Microsoft Powerpoint ( 2.32 MB )

advertisement
Childbearing and
Labor Market:
Time and Space Dynamics
PhD-student Elena Kotyrlo
Supervisor Prof. Magnus Wikström
School of Business and Economics,
University of Umeå,
Sweden
www.marathon.se/news/article.cfm?NewsId=626103
The purpose of the paper
 is to study how the labor market transformed in
households’ income influences on fertility, generated
by
 increased female labor market participation;
 growing period of professional education ;
 increasing labor mobility;
 space and time transitions of income potential;
 response of a gain of labor market’s tightness on
fertility (the Easterlin hypothesis).
2
How incomes influence fertility I
Time dynamics as postponing or accelerating of
childbearing:
 within one generation, when families compare their
current earnings with the earnings in previous and
nearest future periods.
 through the generations, when households belonging
to the younger generation compare their earnings
relatively to earnings of the parental generation (the
Easterlin hypothesis).
3
4
2008
2006
2004
2002
2000
1998
1996
1994
1992
1990
1988
Norway
1986
1984
1982
1980
1978
1976
1974
1972
1970
1968
TFR in Sweden. 1970-2008
Denmark
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
1.5
2
tfr
2.5
3
TFR and cohort ratio in 1972
.5
1
1.5
2
cohort_ratio
5
2
2.5
1.5
tfr
3
3.5
TFR and cohort ratio in 1990
1
1.2
1.4
cohort_ratio
1.6
1.8
6
1
1.5
2
tfr
2.5
3
3.5
TFR and cohort ratio in 1968-2008
.5
1
1.5
cohort_ratio
2
2.5
7
How incomes influence fertility II
Space diffusion is considered
 in transition of fertility norms across municipalities as
a first-order spatial autocorrelation;
 influencing of relative cohort sizes in surrounding
municipalities on fertility norms in a given one;
 and cross-municipal influence of space diffusion of
income generated by labor mobility.
8
Sweden. Total fertility rates in 1970. x-longitude/ylatitude.
9
Sweden. Total fertility rates in 1982. x-longitude/ylatitude.
10
Sweden. Total fertility rates in 1990. x-longitude/ylatitude.
11
Sweden. Total fertility rates in 1999. x-longitude/ylatitude.
12
Comparing of the fertility dynamics in pairs of
municipalities with the short distances between them
3
2.5
2
TFR
Botkyrka
1.5
Södertälje
1
0.5
0
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
13
Comparing of the fertility dynamics in pairs of
municipalities with the short distances between them
2,5
2
TFR
S toc kholm
S olna
1,5
1
0,5
0
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
14
The literature review
Spatial dimension of fertility
the paper by Waldorf and Franklin (2002), where the
Easterlin model of fertility is tested by using data for 18
Italian regions by spatial diffusion of fertility taken into
account.
Easterlin hypothesis
 D.J. Macunovich (1998) reviewed 185 published articles
with 76 empirical analyses of the hypothesis and concluded
that results are mixed.
 Waldorf and Byun (2005) made meta-analysis of 334
empirical papers and concluded that negative effect is
more robust.
15
The contribution of the paper
 the analysis of spatial interdependence of fertility;
 the Easterlin hypothesis as the long-run income
impact;
 the relation between current income and fertility is
also studied;
 using of panel data which allow monitoring space
diffusion of fertility norms across time in “three
dimensions”;
 municipal level of data.
16
Definitions
 Total fertility rate (TFR) is the sum of the age-
specific fertility rate (SFR) for women in the ages 16-49
49
years old
TFR   SFR i
i  16
 Cohort ratio (R) is the number of men of age 35 to 64
year divided by the number of men of age 15 to 34 at
time t-2
Rjt=M35-64, jt / M 15-34, jt
 Average income per capita in the municipality in 20+
age group is corrected by CPI (1982=100) and logged
17
The model
 TFR =f (TFR, WTFR, R, VR, I, VI, X, t).
 Where TFR is fertility rate. R is relative cohort size, X is a
matrix of explanatory variables. W is a n x n matrix that
summarizes the spatial morphology that is of relevance for
diffusion across n municipalities, and the n x n matrix V
summarizes the spatial morphology relevant for labor
movements.
18
Weight matrices
 WN is based on contiguity
 wij=1/ki if i,j share a common border, ki is the number of
municipalities bordering i;
 and wij=0 otherwise.
 VN is based on spherical distances between municipalities,
weighted by population
 where dij is a spherical distances between i and j
municipality.
v ij ( t ) 
Pop j ( t ) / d ij
 Pop
j
( t ) / d ij
j
 For panel data we use and , t = 1..19 for the period 1981-
2008.
19
Empirical Specification
 Spatial lag model SAR(2,1) for panel data
T F R t   1 T F R t 1   2 T F R t  2   W N T T F R t 1   R t 1 
 V N T R t 1   ln I t 1   V N T ln I t 1  X t 1   g ( t ) i  ε t
 Where
W NT  IT  W N ; V NT  I T  V N ;
IT is identity matrix of dimension T, E(it)=0 and
E(itit/)=2INT , t=1..NT;  is a Kronecker product
20
Marginal spatial effects in the short-run
 The short-run effect of the lagged TFR is
T F R t
  W  IN
/
 T F R t 1
 The marginal effects of cohort size ratio and log-
income on fertility are
T F R t
 R t 1
 V  IN
/
and
T F R t
 ln( I ) t 1
 V  IN
/
21
The long-run effects
 can be estimated only in the models with time
specific fixed effects or incorporation of GDP
growth instead of time trend.
 The equation below provides the long-run spatial
effects in the presence of non-zero parameter of the
spatially lagged variable.
T F R
R

