CoreEconomics 2 nd edition by Gerald W. Stone
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
1
• Market Structure Analysis
• Competition: Short-Run Decisions
• Nobel Prize: Herbert Simon
• Competition: Long-Run Adjustments
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
2 of 32
• At the end of this chapter, the student will be able to:
– Name the primary market structures and describe their characteristics
– Define a competitive market and the assumptions that underlie it.
– Distinguish the differences between competitive markets in the short run and the long run.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
3 of 32
• At the end of this chapter, the student will be able to:
– Analyze the conditions for profit maximization, loss minimization, and plant shutdown.
– Derive the firm’s short-run supply curve.
– Use the short-run competitive model to determine long-run equilibrium.
– Describe why competition is in the public interest.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
4 of 32
• Economists use market structure analysis to categorize industries based on a few key characteristics, such as:
– Number of firms
– Nature of product
– Barriers to entry
– Extent of control over price
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
5 of 32
• Competition
• Monopolistic Competition
• Oligopoly
• Monopoly
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
6 of 32
• Characteristics of competitive markets:
– They have many buyers and sellers, each one so small that none can individually influence the price.
– Firms in the industry produce a homogeneous or standardized product.
– Buyers and sellers have all the information about prices and product quality they need to make informed decisions.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
7 of 32
• In competition , each individual firm is a price taker.
• This means that the firm can sell as much as it would like at the going market price.
• The firm’s total revenue will be equal to
price x quantity sold.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
8 of 32
• Characteristics of competitive markets:
– Barriers to entry or exit are insignificant in the long run; new firms are free to enter the industry if so doing appears profitable, while firms are free to exit if they anticipate losses.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
9 of 32
200
Panel A
Industry
Panel B
Firm
S d=MR=P =$200
200
D
Qe
Industry Output q
1
Firm’s Output q
2
The individual firm takes the market price as given.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
10 of 32
• In the short run, one factor of production is fixed, usually the plant size.
– Firms cannot enter or leave the industry.
• In the long run, all factors are variable.
– Firms will enter the industry in response to profits.
– Firms will leave the industry in response to losses.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
11 of 32
Market structures include
competition (many buyers and sellers)
monopolistic competition
(differentiated product)
oligopoly
(only a few firms that are interdependent)
monopoly (a one-firm industry)
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
12 of 32
Competition is defined by four attributes:
many buyers and sellers who are so small that none individually can influence price
firms produce and sell a homogeneous
(standardized) product
buyers and sellers have all the information necessary to make informed decisions
barriers to entry and exit are insignificant
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
13 of 32
• Firms in competitive markets get the product price from national or global markets.
Therefore, competitive firms are price takers.
• In the short run, one factor (usually plant size) is fixed. In the long run, all factors are variable, and firms can enter or leave the industry.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
14 of 32
• Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue that results from the sale of one added unit of a product.
• Total revenue is price times quantity sold.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
15 of 32
• A firm maximizes profit by producing at the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost.
• If a firm is earning zero economic profits at this point, it means that it is earning a normal rate of accounting profit.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
16 of 32
200
180
Profit
MC
ATC d=MR=P=$200
AVC
Output of Sails
Profit = (P – ATC) x Quantity
84
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
Figure 3
17 of 32
• In the long run, we expect that firms within a competitive industry will earn zero economic profit.
• This means that price will equal average total cost.
• Follow the example of the firm producing sails for windsurfing.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
18 of 32
177.60
MC
ATC
AVC
Output of Sails 75
Price falls to $177.60 per sail
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
19 of 32
• Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue from selling an additional unit of a product.
• Competitive firms are price takers, so they can sell all they want at the going market price. As a result, their marginal revenue is equal to product price.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
20 of 32
• The demand curve facing the competitive firm is a straight line demand at market price.
• Competitive firms will maximize profit by producing that output where marginal revenue equals marginal cost (MR = MC).
• When price is greater than the minimum point of average total cost, firms earn economic profits.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
21 of 32
• When price is just equal to the minimum point of average total cost, firms earn normal profits.
• When price is below the minimum point of average total cost, but above the minimum point of average variable costs, the firm continues to operate at a loss.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
22 of 32
• When price falls below the minimum point on the average variable cost curve, the firm will shut down and incur a loss equal to the amount of total fixed costs.
