Workshop on Electoral Methods Designing electoral systems: Properties, thresholds, methods. Application to the Riksdag election in Sweden Victoriano Ramírez-González University of Granada (Spain) vramirez@ugr.es Stockholm, May 30-31, 2011 OUTLINE 1. Introduction to electoral systems 2. Properties of an electoral system 3. Continuous thresholds 4. Application to the current electoral system in Sweden Properties for a proportional electoral system Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Introduction to electoral systems • Size of the Parliament – No problem in designing an E.S. It can have 300, 500,…seats. • Constituencies – Tradition. – Geographic limitations. – Gerrymandering is important when there are uninominal districts, but it is not relevant if the total number of seats of the political parties depends on their total number of votes. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Introduction to electoral systems (cont.) • Representation of political parties – Sometimes it is calculated by applying a proportional method in each constituency and, when doing so, discordant allotments frequently emerge. – In other cases the representation of political parties depends on the total number of votes of each party. We can cite several examples, such as Germany, Mexico, Sweden, Greece and Italy (but with different criteria applied in each country). Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Introduction to electoral systems (cont.) • Thresholds – Continuous thresholds are not oftenly used. I consider it is better not setting thresholds or change. o Classical thresholds imply obtaining a minimal number of votes or a minimum percentage of votes. Hence: • If the minimal is small, then the threshold provide non-practical consequences. • If the minimal is large, unfair results can be obtained. For example, a change of one vote can lead to a change in a big number of seats. – E.g. In Italy, a difference of one vote between two parties leads to a change of more than 60 seats from one party to another party. • Therefore, classical thresholds are not logical. o Moreover, a threshold is continuous if a change of one vote leads to a new allotment which does not differ more than one seat from the previous allotment, for any of the political parties. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Hamilton Electoral Method: I • Alabama paradox (First, the integer part of their exact proportion (quota) is assigned to each political party. Then, the distribution is completed by assigning an additional seat to those political parties with greater remainders) Hamilton-12 Votes Quota Seats A 433000 4.33 4 B 340000 3.4 3 C 240000 2.4 2 D 142000 1.42 2 E 45000 0.45 1 Hamilton-14 Votes Quota Seats A 433000 5.05 5 B 340000 3.97 4 C 240000 2.8 3 D 142000 1.66 2 E 45000 0.53 0 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Hamilton Electoral Method: II • Inconsistency A 425000 4.25 4 B 135000 1.35 1 C 40000 0.40 1 Hamilton-2 Votes Quotas Seats B 135000 1.54 2 C 40000 0.46 0 Hamilton-6 Votes Quota Seats Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Divisor Methods • If we multiply the votes by a factor k, fractions appear. How are the fractions rounded to integers? • Example: if V = ( 90, 130, 360 ) and k = 0.01, then we have the fractions: k V = ( 0.90, 0 1 1.30, 2 3.60 ) 3 4 5 6 Threshold for rounding: 0.8, 1.4, 2.4, 3.1, 4.8, 5.2, …. 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Rounding: 1, 1, 4. To assign 6 seats this is the solution, but to allocate only 5 seats then we have to decrease k. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Some Divisor Methods • Jefferson (d’Hondt). Rounding down . The thresholds are: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, … • Webster (Sainte-Laguë). Rounding to the nearest entire number • The thresholds are: 0.5, 1.5, 2.5, 3.5, 4.5, 5.5, 6.5, … Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Jefferson method (also called d’Hondt method) • Example: To allot 24 seats Votes 990, 430, 400, 270, 180, 80, 50 Quota 9.9, 4.3, 4.0, 2.7, 1.8, 0.8, 0.5 Hondt Votes *0.0113 11.18, 4.86, 4.52, 3.05, 2.03, 0.90, 0.57 0 11, 4, 4, 3, 2, 0, 0 • Lower quota. • It penalizes the fragmentation of the political parties. • It benefits the large political parties. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Webster method (Sainte-Laguë method) • Example: To allot 24 seats Votes 990, 430, 400, 270, 180, 80, 50 Quota 9.9, 4.3, 4.0, 2.7, 1.8, 0.8, 0.5 Webster Votes *0.01 9.9, 4.3, 4.0, 2.7, 1.8, 0.8, 0.5 10, 4, 4, 3, 2, 1, 0 • It is impartial. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Criteria for choosing an electoral method • Desirable properties: Exactness, lower quota, impartial, monotonous, consistency, punish schisms. Hamilton Webster Hondt Exacness yes yes yes Lower Quota yes No yes Impartial yes yes No Monotonous No yes yes Consistency No yes yes Punish Schisms No No yes d’Hondt is one of the most recommended methods for allocating seats to parties. Webster should be used when impartiality is very important. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Properties for an electoral system: I • Applying acceptable methods of apportionment (consistency, no paradoxes, exactness, homogeneous, etc.) – Divisor methods (in general). – Jefferson for allocating seats to the different political parties. – Webster when impartiality is required. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Properties for an electoral system: II Representativity • A good representativity involves that an electoral system must meet the following properties: – Local representativity (i.e. representation of the most voted parties). – Global representativity (i.e. high proportionality. For example, more than 95% with the usual indexes to measure it.). – Equity. Two political parties with a similar number of votes must be allocated an equal or almost equal number of seats. – No discordant allotments. – Fair representation of voters. • Usually several (sometimes even all) of these requirements are not verified. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Properties for an electoral system: III • Governability – Bonus in the representation of the winner party. • Continuity – Application of continuous methods to transform votes into seats. – Application of continuous thresholds. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Why Governability? • Are both representativity and governability mutually self-excluding? – No, it is possible governability. to obtain large representativity and • A country must: – Be well represented. – Enjoy governance. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Governance in the current electoral systems • The vast majority of electoral systems. • Proportional electoral systems with plenty of small or median constituencies (many countries). • Electoral laws (e.g. Italy, Mexico, Greece). • Large thresholds. • Exceptions: Israel, Netherlands, Estonia (only one constituency and small or null threshold). Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden U.K. 2010-Election U.K. 2010-Election Political party % votes Conservative 36.1 Labour 29.0 Liberal 23.0 Democrat UKIP 3.1 BNP 1.9 SNP 1.7 Green 1.0 Sinn Fein 0.6 Democratic 0.6 Unionist Plaid Cymru 0.6 SDLP 0.4 Other parties 2.0 100.00 Seats 306 258 57 0 0 6 1 5 8 3 3 3 650 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Some current bonus for the winner • Italy, 2008: – Il PDL 37.64% votes 44.08% seats • Germany, 2005: – SPD 34.25% votes 40.67% seats • Spain, 2008: – PSOE 43.20% votes 48.28% seats 43.90% votes 53.33% seats • Greece, 2009: – PASOK • Netherlands, 2010 – VVD 20.49% votes 20.67% seats Fragmentation: 31 – 30 – 24 – 21 – 15 – 10 – 10 – 5 – 2 - 2 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Threshold: Proportionality 40 30 20 10 10 000 20 000 30 000 40 000 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Usual threshold (non-continuous) 50 40 30 20 10 10 000 20 000 30 000 40 000 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous threshold 50 40 30 20 10 10 000 20 000 30 000 40 000 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Comparison Usual (non-continuous) vs Continuous thresholds 50 40 30 20 10 10 000 20 000 30 000 40 000 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Is it possible to meet all the properties mentioned before? Yes, it is possible to design electoral systems verifying: » To apply accpetable methos of apportionment » High proportionality and representativity (for parties and voters). » Bonus for the winner (governability). » Continuity and equity. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden How? By using only continuous thresholds. By allocating the seats to the political parties in several stages and as a function of its total votes. By allocation the seats to the constituencies in proportion to the number of electors By using a biproportional allotment to determine the number of seats for each party in each constituency. In the next section, I apply all this to the Swedish case. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Application to the Rikstag election in Sweden • Motivation and some undesirable behavior • Analysis • Examples • Alternative Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Some clarifications • First of all, the Swedish electoral system can be considered as very good. • But we are here to try to improve it. So I am going to show all undesirable behaviors (in my opinion) that have occurred in the past in the Swedish electoral system or that may emerge in the future. • Finally I will show the results when using the biproportionality, which I consider to be more appropriate. Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden The Swedish electoral system • The small alarm as a result of the current allocation – Deficiency of proportionality in the current distribution. – The same has happened in several regional parliaments. • Other undesirable behavior may happen in the future – The final size of constituencies is not proportional to the citizens called to vote. A more populous constituency may have fewer representatives than other less populous one (this occurs in the current distribution). – A political party with more votes can have fewer representatives. – The electoral system it is no equitable for two political parties, both with similar number of votes, one of them having less than 4% of total votes and the other one having more than 4% Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Deficiency of proportionality in the current allotment • The allocation of 310 seats among 29 constituencies Party Votes Perma. Proport. Current Social Democrats 1 827 497 112 109 112 Moderate 1 791 766 107 106 107 Green 437 435 19 26 25 Liberal 420 524 17 25 24 Centre 390 804 21 23 23 Sweden Democrats 339 610 14 20 20 Left 334 053 9 20 19 Christian Democrats 333 696 11 20 19 5 875 385 310 349 349 Total Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden The final size of constituencies is not proportional Constituency Electors Perman. Seats 310 Current seats Proport. Seats 349 Stockholms län 850 629 37 38- 42 Stockholms kommun 634 464 28 29- 31 Göteborgs kommun 389 821 17 18- 19 Östergötlands län 330 010 14 15- 16 Skåne läns södra 267 562 12 13 13 Västra Götalands läns västra Jönköpings län 264 666 12 13 13 256 538 11 13 13 Uppsala län 253 765 11 13+ 12 Skåne läns norra och östra 232 273 10 12+ 11 Hallands län 229 891 10 12+ 11 Gävleborgs län 217 152 10 12+ 11 Dalarnas län 217 072 10 11 11 Örebro län 215 772 9 12+ 11 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden The final size of constituencies is not proportional Constituency Electors Perman. seats Current seats Proport. seats Malmö kommun Skåne läns västra Värmlands län: Västra Götalands läns norra Södermanlands län Västerbottens län Västra Götalands läns östra: Norrbottens län Västmanlands län Västernorrlands län Kalmar län Västra Götalands läns södra Kronobergs län Blekinge län Jämtlands län Gotlands län 214 326 213 580 213 239 205 328 204 779 201 902 200 322 194 788 192 258 191 150 184 737 144 186 138 781 118 279 100 144 46 237 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 8 8 8 6 6 5 4 2 1010 12+ 12+ 11+ 11+ 10 911+ 9 9 666 42 11 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 9 7 7 6 5 2 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden More votes but fewer seats • If in the last elections in Sweden, the Moderate political party would have obtained some more votes, for example their votes multiplied by the factor of 1.02 in each of their constituencies, then we would have the following result: – The distribution of the 310 seats in 28 constituencies unchanged. – In Goteborgs Kommun the allot change: Moderate gains a seat and Socialist loses a seat. We have: Party: Votes: M.S C FL KD A.S V MP SD 1827601, 390804, 420524, 333696, 1827497, 334053, 437435, 339610 310 seats 108 21 17 11 111 9 19 14 349 seats 108 23 24 19 111 19 25 20 Quota 107.9 23.1 24.8 19.7 107.9 19.7 25.8 20.1 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Equity and Threshold Party Votes % Seats Green 296,935 5.5 20 Christian Democratic 158,182 2.9 0 1991 Left Party Green Party 246,905 185,051 4.5 3.4 16 0 2006 Green Party Sweden Democrats 291,121 162,463 5.2 2.9 19 0 1988 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Bonus for the winner party Election Winner party %Votes %Seats Dif. 1982 Social Democratic 45.61 47.56 1.95 1985 Social Democratic 44.68 45.56 0.88 1988 Social Democratic 43.21 44.70 1.49 1991 Social Democratic 37.71 39.54 1.83 1994 Social