  ((1 

2

k 1
k
)I N

  W ) ( V   I N ) 

/
1
22
Stationarity condition
|  j | 1
j 
 1   i 
( 1   i )  4 2
2
2
 Where {i}, i=1..N is a set of the eigenvalues of
the matrix W. Thus, it is sufficient to estimate
maximum and minimum value of .
23
Empirical method
 The estimation of the panel data models with
spatially lagged dependent variables is based
on the method of moments techniques (GMM)
because of autocorrelation of explanatory
variables.
 Arellano-Bond dynamic panel-data
estimation where lag equaled 1 and lag
equaled 2
24
Sets of exogenous variables
First set
 Log_Incomet-1
 Relative cohort t-1
 Share of flow of out/inmigrated women 16-49 age t-1
Second set
 Log_Incomet-1
 Relative cohort t-1
 Share of flow of out/inmigrated women 16-49 age t-1
 Share of women 16-49 with post secondary education
more than 3 years t-1
 Share of women 16-49 with education less than 9 years t-1
25
[1]
Panel data estimates without space weighted elements.
GMM estimates for log(TFR) - fragment
1981-2008
No spatial effects
Variables
1
Coeff.
Number
observations
of
Wald 2
LnTFR t-1
LnTFR t-2
SAR (2,1)
2
St.
dev.
Coeff.
SAR(2,1) with exogenous spatial interaction effect
St.
dev.
3
4
Coeff St.
Coeff. St.
.
dev.
dev.
6596
6596
6322
6596
6322
8406
9007
9963
9612
Coeff.
5
St. dev.
6
Coeff.
7
St.
dev.
659
6
6322
6322
6596
6322
6596
6322
938
8
9007
9615
8406
9007
9963
9612
9936
Coeff.
6596
8
St.
dev.
Coeff.
St.
dev.
6596
6322
6322
9388
9007
9615
9936
0.095*
***
0.015
0.044**
0.016
0.033
*
0.0
15
0.033*
0.015
0.033*
0.015
0.037*
0.015
0.044**
0.016
0.032*
0.015
0.148
****
0.014
0.100
****
0.015
0.084
****
0.0
14
0.086*
***
0.014
0.084
****
0.014
0.092*
***
0.015
0.100
****
0.015
0.086
****
0.014
0.422
****
0.0
32
0.431
****
0.032
0.423
****
0.032
0.430*
***
0.032
Weighted Ln TFR
t-1
-0.759
****
0.200
0.848*
***
0.306
0.269
0.247
0.274
0.398
0.279
0.328
0.272
-0.198
***
0.061
-0.251
****
0.062
-0.011
0.067
-0.042
0.065
-0.660
0.597
-0.458
0.608
-0.639
0.625
-0.708
0.610
Ln(It-1)
0.961
****
0.100
0.120
0.130
0.708
0.066
0.215
*
0.1
94
0.220*
0.130
0.203
-0.017
0.156
0.319*
0.154
Weighted Ln(It-1)
-0.225
****
R t-1
Weighted Rt-1
0.063
-0.014
0.0
59
-0.050
0.065
**** means p-value less than 0.0001, *** - 0.001, ** - 0.01, * - 0.1.
26
Estimates of time-space dynamics in the model describing
TFR as a SAR (2,1) process
Variables
TFR t-1
Weighted TFR t-1
TFR t-2
Ln(It-1)
Weighted Ln(It-1)
R t-1
Weighted R t-1
The share of flow of
out/inmigrated women 16-49
age t-1
The share of women 16-49 with
postsecondary education more
than 3 years t-1
The share of women 16-49 with
education less than 9 years t-1
Intercept
Number of observations
Wald 2
Stationarity
Coeff.
0.032*
0.430****
0.086****
-0.319*
0.328
-0.042
-0.708
1.328**
St. dev.
0.015
0.032
0.014
0.154
0.272
0.065
0.610
0.526
0.978****
The average short-run
effect
Direct
indirect
Total
0.032
0.014
0.132
The average long -run
effect
Direct Indirect Total
0
0
0
0.086
-0.319
0
-0.319
-0.382
-0.323
-0.042
0
-0.042
-0.050
-0.042
1.328
1.594
1.343
0.706
0.093
2.937
0.281
0.978
1.174
0.989
2.163
1.067****
0.274
1.067
1.281
1.079
2.360
1.798****
0.541
1.798
6322
9615
Accepted
27
Main results
 the existence of a spatial positive autocorrelation of
fertility across municipalities 
 declining or rising of fertility in one municipality affects
neighboring municipalities in the same direction;
 the indirect spatial effect and the direct effect in the
short-run explain 0.014% and 0.032% of relative
changes of total fertility rates, correspondently;
 a weak direct effect of the inverted Easterlin
hypothesis .
 a weak negative direct effect of earnings on total
fertility rates.
28
Conclusions
 a set of factors, determining total fertility rates,
influences it in the same direction as in a given
municipality so in the surrounding municipalities;
 the inverted Easterlin hypothesis has been supported.
It has the short-run direct effect, and the long-run
direct and indirect effects.
 Earnings have a negative direct effect. It means the
dominating substitution effect in the choice between
female labor supply and childbearing as a households’
production despite the fact that the family policy in
Sweden provides opportunities to combine them.
29
Download