HKALE Macroeconomics Chapter 2: Elementary Keynesian Model (I)Two-sector References: • CH 3, Advanced Level Macroeconomics, 5th Ed, Dr. LAM pun-lee, MacMillan Publishers (China) Limited • CH 3, HKALE Macroeconomics, 2nd Ed., LEUNG man-por, Hung Fung Book Co. Ltd. • CH 3, A-L Macroeconomics, 3rd Ed., Chan & Kwok, Golden Crown Introduction • National income accounting can only provide ex-post data about national income. • The three approaches are identities as they are true for any income level. Introduction • In order to explain the level and determinants of national income during a period of time, we count on national income determination model, e.g. Keynesian Models. Business Cycle GNP Recovery Boom Recession Depression 0 Time Business Cycle • It shows the recurrent fluctuations in GNP around a secular trend Trough Recovery Peak Recession the lowest Rising the highest Falling Growth rate of Negative real GNP Rising the highest Falling Prices Rising the highest falling Employment level the lowest HK’s Economic Performance Assumptions behind National Income Models Assumptions behind National Income Models • Y = National income at constant price • Potential/Full-employment national income, Yf is constant • Existence of idle resources, i.e. unemployment • The level of price is constant – as Y = P×Q & P = 1, then Y = (1)×Q Y = Q – Price level tends to be rigid in downward direction Equilibrium Income Determination of Keynesian's Two-sector Model (1)A Spendthrift Economy John Maynard Keynes Assumptions • Two sectors: households and firms • no saving, no tax and no imports no leakage/withdrawal Y=Yd while Yd = disposable income • consumer goods only no investment or injection Simple Circular Flow Model of a Spendthrift Economy C Households National income National expenditure Income generated Y E Firms Payment for goods and service By Income-expenditure Approach • AD → (without S) E = C → Y (firms) ↑ ↓ Y (households) ← AS ← D for factors By Income-expenditure Approach • Equilibrium income, Ye is determined when – AS = AD – Y = E Y = E = C Equilibrium Income Determination of Keynesian's Two-sector Model (2)-A Frugal Economy Assumptions 1. Households and firms 2. Saving, S, exists • Income is either consumed or saved Y ≡ C+S • leakage, S, exists 3. Without tax, Y=Yd Assumptions 4. Consumer and producer goods • Injection (investment, I) exist 5. Investment is autonomous/exogenous 6. Saving and investment decisions made separately • S=I occurs only at equilibrium level of income Simple Circular Flow Model of a Frugal Economy C Households S National income National expenditure Financial markets I Income generated Y E Firms Payment for goods and service Income Function: Income line/45 line/Y-line • an artificial linear function on which each point showing Y = E E Y-line E2 E1 45 0 Y1 Y2 Y Expenditure Function (1): Consumption Function, C • showing that planned consumption expenditure varies positively with but proportionately less than change in Yd • A linear consumption function: C = a + cYd where – a = a constant representing autonomous consumption expenditure – c = Marginal Propensity to Consume, MPC A Consumption Function, C E C = a + cYd C2 C1 a 0 Y1 Y2 Y Marginal Propensity to Consume, MPC, c • MPC = c = C Yd E M C = a + cYd △C △Y a 0 Y Properties of MPC: • the slope of the consumption function • 1>MPC>0 • the value of 'c' is constant for all income levels Average Propensity to Consume, APC • APC = C Yd E M C = a + cYd C a Y 0 Y Properties of APC: • the slope of the ray from the origin • APC falls when Y rises • Since C = a + cYd Then i.e. C Yd a c Yd APC Yd ( Yd a C Yd ) a (c ) Yd MPC Yd Thus, APC>MPC for all income levels Consumption Function Without ‘a” • If ‘a’ = 0, then C = cYd E a =0 C = cYd <45 Y Consumption Function Without ‘a” • If ‘a’ = 0, then MPC = APC = C Yd E C = cYd M C = △C Y a =0 Y = △Y Expenditure Function (2): Investment Function, I • showing the relationship between planned investment expenditure and disposable income level, Yd Autonomous Investment Function • Autonomous investment function: I = I* where I* = a constant representing autonomous investment expenditure E I* 0 I = I* Y Induced Investment Function • Induced investment function: I = I* + iYd where i = Marginal Propensity to Invest = MPI = I Yd E I = I* + iYd I* 0 Y Properties of MPI: • the slope of the investment function • 1>MPI>0 • the value of ‘i' is constant for all income levels Average Propensity to Invest, API • API = I Yd E I = I* + iYd M I I* Y 0 Y Properties of API: • the slope of the ray from the origin • API falls when Y rises • Since I = I* + iYd Then i.e. I Yd I* i Yd API I* Yd ( Yd I Yd ) I* (i ) Yd MPI Yd Thus, API>MPI for all income levels MPI under Autonomous Investment Function • If I = I*, then Y will not affect I • Therefore, MPI = E I* 0 I Yd 0 Yd 0 Slope = MPI = 0 I = I* Y Expenditure Function (3): Aggregate Expenditure Function, E • Showing the relationship between planned aggregate expenditure and disposable income level, Yd • Aggregate expenditure function: E = C+I Aggregate Expenditure Function, E • Since • Then C = a + cYd I = I* (autonomous function) E = C+I E = (a + cYd) + (I*) E = (a + I*) + cYd Where • (a + I*) = a constant representing the intercept on the vertical axis • ‘c’ = slope of the E function Aggregate Expenditure Function, E • Since C = a + cYd I* + iYd (induced function) E = C+I • Then E = (a + cYd) + (I* + iYd) E = (a + I*) + (c + i)Yd Where • (a + I*) = a constant representing the intercept on the vertical axis • ‘c + i’ = slope of the E function Aggregate Expenditure Function E E=C+I C = a + cYd E2 E1 (a+I*) a I = I* I* 0 Y Y1 Y2 Aggregate Expenditure Function E E2 C = a + cYd E1 I = I*+iYd a I* 0 Y Y1 Y2 Leakage Function (1): Saving Function, S • showing that planned saving varies positively with but proportionately less than change in Yd • A linear saving function: S = -a + sYd where – -a = a constant = autonomous saving – s = Marginal Propensity to save, MPS A Saving Function, S E, S S = -a + sYd S2 S1 0 -a Y Y1 Y2 MPC (c) and MPS (s) Marginal Propensity to Saving, MPS, s • MPS = s = E, S S Yd M S = -a + sYd △S △Y 0 -a Y Properties of MPS: • the slope of the saving function • 1>MPS>0 • the value of ‘s' is constant for all income levels • Since Y ≡ C + S Then Yd Yd C Yd S Yd Hence 1 = c + s and s = 1 - c Average Propensity to Save, APS • APS = E, S S Yd M S = -a + sYd S 0 -a Y Y Properties of APS: • the slope of the ray from the origin • APS rises when Y rises • Since S = -a + sYd Then i.e. S Yd a s Yd APS Yd ( Yd a S Yd ) a (s) Yd MPS Yd Thus, APS<MPS for all income levels Saving Function Without ‘-a” • If ‘-a’ = 0, then S = sYd E, S S = sYd -a = 0 <45 Y Saving Function Without ‘-a” • If ‘-a’ = 0, then MPS = APS = S Yd E, S M S = sYd S = △S Y -a = 0 Y = △Y Determination of Ye by Income-expenditure Approach • Equilibrium income, Ye is determined when – AS = AD – Total Income = Total Expenditure i.e. Y = E = C + I Given C = a + cYd Ye = Y and I = I* and Yd = Y Determination of Ye by Income-expenditure Approach • In equilibrium: Y= E = C + I = (a + cYd) + (I *) Y- cY= a + I* Then Y(1-c) = a + I* Therefore Ye aI* 1 c or aI* s If Investment Function is Induced … • In equilibrium: Y= E = C + I = (a + cYd) + (I *+iYd) Y- (c+i)Y= a + I* Then Y(1-c-i) = a + I* Therefore Ye aI* 1 c i or aI* si Graphical Representation of Ye Y-line E E=C+I C = a + cYd Ee (a+I*) a I = I* I* 0 Y Ye If Investment Function is Induced…. E Y-line C = a + cYd Ee a 0 Y Ye Determination of Ye by Injection-leakage Approach • Equilibrium income, Ye is determined when – Total Leakage = Total Injection • Given S = -a + sYd I = I* Ye = Y and Yd = Y Determination of Ye by Injection-leakage Approach • In equilibrium: S=I (-a + sYd) = (I *) Then sY = a + I* Therefore