A Nation of Immigrants: Assimilation and Economic Outcomes in the Age of Mass Migration Ran Abramitzky Stanford and NBER Leah Boustan Katherine Eriksson UCLA and UCLA NBER Larger project: age of mass migration (1850-1913) We construct large panel datasets to analyze economic decisions & outcomes of trans-Atlantic migrants Origin (Europe : Norway): compare migrants with stayers 1. 2. Linking migrants across population censuses Possible with historical censuses: “72-year rule” allows to link people by name, age, birthplace Identifying selection of migrants using sibling-pairs Role of childhood environment in migration Destination (US): compare migrants and 2nd generation migrants from 16 European countries with US natives Today’s paper: migrants’ performance in US Why focus on this period? Mass migration episode: European countries lost quarter of their population through mass migration. In 1910, 22% of US labor force was foreign born 1. 2. Large enough to affect labor supply and economic development on both sides of the Atlantic US open border policy allows us to focus on migrant decisions, free of immigrant selection policies Question 1: How did European immigrants perform relative to US natives? How did migrants perform in labor markets upon first arrival? Did migrants converge to natives? Convergence: a migrant starts below natives & catches up over time How did their children fare in the US labor market? Economic outcome is occupation. We match occupation to median earnings [details later] Limitation: only capture convergence in occupations, not within-occupation income convergence Question 2: How were return migrants selected from migrant pool? Were return migrants positively or negatively selected from the migrant pool? Important because over 25% of migrants returned home (Gould, 1980; Bandiera, Rasul & Viarengo, 2010) Conceptually, nature of selection of return migrants is ambiguous Negatively selected: If migrants who were not successful in US returned home Positively selected: If migrants intended to go back home, and more productive migrants reached “saving targets” faster Why challenging to address these basic questions? Because of a lack of historical panel dataset Previous literature mostly relies on cross-sectional data Inferring convergence from a cross section raises well-known biases (Borjas 1985, Duleep & Dowhan 2002, Lubotsky 2007) We construct panel of 24,000 men from 16 sending countries in 1900-1920 using census manuscripts (in Ancestry, then digitizing) Paper in a nutshell: Inferring convergence from the data Data Wage 25 years Panel A A A 100 80 60 B Repeated cross-section Same immigration cohort Cross-section C D 40 5 years 1895 1900 1915 Immigrants A and B arrived in 1895 and stayed Year 1920 Convergence Wage Immigrants C and D arrived in 1915 and stayed Negatively selected return migration 100 90 A A,B Decline in cohort quality Panel A A,B RCS CS 50 C,D 5 25 Years in US Rest of the talk A word on historical context Building a panel dataset, 1900-20 Results for full immigrant population Results by country of origin Mechanisms Outcomes of the 2nd generation Assimilation through marriage “New immigrants” and assimilation Big concerns in US at the time about migrants Migrants have low natural intelligence Poverty in immigrant neighborhoods and low levels of school attendance of immigrant children Nativist view: new arrivals would not be able to assimilate Progressive reformer view: immigrant behavior could be changed Initiated public legislation, including child labor laws and schooling requirements to aid immigrant communities Assimilation and temporary migration Immigration Commission (1911) concluded that migrants (especially from Southern/Eastern Europe) would not be able to assimilate Concluded that immigration was a threat to economic and social fabric of the US Temporary migration in part to blame “If an immigrant intends to remain permanently in the US and become an American citizen, he naturally begins at once… to fit himself for the conditions of his new life…If, on the other hand, he intends his sojourn in this country to be short… acquisition of the English language will be of little consequence… The chief aim of a person with this intention is to put money in his purse… not for investment here but for investment in his home country.” -- Jenks and Lauck, Dillingham