Currency Swaps 1 Overview of the Lecture 1. Definitions 2. Motivation 3. A simple example 4. A real world example © 1999-2003 1. Definitions 3 Presentation • There are two main kinds of swaps (currency and interest rate) but many different variations exist. • As a whole, the swaps market is by far the largest financial derivative market in the world. • Currency swap is a long-term financing/hedging technique. It helps manage both interest and exchange rate risk. • It can be viewed as a series of forward contracts. © 1999-2003 4 Currency swap • A currency swap is an agreement to exchange principal and fixed interest in one currency for principal and fixed interest in another currency. • The initial value of the contract is usual chosen to be zero. © 1999-2003 5 Properties • A currency swap gives the parties to the contract the right of offset, that is the right to offset any nonpayment of principal or interest with a comparative nonpayment. • A currency swap is not a loan and therefore does not change the liability structure of the parties’ balance sheets. • There is an exchange of principal (unlike for interest rate swaps). © 1999-2003 6 A bit of history • Before 1981 companies were involved in back-to-back loans where they agreed to borrow in their domestic currency and lend to each other these currencies. • The long-term currency swap transactions started in August, 1981. • The World Bank issued $290mln in bonds and used the dollar proceeds in currency swaps with IBM for German marks and Swiss francs. © 1999-2003 2. Motivation: Crosscurrency comparative advantage Usual conditions for a currency swap • In general, currency swap assumes that one counterparty borrows under specific terms and conditions in one currency, while the other counterparty borrows under different terms and conditions in a second currency. • The two counterparties exchange the net receipts from their respective issues and agree to service each other’s debt. © 1999-2003 8 9 Example 1 Suppose two firms, A and B, can borrow at the fixed rates of interest as follows: Firm A $ 10.0% € 12.2% Firm B 12.8% 11.0% © 1999-2003 An absolute borrowing advantage 10 • Observe: – Firm A can pay 2.8% less than firm B on the debt denominated in U.S. dollars. – Firm A must pay 1.2% more than firm B on the debt denominated in euros. • Therefore: – Firm A has an absolute advantage in borrowing in the U.S. dollar market. – Firm B has an absolute advantage in borrowing in the euro market. • The minimum rate in each market could be reached. © 1999-2003 11 Example 2 Suppose two firms, A and B, can borrow at the fixed rates of interest as follows: Firm A $ 10.0% € 12.2% Firm B 11.0% 12.8% © 1999-2003 A comparative borrowing advantage 12 • Observe: – Firm A can pay full 1.0% less than firm B on the debt denominated in U.S. dollars. – Firm A can pay only 0.6% less than firm B on the debt denominated in euros. • Therefore: – Firm A has a comparative advantage in borrowing in the U.S. dollar market. – Firm B has a comparative advantage in borrowing in the euro market. • The total cost of borrowing could be decreased. © 1999-2003 13 How does it happen? • Firm A may be an American company and/or known better to American investors and financial institutions. • Firm B may be a German company and/or known better to German or European investors and financial institutions. © 1999-2003 3. A Simple Example Firms need financing in a foreign currency • Suppose firm A wants to borrow €30M to finance its new production line in Germany. • Suppose firm B wants to borrow $20M to raise capital for its subsidiary in the U.S. © 1999-2003 15 Scenario 1: direct borrowing • Firm A borrows € at 12.2%. • Firm B borrows $ at 11.0%. • The combined cost of borrowing for two firms is 12.2+11.0 = 23.2%. © 1999-2003 16 Scenario 1: initial cash flow 17 diagram German Bank €30M 12.2% U.S. Bank $20M 11.0% €30M $20M Firm A Firm B €30M $20M German Branch U.S. Subsidiary © 1999-2003 18 Scenario 2: indirect borrowing (with a currency