The Economics of Happiness and Health Andrew Oswald IZA and Warwick I would like to acknowledge that much of this work is joint with coauthors Chris Boyce, Andrew Clark, Nick Powdthavee, David G. Blanchflower, and Steve Wu. This week I’d like to propose a number of ideas. #1 ‘Happiness’ data offer us interesting potential as proxy-utility data. u = u(y, z, ..) Regression equations Mental well-being = f(Age, gender, education level, income, marital status, friendship networks, region, year…) We now know: • There is a lot of regularity in these regression-equation patterns, across countries and well-being measures. • Fairly robust to panel estimators and different methods. • Progress can be made on causality. One potentially important implication: If this form of function can be estimated (and K, L, M are life events): Happiness = a + bK + cL + dM +eY where Y is income, If this form of function can be estimated (and K, L, M are life events): Happiness = a + bK + cL + dM +eY where Y is income, then we may be able to use such equations to calculate the implied dollar value of the happiness from life events K, L, M. Monetary equivalences A life satisfaction equation: Life satisfaction = B1*income + B2*Event + error Marriage - $100,000 (Blanchflower and Oswald, 2004), Neuroticism - $314,000 (Boyce et al., in press), Widowhood – ($175,000-$496,000), Health limiting daily activities ($473,000) (Powdthavee, van den Berg, 2011) #2 The next 20 years are likely to see economists work more and more with physiological and hard-science data. #3 Biomarker data will (slowly) be used more and more in economics. #4 Empirically, there are strong relative effects on utility: #4 Empirically, there are strong relative effects on utility: u = u(y, y*) eg. if y* is others’ incomes. #5 A crucial role in social-science behaviour is played by the second derivative, v″, of the function utility = v(relative status)+ .. In humans (I shall argue) • Concavity of v(.) leads to imitation and herd behaviour • Convexity of v(.) leads to deviance. #6 The Stiglitz Commission’s ideas will eventually take hold. Stiglitz Report 2009: “Measures of .. objective and subjective wellbeing provide key information about people’s quality of life. Statistical offices [worldwide] should incorporate questions to capture people’s life evaluations, hedonic experiences … in their own survey.” P.16. Executive Summary of Commission Report. So........ Could we perhaps learn … ..how to make whole countries happier? Preferably not like this… Germany 4 England 1 Germany 4 England 1 Useful introductions • “Relative Income, Happiness and Utility: An Explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and Other Puzzles” (Andrew Clark, Paul Frijters and Mike Shields), Journal of Economic Literature, 2008. • The Happiness Equation (Nick Powdthavee), Icon Books, 2010. This is a good time for general questions if people would like to ask some? Now let’s think about how human beings report their feelings (for example, in a survey). • First, they have genuine feelings inside themselves (about how happy they are, say). • Second, they make a decision about how to report those feelings. There are then two processes going on inside a person. Human feelings Human reporting • Let’s think of the example of money and people’s well-being. Assume Assume People get true happiness, h, from income, y. Call it h(y). Assume People get true happiness, h, from income, y. Call it h(y). They give a number for this, which is their reported happiness, r. Call it r(h). The Reporting Function The Reporting Function Write R(y) which is reported happiness as a function of income. This is what is studied in wellbeing regression equations. Now think of the function-of-afunction rule in calculus. By definition R(y) = r(h(y)) By definition R(y) = r(h(y)) so Rʹ(y) = rʹ(h) hʹ(y) > 0 where y is income. In the cross-section, income is positively correlated with happiness Take America in 1994 for example From Deaton-Kahneman in PNAS 2010 Now let’s think of the second derivative The first derivative earlier was: Rʹ(y) = rʹ(h) hʹ(y) The first derivative earlier was: Rʹ(y) = rʹ(h) hʹ(y) where y is income, r is reported happiness, h is actual happiness. Think of the second derivative The curvature of reported happiness is Think of the second derivative The curvature of reported happiness is R″(y) = r″(h) hʹ(y) hʹ(y) + rʹ(h) h″(y) But if R″(y) is found to be negative that does not prove that h″(y) is negative. R is reported happiness h is true happiness Hence there are lots and lots of papers in the literature that get this wrong. Reiterating why: The curvature of reported happiness is R″(y) = r″(y) hʹ(y) hʹ(y) + rʹ(h) h″(y) Even if the estimated happiness function itself is concave, we cannot be certain that true happiness is concave. All social scientists (and many medical scientists) need to know more about the reporting function. • So is there any way to make progress on this tricky issue? Height as an example 113 Men and 106 Women • The respondents were asked to record how tall they felt, using a continuous un-numbered line with the words ‘very short’ written at the left-hand end to ‘very tall’ at the right-hand end. 113 Men and 106 Women • The respondents were asked to record how tall they felt, using a continuous un-numbered line with the words ‘very short’ written at the left-hand end to ‘very tall’ at the right-hand