Commission investigators (1922) Provided fuel for literacy test (1917) & quotas (1924) Building panel dataset Panel of 24,000 native and immigrant men from 16 sending countries Ages 18-35 in 1900; immigrants arrived before 1900; exclude US south We use iterative procedure to match individuals by name, age and place of birth from 1900 to 1910/20 Note: need to be able to search complete 1910/20 censuses for procedure (use Ancestry, then digitize) Match rates: 19% of natives, 13% foreign-born (to both 1910 & 1920) Illustrating our matching procedure Is matched sample representative of population? [details] Estimating migrant-native convergence Estimate age-earnings profiles using cross-sections, repeated cross-sections, panel Outcome = occupation score. Occupation-based earnings, expressed in 2010 dollars. 125 occupations [details] Occupation score = f(age, Census yr, country-of-origin and…) Years in the US indicators aggregated to 5-yr intervals Arrival cohort indicator (before/after 1890) j = country of origin; m = year of arrival; t = Census year; t-m = years spent in US Regressions: Tables Figure 2: Convergence in occupation score between immigrants and native-born workers by years spent in the US Years in the US Figure 2: Convergence in occupation score between immigrants and native-born workers by years spent in the US Years in the US Cohort quality Figure 2: Convergence in occupation score between immigrants and native-born workers by years spent in the US CS RCS Panel Occupation-based earnings (in 2010 dollars) 800 400 Negatively selected return migration 0 0-5 yrs 6-10 yrs 11-20 yrs 21-30 yrs 30+ yrs Years in the US -400 Cohort quality -800 -1200 -1600 Alternative specifications [details] Concern: other sources of selective attrition [details] Drop immigrants who arrived as children Interact country FE * arrival cohort dummies Match occupations to 1900 earnings [details] Subdivide into finer arrival cohorts Robustness to farmers’ earnings Add state FE and state FE * urban area (endogenous, but can shed light on mechanism) Compare earning distributions of migrants and natives Log(occupation-based earnings) instead of occupationbased earnings Heterogeneity across countries Permanent immigrants from five countries held higherpaid occupations than US natives upon first arrival English-speaking countries: England, Scotland, Wales, plus Russia and France Permanent migrants from six countries held lower-paid occupations than US natives Permanent migrants from most sending countries appear to experience occupational upgrading over time similar to natives Heterogeneity by country is important to consider… 2000 1000 0 -5000 -4000 -3000 -2000 -1000 Occupation-based earnings (in 2010 dollars) 3000 4000 Figure 3: Occupation-based earning gap, permanent immigrants upon first arrival (0-5 years in US) vs. natives by country of origin. Panel data 2000 1000 0 -5000 -4000 -3000 -2000 -1000 Occupation-based earnings (in 2010 dollars) 3000 4000 Figure 3: Occupation-based earning gap, permanent immigrants vs. natives upon first arrival (0-5 years in US) and after 30+ years, by country of origin. Panel data 0-5 years in the US 30+ years in the US Selection of return migrants by country We infer selection of return migrants by comparing convergence in panel and repeated C-S Significantly negatively selected return to five countries (England, Italy, Norway, Russia and Switzerland) Significantly positively selected return to one country (Finland) Adjust for (small) differences in return rates: multiply each coefficient by the ratio of the average migration rate to the country’s actual migration rate Magnitudes do not change Exception: even more negative selection to Russia Figure 5: Implied selection of return migrants, by country of origin. Difference between estimated 1000 0 -1000 -2000 -3000 -4000 -5000 -6000 Occupation-based earnings (in 2010 dollars) 2000 3000 convergence in panel and repeated cross-section data Direct evidence on return migration to Norway 1910 Norwegian census added supplement: return migrants were asked when they moved to US, when they returned, and occupation held in US We compare US occupational distribution in 1910 of Norwegian migrants who stayed in US vs. returned Migrants who returned had occupations paying $1,659 less on average Remarkably similar to indirect inference from comparing panel and repeated cross section (-$1,757) Explaining cross-country variation in immigrant performance [details] Regress country coefficients on country characteristics Migrant countries that fared better in US: Note: Only 16 countries and no exogenous variation, so these relationships are merely suggestive had higher real wages in 1880 had more similar culture, language and religious Low correlation between countries performance in US and: population pressure (rates of natural population increase) health conditions (measured by infant mortality) 2nd generation migrants How do 2nd generation migrants perform in US labor markets? 