Global imbalances as constraints to the economic recovery in developed economies. Jesus Ferreiro, Patricia Peinado and Felipe Serrano Department of Applied Economics V University of the Basque Country UPV/EHU Conference “International Economic Policies, Governance and the New Economics” The Cambridge Trust for New Thinking in Economics Cambridge, Thursday 12 April 2012 Do Current Account Imbalances (CAIs) matter? • CAIs involve financial flows. High CAIs involve high net financial (in/out)flows, and the latter may be a source of problems (via interest rates, exchange rates…) • CA deficits may be generated by fiscal deficits, leading to the possibility of twin crises (BoP and fiscal crisis) • Permanent CA deficits lead to the accumulation of external debt. Problems in case of sudden stops • CA imbalances involves: – a trade deficit that constrains the economic activity – a trade surplus that involves an export-led growth strategy, whose long-term sustainability depends on the economic activity in foreign partners 2 Can CA Imbalances be a problem for the World economy? Current Account imbalances can be a source of systemic risks depending on the: • • • • Size of the imbalances Trend (conjunctural or structural nature) Concentration in a low/high number of countries Extension of the phenomenon: number of countries with high CA imbalances 3 Size of Current Account Imbalances Current Account Balances (billions US dollars) 2000 1500 1000 500 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 0 -500 -1000 -1500 -2000 Deficit CAB Surplus CAB 4 Current Account Imbalance as % World GDP 3,0 2,5 2,0 1,5 1,0 0,5 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 0,0 The size of the CAI is measured as the average of the sums of the absolute values of the CA deficits and surpluses as percentage of the World GDP 5 The evolution of the current account imbalances shows a clear rising trend: • 1980-1999: 1.26 per cent World GDP • 2000-2011: 2.21 per cent World GDP Is this evolution the result of a cyclical pattern, a long-term smooth trend, or the result of a structural break in the framework of foreign trade relations? 6 Trend of Current Account Imbalances To test this hypothesis we have applied a structural time series analysis to the behaviour of the size of current account imbalances in the world economy. The model tested is: where μ is the level, ψ is the cycle, and ω an intervention (dummy variable) The stochastic trend (level+slope) component is specified as: We include 3 interventions variables : years 2001 and 2009 (outliers taking the value 1 for that years , and 0 for the others) and an intervention adopting the form of a break in the level in year 2000 (taking the value 1 since 2000) 7 Summary statistics Var1 T 32.000 p 5.0000 std.error 0.14639 Normality 4.9227 H(8) 0.51530 DW 2.2448 r(1) -0.23878 q 9.0000 r(q) -0.038520 Q(q,q-p) 12.007 Rd^2 0.69100 Variances of disturbances: Value (q-ratio) Level 0.000000 ( 0.0000) Slope 7.81691e-006 ( 0.007854) Cycle 0.00446176 ( 4.483) Irregular 0.000995301 ( 1.000) Cycle other parameters: Variance 0.04744 Period 7.44442 Frequency 0.84401 Damping factor 0.95182 Order 1.00000 State vector analysis at period 2011 Value Prob Level 2.17949 [0.00000] Slope -0.21398 [0.02726] Cycle 1 amplitude 0.33856 [ .NaN] Regression effects in final state at time 2011 Coefficient RMSE t-value Prob Outlier 2001(1) -0.22155 0.07511 -2.94954 [0.00681] Outlier 2009(1) -0.48065 0.07495 -6.41261 [0.00000] Level break 2000(1) 0.22388 0.11973 1.86994 [0.07325] The model shows a significant structural break (equivalent to 0.22 p.p. world GDP) in the size of CA imbalances that took place in 2000 8 9 The models shows that since 2000 the size of current account imbalances has a rising trend. This involves that the problems (directly and/or indirectly) generated by these imbalances are more intense than in the past 10 Concentration of world disequilibria in the current account balance Year 1980 Accumulated percentage of the disequilibria 25% 50% 75% 1990 25% 50% 75% 1995 25% 50% 75% 2000 25% 50% 75% 2007 25% 50% 75% 2011 25% 50% 75% Surplus countries Deficit countries Saudi Arabia Saudi Arabia, Kuwait Italy, Germany, Brazil