Regression Analysis of Youth Labour Market Variables A weakness of the approach taken above is that it fails to control systematically for all the factors which might explain the regional differences in youth labour market performance. That is, the analysis made above may be misleading because it does not allow us to control for all the relevant variables which might account for the behaviour of key youth labour market statistics. In order to partially correct for other influences which might affect these variables, we estimated "reduced form" regression models of the youth unemployment rate, the youth employment rate, and the youth labour force participation rate, controlling for general economic conditions, provincial real minimum wage rates, and province specific effects. In order to make our data set as large as possible, we used pooled time series-cross sectional data for each of the 10 provinces over the sample period from 1976 to 1996. The idea behind regression analysis is to estimate the impact of a number of explanatory variables on a particular variable of interest. What makes empirical economics difficult is that we cannot observe directly the process which generates our data. Another confounding factor is that there are generally several variables which might affect the behaviour of a particular variable of interest. For instance, the unemployment rate among youth in Canada may be related in some way to the adult unemployment rate. However, other factors in addition to the adult unemployment rate may also influence the youth unemployment rate. Limiting our analysis to the adult and youth unemployment rate may give us misleading inferences because we have not "controlled" for the effect that other variables have on the youth unemployment rate. Hence, the purpose of regression analysis is to estimate the impacts of particular variables on the variable of interest, while controlling for the fact that other variables may also affect that variable. Regression analysis therefore allows us to determine the direction and magnitude by which one variable affects another, holding all other variables constant. A "reduced form" regression model is sometimes called a "nonstructural" regression model. The distinction between structural and non-structural (or reduced form) regression models is very important. When we estimate a reduced form model, we are simply trying to determine the direction of effect a number of independent variables have on a particular dependent variable. In contrast, the motivation behind a structural model is to uncover particular structural parameters (or economic "primitives") which govern economic behaviour. Structural models are based on a specific theoretical model and hence, provide the most direct way of testing a particular economic theory. In contrast, reduced form models are, in themselves, atheoretical. While the particular choice of explanatory variables to include in a reduced form may be governed by economic theory, no effort is made to uncover the structural parameters which are buried within the estimated reduced form coefficients. A weakness of this approach is that it is not invariant to shifts in policy regime. That is, because the structural parameters which generate the data are not directly estimated, the reduced form coefficients may be unstable when policy regimes change. Because of this inherent weakness in reduced form models, caution should be exercised when making specific policy recommendations on the basis of reduced form coefficient estimates. However, there are some advantages to using the reduced form method as opposed to the structural method. One advantage is that, under some assumptions, it still enables us to answer some questions, such as how one variable affects another, while maintaining a reasonably agnostic approach as to how the data is generated. Another advantage is that reduced form regression models are easier to construct and estimate than structural models (Davidson and MacKinnon 1993). In order to estimate a structural econometric model, one must explicitly derive an economic model and try to identify the structural parameters. Since our interest is simply to discover how some variables affect youth unemployment, employment and labour force participation rates, we will limit our attention to the reduced form approach. Table 5 presents coefficient estimates from a reduced form regression of provincial youth unemployment rates on provincial adult unemployment rates (UN), the real provincial minimum wage rate (W), and cross sectional dummies representing the 10 provinces. We incorporate adult unemployment rates in order to control for the effect of provincial economic conditions on the youth unemployment rate. The real provincial minimum wage rate is included because economic theory suggests that high real minimum wages should reduce the employment prospects of relatively unskilled workers. Since most empirical studies have found that minimum wages have a statistically significant impact on youth labour markets, it is important to control for this factor. Finally, cross sectional dummy variables are included for each provinces. These dummy variables essentially capture any province-specific difference which cannot be accounted for by minimum wages or general macroeconomic conditions. Ideally, we would like to be more explicit about these province-specific variables (which might include rates of unionization, welfare benefit rates, employment insurance rates, demographic variables) and estimate their impacts individually. However, because of data limitations, we were restricted to using dummy variables. Table 5: Reduced Form Model of the Youth Unemployment Rate, Estimated by Ordinary Least Squares Variable Name Coefficient Estimate Standard Error T-Ratio UN 1.2356 0.07284 16.96 W 0.3453 0.1015 3.403 BC 4.1229 1.022 4.034 AB 2.5232 0.8335 3.027 SK 4.0407 0.7873 5.133 MB 3.7084 0.8439 4.394 ON 3.9029 0.9539 4.097 PQ 4.0303 1.177 3.423 NB 5.9347 1.135 5.277 NS 6.1129 1.111 5.503 PE 3.0238 1.276 2.369 NF 8.2672 1.406 6.897 R-Squared Adjusted = 0.9050 Note: Standard errors were estimated using White’s (1980) heteroskedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator (HCCME). Calculations: The Fraser Institute. The results are basically in accord with our prior beliefs about the behaviour of youth unemployment rates. The high adjusted Rsquared statistic (0.90) suggests that our reduced form model can explain most of the variance in youth unemployment rates. Increases in adult unemployment rates (declines in general economic activity) have a positive and statistically significant effect on youth unemployment rates (i.e., as adult unemployment rates rise, so do youth rates). Similarly, increases in real provincial minimum wage rates also have a statistically significant and positive impact on youth unemployment rates, albeit by a fairly small amount (i.e., increases in provincial minimum wages raise youth unemployment rates). Provincial dummy variables are statistically significant and vary considerably in magnitude. Hence, it appears that province-specific factors play a very strong role in determining a province’s unemployment rate. This is not altogether surprising, since many policy variables which have a large impact on labour supply and labour demand decisions (such as welfare rates, payroll taxes, unemployment insurance benefit rates) differ across provinces. In accord with our findings from figure 6, the dummy variable for Alberta is smaller than every other province and the dummy variable for Newfoundland is higher than every other province. In other words, if all provinces had the same minimum wage and the same adult unemployment rate, Alberta would have the lowest youth unemployment rate and Newfoundland would have the highest. Table 6 presents coefficient estimates from a reduced form regression of the youth employment rate on the adult unemployment rate, the real minimum wage, and provincial dummy variables. Again, the results are in accord with our expectations. The adult unemployment rate has a negative impact on youth employment rates (i.e. the proportion of youth who are employed falls when general economic conditions decline). The impact of minimum wages on youth employment rates is also negative and statistically significant. Also, dummy variables differ significantly across provinces. Alberta’s provincial dummy is highest while Newfoundland’s is lowest. In fact, provincial dummy variables appear to become smaller as one moves farther east. Assuming that all provinces have identical adult unemployment rates and identical minimum wages, our estimates suggest that Alberta would have the highest youth employment rate while the Atlantic provinces would have the lowest. The high R-squared statistic (0.92) shows that our independent variables "explain" the bulk of the variation in the youth employment rate. Table 6: Reduced Form Model of the Youth Employment Rate (estimated using ordinary least squares) Variable Name Coefficient Standard Error T-Ratio UN -1.0483 0.1099 -9.561 W -0.8005 0.1802 -4.442 BC 71.192 1.710 41.64 AB 73.612 1.441 51.07 SK 68.826 1.370 50.23 MB 71.801 1.408 51.00 ON 70.741 1.638 43.18 PQ 65.241 1.942 33.60 NB 60.349 1.805 33.75 NS 63.349 1.760 36.00 PE 68.034 1.971 34.53 NF 54.007 2.080 25.89 R-Squared Adjusted = 0.9192 Standard errors were estimated using White’s (1980) HCCME. Calculations: The Fraser Institute. Finally, Table 7 displays coefficient estimates from our reduced form model of the youth labour force participation rate. In this case, the coefficient estimates are slightly more difficult to interpret. As one might expect, the adult unemployment rate is negatively related to the youth participation rate: the youth labour force shrinks slightly when general economic conditions decline. Furthermore, the dummy variables vary considerably across provinces and decline as one moves eastward. Interestingly, the minimum wage variable is negatively related to the labour force participation rate. This is contrary to what standard economic theory would predict: that increases in wage rates should result in increases in labour supply. Table 7: Reduced Form Model of the Youth Participation Rate (estimated using ordinary least squares) Variable Name Coefficient Standard Error T-Ratio UN -0.17555 0.08702 -2.017 W -0.74223 0.1361 -5.456 BC 74.862 1.347 55.58 AB 76.360 1.143 66.81 SK 72.245 1.138 63.81 MB 75.325 1.115 67.56 ON 74.175 1.255 59.09 PQ 67.503 1.499 45.03 NB 63.442 1.411 44.98 NS 66.802 1.373 49.67 PE 69.901 1.511 46.27 NF 67.633 1.784 38.68 R-Squared Adjusted = 0.8014 As before, standard errors were computed using White’s (1980) HCCME. Calculations: The Fraser Institute. The failure of this particular model to achieve results fully consistent with economic theory is not altogether surprising, however. This is because the participation rate equation we estimated is not, strictly speaking, a labour supply equation since we have made no effort to separately identify labour supply and labour demand shocks. That is, we have made no effort to solve the "identification problem" which is so pervasive in applied econometrics. The reason that youth labour force participation rates appear to be negatively related to the minimum wage is likely due to the fact that increases in the minimum wage rate have a stronger effect on labour demand than on labour supply. That is, when the minimum wage rises, it reduces the demand for workers and, because fewer youth can now find work, some youth withdraw from the labour force (Rottemburg 1981). Since we have not separately identified labour demand and labour supply, the coefficient estimate on the minimum wage rate in our reduced form model will likely be inaccurate. Notwithstanding the weaknesses outlined above, the general conclusion we can draw from this section are as follows. Provincial economic performance is an important determinant of youth unemployment and employment rates. Minimum wages have a small negative effect on the employment prospects for young Canadians. Finally, province-specific factors are very important determinants of youth labour market variables. Controlling for differences in minimum wages and provincial economic performance, youth unemployment is higher in the Maritimes than in either central or western Canada. Hence, youth unemployment is a fairly regional phenomenon in the Canadian context.