1. 2. Convergence may take more than one generation 2nd generation migrants educated in US: likely fluent in English and possibly exposed to US norms and culture Differences can persist over generations: if lived in migrant enclaves or inherited occupational skills from parents We find persistence over generations: if 1st generation out- (under-)performs natives, so does 2nd generation Occupation score comparisons for immigrants from England nd 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 Assimilation of 2 generation migrants All areas 20 30 40 50 Age Immigrants, 1900-1920 Sepa rate regressi on for e ach li ne. Further restricti on on ages between 20 and 60 i n regressio n # obs i n (i mm i gra nts 19 00-20, natives 1900 -20 ) reg s are (2261,1351 4) re specti vel y Gra phs pl otted for in dividu als ag ed 25 i n 1900 T he graph for assum es im m ig ratio n year 189 0 Sons of US born parents, 1900-1920 Occupation score comparisons for immigrants from England nd 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 Assimilation of 2 generation migrants All areas 20 30 40 50 Age Immigrants, 1900-1920 Sons of US born parents, 1900-1920 Sons of immigrants, 1920-1950 Sons of US born parents, 1920-1950 Sepa rate regressi on for e ach li ne. Further restricti on on ages between 20 and 60 i n regressio n # obs i n (i mm i gra nts 19 00-20, natives 1900 -20 , im m igrants' sons 1920-50, na ti ves 19 20-5 0) re gs are (2261 ,135 14,4 957,33542 ) respecti vel y Gra phs pl otted for fi rst-ge n an d secon d-ge n i ndi vi dual s aged 25 i n 19 00 a nd 1920 re specti vel y Gra phs pl otted for natives in the sam e ages as the fi rst- or second -gen erati on im m igrants 2nd gen erati on im m igrants are sons to m other a nd father bo rn Engl and T he graph for the first-g enerati on im m i gran ts assum e im m i grati on year 18 90 Occupation score comparisons for immigrants from Norway nd 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 Assimilation of 2 generation migrants All areas 20 30 40 50 Age Immigrants, 1900-1920 Sepa rate regressi on for e ach li ne. Further restricti on on ages between 20 and 60 i n regressio n # obs i n (i mm i gra nts 19 00-20, natives 1900 -20 ) reg s are (1435,1351 4) re specti vel y Gra phs pl otted for in dividu als ag ed 25 i n 1900 T he graph for assum es im m ig ratio n year 189 0 Sons of US born parents, 1900-1920 Occupation score comparisons for immigrants from Norway nd 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 Assimilation of 2 generation migrants All areas 20 30 40 50 Age Immigrants, 1900-1920 Sons of US born parents, 1900-1920 Sons of immigrants, 1920-1950 Sons of US born parents, 1920-1950 Sepa rate regressi on for e ach li ne. Further restricti on on ages between 20 and 60 i n regressio n # obs i n (i mm i gra nts 19 00-20, natives 1900 -20 , im m igrants' sons 1920-50, na ti ves 19 20-5 0) re gs are (1435 ,135 14,3 976,33542 ) respecti vel y Gra phs pl otted for fi rst-ge n an d secon d-ge n i ndi vi dual s aged 25 i n 19 00 a nd 1920 re specti vel y Gra phs pl otted for natives in the sam e ages as the fi rst- or second -gen erati on im m igrants 2nd gen erati on im m igrants are sons to m other a nd father bo rn Norway T he graph for the first-g enerati on im m i gran ts assum e im m i grati on year 18 90 Difference in predicted occupational score between migrants (1st and 2nd generation) and natives First generation Second generation 8 6 4 2 SS R/ Ru ss ia ot la nd Sc la nd En g ce Fr an lan d Ire ale s W a Ge rm an y st ri Au Ita ly en Sw ed m Be lgi u De nm ar k er lan d wa y la nd Fin Sw izt Ot he rU -2 No r Po rtu ga l 0 -4 Predicted values are for males aged 35 in 1910 and who immigrated in 1890 (for 1st