end. • Numbers were coded 1…10 afterwards. • Then we looked at the correlation between feelings of being tall and actual true height. How well correlated are feelings of height and actual height? Feelings of height and actual height in 113 men y = -28.966 + 0.19528x R= 0.80909 Subjective assessment of height from very short to very tall 10 8 6 4 2 0 150 160 170 180 Actual height of men (in cm) 190 200 Feelings of height and actual height in 106 women y = -38.202 + 0.26151x R= 0.85423 Subjective assessment of height from very short to very tall 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 140 145 150 155 160 165 170 Actual height of women (in cm) 175 180 These plots are consistent with a linear reporting function. Much more research on the reporting function r(.) will be required in the future. Evidence from Neuroscience • Positive feelings correspond to brain activity in the left-side of the pre-frontal cortex, above and in front of the ear • Negative feelings correspond to brain activity in the same place in the right side of the brain Happy and Sad Pictures The Brain Responses to Two Pictures (MRI Scan) Source: Richard Davidson, University of Wisconsin The types of statistical sources General Social Survey of the USA British Household Panel Study (BHPS) German Socioeconomic Panel Australian HILDA Panel Eurobarometer Surveys Labour Force Survey from the UK World Values Surveys NCDS 1958 cohort BRFSS From the U.S. General Social Survey (sample size 40,000 Americans approx.) • “Taken all together, how would you say things are these days - would you say that you are very happy, pretty happy, or not too happy?” An alternative DRM approach • A study by Daniel Kahneman and his colleagues on 1,000 working women in Texas (see Kahneman et al, 2003) • These women were asked to divide the previous day into 15 episodes. They were then asked what they were doing in each episode, and who were they doing it with. Happiness in Different Activities Happiness while Spending Time with Different People The average reported feelings across 1,000 people correspond well with activities predicted to be good for us, as well as activities predicted to be bad for us So how has the modern work on the economics of happiness proceeded? Here is a modern US happiness equation (courtesy of David Blanchflower, Dartmouth College and NBER) • Could you turn to the NBER Blanchflower-Oswald paper on international happiness? Some cheery news: Some cheery news: In Western nations, most people are pretty happy with their lives. Some cheery news: In Western nations, most people are pretty happy with their lives. Some cheery news: In Western nations, most people are pretty happy with their lives. Some cheery news: In Western nations, most people are pretty happy with their lives. The distribution of life-satisfaction levels among British people 35 Percentage of Population 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Self-rated Life Satisfaction Source: BHPS, 1997-2003. N = 74,481 7 Exogenous shocks and happiness New work looks at Genes Lottery wins 9-11’s effects Deaths of children Sporting results Movements in air pollution Other work on happiness as causal • John Ifcher and Homa Zarghamee, forthcoming in the AER, on happiness leading to different rate of time discount. • Oswald, Proto, Sgroi on happiness leading to higher productivity. These randomly assign happiness. Is modern society going in a sensible direction? This is an empirical question • "Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot?" Richard Easterlin in Paul A. David and Melvin W. Reder, eds., Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz, New York: Academic Press, Inc., 1974. • We will focus on it tomorrow. Let’s return for a moment to the microeconomics of human well-being What have we learned? Big effects Unemployment Divorce Marriage Bereavement Friendship networks Health No effects from children [but + for grandchildren: Nick Powdthavee] There is also an intriguing life-cycle pattern The pattern of a typical person’s happiness through life Average life satisfaction score 5.6 5.5 5.4 5.3 5.2 5.1 5.0 4.9 15-20 21-30 31-40 41-50 Age group 51-60 61-70 Arthur Stone, Angus Deaton, et al (2010) Overall well-being Quadratic Life-Satisfaction in the US Steve Wu on BRFSS 2010 data age -.0030621 agesq .0000419 Again the U-shape. A life satisfaction U-shape in age also exists in many developing nations In World Values Survey data, there is a Ushape and it reaches its minimum at: A life satisfaction U-shape in age also exists in many developing nations In World Values Survey data, there is a Ushape and it reaches its minimum at: Brazil 37 China 46 El Salvador 48 Mexico 41 Nigeria 42 Tanzania 46 Obviously life is a mixture of ups and downs Much of the recent research follows people through time. eg. Andrew Clark’s work The unhappiness from bereavement Human beings also bounce back from, say, disability. Work with N. Powdthavee, Journal of Public Economics, 2008 Life-Satisfaction Path of Those Who Entered Disability at Time T and Remained Disabled in T+1 and T+2 BHPS data 1996-2005 6.5 6.0 Mean Life Satisfaction 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 T-2 T-1 T T+1 T+2 However, there is a downside to that adaptability (eg. marriage) However, there is a downside to that adaptability (eg. marriage) Is there income adaptation? Maybe. The joy of having higher income may also