Chapter 2

advertisement
Chapter 2
Arbitrage-Free Pricing
Definition of Arbitrage
• Suppose we can invest in n assets.
Price of asset i at time t : ๐‘ƒ๐‘– ๐‘ก
Units of asset I : ๐‘ฅ๐‘–
Portfolio value : ๐‘‰ ๐‘ก =
๐‘›
๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ๐‘– (๐‘ก)
Definition of Arbitrage
• ๐‘‰ 0 = ๐‘›๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ๐‘– (0) = 0
• ๐‘ƒ ๐‘‰ ๐‘‡ ≥0 =1
• ๐‘ƒ ๐‘‰ ๐‘‡ >0 >0
ๅฅ—ๅˆฉ็š„ๅฎš็พฉ๏ผŒๆขไปถ็ผบไธ€ไธๅฏ
• Besides the definition given above, the principle of
no arbitrage has the following equivalent forms :
โ–ซ We can not construct a riskless portfolio which returns more
than ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“
โ–ซ If two portfolio have identical future cashflows with
certainty, then the two portfolio must have the same value at
the present time.
2.1 Example of Arbitrage
parallel yield curve shifts
• Suppose that
๐‘ƒ 0, ๐‘‡ = exp[−
๐‘‡
๐‘“
0
0, ๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข]
• ๐‘“ 0, ๐‘ข is the initial forward-rate curve at t=0
• Parallel shifts model dictates that at t=1 the forwardrate curve will be : ๐‘“ 1, ๐‘‡ = ๐‘“ 0, ๐‘‡ + ๐œ–
2.1 Example of Arbitrage
parallel yield curve shifts
• At t=1
๐‘‡
๐‘ƒ 1, ๐‘‡ = exp −
๐‘“ 1, ๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข = exp −
1
๐‘‡
= exp −
๐‘‡
1
๐‘“ 0, ๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข −
0
๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡) −(๐‘‡−1)๐œ–
=
๐‘’
๐‘ƒ(0,1)
(๐‘“ 0, ๐‘ข + ๐œ–)๐‘‘๐‘ข
1
๐‘“ 0, ๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข − ๐‘‡ − 1 ๐œ–
0
ๆญค่™•็š„็ตๆžœๆœƒๅœจไน‹ๅพŒ็š„ๆŠ•ๅฝฑ็‰‡ไธญ็”จๅˆฐ
2.1 Example of Arbitrage
parallel yield curve shifts
• Let ๐‘ฅ๐‘– be the number of units held at t=0 of the bond
maturing at ๐‘‡๐‘– , i=1~3
• For an arbitrage we require
โ–ซ๐‘‰ 0 =
โ–ซ๐‘‰ 1 =
≥ 0,
> 0,
3
๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– )
3
๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ(1, ๐‘‡๐‘– )
=0
๐‘ค๐‘–๐‘กโ„Ž ๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘œ๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘๐‘–๐‘™๐‘–๐‘ก๐‘ฆ 1
๐‘ค๐‘–๐‘กโ„Ž ๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘œ๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘๐‘–๐‘™๐‘–๐‘ก๐‘ฆ ๐‘”๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘Ž๐‘ก๐‘’๐‘Ÿ ๐‘กโ„Ž๐‘Ž๐‘› 0
2.1 Example of Arbitrage
parallel yield curve shifts
• The value of portfolio at t=1 is
• ๐‘‰1 ๐œ– =
3
๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ
1, ๐‘‡๐‘– =
๐‘’ −๐œ– ๐‘‡2 −1
๐‘ƒ 0,1
๐‘”(๐œ–)
ๆญค่™•ไนƒๆ‡‰็”จ็จๆ—ฉ็ฌฌ5ๅผตๆŠ•ๅฝฑ็‰‡็š„็ตๆžœ่€Œๆฑ‚ๅพ—ไน‹็ตๆžœ๏ผŒ
•๐‘” ๐œ– =
3
๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ
0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ๐‘’ −๐œ–(๐‘‡๐‘– −๐‘‡2)
่‡ณๆ–ผๆŠŠT2็จ็ซ‹ๅ‡บไพ†็š„็›ฎ็š„๏ผŒๅ‰‡ๆ˜ฏ็‚บไบ†ๆ–นไพฟไน‹ๅพŒ็š„้‹็ฎ—ใ€‚
ไธ”็”ฑๆ–ผV1(ε)ไธญ๏ผŒๅทฆ้‚Šๅˆ†ๆ•ธไน‹ๅˆ†ๅญๅˆ†ๆฏ็š†ๅคงๆ–ผ้›ถ๏ผŒ่กจ็คบV1(ε)็š„ๆญฃ่ฒ ใ€
ๅคงๅฐๅƒ…่ˆ‡g(ε)ๆœ‰้—œ
2.1 Example of Arbitrage
parallel yield curve shifts
• ๐‘” ๐œ– =
3
๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ
0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ๐‘’ −๐œ–(๐‘‡๐‘– −๐‘‡2 )
• For an arbitrage , we require that ๐‘‰1 ๐œ– > 0 for all ๐œ– ≠ 0, and
since 3๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ) = 0
๏ƒจ๐‘” 0 =0
we must have first order condition
๐‘”′ 0 = 0
3
๐‘ฅ๐‘– (๐‘‡2 − ๐‘‡๐‘– )๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ) = 0
๐‘–=1
3
๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘‡๐‘– ๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ) = 0
๐‘–=1
ๅ› ็‚บg(0)=0๏ผŒ ๐‘‰1 0 = 0
ๅˆ๐‘‰1 ๐œ– > 0๏ผŒๆ‰€ไปฅ๐œ–=0ๅฟ…ๅฎš็‚บ
g(๐œ–)็š„ๆœ€ไฝŽ้ปžใ€‚
2.1 Example of Arbitrage
parallel yield curve shifts
• And S.O.C
3
๐‘”′′ ๐œ– =
๐‘”′′ (0) ≥ 0
๐‘ฅ๐‘– (๐‘‡2 − ๐‘‡๐‘– )2 ๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– )๐‘’ −๐œ–(๐‘‡๐‘– −๐‘‡2)
๐‘–=1
Example 2.1
• Suppose that ๐‘ƒ 0, ๐‘ก = ๐‘’ −0.08๐‘ก for all t > 0, and that,
for all t > 0,
๐‘’ −0.1๐‘ก
๐‘–๐‘“ ๐ผ = 1
๐‘ƒ 1, ๐‘ก + 1 = −0.06๐‘ก
๐‘’
๐‘–๐‘“ ๐ผ = 0
where I= 0 or 1 is a random variable. In other words,
the spot- and forward-rate curves will both have a
shift up or down of 2%.
Example 2.1
Suppose that we hold ๐‘ฅ1 , ๐‘ฅ2 and ๐‘ฅ3 units of the bonds
maturing at times 1, 2 and 3 respectively, such that
๐‘ฅ2 ๐‘ƒ 0,2 = −1
๐‘ฅ1 ๐‘ƒ 0,1 + ๐‘ฅ2 ๐‘ƒ 0,2 + ๐‘ฅ3 ๐‘ƒ 0,3 = 0
๐‘ฅ1 ๐‘ƒ 0,1 + 2๐‘ฅ2 ๐‘ƒ 0,2 + 3๐‘ฅ3 ๐‘ƒ 0,3 = 0
้‹็”จๅˆฐ็š„ๆขไปถ๏ผš
1. ๅ‡ๅฎš๐‘ฅ2 ๐‘ƒ 0,2 = −1
2. 3๐‘–=1 ๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ) = 0
3. F.O.C.
3
๐‘ฅ๐‘– ๐‘‡๐‘– ๐‘ƒ(0, ๐‘‡๐‘– ) = 0
๐‘–=1
Example 2.1
1
๐‘ฅ1 =
= 0.541644
2๐‘ƒ(0,1)
−1
๐‘ฅ2 =
= −1.173511
๐‘ƒ(0,2)
1
๐‘ฅ3 =
= 0.635624
2๐‘ƒ(0,3)
• At time 1 the value of this portfolio is 0.00021 if I=1
or 0.00022 if I=0.
2.2 Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing
• Suppose risk-free rate r(t) is stochastic.
Randomness in r(t) is underpinned by the
probability triple Ω, โ„ฑ, ๐‘ƒ , P is the real world
probability measure.
