Department of Economics, University of Toronto Halina Kalita von dem Hagen ECO 208Y: MACROECONOMIC THEORY PROBLEM SET #2 – Solutions for Students PART I: 1. Main points: In ALL the models: 1. there is a positive relationship between output and employment in the short run, and there is a negative relationship between employment and real wage. 2. Once MS increases, LM shifts down, and AD shifts then to the right. (a) Classical Model perfect information, rational expectations, wage and price flexibility, they all cause an INSTANTANEOUS adjustment of prices to equate again the shifted AD with the unchanged AS (recall: classical AS is vertical at the full-employment level of income). Results: unchanged output (hence: unchanged employment and real wage), prices increase, LM shifts back to its original position. In the classical model we cannot make distinction between (i) and (ii) above as it violates the assumption of "perfect information". (b) Imperfect information (New Classical) model Case (i) is identical with (a) above. Case (ii): draw a positively-sloped EAS curve. Assume: fixed expectations (hence EAS does not shift) OR revised expectations (hence EAS does shift up but not as much as the AD shifted since the extent of the shock is not fully known). Either way, get the result: output deviates from its long-run level, prices increase. Since output increases, employment increases, and this means that the real wage rate must have decreased. ( c) New Keynesian model Irrelevant whether we deal with (i) or (ii) because due to the presence of contracts, agents cannot act upon the new information regarding money supply, and hence it makes no difference (at least for the time being) what they know about the shock. (Although one can also argue that the shock may affect those contracts that are being re-negotiated NOW). The short-run New Keynesian AS is flatter than the Lucas supply curve in (b) above because in (b) wages do adjust somewhat as a result of increased demand for labour, whereas in (c) nominal wage rate remains fixed. Hence in (c), output increases more than in (b), and so does employment. Consequently, a decrease in the real wage in (c) will be larger than in (b). Conclusions regarding the effectiveness of monetary policy In the long-run: 1. all agents learn about the shock, and correctly revise their expectations; 2. all contracts may be re-negotiated. Hence, in the long run, both (b) and (c) "collapse" into (a), which means: output returns to its long-run equilibrium, and so do employment and real wage. The only lasting consequence of the monetary expansion is an increase in the price level. In the short-run: monetary policy is most effective within the New Keynesian framework because of the nominal wage rigidity. Its effectiveness within the New Classical model depends on the information held by the agents regarding the shock. In the classical framework, monetary policy is neutral. 1 PART II: Evaluate the following statements. Carefully explain your reasoning: 1. Residential fixed investment is more sensitive to changes in r than the non-residential fixed investment is. Lags in the investment process weaken further the link between investment and r. Since MPI is higher in A than in B, the product-market multiplier in A is greater than in B. These features of investment demand will make the IS curve in country A flatter than in country B. Draw two differently sloped intersecting IS curves. Through their intersection point, draw the LM curve. This is your original equilibrium, the same for country A and B. The monetary policy shifts the LM curve. Mark the resulting equilibria for each country (i.e. the intersection points between the shifted LM curve and the two IS curves). Compare them to the original equilibrium. Conclude: The steeper IS, the smaller change in Y that results from the LM shift. It follows that the monetary policy is more effective in country A (i.e., with the flatter IS curve) – this part of the statement is true. The fiscal policy case is trickier. Recall how the fiscal policy works within the model: for example, an increase in G expands income. The money market is out of equilibrium, r has to increase to offset an increase in demand for money triggered by higher income. However, higher r decreases investment, triggering thus a fall in income. The decrease in income related to falling investment offsets the initial increase in income related to increasing government spending. This is the essence of the crowding-out effect. The effectiveness of the fiscal policy will weaken therefore with a higher interest-rate elasticity of investment. On this account, ceteris paribus, fiscal policy would be less effective in country A (i.e., YI below will be high in A). However, the final effect of the fiscal policy is given by: Ynet = ( YG - YI) * product-market multiplier It follows that the higher the marginal propensity to invest (i.e., the higher the product-market multiplier) the more effective, ceteris paribus, fiscal policy would be. On this account, fiscal policy will work better in A. On the basis of the original information it is impossible to conclude then in which country fiscal policy would be more effective. 2. You can address this issue in ONE of the following ways: A. State that the statement is false, and discuss the New Keynesian model to support your argument. Conclude: the presence of contracts prevents agents from adjusting to policy changes during the duration of contracts. Hence, even when economic agents do understand consequences of the policy, and they correctly revise their expectations, they cannot act upon this information, and hence output may deviate from its long-run level as a result of such policy shocks introduced during the duration of contracts. B. The above statement is certainly true in the imperfect-information models: whenever price level deviates from its forecast AND whenever the changes in the firm's own price are only 2 partially attributed to the changes in the general price level (i.e. b is smaller than 1), then output will deviate from its natural level only as a result of expectational errors. The above is true in some sense also within the New Keynesian framework: contracts are conditioned on the expectations on the future policies. With no shocks, employment would remain at its natural level during the duration of the contract, and hence the above statement would be true. However, if contracts in the economy are staggered, there will be some inertia in the wage-setting, and hence at least part of the output deviations could be explained on this basis. Moreover, one can argue that the statement is false within the short-run New Keynesian framework for the reasons discussed in A above. 