wear off … Source: Di Tella et al (2008), German Socio-Economic Panel And should you invest in a baby? Happiness and children But people do not seem to adapt to joblessness The evidence suggests that when a person is made unemployed: The evidence suggests that when a person is made unemployed: • 20% of the fall in mental well-being is due to the decline in income • 80% is due to non-pecuniary things (loss of self-esteem, status..). An important question in a modern society is the impact of divorce. Divorce (eventually) makes people happier Divorce (eventually) makes people happier Points or questions? What about money and happiness? A key social-science fact A key social-science fact The data show that richer people are happier and healthier. But some general economists have low life-satisfaction when they hear about this research. The tradition of economics has been to ignore what people say about the quality of their own lives. The tradition of economics has been to ignore what people say about the quality of their own lives. Many are opposed to the idea of measuring ‘happiness’. I always liked the retort: I always liked the retort: If molecules could talk, would physicists refuse to listen? A. Blinder I always liked the retort: If molecules could talk, would physicists refuse to listen? A. Blinder So how could we move forward? So how could we move forward? • Brain-science correlates as a validation So how could we move forward? • Brain-science correlates as a validation • Physiological correlates as a validation A brain-science approach (Urry et al Psychological Science 2004) But, for a sceptic, there is a major difficulty. Biological data only validate well-being scores in so far as they are unambiguously measures of utility or ‘happiness’. A killer question • Can we devise a test in the economist’s spirit that shows, once and for all, a match between subjective well-being data and objective well-being data? Yes. I would like to give you the flavour of the argument in Oswald-Wu in Science in 2010. Are objective and subjective data on quality-of-life correlated? 13 4 We can exploit neo-classical economic theory to assess the validity of well-being data. Think not about people but about places. Joint work with Steve Wu • New data from the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System (BRFSS) • 1.3 million randomly sampled Americans • 2005 to 2008 • A life-satisfaction equation Then we go to the compensatingdifferentials literature dating back to Adam Smith, Sherwin Rosen, Jennifer Roback, etc. The most recent is Gabriel et al 2003. Gabriel painstakingly takes data on • • • • • • • • • • • • Precipitation Humidity Heating Degree Days Cooling Degree Days Wind Speed Sunshine Coast Inland Water Federal Land Visitors to National Parks Visitors to State Parks Number of hazardous waste sites and • • • • • • • Environmental Regulation Leniency Commuting Time Violent Crime Rate Air Quality-Ozone Air Quality-Carbon Monoxide Student-teacher ratio State and local taxes on property, income and sales and other • State and local expenditures on higher education, public welfare, highways, and corrections • Cost-of-living Then there are 2 ways to measure human well-being or ‘utility’ across space. Subjective and objective Gabriel’s work assigns a 1 to the state with the highest imputed quality-of-life, and 50 to the state with the lowest. So we need to uncover a negative association – in order to find a match. • And there is one. One Million Americans’ Life Satisfaction and Objective Quality-of-Life in 50 States y = -0.0032082 - 0.0012154x R= 0.60938 Life Satisfaction Fully Adjusted (ie income also) 0.04 0.02 0 -0.02 -0.04 -0.06 -0.08 -0.1 0 10 20 30 40 50 Objective Quality of Life Ranking (where 1 is high and 50 is low) 60 To conclude across US states: There is a match between lifesatisfaction scores and the quality of life calculated using (only) nonsubjective data. Some ideas to end: My hunch My hunch The methods of the economics of happiness and mental wellbeing will slowly enter public life. Other important applications Other important applications The valuation of environmental amenities Other important applications The valuation of environmental amenities The valuation of health states Other important applications The valuation of environmental amenities The valuation of health states The valuation of emotional damages for the courts. Conventionally: • Economics is a social science concerned with the efficient allocation of scarce resources We owe this definition to Lionel Robbins of the London School of Economics. For a long time, it served us well. But perhaps the time has come to think differently – and to define economics differently. An alternative definition: An alternative definition for 2011: • Economics is a social science concerned with the best way to allocate plentiful resources to maximize a society’s well-being and mental health. Looking ahead Policy in the coming century may need to concentrate on non-materialistic goals. Looking ahead Policy in the coming century may need to concentrate on non-materialistic goals. GNH not GDP. And the next research area? Thank you. The Economics of Happiness and Health Andrew Oswald Research site: www.andrewoswald.com I would like to acknowledge that much of this work is joint with coauthors Chris Boyce, Andrew Clark, Nick Powdthavee, David G. Blanchflower, and Steve Wu.