Democratic 45.25 46.13 0.88 1998 Social Democratic 36.39 37.54 1.15 2002 Social Democratic 39.85 41.26 1.41 2006 Social Democratic 34.99 37.25 2.26 2010 Social Democratic 30.66 32.09 1.43 Mean 1.48 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Conclusions for the current electoral system in Sweden Acceptable methods. Hamilton’s method is used in order to allocate the 310 seats of the Rikstag into the constituencies. Consequently, it is reasonable to replace this method by Webster’s method. Governability. Yes (small) Representativity Local. Yes Global. Yes (high) Equity. No (for the threshold) More votes not less seats. Almost Yes Representativity of the citizens (right size of constituencies) No So, Some undesirable behaviors are possible Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Alternative • To determine the constituencies size using Webster’ method for the 349 seats • To apply a continuous threshold to determine the representation of the political parties in proportion to their total votes (Webster’ method is used) • To apply biproportional method of M. Balinski and G. Demange (Webster is used) Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden The size of constituencies using Webster Constituency Electors Seats Constituency Electors seats Stockholms län 850 629 42 Skåne läns västra 213 580 10 Stockholms kommun 634 464 31 Värmlands län: 213 239 10 Göteborgs kommun 389 821 19 Västra Gö. läns norra 205 328 10 Östergötlands län 330 010 16 Södermanlands län 204 779 10 Skåne läns södra 267 562 13 Västerbottens län 201 902 10 Västra G. läns västra 264 666 13 Västra Götal. läns östra: 200 322 10 Jönköpings län 256 538 13 Norrbottens län 194 788 10 Uppsala län 253 765 12 Västmanlands län 192 258 9 Skåne länsöstra 232 273 11 Västernorrlands län 191 150 9 Hallands län 229 891 11 Kalmar län 184 737 9 Gävleborgs län 217 152 11 Västra Götala. läns södra 144 186 7 Dalarnas län 217 072 11 Kronobergs län 138 781 7 Örebro län 215 772 11 Blekinge län 118 279 6 Malmö kommun 214 326 11 Jämtlands län 100 144 5 Gotlands län 46 237 2 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous Threshold for Sweden, 2010 • We show two posibilities: 0.5% and 1% • 0.5% means decreasing the number of votes, for each political party, in a number equal to 0.5% of the total valid votes obtained by the parties. So, in the 2010 election the total votes were: 5960408 The political parties obtained the next number of votes: 1827497, 1791766, 437435, 420524, 390804, 339610, 334053, 333696, 85023 (several parties) Then, if we use the 0.5% threshold we would be decreasing the votes: 0.005*5960408=29802 votes 1797695, 1761964, 407633, 390722, 361002, 309808, 304251, 303894, 0 (all parties) Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous Threshold for Sweden, 2010 Party Social D. Moderate Green Liberal Center Sweden D. Left Kristian D. Votes -0.5% 1797695, 1761964, 407633, 390722, 361002, 309808, 304251, 303894, Seats Votes -1% 112 1767893 109 1732162 25 377831 24 360920 22 331200 19 280006 19 274449 19 274092 349 Seats 115 112 24 23 21 18 18 18 349 Current 112 107 25 24 23 20 19 19 349 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous Threshold for Sweden, 2006 List-2006 Votes Quota Social Democratic Party 1,942,625 122.13 Moderate Party 1,456,014 91.74 Center Party 437,389 27.50 Liberal Party 418,395 26.30 Christian Democratic Party 365,998 23.01 Left Party 324,722 20.41 Green Party 291,121 18.30 Sweden Democrats 162,463 10.21 % 35.0 26.2 7.9 7.5 6.6 5.8 5.2 2.9 Current -0.5% -1% 130 97 29 28 24 22 19 0 129 96 28 26 23 20 18 9 133 98 27 25 22 19 17 8 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous Threshold for Sweden, 1991 List-1991 Votes Quota % Social Democratic Party Moderate Party Liberal Party Center Party Christian Democratic Party New Democracy Left Party Green Party 2,062,761 1,199,394 499,356 465,175 390,351 368,281 246,905 185,051 131.59 76.51 31.86 29.67 24.90 23.49 15.75 11.81 37.7 21.9 9.1 8.5 7.1 6.7 4.5 3.4 Current -0.5% -1% 138 80 33 31 26 25 16 0 136 79 32 29 24 23 15 11 141 80 31 29 24 22 13 9 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous Threshold for Sweden, 1988 List-1988 Social Democratic Party Moderate Party Liberal Party Center Party Left Party Communists Green Party Christian Democratic Party Votes 2,321,826 983,226 655,720 607,240 314,031 296,935 158,182 Quota 150.79 63.86 42.59 39.44 20.40 19.28 10.27 % 43.2 18.3 12.2 11.3 5.8 5.5 2.9 Current 156 66 44 42 21 20 0 -0.5% -1% 156 65 43 39 19 18 9 160 66 42 39 18 17 7 