Lesson 2 “First Generation” theories of economic growth The Harrod-Domar Model The Solow “Neoclassical” Growth Model Convergence Developed by Sir Roy Harrod (1939) and Evsey Domar (1946) Economic growth is the result of sacrificing current consumption Households save from current income => firms invest these savings => creation of capital goods => production of output increases => economic growth National income, Y(t), is either spent on consumption goods, C(t), or saved, S(t): Y(t)=C(t)+S(t) In a closed economy, the supply of savings must equal the demand for investment, I(t): S(t)=I(t) Investment increases the economy’s stock of capital, while replacing the part of this stock that is wearing out: K (t ) I (t ) K ( t ) Notation: x(t ) dx(t ) dt K (t ) : the economy's stock of capital goods : the rate of depreciation of capital Assumptions of the model: Savings is a fixed fraction of income: S (t ) sY (t ), 0 s 1 The capital-output ratio is constant: K (t ) Y (t ) The savings rate, s, and the capital-output ratio, , are the two key variables in the model The key equation in the Harrod-Domar model is: g s Where, g Y (t ) Y (t ) : the growth rate of output Note: Details of the above equation to be derived in class Adding population growth (n) to the model, we get: s g n g* is now the rate of growth of per-capita output This growth equation was instrumental in shaping policies in socialist countries such as India and the Soviet Union in the 1950s and 1960s The key variables in the Harrod-Domar model are: The savings rate The population growth rate The capital-output ratio All these variables are assumed to be exogenous, which is unrealistic What determines these variables? There is evidence to suggest that the savings rate (s) rises with income: Poor people or countries close to subsistence do not or cannot save much As income rises, there is more room for savings; but the very rich have less need for savings Some inequality might also affect the savings rate: middle class saves more than poor or rich This implies that poor and rich countries should have low growth rates, compared to middle-income countries Huge body of evidence suggests that population growth changes with the level of development: Demographic Transition At low levels of per-capita income, death rates are very high. This leads to high birth rates too. Combined effect is a low rate of population growth As per-capita income rises, living standards improve and death rates fall sharply. But birth rates don’t. So population growth is high At very high levels of per-capita income, birth rates fall as well, and population growth declines Relationship between per-capita income and population growth: “inverse-U” Developed by Nobel Prize winning economist, Robert Solow (1955) Extends the Harrod-Domar story in a very important direction: Endogeneizes the capital-output ratio, . Based on the Law of Diminishing Returns The capital-output ratio depends on the relative endowments of capital and labor in the economy Rate of capital accumulation (per-capita): k(t ) sy(t ) ( n)k (t ) Where, k (t ) K (t ) / L(t ) capital per unit of labor y (t ) Y (t ) / L(t ) per - capita output L(t ) Size of labor force Key difference from Harrod-Domar story: Production function: per-capita output is a function of per-capita capital stock: y f k , f 0, f 0 Over the long-run, due to diminishing returns, the per-capita stock of capital stops eventually stops growing: k(t ) 0 as t This situation (stationary per-capita capital stock) is called the steady-state equilibrium: ~ ~ sf (k ) nk Given the parameters , s, and n, we can determine ~ the unique steady-state per-capita stock of capital, k There is no per-capita growth in output in the steady-state (due to diminishing returns to capital) Total output and capital grow at the rate of population growth: Y K n Y K An increase in the population growth rate (n): Lowers the steady-state level of per-capita output Increases the growth rate of total output Why the “dual” effect? Labor is both an input in production as well as a consumer of final goods Growth Effect: changes the growth rate of a variable Level Effect: changes the level of a variable, but leaves its growth rate unchanged In the previous version, growth of per-capita output cannot be sustained indefinitely Economy eventually converges to a stationary equilibrium (constant per-capita output) What happens if we introduce technical progress? Production function shifts upwards over time as new knowledge and efficiency is gained and applied Does this outweigh the effect of diminishing returns? The answer is … Assumption: Labor-augmenting technical progress Technical progress enhances the efficiency or productivity of the labor force Let E(t) denote the level of labor productivity and let denote its growth rate Then, the effective labor force is defined as: E(t)L(t) Note that the effective labor force is growing at the rate (n + ) Now, define all quantities in terms of units of effective labor (not per-capita): kˆ K EL : capital per effective worker yˆ Y EL : output per effective worker The accumulation of capital per effective worker is then given by: kˆ syˆ n kˆ At the steady state, there is no growth in capital per effective worker: kˆ 0 as t The level of the capital stock per effective worker is stationary (constant) in the steadystate, and solves: sf (kˆ) n kˆ If the capital stock per effective worker is constant in the steady state, then it must be the case that: Per-capita output (and capital) is growing at the rate of technical progress, . Total output (and capital) is growing at the rate (n + ) Unconditional Convergence: If structural parameters are identical across countries, then all countries must converge to a common level of per-capita income, irrespective of initial conditions Poor countries have higher marginal product of capital than rich countries, and therefore grow faster (“catching-up”) History does not matter for the long run This is one of the strongest predictions of the Solow model Baumol (1986) Examined growth rates of the world’s richest 16 countries, using data from 1870-1979 Horizontal axis: plot per-capita income in 1870 (initial condition) Vertical axis: plot per-capita income growth from 1870-1979 Prediction of the model: inverse relationship Countries in Baumol’s sample: Richest countries in 1979 Japan, Finland, Sweden, Norway, Germany, Italy, Austria, France, Canada, Denmark, USA, Netherlands, Switzerland, Belgium, UK, Australia But in 1870, Japan was not one of the richest countries; Argentina, East Germany, and Portugal were rich, but are excluded from the sample Only those countries that were successful at the end of the sample were chosen Selection Bias: using wisdom after the event A good test should look at a set of countries that, ex-ante, seemed likely to converge to high per-capita GDP levels over time Use countries with similar initial conditions, and not similar terminal conditions De Long (1988) addressed this problem by extending Baumol’s dataset to include 23 countries, but excluded Japan Use a large set of countries, but over a short time horizon Parente and Prescott (1993) Studied 102 countries over the period 1960-85 Each country’s per-capita GDP is expressed as a fraction of US per-capita GDP in a given year Standard deviation of relative GDP for each year is calculated If convergence hypothesis is true, then standard deviations should decline over time Structural parameters (technology, population growth, savings) differ across countries Countries converge to their own steady states, and not to a common steady state Although long-run levels of per-capita income can vary across countries, there could be convergence in growth rates, if technological progress is identical In testing for convergence, one must control for all the factors that are different across countries