Ye aI* s or aI* 1 c If Investment Function is Induced… • In equilibrium: Then S=I (-a + sYd) = (I *+iYd) (s-i)Y = a + I* Therefore Ye aI* si or aI* 1 c i Graphical Representation of Ye E, S I=S S = -a + sYd I* 0 -a I = I* Y Ye If Investment Function is Induced… E, S S = -a + sYd I=S 0 -a Y Ye Graphical Representation of Ye E($) Y-line E=C+I C S 45o I Ye Y($) If Investment Function is Induced… E($) Y-line E=C+I C S I 45o Ye Y($) A Two-sector Model: An Example • Given: – C = $80 + 0.6Y – I = $40 • Since – E = C + I = ($80 + 0.6Y)+($40) Then, E = $120 + 0.6Y A Two-sector Model: An Example • By income-expenditure approach, in equilibrium: –Y=E=C+I Then Y = ($120 + 0.6Y) (1-0.6)Y = $120 Thus, Y = $120/0.4 = $300 A Two-sector Model: An Example • By injection-leakage approach, in equilibrium: – Total injection = Total leakage i.e. I=S – Given I = $40 and S = -a + sYd Then, $40 = (-$80 + 0.4Y) 0.4Y = $120 Thus, Y = $120/0.4 = $300 A Two-sector Model: Exercise • Given: – C = $30 + 0.8Y – I = $50 • Question: (1) Find the equilibrium national income level by the two approaches. (2) Show your answers in two separate diagrams. A Two-sector Model: Exercise • By income-expenditure approach, in equilibrium: –Y=E=C+I Then Y = ($30 + 50) + 0.8Y (1-0.8)Y = $80 Thus, Y = $80/0.2 = $400 Graphical Representation of Ye E Y-line E = $80+0.8Yd Ee C = $30 + 0.8Yd $(30+50) I = $50 $50 $30 0 Y Ye =$400 A Two-sector Model: An Example • By injection-leakage approach, in equilibrium: – Total injection = Total leakage i.e. I=S – Given I = $50 and S = -a + sYd Then, $50 = (-$30 + 0.2Y) 0.2Y = $80 Thus, Y = $80/0.2 = $400 Graphical Representation of Ye E, S I=S S = -$30 + 0.2Yd $50 0 -$30 I = $50 Y Ye=$400 Aggregate Production Function • It relates the amount of inputs, labor (L) and capital (K), used by the entire business sector to the amount of final output (Y) the economy can generate. – Y = f(L, K) • Given the capital stock (i.e. K is constant), Y is a function of the employment of labor. – Thus, Y = 2L (the figure is assigned) An Application • Given Ye = $300 and the labor force is 200. Find (1) the amount of labor (L) required to bring it happened; (2) the level of unemployment and (3) the fullemployment level of income An Application (1) Since Y = 2L ($300) = 2L Then, L = 150 (2 Unemployment level = 200-150 = 50 (3) Since Yf = 2L = 2(200) = $400 Then, Ye < Yf by (400 – 300)$100 Ex-post Saving Equals Expost Investment • Actual income must be spent either on consumption or saving Y ≡ C + S • Actual income must be spent buying either consumer or investment goods Y≡E≡C+I Ex-post Saving Equals Expost Investment • In realized sense, – Since Y ≡ C + S and Y ≡ C + I – Then, I ≡ S • At any given income level, ex-post investment must be equal to ex-post saving, if adjustments in inventories are allowed Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • If planned investment is finally NOT realized (i.e. unrealized investment is positive), then past inventories must be used to meet the planned investment, thus leading to unintended inventory disinvestment. – Unrealized investment invites unintended inventory disinvestment Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • Therefore, – Realized I = Planned I + Change in unintended inventory OR – Realized I = Planned I – Unrealized investment Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • As planned saving and investment decisions are made separately, only when the level of national income is in equilibrium will ex-ante saving be equal to ex-ante investment. Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • In equilibrium, – By the Income-expenditure Approach, • Actual Income = Planned Aggregate Expenditure Y = E = Planned C + Planned I Y = (a + cY) + (I*) – By the Injection-leakage Approach. • Total Injection = Total Leakage Planned I = Planned S (= Actual I = Actual S) Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • If planned aggregate expenditure is larger than actual income or output level, i.e. E > Y, then AD > AS planned I > planned S unintended inventory disinvestment AS (next round) = AD Y = E Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • If planned aggregate expenditure is smaller than actual income or output level, i.e. E < Y, then AD < AS planned I < planned S unintended inventory investment AS (next round) = AD Y = E and unintended stock = 0 Ex-ante Saving Equals Exante Investment • If ex-ante saving and ex-ante investment are not equal, income or output will adjust until they are equal. • In equilibrium, therefore – Y = E or I = S – Unintended inventory = 0 – Unrealized investment = 0 An Illustration (1) =(2)+(3) (2) = (1)-(3) (3) =(1)-(2) (4)=I* (5) =(2)+(4) (6) =(1)-(5) (7) = -(6) (8) =(4)+(6) Y P. C. P. S. P. I. P. A. E. U.C.I. UR.I. A. I. Level of Income Planned Consumption Expenditure Planned Saving Planned Investment Expenditure Planned Aggregate Expenditure Unintended Change in Inventory Unrealized Investment Actual Investment 0 80 -80 40 120 -120 120 -80 100 140 -40 40 180 -80 80 -40 200 200 0 40 240 -40 40 0 300 260 40 40 300 0 0 40 400 320 80 40 360 40 -40 80 500 380 120 40 420 80 -80 120 •MPC, c = (140-80)/(100-0) = 0.6 •C = a + cYd = 80 + 0.6Yd •I = 40 and E = C + I = 120 + 0.6Yd An Illustration Actual income or output level (Y) Planned aggregate expenditure (E) Ex-ante Unintended change in stocks Actual aggregate expenditure Ex-post 200 300 400 240 300 360 E>Y I>S -40 E=Y I=S 0 E<Y I<S 40 240-40 300 360+40 =200 =400 YE YE YE Exercise 1 • Given: C = 60 + 0.8Y & I = 60 • Find the equilibrium level of national income, Ye, by the incomeexpenditure and injection-leakage approaches. Answer 1 • Given: C = 60 + 0.8Y & I = 60 • By the Income-expenditure Approach: Ye = E = C + I Ye = (60 + 0.8Y) + (60) Ye = 600 # Answer 1 • Given: C = 60 + 0.8Y & I = 60 • By the Injection-leakage Approach: I=S 60 = -60 + 0.2Y Ye = 600 # Exercise 2 • Given: C = 60 + 0.8Y & I = 60 • Show the equilibrium level of national income, Ye, in a diagram. Exercise 3 (1) =(2)+(3) (2) = (1)-(3) (3) =(1)-(2) (4)=I* (5) =(2)+(4) (6) =(1)-(5) (7) = -(6) (8) =(4)-(7) Y P. C. P. S. P. I. P. A. E. U.C.I. UR.I. A. I. Level of Income Planned Consumption Expenditure Planned Saving Planned Investment Expenditure Planned Aggregate Expenditure Unintended Change in Inventory Unrealized Investment Actual Investment 0 60 -60 60 120 -120 120 -60 200 220 -20 60 280 -80 80 -20 300 300 0 60 360 -60 60 0 400 380 20 60 440 -40 40 20 500 460 40 60 520 -20 20 40 600 540 60 60 600 0 0 60 700 620 80 60 680 20 -20 80 Exercise 4 • Given C = 10 + 0.8Y • If Y = 1000, then and I = 8 – What is the level of realized investment? Exercise 4 • Given C = 10 + 0.8Y • If Y = 1000, then and I = 8 – What is the level of realized investment? – As Y = 1000, C = 10 + 0.8(1000) = 810 – As Y C + S Actual S = I = 1000-810 = 190 Exercise 4 • Given C = 10 + 0.8Y • If Y = 1000, then and I = 8 – What is the level of unplanned inventory investment? Exercise 4 • Given C = 10 + 0.8Y • If Y = 1000, then and I = 8 – What is the level of unplanned inventory investment? – Unplanned inventory investment = actual I – planned I = 190 – 8 = 182 In Equilibrium… • Actual Y = Planned aggregate E • Ex-ante I = ex-ante S (=actual I = actual S) • Unplanned investment = 0 • Unrealized investment = 0 Movement Along a Function • A movement along a function represent a change in consumption or investment in response to a change in national income. • While the Y-intercepting point and the function do NOT move. • YC = a + cYd C • YI = I* + iYd I Movement Along a Consumption Function • YC = a + c Yd C E B C2 A C1 C = a + cYd a 0 Y1 Y2 Y Exercise 5 • Given C = 80 + 0.6Yd. How is consumption expenditure changed when Y rises from $100 to $150? Show it in a diagram. Answer 5 E B 170 A 140 C = $80+0.6Yd $80 0 100 150 Y Exercise 6 • Given I = 40 + 0.2Yd. How is investment expenditure changed when Y rises from $100 to $150? Show it in a diagram. Answer 6 E B $70 $60 A I = $40+0.2Yd $40 0 $100 Y $150 Shift of a Function • A shift of a consumption or investment function is a change in the desire to consume(i.e. ‘a’) or invest(i.e. ‘I*) at each income level. • As the change is independent of income, it is an autonomous change. • a C = a + cYd • I* I = I* or I = I* + iYd Shift of a Function • A change in autonomous consumption or investment expenditure (i.e. ‘a’ or ‘I*) will lead to a parallel shift of the entire function. • The slope of the function remains unchanged. • An upward parallel shift in C function implies a downward parallel shift of S function Shift of a Consumption Function • a C = a + cYd E, Y C2=a2+cYd C1=a1+cYd a2 a1 0 Y Exercise 7 • Given C=80+0.6Yd & Y=$100. How is consumption function affected if autonomous consumption expenditure rises to $100? Show it in a diagram. Answer 7 E, Y C2=100+0.6cYd C1=80+0.6Yd 160 140 100 80 0 Y 100 Shift of an Investment Function • I* I = I* E, Y I*2 I*1 0 I2=I*2 I1=I*1 Y Rotation of a Function • A change in marginal propensities, i.e. MPC and MPI, will lead to a rotation of the function on the Y-axis. • The slope of the function rises with larger marginal propensities; vice versa. • An upward rotation of C function implies a downward rotation of S function Rotation of a Consumption Function • c C = a + cYd E, Y C2=a+c2Yd C1=a+c1Yd a 0 Y Exercise 8 • Given C=80+0.6Yd & Y=$100. How is consumption function affected if MPC rises to 0.8? Show it in a diagram. Answer 8 E, Y C2=80+0.8Yd 160 C1=80+0.6Yd 140 80 0 Y 100 The Multiplier • A n autonomous change in consumption expenditure (‘a’) or investment expenditure (‘I*) will lead to a parallel shift of the aggregate expenditure function (E). • The slope of E function rises with larger autonomous expenditure; vice versa. The Multiplier • a or I* E • E > Y planned I > planned S unintended inventory disinvestment AD > AS excess demand occurs AD = AS (next round) E = Y (higher Ye) The Multiplier • The (income) multiplier, K, measures the magnitude of income change that results from the autonomous change in the aggregate expenditure function. • If I is an autonomous function, then autonomous expenditure = (a + I*). • Multiplier, K change in Y change in autonomous expenditur e The Multiplier The Multiplier E or Y In itia l e x p e n d itu re 2 n d ro u n d 3 rd ro u n d … T o ta l S $1 $ 0 .6 $ 0 .4 $ 0 .3 6 $ 0 .2 4 … … $ 1 (1 /0 .4 )= $ 2 .5 $ 0 .4 (1 /0 .4 )= $ 1 The Multiplier E, Y Y-line E2 E E1 (with a1) a2 E1 a1 0 E2 (with a2) K=Y/E Y Y1 Y2 The Multiplier Y a I* or a I* 1- c Y Then, Δ(a I*) 1 c Y (a I*) s or Δ(a I*) s 1 1 c or Thus, by definition , k If s 1, then k 1 1 s Y E ΔY Δ(a I*) 1 1 c or 1 s The Multiplier • If I is an induced function, then... Y a I* or a I* 1 - c -i Y Then, Δ(a I*) 1 c -i Y (a I*) s -i or Δ(a I*) s -i 1 1 c -i Thus, by definition , k or 1 s -i Y E ΔY Δ(a I*) 1 1 c -i or 1 s -i Remarks on the Multiplier • If I is an induced function, then the value of multiplier is smaller. • The larger the value of MPC or MPI, the larger the value of the multiplier; vice versa. • The smaller the value of MPS, the larger the value of the multiplier; vice versa. Remarks on the Multiplier • If MPS = 1 or MPC = 0 and MPI = 0 – then, k=1/1-c = 1 • If MPS = 0 or MPC = 1 and MPI = 0 – then, k=1/1-c = 0, i.e. infinity – then there is an infinite increase in income Exercise 9 • Given C = $80 + 0.6Yd • Find the value of the multiplier if – I = $40 – I = $40 + 0.1Yd Exercise 10 • ‘By redistribute $1 from the rich to the poor will help increase the level of national income.’ Explain with the following assumptions: Exercise 11 • What is the size of the multiplier if the economy has already achieved full employment (i.e. Ye = Yf)?