• Let cash account be
๐‘ก
๐ต ๐‘ก = ๐ต 0 exp(
๐‘Ÿ ๐‘  ๐‘‘๐‘ )
0
๐‘‘๐ต ๐‘ก = ๐‘Ÿ ๐‘ก ๐ต ๐‘ก ๐‘‘๐‘ก
2.2 Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing
• Theorem 2.2
1. Bond price evolve in a way that is arbitrage free if
and only if there exists a measure Q, equivalent to P,
under which, for each T, the discounted price process
P(t,T)/B(t) is a martingale for all t: 0<t<T
2. If 1. holds, then the market is complete if and only if
Q is the unique measure under which the P(t ,T)/B(t)
are martingales.
The measure Q is often referred to, consequently, as the
equivalent martingale measure.
2.2 Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing
• Value of zero coupon bond at time t :
๐‘‡
๐‘ƒ ๐‘ก, ๐‘‡ = ๐ธ๐‘„ exp − ๐‘ก ๐‘Ÿ ๐‘  ๐‘‘๐‘  โ„ฑ๐‘ก
(since P(T,T)=1)
• If X is some โ„ฑt -measurable derivative payment
payable at T, V(t) is the fair value of this derivative
contract
๐‘‡
๐‘‰ ๐‘ก = ๐ธ๐‘„ exp − ๐‘ก ๐‘Ÿ ๐‘  ๐‘‘๐‘  ๐‘‹ โ„ฑ๐‘ก
Example 2.5 forward pricing
• A forward contract has been arranged in which a
price K will be paid at time T in return for a
repayment of 1 at time S (T<S). Equivalently, K is
paid at T in return for delivery at the same time T of
the S-bond which has a value at that time of P(T,S).
How much is this contract worth at time t<T ?
Example 2.5 forward pricing
• As an interest rate derivative contract, this has value ๐‘‹ =
๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† − ๐พ at time t.
• ๐‘‰ ๐‘ก = ๐ธ๐‘„ exp −
= ๐ธ๐‘„ exp −
=
๐‘‡
๐‘Ÿ
๐‘ก
๐‘‡
๐‘Ÿ
๐‘ก
๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข ๐‘‹ โ„ฑ๐‘ก
๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข (๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† − ๐พ) โ„ฑ๐‘ก
=
−
๐‘†
๐ธ๐‘„ exp − ๐‘ก ๐‘Ÿ ๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข
๐‘‡
K๐ธ๐‘„ exp − ๐‘ก ๐‘Ÿ ๐‘ข ๐‘‘๐‘ข
โ„ฑ๐‘ก
โ„ฑ๐‘ก
= ๐‘ƒ ๐‘ก, ๐‘† − ๐พ๐‘ƒ ๐‘ก, ๐‘‡
• If we choose K to ensure that V(t)=0, then
๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก, ๐‘†)
๐พ=
๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก, ๐‘‡)
where
2.6 Put-Call Parity
• Consider European call and put options with the same
exercise date T, a strike price K, and the underlying Sbond, P(t,S), S>T
• Time=t
๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘’ ๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘™๐‘™ ๐‘œ๐‘๐‘ก๐‘–๐‘œ๐‘› ๐‘๐‘™๐‘ข๐‘  ๐พ ๐‘ข๐‘›๐‘–๐‘ก๐‘  ๐‘œ๐‘“ ๐‘‡๐‘๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘‘, ๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก, ๐‘‡)
๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘’ ๐‘๐‘ข๐‘ก ๐‘œ๐‘๐‘ก๐‘–๐‘œ๐‘› ๐‘๐‘™๐‘ข๐‘  ๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘’ ๐‘ข๐‘›๐‘–๐‘ก ๐‘œ๐‘“ ๐‘กโ„Ž๐‘’ ๐‘†๐‘๐‘œ๐‘›๐‘‘, ๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก, ๐‘‡)
• Time=T
max ๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† − ๐พ, 0 + ๐พ = max{๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† , ๐พ}
max ๐พ − ๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† , 0 + ๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† = max{๐‘ƒ ๐‘‡, ๐‘† , ๐พ}
2.6 Put-Call Parity
• By the law of one price, the values of the two
portfolio at any earlier time must also be equal
๏ƒจ
๐‘ ๐‘ก + ๐พ๐‘ƒ ๐‘ก, ๐‘‡ = ๐‘ ๐‘ก + ๐‘ƒ(๐‘ก, ๐‘†)
Download