‘Inclusion and growth’ Talk at YSP5 Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research Mumbai June 24, 2009 by Pulapre Balakrishnan Senior Fellow Nehru Memorial Museum and Library New Delhi • For five years from 2003 India was at the very top of the league of fast growing economies in the world today. • China was of course the fastest, but India was watched by the world at least as keenly. • Politically, India fascinates because it has endured as a democracy despite conditions that would predict its withering away. • During the period of its high growth India was the cynosure of all eyes, partly due to the allure of its highly visible corporate capability, particularly in IT, which extends from management to R&D. • From an economic point of view, India continues to fascinate by being at the cutting edge of technology and ideas despite a very low average income. • Consider this: • “Aircraft engines need to be put through rigourous tests before they are sold. What will happen in case of a bird hit, or if a fan blade disengages? Done physically, each of these tests can cost up to $15 million. And each test has to be carried out under different conditions. This can burn hundreds of millions of dollars. General electric, the world’s leading maker of aircraft engines, carries out all such tests on computers in an industrial estate in Bangalore at a fraction of the cost and time. As a result, GE hopes to rollout four or five engines over the next five years. An engine can take up to 20 years to develop. Nobody has ever flooded the market with so many engines in a span of just five years.” • Bhupesh Bhandari, “Frugal innovation”, ‘Business Standard’, June 13/14, 2009 • India has grown faster since 1991, suggesting that the aim of integrating with the global economy has paid dividends. • However, an increasingly heard criticism is that the currently high economic growth in India is not inclusive. India: Child anaemia (source: Bose, 2007) Status NFHS (2005-06) NFHS (1998-99) Any 78.9 74.3 Mild 25.7 22.9 Mod. 49.4 45.9 Severe 3.7 5.4 Nutrition status of Indian adults Men Women Proportion of adults with Body Mass Index below 18.5 1975-79 1988-90 1996-97 2000-01 56 49 46 37 52 49 48 39 2004-05 33 36 Body Mass Index is the ratio of weight (in kilos) to the square of height (in metres). BMI less than 18.5 is the cut-off conventionally associated with “chronic energy deficiency”. Source: Deaton and Dreze (2009). BMI: an international comparison (women aged 15-49 years) Mean BMI % women with BMI < 18.5 South Asia: India Bangladesh Nepal 20.5 20.2 20.6 35.6 34.3 24.4 Sub-saharan Africa: Eritrea Ethiopia Burkina Faso Chad Madagascar Niger Senegal Nigeria Zambia Congo 2005 Guinea Mauritania Kenya Uganda Benin Tanzania Rwanda Ghana Malawi Zimbabwe Mozambique Gabon Lesotho Mean for sub-Saharan Africa 20.0 20.2 20.9 20.8 20.8 21.4 22.3 22.3 21.6 22.9 21.8 24.3 22.7 22.2 22.4 22.3 21.8 23.1 22.0 23.1 22.1 23.5 25.1 21.9 37.3 26.5 20.8 20.3 19.2 19.2 18.2 15.2 15.0 13.2 13.2 13.0 12.3 12.1 10.7 10.4 9.8 9.3 9.2 9.2 8.6 6.6 5.7 15.8 Source: Deaton and Dreze (2009). The trend in child nutrition in India Proportion of children under 3 years who are undernourished 1992-93 1998-99 2005-06 Weight-for-age 52.0 47.0 45.9 Height-for-age n/a 45.5 38.4 Weight-for-height n/a 15.5 19.1 Source: Deaton and Dreze (2009). Countries with the highest levels of child undernutrition Country Nepal Bangladesh India Timor-Leste Yemen Burundi Madagascar Sudan Lao Niger Eritrea Afghanistan Proportion of children with ‘Weight-for-age’ 48.3 47.5 46.7 45.8 45.6 45.1 41.9 40.7 40.4 40.1 39.6 39.3 Source: Source: Deaton and Dreze (2009). • In this talk, I shall: • i. Reflect on the idea of ‘inclusion’ in the context of an economy, and • ii. Assess how the current growth in India measures up to some rudimentary criteria of inclusiveness that we might consider. Why ‘inclusive’ growth? The genius of a country “… is not best or most in its executives or legislatures, nor in its ambassadors or authors or colleges or churches or parlors, not even in its newspapers or inventors … but always most in the common people.” ‘Leaves of Grass’ Walt Whitman, American poet The very idea of ‘India’ “To bring freedom and opportunity to the common man, to the peasants and workers of India; to fight and end poverty and ignorance and disease: to build up a prosperous, democratic and progressive nation, and to create social, economic and political institutions which will ensure justice and fullness of life to every man and woman.” Jawaharlal Nehru Address to the Constituent Assembly August 14-15, 1947 There would be no ‘India’ without inclusiveness! The method of the economist • “While it is difficult for economists to perform experiments to test their