Excise tax increases, cigarette consumption and government revenue: A win-win-win situation in South Africa Corne van Walbeek School of Economics University of Cape Town This research was made possible with funding from the American Cancer Society Win-win-win in South Africa • Win 1: Public health • Win 2: Government revenue • Win 3: Tobacco industry benefits through their pricing strategy and this pricing strategy has had a positive impact on public health and government revenue Why are excise tax increases so effective in reducing tobacco consumption? • Despite its addictiveness, people respond to changes in the price of cigarettes • Price elasticity of demand for cigarettes in SA (and many low- and middle-income countries is around -0.6) • Thus a 10% increase in cigarette prices reduces consumption by 6% • Not all people respond to changes in cigarette prices, but the poor and youth are typically more responsive than the better-off and the old • Some indicative numbers: – 1000 smokers initially – If price increases by 10%, we would expect 3% (= 30) smokers to quit – Remaining smokers will cut down their consumption by an average of 3% (some more and some less) 0.80 0.40 1960/1961 1961/1962 1962/1963 1963/1964 1964/1965 1965/1966 1966/1967 1967/1968 1968/1969 1969/1970 1970/1971 1971/1972 1972/1973 1973/1974 1974/1975 1975/1976 1976/1977 1977/1978 1978/1979 1979/1980 1980/1981 1981/1982 1982/1983 1983/1984 1984/1985 1985/1986 1986/1987 1987/1988 1988/1989 1989/1990 1990/1991 1991/1992 1992/1993 1993/1994 Excise tax, Rand per 10 cigarettes, constant 2010 prices 1.00 Nominal excise tax per pack of 20 Excise tax increases do not keep up with inflation 0.00 30 Consumer Price Index 25 0.60 20 15 10 0.20 5 0 Consumer Price Index (2010 = 100) Lesson 1 from South Africa Specific taxes are good, but they have to be updated regularly, especially in inflationary times 40 35 2008/2009 2006/2007 2004/2005 2002/2003 2000/2001 1998/1999 1996/1997 1994/1995 1992/1993 1990/1991 1988/1989 1986/1987 1984/1985 1982/1983 1980/1981 1978/1979 1976/1977 1974/1975 5.00 1972/1973 1970/1971 2.00 1968/1969 3.00 1966/1967 4.00 1964/1965 1962/1963 1960/1961 Excise tax, Rand per 20 cigarettes, nominal values 9.00 200 8.00 180 7.00 160 6.00 Nominal excise tax per pack of 20 140 Consumer Price Index 120 100 Government commits to a TC policy based on keeping the tax burden at 50% of the retail price 80 60 40 1.00 20 0.00 0 Consumer Price Index (2010 = 100) Since 1994 rapid excise tax increases followed the small nominal increases in the 1970s and 1980s Lesson 2 from South Africa Don’t make the tobacco industry your tax advisor on excise tax matters Minister of Finance, 1983: “The Tobacco Board has presented justified arguments for the maintenance of the status quo regarding the excise taxes on tobacco, and I do not intend to wake sleeping dogs” Minister of Finance, 1986: “any increases in excise duties at present could be counter-productive, since it could in fact – on account of the potentially adverse effect on consumption – lead to a reduction of revenue from this source” Article 5.3 of the FCTC: In setting and implementing their public health policies with respect to tobacco control, Parties shall act to protect these policies from commercial and other vested interests of the tobacco industry in accordance with national law Lesson 3 from South Africa Keep the tax system simple Specific tax is administratively best, and does not actively encourage the creation of low-price market Complicated tax systems are likely to be used by the tobacco industry to their benefit, and against the public health and/or fiscal interests of the government Example of a complicated excise tax regime: Jamaica – Special consumption tax (SCT): • A specific amount per 100 cigarettes PLUS • An ad valorem tax of X % on cigarettes in excess of specified benchmark value – “Excise levy” payable to the National Health Fund: 23 % of the sum of the ex factory price and the SCT – General Consumption Tax (GCT): Like VAT, an ad valorem tax Lesson 4 from South Africa The math is quite simple Ignoring the impact of changes in income, the impact of a 20% increase in the (specific) excise tax is as follows: Net-of-tax Excise tax price increase increase (percentage) (percentage) Excise tax as percentage of retail price Price elasticity 40 -0.6 20 0 -4.5 14.6 40 -0.3 20 0 -2.3 17.3 40 -1.1 20 0 -8.1 10.3 40 -0.6 20 10 -7.6 10.9 40 -1.1 20 10 -13.4 3.9 70 -0.6 20 0 -7.6 10.9 70 -0.6 20 10 -9.0 9.2 % change % change quantity govt revenue Lesson 5 from South Africa 6000 500 5000 400 4000 300 3000 200 2000 100 1000 Real excise rate Real excise revenue 2009 2005 2001 1997 1993 1989 1985 1981 1977 1973 1969 0 1965 0 Real excise revenue (R million, 2000 prices) 600 1961 Real excise rate (in constant 2000 cents) Big increases in the excise tax have resulted in big increases in tax revenue Between 1993 and 2011 real excise tax increases by 487% and real excise tax revenue increases by 249% Lesson 6 from South Africa The industry has a very strong interest in exaggerating the threat of illicit trade – “The increase in the excise tax will encourage illicit trade” (TISA and BAT, numerous years) – “The illicit market has grown from nothing ten years ago to 20% of the total SA market” (TISA, 2006) – “Illicit trade has doubled over the past two years” (BAT CEO, 2010) – “The government loses R2.6 billion each year to illegal sales” (TISA, 2011) The evidence for a large increase in illicit sales is not convincing 40 35 35 30 30 25 25 20 20 15 15 10 10 5 5 0 0 Illicit market share (Euromonitor) Aggregate cigarette consumption in SA 11% increase in total (legal and illicit) sales 4.3% increase in legal sales 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Cigarette consumption (billion sticks) 40 "Illicit market share" • Total cigarette consumption Legal cigarette consumption In an environment of rapidly increasing average prices and strong tobacco control legislation it seems unlikely that total cigarette consumption would increase by 11% between 2003 and 2009 Bottom line: While illicit trade may be a real issue in many countries, and one should always be vigilant, the industry is not a credible source about the magnitude of the problem Lesson 7 from South Africa The tobacco industry’s pricing model may have beneficial long-run fiscal and public health consequences • The third WIN in the equation: Tobacco industry in SA is more profitable now than before, despite the decrease in cigarette consumption • • • Sharp increase in the net-of-tax price (and thus profit) per cigarette Can do this because tobacco industry in SA, as in most countries, is highly concentrated Low price elasticity works in the industry’s favour • Excise tax in SA is specific but set such that tax burden is 52% of the retail price • Substantially increasing the excise tax initiated a cycle of 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. Increasing retail price (excise tax being passed through) Decreasing consumption (as consumers respond to higher prices) Increasing net-of-tax price (as industry wants to maintain/expand its profitability) Increasing retail price (as the net-of-tax price increases) Decreasing consumption (as consumers respond to higher prices) Increasing excise tax (as government wants to maintain the 52% tax burden) Increasing retail price (back to point 1) A gradual upward ratchet of the real price of cigarettes, with a corresponding decrease in consumption 1200 2000 1000 1500 800 600 1000 400 500 200 Net-of-tax price Excise tax Sales tax (GST/VAT) 2010 2006 2002 1998 0 1994 0 Cigarette Consumption (million packs) 2500 1990 Cents/pack (constant 2000 prices) 1400 Cigarette consumption