3. This is a straightforward question on the New Classical model: assume perfectly flexible prices and wages, and imperfect information. Firms observe immediately prices of their own products, and only with some delay they learn about movements in the general price level. In the meantime, they form expectations regarding this general price level. They change their output only if their price changed IN RELATION TO other prices. Whenever their price rises, they attribute part of this increase to the change in relative prices (and accordingly, they increase their output), and part of it - to the unexpected change in the general price level (which does not affect their production). If they make mistakes regarding the weigths attributed to the relative and general price change, then their output (and hence the aggregate output) will deviate from its full employment level. Hence the statement is true ONLY IF we also assume perfect information (and rational expectations). Otherwise, it is false. 4. In the classical model the aggregate supply curve is always vertical. Perfect information and perfect price and wage flexibility ensure that the economy is always at the natural level of employment and output. The slope (i.e. the elasticity) of the labour supply is irrelevant for the slope of the AS. In the New Keynesian model, the nominal wage rate is fixed by a contract. The labour supply becomes then horizontal in the short-run at the contractual W (i.e. it is perfectly elastic). The slope of the AS will therefore be determined only by the slope of the labour demand. The New Classical case merits a consideration only if we assume mistaken expectations (since otherwise the New Classical model is reduced to the Classical one). Draw two differently sloped labour supply curves, initially intersecting labour demand at the same point. Assume fixed price expectations by workers (so that the labour supply curves do not move). Shift then the labour demand upward (or downward) as a result of higher (lower) than expected prices in product markets. Show the new levels of employment as determined by the new labour demand curve and the two labour supply curves. Note that the flatter (i.e. the more elastic) labour supply is, the more level of employment changes. Given the production function, this means that the flatter the labour supply, the more output changes for any given change in prices. Hence the statement is true within the New Classical framework with mistaken price expectations. (This also explains why the New Keynesian Aggregate Supply is always flatter than the New Classical Aggregate Supply.) 3 5. The increase in money supply shifts the LM curve to the right, and hence it shifts the aggregate demand to the right. This will cause prices to increase in the long run, and since the AD shift is partly anticipated, rational agents revise upwards their price expectations. Consequently, the expectations-augmented aggregate supply shifts upward, but it shifts by less than the AD shifted because the strength of the AD shift is underestimated. The new equilibrium is determined by the intersection of the new AD and EAS curves (point A). The actual price level increases, and so does the output. The increase in output implies a higher level of employment. Since the higher level of employment reduces the marginal product of labour, and profitmaximization requires the equality of MPL with real wages, it follows that the real wage rate decreases. 6. Draw the AD-AS graph, start with the long-run equilibrium at A, expected and actual prices are PA. Assume that the Aggregate Demand is expected to shift upwards. Due to this expectation, rational agents will expect higher prices, let’s say: PB. This expectation leads workers to demand higher nominal wages at each level of their working effort, to which firms concede as they expect that their higher cost will be compensated by higher prices. As a result, the New Classical Aggregate Supply (NCAS, EAS, Lucas’ supply curve) shifts upward. However, by assumption – the rumours are unsubstantiated, i.e. the Aggregate Demand does not shift. The short-run equilibrium is where the shifted EAS curve based on expected prices PB intersects the actual (non-shifted) Aggregate Demand: at S. Compare the equilibrium at S to the one at A. At S, output Y is lower. Since output is lower, employment N is lower (assumption #1 of the Aggregate Supply models). Lower employment implies higher Marginal Product of Labour MPL (assumption #2 of the models). And given that the firms at all times equalize MPL with real wages W/P (assumption #3 of the model), real wages are now higher. Adjustments towards the long-run equilibrium Note that at S actual prices are below the expected prices: PS < PB = Pe Firms and workers therefore revise their expectations, in particular – they lower them. As long as expectations are above PA, the actual prices will continue to be lower than expected prices, and agents will continue revising their expectations downwards, towards A. Similarly, if they lower their expectations below PA, the actual prices will be above the expected one, causing the agents to revise their price expectations upward. As expectations are revised, the EAS curve will keep shifting, reflecting the underlying changes in nominal wages established in the labour market. Expectations stop being revised only once the “truth” is discovered, i.e. when expected prices will equal PA again. Only at that level of prices, expectations are the same as the reality. This happens in the long run. So, in the long run, we are back to the initial position at A = L. Output returns to its initial (long-run, full-employment, natural) level, and so do employment, marginal product of labour and real wages. So: the statement is true in the short run (rumours, if credible, may have real effects on all the variables listed) but not in the long run (the truth is discovered, and only the reality matters – and not the rumours). PART III: Multiple choice answers 1C 2C 3C 4C 5D 6B 7C 8A 9D 10B 11D 12C 13D 14A 15C 16D 4