• The short run supply curve of the firm is the marginal cost curve above the minimum point on the average variable cost curve.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
23 of 32
162.50
MC
ATC
Shutdown point
AVC
65 Output of Sails
Price falls to $162.50 per sail
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
24 of 32
• The firm’s short-run supply curve is its marginal cost curve above the minimum point on the average variable cost curve.
• The short run supply curve for an industry is simply the horizontal summation of the supply curves of all the individual firms.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
25 of 32
• If firms in the industry are earning short run economic profits, new firms can be expected to enter the industry in the long run, or existing firms may increase the scale of their operations.
• Losses will lead to the exit of some firms.
• Final equilibrium in the long run is the point at which industry price is just tangent to the minimum point on the ATC curve.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
26 of 32
P
In long run equilibrium, the firm will earn zero economic profit, and the market will produce the maximum possible consumer and producer surplus.
MC
Consumer
Surplus
P
ATC
P=ATC
Producer
Surplus
Industry Firm
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
27 of 32
• The long-run outcome in competitive markets will be:
– Productively Efficient
• Goods are supplied at the lowest possible opportunity cost.
– Allocatively Efficient
• The market is directing scarce resources to the goods where they are most highly valued.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
28 of 32
• Economies or diseconomies of scale determine the shape of the long-run average total cost curve for individual firms.
• When all firms in an industry expand, this new demand for raw materials and labor may push up the price of some inputs. When this happens, it gives rise to an increasing cost industry.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
29 of 32
• A decreasing cost industr y arises when economies of scale present themselves with the entry of more firms:
– Perhaps raw materials suppliers enjoy economies of scale as this industry’s demand for their product increases.
– The semiconductor industry seems to fit this profile: As the demand for semiconductors has risen over the past few decades, their price has fallen dramatically.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
30 of 32
• Constant cost industries expand in the long run with no significant rise in average cost.
– Some fast food franchises and retail stores re-create their operations from market to market without any upward gravitation of the average cost curve.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
31 of 32
• When competitive firms are earning short run economic profits, these profits attract firms into the industry.
– Supply increases and market price falls until firms are earning zero economic profits.
• Losses mean that some firms will leave the industry. This reduces supply, increasing prices until profits return to normal.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
32 of 32
• Competitive markets are efficient because
P = MR = MC = SRATC min
= LRATC min
.
• Competitive markets are productively efficient because products are produced at their lowest possible opportunity cost.
• Competitive markets are allocatively efficient because P = MC and consumer and producer surplus is at a maximum.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
33 of 32
• An industry where prices rise as the industry grows is an increasing cost industry.
• Decreasing cost industries see their prices fall as the industry expands.
• Constant cost industries seem to be able to expand without facing higher or lower operating costs.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
34 of 32
• The development of shipping containers has facilitated the expansion of trade.
– Firms producing products in foreign countries can fill a container and send it directly to the customer or wholesaler in the
United States.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
35 of 32
• A 40-foot container with 32 tons of cargo shipped from China to the United States costs roughly $5,000, or 7 cents a pound.
– This efficiency has facilitated the expansion of trade worldwide and increased the competitiveness of many industries.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
36 of 32
• In the long run, a firm in a competitive industry will produce at the point where
– A) price equals average total cost.
– B) price equals average variable cost.
– C) average variable cost is minimized.
– D) marginal cost is minimized.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
37 of 32
• In the long run, a firm in a competitive industry will produce at the point where
– A) price equals average total cost.
Correct!
– B) price equals average variable cost
– C) average variable cost is minimized
– D) marginal cost is minimized
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
38 of 32
• Competition is a market structure in which industries contain many sellers and buyers, each so small that they ignore the others’ behavior and sell a homogeneous product.
• Sellers maximize profits by producing at the point where price equals marginal cost.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
39 of 32
• In the long run, firms will produce output where P = MR = MC = LRATC min and profits are enough to keep capital in the industry.
• This output level is efficient because it gives consumers just the goods they want and provides these goods at the lowest possible opportunity costs.
• Competitive market efficiency represents the benchmark for comparing other market structures.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
40 of 32
• Most business you encounter such as barber shops, salons, bars, restaurants, coffee houses, gas stations, fast food, cleaners, grocery stores, shoe and clothing stores all operate like competitive firms.
• While their products (and locations) are slightly different, they basically take their prices from the market and earn normal profits over the long term.
© 2011 Worth Publishers ▪ CoreEconomics
▪ Stone
41 of 32