generation) Assimilation through marriage [details] What about cultural assimilation of immigrants? Look at inter-marriage between immigrants and US natives Endogamy could reflect preferences or constraints We find strong endogamy among 1st generation immigrants; less endogamy among 2nd generation Strong cross-country persistence of in-group marriage rates across generations Migrants from countries with better-paid occupations somewhat less likely to marry within same country Conclusions Contrary to conventional wisdom, in early 20th century, long term migrants: Apparent convergence in CS data between immigrants and natives driven by: didn’t hold lower-paid occupations than US natives experienced similar occupational upgrading over time lower occupational quality of later immigrant cohorts lower occupational quality of temporary/return migrants Substantial variation by country Persistence in labor & marriage patterns over generations Other sources of selective attrition Any form of selective attrition of migrants vs. natives could drive assimilation-pattern differences between panel and repeated CS: 1. Selective mortality: Quantitatively less important than return migration For natives, repeated cross sections are similar to panel, implying selective mortality is non-issue for them Direct data on mortality by country of origin and by occupation (from death registries) Other sources of selective attrition [back] 2. Selective name changes: Name changes that occurred upon entry to US (before we first observe migrants) are non-issue Men who changed name between censuses would not be in panel but stay in repeated CS before & after name change Foreign-born men in panel have slightly more “foreign” names than their foreign-born counterparts in the CS An indication they may have changed name Difference in the “foreignness” index is associated with only a $60 difference in occupation-based earnings Other sources of selective attrition [back] The “foreignness” index: first calculating probability of being foreign born conditional on having a given first name (and, separately, a given last name) in the 1900-20 IPUMS samples The “foreignness” index is then the sum of the two probabilities; the index varies between zero and two. Foreign-born men in the cross-section (panel sample) have an index value of 1.13 (1.23) Matching procedure Potential 1900 population to be matched: Men aged 18-35 Small sending countries: find all migrants who moved to US between 1880-1900 Big sending countries and natives: start with all migrants in 5% Integrated Public Use Microdata Series (IPUMS) sample Matching procedure STEP 1: Standardize first and last names of men in 1900 sample to address orthographic differences between phonetically equivalent names using the NYSIIS algorithm (Atack & Bateman,1992) Men who are unique by first and last name, birth year, and place of birth (state or country) in 1900 become candidates for our matching procedure Matching procedure STEP 2: Identify potential matches in 1910 and 1920 by searching for all men in our 1900 sample in the 1910 and 1920 Census manuscripts For small sending countries, we compile complete populations of men with relevant sample characteristics in 1910 and 1920 For large sending countries and native born, we use the (expansive) Ancestry.com algorithm to search for candidate matches in 1910 and 1920; this search returns many potential matches for each case, which we cull using the iterative match procedure described in the next step STEP 3. Iterative matching procedure We start by looking for a match by first name, last name, place of birth (state or country) and reported birth year Three possibilities: 1. If find a unique match, stop and consider the observation “matched” If find multiple matches for same birth year, observation is thrown out If do not find a match, we try matching first within a oneyear band (older and younger) and then with a two-year band around the reported birth year; only accepts unique matches 2. 