theories, as a chemist or a physicist might, the world provides a vast array of natural experiments as dozens of countries try different strategies.” Joseph Stiglitz, Nobel Laureate ‘Making Globalization Work’, 2006 • It’s official now! • ‘Inclusive growth’ has been stated as an objective in the Approach Paper to the Eleventh Plan. • It has also been referred to continuosly by the representatives of the government that has just assumed office in New Delhi. • However, the Approach Document itself does not spell out clearly the means to inclusive growth, or even what it means. • This leaves the task to us. • I shall spend some time considering alternative ways of viewing ‘inclusive growth’, and consequently potential routes to it. • At the outset, it needs be recognised that there is no costless ‘formula’. • As we are a democratic polity, we need to generate political will. As we are a market economy, we would need to commit resources. • It would seem that at least two conditions are to be satisfied for growth to be considered inclusive: • i. ‘Growth does not leave behind large numbers.’ Note that this is a very mild requirement. In an adaptation from Rawls, we could have adopted ‘maximin’ as the first criterion. • The maximin principle is a justice criterion for the design of social systems proposed by the philosopher Rawls. • According to this principle the system should be designed to maximise the position of those who will be worst off in it. • ii. Growth is characterised by an evenness across the economy, such that the widest range of our material needs are satisfied. • Easily recognised as absent in India where till recently there was a boom in the IT sector combined with slowing agricultural growth. • Or, in Kerala, where there has been ‘social development’ without development of what Marx had referred to as the ‘productive forces’. • Querying accounts of progress based on the growth rate alone is a concern worldwide today. • In 2008 the French president appointed an Indian adviser to re-define economic progress bearing in mind the quality of life. • I suggest that, at least for India, we use a paired criteria by which to judge how inclusive is growth. • First, growth must carry the many with it. Secondly, it must satisfy the widest range of our material needs. • Some features of the growth of the last decade or so: • Growth has accelerated since 1991. • Significant feature is the resurgence of manufacturing in the very recent past. • Manufacturing is important not only for faster growth, but also as this growth is in new sectors: automobiles, high-end consumer durables. • However, by the definition that we have sketched, growth in the past decade and a half has not been inclusive. • First, are the emerging opportunities being distributed equally? • While we cannot be certain, we have reason to believe that they are not. • But why? • As the demand for labour is what we term ‘derived demand’ it is related to the growth of output. • And we know that not all sectors are growing at the same rate. • While this is not unusual the world over, there has occurred a great shift in labour from the slow growing to the fast growing sectors. • In India such is shift is being thwarted by a very low level of education and general capability development. This constraint is fundamental. • So recent growth has not been inclusive by our first criterion, as the opportunities are not equally distributed. • Recent growth also does not satisfy our second requirement, that growth cater to the entire range of our needs. • The absence of growth in two widely different areas may be noted. • First, in agriculture. And secondly, in infrastructure, both social and physical. • So we can identify education, health and physical infrastructure as the missing elements in the Indian economy. • What can we do to rectify this absence? • Both history and economic theory tell us that the broad policy of relying on the market is not sufficient to deal with this problem. • All succesful economies from Europe to Japan have relied on mass public education to raise the general level of capability of their economies. • For half a century, the UK has had a National Health Service that provides free medical care of the highest order. • The inter-state highway system in the United States was built by the government. • The economies of the EC combine high levels of income with substantial welfare provision. • The role of public provision of services is that it mitigates income poverty. It is an important instrument of inclusiveness. • The theoretical reason for the belief that better government alone can bring about inclusiveness is investment on education and infrastructure, and even health, has a social rate of return that is higher