Italy, Germany, Brazil, Japan, Mexico, Poland, Canada, Korea, Spain Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, United Arab Emirates, Qatar, Libia, Italy, Germany, Brazil, Japan, Mexico, Poland, Canada, Nigeria Korea, Spain, Belgium, Australia, Sweden, France, Austria, Iran, Turkey, Ivory Coast, Argentina, Philippines, Romania, Ireland Germany, Japan USA Germany, Japan, China USA, United Kingdom, Italy, Canada Germany, Japan, China, Taiwan, Switzerland, Venezuela, USA, United Kingdom, Italy, Canada, Spain, Australia, Netherlands, United Arab Emirates France, India, Mexico, Thailand Japan USA Japan, Netherlands, Italy USA, Germany, Australia, Brazil Japan, Netherlands, Italy, Switzerland, Belgium, Singapur, USA, Germany, Australia, Brazil, United Kingdom, France Thailand, Hong Kong, Korea, Malaysia, Austria, Indonesia, India, Turkey Japan, Russia USA Japan, Russia, Switzerland, Norway, France, China USA Japan, Russia, Switzerland, Norway, France, China, USA, United Kingdom, Germany, Brazil Canada, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, Iran, Korea, United Arab Emirates, Venezuela, Libia, Singapur China, Germany USA China, Germany, Japan, Saudi Arabia USA, Spain China, Germany, Japan, Saudi Arabia, Norway, USA, Spain, Australia, Italy Netherlands, Singapore, Sweden, Kuwait, Switzerland, Taiwan China, Germany USA China, Germany, Japan, Saudi Arabia, Russia USA, Turkey, Italy, France China, Germany, Japan, Saudi Arabia, Russia, USA, Turkey, Italy, France, United Kingdom, Canada, Switzerland, Norway, Netherlands, Kuwait, Qatar, Brazil, Spain, India Taiwan, Singapore, Sweden 11 Current account imbalances (billions US dollars) 1800 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 -200 -400 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 0 -600 -800 -1000 -1200 -1400 -1600 3 higher deficits 3 higher surpluses Cumulated deficits Cumulated surpluses 12 3 higher deficits 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 Three highest CA imbalances as a percentage of total imbalances 80 75 70 65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 3 higher surpluses 13 Extension of CA imbalances: number of countries with high imbalances Number of countries CA deficit ≥ 4% GDP CA surplus ≥ 4% GDP 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 110 105 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 other countries 14 CA deficit ≥ 4% GDP CA surplus ≥ 4% GDP 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 Percentage out of total number of countries (%) 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 other countries 15 Reasons of Current Account Imbalances 1. Real versus financial causes: • Based on current account (CA) balance: disequilibria in BC lead to disequilibria in BK – (S-I) (X-M) – (X-M) (S-I) • Based on capital account balance (Bracke et al, 2008): disequilibria in BK lead to disequilibria in BC: – Asian crisis – Underdeveloped financial sectors in Emerging Market Economies 16 2. U.S. versus rest of the world (EMEs) origins: • USA: – Rise of US productivity growth (Hunt and Rebucci, 2005; Engel and Rogers, 2006; Bracke et al, 2008; Kroszner, 2008) – Increases in private consumption and declines in saving rate (Bernanke, 2005; Kroszner, 2008) – Attractiveness of US financial system (Bernanke, 2005) – Dollar liquidity and low US policy rates since 2001(Bibow, 2008-9) – Special international status of US dollar (Bernanke, 2005) – Rise of US household consumption not offset by declines in the spending of other sectors (Gruber and Kamin, 2009) 17 • Rest of the world (EMEs, aged developed economies, oil exporters) – Global savings glut - investment draught (Bernanke, 2005, 2007; Rajan, 2006) – Rise in Chinese saving rate – Chinese public savings glut (Hermann and Winkler, 2009) – Weakness of financial systems in developing economies (Bracke et al, 2008, Kroszner, 2008, Hermann and Winkler, 2009) – Financial crises in EMEs lead to build up foreign exchange reserves as a buffer against capital outflows (Aizenmann and Lee, 2007; Aizenmann and Sun, 2009; Bernanke, 2005; Gruber and Kamin, 2009; Hermann and Winkler, 2009; Lee, 2009; Cova et al, 2009) – Sharp in oil prices (Gruber and Kamin, 2009) – Domestic demand stagnation in some developed countries (Bibow, 2008-9) – Ageing in developed economies 18 – China’s policies (Corden, 2009): exchange rate policy, build-up of foreign exchange reserves as a form of self-protection (parking theory), high household and corporations savings – Massive excess supply of labor in Asia (Dooley et al, 2009) – Financial liberalization in Emerging Asian Countries (Dooley et al, 2004; Chadha, 2006; Caballero et al, 2006) – Financial liberalization plus higher productivity growth in the rest of the world (Chakraborty and Dekle, 2009) – Productivity slowdown in the nontradeable sector of emerging Asia (Cova et al, 2009) 19 3. Mixed Origin: • Bretton Woods II (Dooley et al, 2003): symbiosis of interest among US and surplus developing countries: Developing countries base their development in exporting to US; the US finance its CA deficit by selling safe financial assets, which provide the collateral for inward FDI in developing countries • Differences in financial development: spending in the US is more responsive to lower costs and higher availability of credit stemming from the global saving glut than other advanced economies (“spending response” hypothesis: Gruber and Kamin, 2009) • Differences in the productivity growth: higher TFP growth in the US nontradable sector and higher TFP growth in the tradable sector of the rest of the world (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2007; Cova et al 2008) 20 All these hypothesis have problems: • The assumption of a direct relationship between financial and current account flows • They can not explain why the desire/objective of some countries to generate a surplus in their current accounts (accumulation of foreign reserves) can effectively be materialized • They can not explain why during the last decade, the generation and the rising size of current account imbalance is a generalized (and long-lasting) phenomenon, and why the increase in the number of deficit countries is higher than that of surplus economies 21 The size and the evolution of these imbalances (and that of EU with China) is explained by a process of worldwide relocation of production of tradeable goods: a change in the global value added chain. This process has been fuelled by FDI inflows from developed economies to emerging economies Consequently, it is a structural-nature process that cannot be solved with short-term measures like exchange rate adjustments or macroeconomic (fiscal-monetary) policies 22 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Current Account Imbalances and FDI (% World GDP) 4,5 35 4,0 30 3,5 3,0 25 2,5 20 2,0 15 1,5 10 1,0 0,5 5 0,0 0 FDI flows CAI FDI stock 23 Structural break in the series of FDI flows We have applied a structural time series analysis to the behaviour of the FDI flows in the world economy. The model tested is: We include 3 interventions variables : years 1999 and 2000 (outliers taking the value 1 for that years , and 0 for the others) and an intervention adopting the form of a break in the level in year 1998 (taking the value 1 since then) 24 Log-Likelihood is 29.3507 (-2 LogL = -58.7014). Prediction error variance is 0.051874 Summary statistics FDI flows T 31.000 p 5.0000 std.error 0.22776 Normality 2.3426 H(8) 19.134 DW 2.1309 r(1) -0.089814 q 9.0000 r(q) 0.10100 Q(q,q-p) 13.531 Rd^2 0.84615 Variances of disturbances: Value (q-ratio) Level 0.000000 ( 0.0000) Slope 0.000000 ( 0.0000) Cycle 0.0397524 ( 1.000) Irregular 0.000000 ( 0.0000) Cycle other parameters: Variance 0.15859 Period 7.12684 Frequency 0.88162 Damping factor 0.86564 Order 1.00000 State vector analysis at period 2010 Value Prob Level 2.14618 [0.00000] Slope 0.06201 [0.00001] Cycle 1 amplitude 0.60289 [ .NaN] The results show a rising trend in the FDI flows and a structural break in 1998, equivalent to a permanent increase of 0.6 per cent of the world GDP Regression effects in final state at time 2010 Coefficient RMSE t-value Prob Outlier 1999(1) 1.03042 0.23280 4.42611 [0.00015] Outlier 2000(1) 1.50617 0.23185 6.49630 [0.00000] Level break 1998(1) 0.58385 0.20102 2.90439 [0.00741] 25 26 Structural break in the series of FDI flows We have applied a structural time series analysis to the behaviour of the FDI flows in the world economy. The model tested is: We include 4 interventions variables : years 2002, 2005 and 2008 (outliers taking the value 1 for that years , and 0 for the others) and an intervention adopting the form of a break in the slope in year 1997 (taking the value 1 since then) 27 Log-Likelihood is -5.86179 (-2 LogL = 11.7236). Prediction error variance is 0.955449 Summary statistics Stock FDI T 31.000 p 2.0000 std.error 0.97747 Normality 5.9052 H(8) 19.651 DW 1.4250 r(1) 0.18574 q 6.0000 r(q) -0.077398 Q(q,q-p) 2.0861 Rd^2 0.83958 Variances of disturbances: Value (q-ratio) Level 1.18448 ( 1.000) Slope 0.000000 ( 0.0000) Irregular 0.000000 ( 0.0000) State vector analysis at period 2010 Value Prob Level 19.80295 [0.00155] Slope 0.48508 [0.08676] The results show a rising trend in the FDI stock and a structural break in 1997, equivalent to a permanent increase of 0.9 per cent of the world GDP Regression effects in final state at time 2010 Coefficient RMSE t-value Prob Outlier 2008(1) -6.99891 0.76957 -9.09458 [0.00000] Slope break 1997(1) 0.82523 0.39829 2.07193 [0.04874] Outlier 2002(1) -1.79850 0.76957 -2.33702 [0.02775] Outlier 2005(1) -2.12150 0.76957 -2.75674 [0.01074] 28 29 How to solve current account imbalances Traditional solutions to solve a current account imbalance are: • Demand-side policies: (T+G) + (S-I)=(X-M) – Current account deficits: restrictive fiscal-monetary policies – Current account surpluses: expansionary fiscal-monetary policies • Exchange rate policy: – Current account deficits: depreciation – Current account surpluses: appreciation 30 In the case of demand-side policies: • the reduction of CA deficits involves a negative impact on economic activity • the reduction of CA surpluses assumes: – that surplus country will increase the demand of goods-services produced abroad, – that domestic agents absorb some of the production formerly exported – that foreign partners will be able to generate the (higher) supply of these goods – that there is a foreign supply of these goods Option b may lead to higher prices of goods exported by the surplus country. If foreign partners do not increase the production of these goods (substituting imports by domestic production) and the demand of imports is highly inelastic, import prices in these deficit countries will rise, increasing the CA deficit 31 In the case of exchange rate policy: • The impact of changes in the exchange rate depends on the elasticity of the demands of imports and exports • Highly inelastic demand of imported goods lead to a deterioration of CA balances if the currency depreciates • A low sustituibility between domestic goods and imported goods involves very high depreciation of the domestic currency • The impact on trade balances of changes in the real exchange rate depends on the level of intra-industrial trade: in countries with low intra-industrial trade, the depreciation of the RER can deteriorate the trade balance (Kharroubi, 2011) • A change in the exchange rate of a single currency might not affect the CA balance of a thirs partner, if the exports of the first country compete with other countries whose currencies do not change • Empirical analyses (Altuzarra, Ferreiro and Serrano, 2010), using cointegration and VCM, show that a depreciation of the euro improves the trade balance with China, but a depreciation of the dollar deteriorates the USA trade balance with China 32 Conclusions • • • • Current Account Imbalances are a source of potential (systemic) risks: – Problems coming from the related financial flows – Constraints to the economic activity in deficit countries Current account imbalances have a structural nature: – The size of CAI has increased in the last decade – The number of countries with high CAI has increased – CAI is concentrated in a low number of economies Current Account Imbalances are explained by a process of worldwide relocation of production of tradeable goods (fuelled by FDI flows from developed economies): is a structural-nature process that cannot be solved with short-term measures like exchange rate adjustments or macroeconomic (fiscal-monetary) policies Adjustment of CA deficit involves a change in the productive structure (size and composition of aggregate supply) of the deficit country: need of supplyside policies (e.g., industrial policies, policies fostering FDI inflows...) 33