3. If these attempts do not produce a match, observation is thrown out Table 1: Match rates by country [back] Country 1900 # in universe A. 1900 source: IPUMS Number matched Match rate, total 1900 # unique Match rate, unique Austria England France Germany Ireland Italy Norway Russia Sweden 4,722 7,296 11,615 19,855 9,737 6,649 3,541 5,641 6,164 397 916 728 2,891 1,115 1,076 575 771 633 0.084 0.126 0.063 0.146 0.115 0.162 0.162 0.136 0.102 -- -- US natives 10,000 1,891 0.190 -- -- 545 1,980 828 584 4,349 3,311 1,342 0.090 0.058 0.035 0.046 0.082 0.149 0.076 5,962 17,425 22,197 8,362 15,529 20,588 9,876 0.091 0.114 0.037 0.070 0.280 0.161 0.135 B. 1900 source: Ancestry.com Belgium 6,060 Denmark 34,594 Finland 23,843 Portugal 12,585 Scotland 53,091 Switzerland 22,276 Wales 17,767 Occupation-based earnings No individual information about wages or income in 1900-20 Census; only occupation is observed We collect occupation string by hand from the historical manuscripts on Ancestry.com How to use occupations meaningfully? Assign individuals median income in their reported occupation from 1950 income distribution (“OCCSCORE” variable) Other ways: social class, education required, etc 1. 2. Occupation-based earnings [back] Reliance on occupation-based earnings in 1950 is a concern. The decades of the 1940s and 1950s were a period of wage compression (Goldin and Margo, 1992) For example, if immigrants were clustered in low-paying occupations, the occupation score variable may understate both their initial earnings penalty and the convergence implied by moving up the occupational ladder To address this concern, we match our occupations to the 1901 Cost of Living survey (which has several disadvantages). We get larger initial penalty, but otherwise similar results Table 2: Common occupations for natives and foreign-born in matched samples, 1920 [back] 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. Total Occupation Farmer Manager Laborer Salesman Operative Clerical Carpenter Machinist Farm laborer Foreman Natives Freq. 352 129 117 75 71 45 45 45 39 27 945 Percent 24.82 9.10 8.25 5.28 5.00 3.17 3.17 3.17 2.75 1.90 66.61 Foreign-born Occupation Freq. Farmer 3,301 Manager 1,999 Laborer 1,791 Operative 1,102 Foreman 603 Mine operative 596 Machinist 578 Carpenter 529 Salesman 495 Clerical 326 11,320 Percent 18.09 10.95 9.81 6.04 3.30 3.27 3.17 2.90 2.71 1.79 62.03 Is matched sample representative of population? Men in both panel and repeated CS must have survived and remained in US until 1920 By 1920, up to sampling error: any difference between cross-section and panel (given age 38-55; arrive by 1900) due to imperfect matching Concern: men with uncommon names and consistent age reporting are more likely to be successfully linked between Censuses. Both may be correlated with socioeconomic status Table 3: Comparing matched samples with the population, 1920 [back] Mean, Panel sample Native born $23,187 Foreign born $24,215 Difference, Panel sample - population Levels Logs 52.92 0.010 (301.546) (0.013) 368.75 (127.42) 0.024 (0.006) Table 4: Age-earnings profile for natives and the foreign-born, Cross-sections by year 1900 1910 1920 0-5 yrs in US -1.208 (0.196) -1.553 (0.254) -1.106 (0.101) -1.697 (0.148) -1.330 (0.295) -2.019 (0.313) 6-10 yrs in US -0.104 (0.164) -0.399 (0.260) -0.500 (0.127) -1.022 (0.167) -1.168 (0.126) -2.375 (0.161) 11-20 yrs in US 0.258 (0.114) 0.153 (0.253) 0.472 (0.122) 0.027 (0.171) -0.045 (0.101) -1.081 (0.140) 21-30 yrs in US 0.485 (0.181) 0.428 (0.296) 0.411 (0.122) 0.172 (0.187) 0.707 (0.155) -0.189 (0.191) 30+ yrs in US 0.591 (0.215) 0.401 (0.325) 0.077 (0.211) -0.245 (0.260) 0.695 (0.159) -0.117 (0.215) Age 0.383 (0.009) 0.384 (0.009) 0.359 (0.008) 0.361 (0.008) 0.337 (0.008) 0.337 (0.008) Age > 35 14.263 (0.420) 14.317 (0.419) 13.345 (0.358) 13.249 (0.358) 12.443 (0.345) 12.504 (0.345) Age * Age > 35 -0.441 (0.011) -0.443 (0.011) -0.409 (0.010) -0.407 (0.010) -0.385 (0.009) -0.386 (0.009) Constant 12.153 (0.228) 12.118 (0.228) 13.697 (0.198) 13.665 (0.198) 15.317 (0.200) 15.265 (0.199) Country FE? N Y N Y N Y N 119,538 159,092 169,296 119,538 159,092 169,296 Notes: IPUMS data, men aged 18-55 in labor force. Contains same set of countries as in matched sample. “Implied Convergence” = 30+ yrs in US – 0-5 years in the US. For columns 2, 4 and 6, omitted country = Italy. [back] Table 5: OLS estimates, Age-earnings profile for natives and foreign-born, 1900-1920, Occupation-based earnings in $2010 dollars (1) Cross-section RHS variable (2) Pooled cross-section and panel 0-5 yrs in US -1184.27 (223.14) (a) Cross-section coefficients -302.72 (193.96) (b) Panel coefficients 279.67 (287.57) 6-10 yrs US -673.57 (200.01) 66.16 (176.39) 447.92 (254.85) 11-20 