Does the Black-Scholes formula contain information regarding the

advertisement
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com
MARK IOFFE
Does the Black-Scholes formula contain information regarding the rate of return
of the stock?
(Studies of Classics)
Abstract
It seems that vast popularity Black-Scholes formula has become primarily because it contains no assumptions
about non-random, predictable the rate of return of the stock changing(“we do not require agreement on the
expected returns on securities”, [2], page 400). Our analysis shows that according to the formula Black-
 x(t ) 
 equal to the interest
 x(0) 
Scholes average value of the rate of return of the stock, i.e. the mean value Ln
rate r that is not dependent on the characteristics of a particular stock. Thus, the model of the Black-Scholes
has quite specific information about the rate of return of the stock.
It seems that vast popularity Black-Scholes formula has become primarily because it contains no
assumptions about non-random, predictable the rate of return of the stock changing (“we do not require
agreement on the expected returns on securities”, [2], page 400).
In deriving formula for the value of an option in terms of the price of the stock Black and Scholes assume
following “ideal conditions” in the market for the stock and for the option [1]:
a) The short-term interest rate is known and is constant through time.
b) The stock price follows a random walk in continuous time with variance rate proportional to the square of the
stock price. Thus the distribution of the possible stock prices at the end of any finite interval is lognormal. The
variance rate of the return on the stock is constant.
New York 2010
1
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com
c) The stock pays no dividends or other distributions.
d) The option is “European”, that is, it can only be exercised at maturity.
e) There are no transaction costs in buying or selling the stock or the options.
f) It is possible to borrow any fraction of the price of a security to buy or to hold it, at the short interest rate.
g) There are no penalties to short selling. A seller who does not own a security will simply accept the price of the
security from a buyer, and will agree to settle with buyer on some future date by paying him an amount equal to
the price of the security on the date.
If you make another additional assumption, namely that the price of European option equals the discounted
expectation of payoff function at maturity, i.e. for Call max( x  c,0) , x stock price, c-strike price, then the above
assumptions is sufficient to derive the formula for calculating price option.
Note that the authors [1] implicitly use this additional assumption in the derivation of the formula (4), using
stochastic calculus. We consider two ways to derive the formula for calculating the option price, based on the
above hypotheses. The first of these is similar to that described in [1] and is based on the known theory of
stochastic diffusion processes.
Consider the log-normal distribution with two parameters,  and m. Density distribution is equal
1
 2 ( Lny  m ) 2
1
plog norm ( y, m, ) 
e 2
2 y
(1)
The first and second moments of this distribution equal
New York 2010
2
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com

M 1   yplog norm ( y )dy  e
1
m  2
2
0

M 2   y 2 plog norm ( y )dy  e 2 ( m 
2
)
0
(2)
If the stock price is described by a geometric random walk in continuous time, the option price as a function
of the current stock price x and time to maturity t, being the math. expectation satisfies the following equation

W ( x, t )   W ( y, t  t ) p( x | y,t )dy
0
p( x | y, t )  plog norm ( y, Lnx  t , 0 t )
(3)
It follows from (2) and (3) the average price at the time of maturity equals
1
(    02 ) t
2
Ex  xe
(4)
By Taylor's formula
W ( y, t  t )  W ( x, t ) 
W
1  2W
W
( y  x) 
( y  x) 2 
t
2
x
2 x
t
(5)
From formulas (2), (3) and (5) follows
New York 2010
3
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com
Lnx  t   02 t
W Lnx t  2 02t
1  2W 2 ( Lnx t  02t )
W
2
W ( x, t )  W ( x, t ) 
(e
 x) 
(
e

2
xe
 x2 ) 
t
2
x
2 x
t
1
1
(6)
We assume t an infinitely small quantity and in formula (5) retain only the members up to the first order. The
result
W ( x, t )  W ( x, t ) 
W
1
1  2W 2 2
W
x( t   02 t ) 
x  0 t 
t
2
x
2
2 x
t
(7)
Thus, from (7) implies that the function W ( x, t ) satisfies the parabolic equation:
W W
1
1  2W 2 2

x(    02 ) 
x 0
t
x
2
2 x 2
(8)
The initial condition for the Call option is obvious
W ( x,0)  max( x  c,0)
(9)
Where c-strike.
Equation (8) essentially simplified, that is reduced to an equation with constant coefficients, if you make the
change of independent variable x to y by the formula
x  ey
New York 2010
4
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com
(10)
In this case, the equation (8) will
W
W 1 2  2W

 0
t
y 2
y 2
(9)
The corresponding initial condition is
W ( y,0)  max( e y  c,0)
(10)
Solution of equation (9) with initial condition (10) has the form
W ( y, t )  e
1
y  (    02 ) t
2
1
Lp( x) 
2
x
e
Lp(
1
 u2
2
y  Ln(c)  (    02 )t
0 t
)  cLp(
y  Ln(c)  t
)
0 t
du

(11)
Option price equals the discounted value of the expectation, i.e.
W1 ( y, t )  W ( y, t )e  rt
W1 ( y, t )  e
1
y  (   r   02 ) t
2
Lp(
y  Ln(c)  (    02 )t
0 t
)  ce rt Lp(
y  Ln(c)  t
)
0 t
(12)
Where
r-riskless interest rate.
Second simpler and more obvious way of calculating the option price as the discounted math. expectation is the
following formula.
New York 2010
5
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com
W1 ( y, t )  e
 rt
1

 2 ( Lnx  Lny  t )
1
2 0 t
(
x

c
)
e
dx
c
2t 0 x
2
(13)
Calculation of the integral (13) leads to formula (12).
Option price formula (12) gets parameter  , which is not in the corresponding formula of [1] (page 644, formula
(13)). This parameter is one of the two parameters needed to describe a lognormal distribution, and characterizing
the systematic component of the diffusion process describing the movement of the stock price.
The authors of [1] managed to exclude from consideration this parameter by considering a portfolio consisting of
stock and a specified number of options (now called delta hedging). On the change of the price of the portfolio
and on delta hedging value  does not have effect. However, in the final formula for the price of the option  is
present.
Comparing our formula (1) and (13) on page 644 of [1], we find that the formulas coincide if and only if the
parameter is  equal
1
2
  r   02
(14)
Note that the parameter  02 in our formula corresponds to the variance rate v 2 in formula (13) [1].
From formulas (4) and (14) that according to the formula Black-Scholes average value of the rate of return of the
 x(t ) 
 equal to the interest rate r, that is not dependent on the characteristics of a
 x(0) 
stock, i.e. the mean value Ln
New York 2010
6
866 United Nations Plaza
Suite 566
New York, NY 10017
Phone: +1 212 223 3552
Fax: +1 212 421 6608
info@egartech.com
www.egartech.com
particular stock. Thus, the model of the Black-Schultz has quite specific information about the rate of return of the
stock.
References
[1] Fisher Black, Myron Scholes. “The pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities”
The Journal of Political Economy, Volume 81, Issue 3 (May-Jun., 1973), 637-654
[2] Fisher Black, Myron Scholes. The Valuation of Option Contracts and a Test of Market Efficiency.
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 27,No 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Thirtieth Annual Meeting of the American
Finance Association, New Orleans, Louisiana, December 27-29, 1971 (May ,1972), pp 399-417.
New York 2010
7
Download