than the private rate of return. We know from theory that the market under-provides such goods. • There is also the general ‘collective goods problem’ in public goods provision. • Recognising the historical experience of development of the currently richest economies and the theoretical case for public provision of public goods, we can turn to the Indian case. • It is by now clear that the policy focus has excluded social and physical infrastructure. • There is a policy deficit. • Public goods are not on the radar, as we find from the flooding of Mumbai during the monsoon, the outbreak of cholera in Bangalore and Chikungunya, a mosquito-borne ailment, in Kerala within the last six months. Public health is in a precarious condition. • Can the ‘reforms’ per se handle the paucity of public goods in India? This question is relevant as the case is constantly made that what India needs most now is “more reforms” • To answer the question posed we need to first understand the nature of the reforms since 1991. • Since 1991 the economic policy environment in India has been liberalised. • Much of this was necessary and has shown results, notably in manufacturing. • However, in areas where the government has been inactive in the past – particularly social and physical infrastructure – it continues to remain so. • This indicates the prospects for greater supply of public goods in India unless the problem is specifically addressed. • We know that ‘benign neglect’ will not deliver the goods. • Improved public goods provision straddle the 2 elements in our definition of ‘inclusive’ growth. • First, they can enable participation in the opportunities thrown up by those currently excluded. • Secondly, in some avatars – such as sanitation, roads and urban recreational spaces – they are constitutive of an ‘inclusive’ growth. • The challenge of bringing about a more inclusive growth may be demonstrated with an example from the agricultural sector. • The agricultural sector currently occupies the overwhelming majority of Indians. Not only is it growing slowly, it is also not able to produce food cheaply. The relative price of food has not declined since 1991. • It is believed on the basis of past research that the main factor in raising the rate of growth of agriculture, as proposed in the Eleventh Plan, is the expansion of irrigation. • But irrigation expansion has actually slowed since 1991. Table 6b The expansion of irrigation crop\year 1970-71 1980-81 1990-91 Cereals 27.6 34.1 41.0 Pulses 8.8 9.0 10.5 : Foodgrains 24.1 29.7 35.1 Oilseeds 7.4 14.5 22.9 Cotton 17.3 27.3 32.9 Sugarcane 72.4 81.3 86.9 Source: Economic Survey 2006-07. 2000-01 49.6 12.3 43.1 22.5 32.6 91.3 Public expenditure on irrigation and flood control Nominal Expenditure in Rs. crore Expenditure at 1993-94 prices Third Plan (1961-66) 664.7 7402.0 Annual Plans (1966-69) 471.0 3699.0 Fourth Plan (1969-74) 1354.1 8484.3 Fifth Plan (1974-79) 3876.5 15095.4 Annual Plan (1979-80) 1287.9 4127.9 Sixth Plan (1980-85) 10929.9 25717.4 Seventh Plan 1985-90) 16589.9 28349.1 Annual Plans (1990-92) 8206.0 10413.7 Eighth Plan (1992-97) 31398.9 28353.7 Ninth Plan (1997-2002) 63009.5 42817.0 Tenth Plan (2002-2007) 103315.0 55450.3 Period Source: Author’s estimates from Economic Survey 2006-07. • The case of irrigation is illustrative that political negotiation is going to be as important as economic resources in bringing about inclusive growth in India. India: relative price of food (source: author’s calculation) 1993-94 1.00 1994-95 0.97 1995-96 0.98 1996-97 1.01 1997-98 1.01 1998-99 1.02 1999-00 1.04 2000-01 1.04 2001-02 1.05 2002-03 1.03 2003-04 1.00 2004-05 0.99 India: A health card, Child anaemia (source: Bose, 2007) Anaemia status (grams per dcl) Any (< 11) NFHS (2005-06) NFHS (1998-99) 78.9 74.3 Mild (10.0 -10.9) 25.7 22.9 Mod. (7 - 9.9) 49.4 45.9 Severe (< 7.0) 3.7 5.4 Nutrition status of Indian adults Men Women Proportion of adults with Body Mass Index below 18.5 1975-79 1988-90 1996-97 2000-01 56 49 46 37 52 49 48 39 2004-05 33 36 Body Mass Index is the ratio of weight (in kilos) to the square of height (in metres). BMI less than 18.5 is the cut-off conventionally associated with “chronic energy deficiency”. Source: Deaton and Dreze (2009). The need to recognise trade-offs • Conflicts: Emerging consequences of the NREGS. • The Knowledge Commission’s recommendation on higher education. • What price PDS? • Where is India headed? • Political consensus and social cohesion. • Far greater debate needed than we have today. Economic policymaking is far more removed from civil society than it was in the fifties. India: Percentage of undernourished households source: Ray (2008) 1987-88 (NSS Round 43) 2001-02 (NSS Round 57) Rural 48.16 66.90 Urban 36.97 51.00