swap) • Firm A borrows $ at 10.0%. • Firm B borrows € at 12.8%. • Firms swap currencies at the beginning and at the maturity of the contract. • Firms pay each other’s interest payments. – Firm A pays firm B 12.8% on €30M, €3.84M. – Firm B pays firm A 10.0% on $20M, $2M. • Firm A compensates firm B for borrowing € at 12.8% rather than $ at 11.0%. © 1999-2003 Scenario 2: initial cash flow diagram U.S. Bank $20M 10.0% German Bank €30M 12.8% $20M €30M $20M Firm A Firm B €30M €30M $20M German Branch U.S. Subsidiary © 1999-2003 19 Scenario 2: interest flow diagram U.S. Bank $20M 10.0% German Bank €30M 12.8% $2M €3.84M $2M Firm A Firm B €3.84M €3.84M $2M German Branch U.S. Subsidiary © 1999-2003 20 Scenario 3: final cash flow diagram U.S. Bank $20M 10.0% German Bank €30M 12.8% $20M €30M $20M Firm A Firm B €30M €30M $20M German Branch U.S. Subsidiary © 1999-2003 21 4. A Real World Example: Kodak’s Zero-Coupon Australian Dollar Swap through Merrill Lynch 23 Kodak’s financial needs • It needs at least $75M for 5 years. • In the U.S. market it can borrow at 7.5% (50 basis points above U.S. Treasuries). • Outside the U.S. it can borrow at 7.35% (35 basis points above U.S. Treasuries). © 1999-2003 Merrill Lynch’s market analysis • Investor interest in non-dollar issues is much stronger in Europe than in the U.S. • Kodak should issue a Eurobond debt dominated in a currency different from the U.S. dollar. • Australian zero-coupon issue is selling very well in Europe. © 1999-2003 24 25 The beginning • Kodak issues a A$200M zero-coupon, 5-year Eurobond. • Net proceeds to Kodak were A$106M or 53% of A$200M. • What is the Kodak’s cost of the Eurobond A$200 issue? A$106 5 1 r$A r$A 13.5% © 1999-2003 What can Kodak do? alternative 1 26 • Kodak can obtain its desired $75M by converting A$106M at the $/A$ = 0.7059. • Kodak is exposed to fluctuations in the value of the Australian dollar against the U.S. dollar. © 1999-2003 What can Kodak do? alternative 2 27 • Kodak enters into a 5-year swap contract with Merrill Lynch. • At the beginning of the contract, Kodak swaps A$106M for $75M. • Over the life of the contract, Kodak pays 7.35% of $75M ($2,756,250 semiannually) to Merrill Lynch. • At the maturity of the contract, Kodak swaps $75M back for A$106M. • Kodak’s currency risk exposure is eliminated. © 1999-2003 The position of Merrill Lynch • The currency risk is fully transferred from Kodak to Merrill Lynch. • Is Merrill Lynch happy with that? No. • What can Merrill Lynch do? It can enter into a currency swap with a party that is willing to pay $ in exchange for A$. © 1999-2003 28 29 • Merrill Lynch’s currency swap conditions Merrill Lynch enters into a swap contract with an Australian Bank agreeing to make semiannual payments of LIBOR less 40 basis points. • The Australian bank cannot swap A$200M. It can only swap A$130M and pay Merrill Lunch 13.39% semiannually. • Merrill Lynch still has currency exposure because it is left with A$70M (A$200MA$130M). © 1999-2003 30 Merrill Lynch’s next step • Merrill Lynch exchanges the remaining A$38M (A$106M-A$68M) for $27M in the spot market. • Merrill Lynch enters into a forward contract with the Australian bank to exchange $37M for A$70M in five years at the rate $/A$ = 0.5286. • Now Merrill Lynch is no longer exposed to currency risk. © 1999-2003 Merrill Lynch’s last risk exposure • Merrill Lunch is exposed to interest rate risk. • Where does this risk come from? From Merrill Lynch’s floating rate obligations on the A$68M for $48M swap with the Australian bank. • What can Merrill Lynch do? It can enter into an interest rate swap with a party that is willing to pay a floating rate and receive a fixed rate. © 1999-2003 31 32 Conclusions • Currency swaps provide real benefits to both parties. • Currency swaps are beneficial when there exist cross-country barriers to full arbitrage. • Currency swaps are useful when long-term capital is needed and the forward foreign exchange markets are not well developed. © 1999-2003