yrs US -378.28 (171.53) 139.52 (135.57) 396.15 (171.07) 21-30 yrs US -273.55 (179.52) 136.59 (139.29) 222.87 (170.96) 30 yrs in US -18.00 (217.551) 98.79 (182.72) 91.17 (216.03) Arrive 1891+ --- -756.38 (110.07) -360.47 (188.92) Native born --- --- -118.68 (167.99) [back] Alexander James in 1900 Alexander James in 1910 Alexander James in 1920 [back] Mass migration from Europe 1850-1913 [back] Alternative specifications (page 1/4) 0-5 years in US A. Without country FE Panel RCS 1236.04 -123.99 (277.75) (178.15) B. 4 arrival cohorts Panel RCS 644.31 73.60 (334.01) (229.34) C. Country x cohort FE Panel RCS 521.42 17.72 (330.27) (257.03) 6-10 yrs in US 372.09 (151.04) 1473.64 (240.27) 113.55 (204.25) 298.21 (293.17) 347.48 (235.99) 611.45 (298.15) 11-20 yrs in US 484.47 (95.872) 1360.54 (144.08) 254.71 (161.86) 418.23 (203.48) 450.95 (210.00) 606.50 (233.08) 21-30 yrs in US 441.59 (101.17) 1187.24 (143.25) 222.50 (162.18) 225.95 (201.39) 426.23 (211.82) 430.14 (233.30) 30+ yrs in US 290.43 (153.28) 1003.94 (191.62) 194.68 (194.15) 113.79 (231.63) 410.13 (244.42) 324.87 (271.49) N 262,248 262,248 262,248 Alternative specifications (2/4) 0-5 years in US D. ln(occupation score) RCS Panel 0.052 0.097 (0.010) (0.013) E. Raise farmer income RCS Panel -656.50 -14.28 (189.66) (281.89) F. 1900 income RCS Panel -3229.19 -2684.36 (153.61) (243.84) 6-10 yrs in US 0.066 (0.008) 0.088 (0.012) -328.66 (172.13) 138.39 (248.69) -2694.53 (146.11) -1905.97 (211.46) 11-20 yrs in US 0.064 (0.006) 0.076 (0.008) -237.93 (132.72) 54.00 (167.11) -2262.48 (116.32) -1902.43 (143.81) 21-30 yrs in US 0.053 (0.006) 0.065 (0.007) -219.24 (136.21) -112.75 (166.18) -2059.95 (117.98) -1933.76 (145.53) 30+ yrs in US 0.042 (0.008) 0.052 (0.009) -225.82 (176.29) -206.18 (207.30) -1823.73 (141.41) -1833.61 (170.24) N 262,248 262,248 264,338 Alternative specifications (3/4) 0-5 years in US G. Drop child migrants Panel RCS 233.82 -393.57 (296.34) (199.28) H. State FE Panel RCS -1304.36 -1668.94 (443.40) (199.36) I. State * urban FE Panel RCS -1734.13 -2234.38 (443.61) (198.16) 6-10 yrs in US -69.63 (183.52) 312.48 (266.25) -1296.98 (191.95) -831.86 (342.69) -2022.29 (190.84) -1304.84 (345.44) 11-20 yrs in US -23.83 (148.76) 190.52 (191.50) -1204.18 (158.29) -730.71 (257.41) -1869.18 (157.95) -962.62 (252.69) 21-30 yrs in US 145.43 (152.17) 118.38 (195.11) -1084.33 (164.63) -1267.70 (229.37) -1668.38 (164.32) -1229.44 (231.92) 30+ yrs in US 130.07 (208.89) 139.59 (256.89) -1018.07 (196.78) -677.59 (231.55) -1547.67 (194.03) -550.95 (232.55) N 246,365 228,793 227,930 Alternative specifications (4/4) [back] Occupation-based earnings distribution, 1900-20 th 10 Cross-section Immigrants Natives $9,900 $8,100 Panel Immigrants $12,550 Natives $8,100 25th $18,000 $12,550 $18,000 $12,550 50th $20,700 $20,700 $20,700 $20,700 75th $22,500 $25,200 $23,400 $25,200 90th $28,800 $34,200 $30,600 $34,200 99th $37,800 $55,800 $37,800 $56,700 Assimilation through inter-marriage First generation 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 Second generation Relationship between first generation immigrant earnings gap and second generation endogamy rates [back] Share of second-generation men married to first or second generation woman 0.7 Finland 0.6 Russia Italy Portugal 0.5 0.4 Norway Ireland Belgium 0.3 Austria Germany Sweden 0.2 Wales Denmark England 0.1 Switzerland France Scotland 0 -5000 -4000 -3000 -2000 -1000 0 1000 Initial earnings gap with natives, immigrants in the US 0-5 years 2000 3000 4000 Explaining cross-country variation in immigrant performance [back] Mean/standard deviation of RHS variable Univariate regression* -6526.86 (3113.67) Multivariate regression: Add economic variable** -7476.85 (3619.31) Multivariate regression: Add cultural variables*** 3546.71 (4309.10) 0.466 (0.172) Real wage 57.726 (25.636) 43.93 (24.67) 23.70 (23.77) 12.79 (17.28) Natural increase 10.406 (3.635) -7.62 (169.49) -85.76 (156.14) -206.82 (105.02) Infant mortality rate 174.933 (54.934) 10.02 (10.15) 16.09 (9.48) 7.35 (8.19) Linguistic distance 0.526 (0.344) -3419.61 (1534.52) -2229.88 (2540.56) 1090.03 (1860.67) Cultural distance 1.053 (0.588) -2999.37 (677.38) -2610.20 (961.15) -1848.62 (920.47) Religious similarity 0.852 (0.045) 39,433.23 (8484.51) 39,140.04 (11,222.16) 22,244.94 (12,943.87) Characteristic of sending country (RHS variable) Share in agriculture