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Continuous Threshold for Sweden, 1982 List-1982 Votes Social Democratic Party 2,533,250 Moderate Party 1,313,337 Center Party 859,618 Liberal Party 327,770 Left Party Communists 308,899 Christian Democratic Party 103,820 Green Party 91,787 Quota % 159.17 82.52 54.01 20.59 19.41 6.52 5.77 45.6 23.6 15.5 5.9 5.6 1.9 1.7 Current 166 86 56 21 20 0 0 -0.5% -1% 164 84 54 20 18 5 4 168 85 55 19 17 3 2 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Which threshold for Sweden? • - 0.5% is small • -1% is more interesting • -1.5% can be aceptable • -2% or more can be opposite to the traditional high representativity in Sweden Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Biproportional Allotment for the 2010 election in Sweden (Threshold: -0.5) Stockholms l.42 Stock. Ko. 31 Goteborgs 19 Ostergotlands Skane lans sod Vastra lans vas Jonkopings Uppsala Skane lans ost. Hallands Gavleborgs Dalamas Orebro Malmo Skane lans vast Varmlands Vastra lans norr Sodermanlands Vasterbottens Vastra ostra Norrbottens Vastmanlands Vasternorrlands Kalmar Vastra sodra Kronobergs 6 Blekinge 5 Jamtlands 2 Gotlands Total seats Soc. Mod. 159222 111688 80543 92164 50557 59477 66316 58862 54529 52319 67893 67139 70818 48450 49900 68520 56060 59463 72008 57095 85035 58222 70341 55116 37817 35555 36520 33013 12855 112 286249 183421 96981 80141 87893 73853 57901 64750 60930 67878 41009 44997 43791 55160 58628 45578 46582 47889 30184 47049 26852 43462 34550 41631 34334 34762 27387 18193 9731 109 Green Lib 53788 65351 34205 21225 16176 15794 11438 18993 10195 11568 10918 10652 11846 14861 9869 9997 12003 13065 12246 9440 8630 9459 8757 8713 7315 7044 5289 5339 3259 25 59461 45939 26829 19017 19622 20194 12134 16878 12677 15286 9444 8747 11415 11768 13967 10652 13393 11299 10296 10387 7082 12016 8253 7847 8883 6667 5431 3155 1785 24 Cen. SD Left C.D 41369 33895 12183 17561 12717 13563 16859 17838 12871 17178 12982 14086 9807 4795 8164 13379 11449 9850 12699 13914 7618 8266 11185 13829 9273 11559 5771 10487 41369 22 29886 16950 15608 14862 19923 12504 13888 10003 21312 10507 12616 12470 11136 13256 17448 8502 10513 11370 4651 9725 6309 9992 7264 8964 8350 7424 9830 3122 1225 19 31617 39565 27246 14242 7597 10506 8775 11845 6113 6904 12814 10533 10311 10118 5847 10231 9907 8637 17034 8223 15240 9154 9642 7679 6136 5380 5075 5340 2342 19 44880 28244 19484 16357 9916 16525 27822 12265 9420 10994 7235 7925 11235 5274 6989 8312 11092 8095 9125 11092 5388 7406 6983 9341 7745 7111 3973 2340 1128 19 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Biproportional Allotment for Sweden, 2010 Soc. Stockholms lan Stock. Común Goteborgs Ostergotlands Skane lans sod Vastra lans vas Jonkopings Uppsala Skane lans ost. Hallands Gavleborgs Dalamas Orebro Malmo Skane lans vast Varmlands Vastra lans norr Sodermanlands Vasterbottens Vastra ostra Norrbottens Vastmanlands Vasternorrlands Kalmar Vastra sodra Kronobergs Blekinge Jamtlands Gotlands Total 10 7 5 5 3 3 4 3 3 3 4 4 4 3 3 4 3 4 4 3 6 3 5 3 3 3 3 3 1 112 Mod. 17 11 6 5 5 4 3 4 3 4 2 3 2 4 4 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 1 1 109 Green Lib 3 4 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 25 3 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 24 Cen. 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 22 SD 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 19 Left C.D 2 2 2 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 19 3 2 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 19 Total 42 31 19 16 13 13 13 12 11 11 11 11 11 11 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 9 9 7 7 6 5 2 349 Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Conclusions for this alternative Acceptable methods. Yes (it uses only Webster method and it is monotonous, consistent, and homogeneous) Governability. Yes (lower, similar as the current, i.e. small bonus to the winner) Representativity Local. Yes Global. Yes (high) Equity. Yes More votes not less seats. Yes Representativity of the citizens. Yes (proport. constituencies size) The biproportional allotment: Easily obtained with hand-held calculator. NO (We always need a computer and a program like BAZI) Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds, methods. Application to Sweden Designing electoral systems: properties, thresholds,… Application to the Riksdag election in Sweden Thank you very much for your attention! Tack så mycket för er uppmärksamhet! Prof. Dr. Victoriano Ramírez-González vramirez@ugr.es