governance Choice-A Problem-solving Approach, Working paper, Olin School of Business, Washington University. Nishiguchi, T. J. Brookfield (1997). The Evolution of Japanese Subcontracting, Sloan Management Review, Fall, 89 - 101. Nonaka, I., R. Toyama, A. Nagata (2000). A Firm as a Knowledge-creating Entity: A New Perspective on the Theory of the Firm, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, 1 –20. Penrose, E. (1959). The Theory of Growth of the Firm, New York. Peteraf, M. (1993). The Cornerstones of Competitive Advantage: A Resource-based View, Strategic Management Journal, 14, 3, 179 - 192. Porter, M.(1980). Competitive Behavior, New York. Porter, M. (1985). Competitive Advantage, New York. Priem, R. I., J. E. Butler (2001). Is the Resource-based „View“ a Useful Perspective for Strategic Management Research? Academy of Management Review, 26, 22 –40. Putterman, L. (1995), Markets, Hierarchies, and Information: On a Paradox in the Economics of Organization, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 26, 373 – 390. Reed, R., R. J. DeFillippi (1990). Causal Ambiguity, Barriers to Imiations and Sustainble Competitive Advantage, Academy of Management Review, 15, 88 – 102. Rindfleisch, A., J. Heide (1997). Transaction Cost Analysis: Past, Present, and Future Applications, Journal of Marketing, 61 (October), 30 - 54. Rumelt, R. P. (1984). Toward a Strategic Theory of the Firm, in: R. Lamb (ed.), Competitive Strategic Management, Englewood Cliffs, 556 - 570. Rumelt, R. P. (1987). Theory, Strategy, and Entrepreneurship, in: D. J. Teece (ed.), The Competitive Challenge, Cambridge, 137 - 158. Sanches, R., A. Heene, H. Thomas (eds.) (1996). Dynamics of Competence-based Competition: Theory and Practice in the New Strategic Management, Oxford. Schumpeter, J. (1934). Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge: MA. Shelanski, H. P. Klein (1995). Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Review and Assessment, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11 (October), 335 - 361. Teece, D. J. , G. Pisano, A. Shuen (1997), Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management, Strategic Managment Journal, 18, 509 – 533. Wathne, K. H., J. H. Heide (2000), Opportunism in Interfirm Relationships: Forms, Outcomes, and Solutions, Journal of Marketing, 64, 36 - 51. Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A Resource-based View of the Firm, Strategic Management Journal, 5, 171 - 180. Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies, New York. Williamson, O. E. (1979). Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations, Journal of Law and Economics, 22, 233 - 261. Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York. Williamson, O. E. (1994). Strategizing, Economizing, and Economic Organization, in R. P. Rumelt, D. e. Schendel, D. J. Teece (eds.), Fundamental Issues in Strategy. Boston, Harvard Business School Press. 21 Williamson, O. E. (1999). Strategy Research: Governance and Competence Perspective, Working Paper, University of California, Berkeley, February 1999. Winter, S. G. (1987). Knowledge and Competence as Strategic Assets, in: D. J. Teece (ed.), The Competitive Challenge, Cambridge, 159 – 184. 22 Ricardian Rents (RR) Resource Advantage Resource Disadvantage Innovation Capabilities Advantage (2a) FIRM: (SR + RR > 0) (2b) MARKET: (SR + RR < 0) Innovation Capabilities Disadvantage Schumpterian Rents (SR) (1) FIRM: (SR + RR > 0) (3a) FIRM: (RR + SR > 0) (3b) MARKET: (RR + SR < 0) (4) MARKET: (RR + SR < 0) RR > 0/SR > 0: Compared to market contracting, the firm organization can realize higher Ricardian/Schumpeterian rents due to its resource advantages or higher innovation or learning capabilities. SR < 0/RR < 0: Compared to market contracting, the firm organization realizes lower Ricardian/Schumpeterian rents because the firm has resource or innovation capability disadvantages. Figure 1: Resource-based Theory 23 Coordination Costs (CC) Low Environmental Uncertainty Opportunism Motivation Costs (MC) No Opportunism (1) MARKET: (CC > 0) (3) MARKET: (CC + MC > 0) High Environmental Uncertainty (2a) FIRM (CC < 0) (2b) MARKET: (CC > 0) (4) FIRM: (CC + MC < 0) CC > 0/MC >0: Market Contracting results in coordination/motivation cost savings. CC < 0/MC < 0: Firm organization results in coordination/motivation costs savings. Figure 2: Transaction Cost-View of the Firm 24 Producer’s Capabilities (Firm-specific Assets) (1) (4) Supplier’s Transaction-specific Investments (2) Supplier’s Capability-upgrading (Knowledge-leveraging) (Firm-specific Investments) (3) Producer’s Transaction-specific Investments Figure 3: The Dynamics of Asset Specifity 25 Strategic Rents (R) YES High Probability of Opportunistic Behavior Low Probability of Opportunistic Behavior Transaction Costs (TC) (1) RB+: FIRM (R > 0) OB: FIRM (TC < 0) (3) RB: FIRM: (R > 0) OB: MARKET: (TC > 0) NO (2) RB: FIRM or MARKET (R = 0) OB: FIRM (TC < 0) (4) RB: FIRM or MARKET: (R = 0) OB: MARKET: (TC > 0) +: RB refers to the resource-based view and OB to the transaction cost view. R > 0: The firm can capture higher strategic rents (Ricardian and/or Schumpeterian Rents) under internal organization, compared to market contracting. TC < (>) 0: The firm organization (market contracting) results in transaction cost savings. Figure 4: An Integrative View 26