Climate Clubs: Designing a Mechanism to Overcome Free-riding in International Climate Policy William Nordhaus, Yale University Presidential Address American Economic Association Environmental Seminar January 4, 2015 1 Outline • Introduction to current state of climate economics • The problem of free riding • The concept of a Climate Club • Modeling club formation and equilibrium • Effectiveness of different Club regimes 2 Four key issues for climate change 1. Climate science: Likely path Mature science and of earth system over this century projections and beyond 2. Estimate costs and benefits of emissions reductions Mature estimates of costs; very rudimentary determination of damages 3. Instruments for implementing Well understood for national policy carbon taxes and national capand-trade systems 4. System to prevent international freeriding Zero progress 3 Most recent data 4 CO2 concentrations, Hawaii (ppm) CO2 concentrations through August 2014 400 380 360 340 320 300 1958 1969 1980 1991 2002 2013 5 Global temperatures (prelim 2014 data) Global mean temperature, deg C (1900 = 0) 1.2 1.0 0.8 Average NCDC Hadley GISS 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2 1900 1925 1950 1975 2000 6 US decarbonization 2.0 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 CO2/GDP Decarbonization at 2.3% per year 0.2 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 EPA estimates, real GDP, 5 months for 2014 1980 1990 2000 2010 7 Free-riding equilibrium for public goods • Free-riding occurs when someone receives the benefits of a public good without contributing to the costs. • This syndrome is seen widely for public goods or “tragedy of the commons” (whales, global warming, contagions) • Because of structure of international law, strong tendency for free-riding in global public goods. – – – – Public goods theory from Paul Samuelson History and treaty theory from Scott Barrett Kyoto Protocol for climate change (later) Modeling simulations (later) 8 Free-riding in the Kyoto Protocol: Share of global emissions covered by binding restraints Covered emissions as % of world 70 Kyoto participants 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 9 Free riding in NATO 800 United States Military spending (billions) 700 600 500 400 300 200 UK Germany France 100 Luxembourg 0 10 100 1,000 GDP (billions) 10,000 Source: Data from NATO 10 Free-Riding in International Climate Agreements • Basic theoretical results: – Without international agreements, have noncooperative (NC) equilibrium. In simple example, carbon prices are efficient levels time Hirfindahl index of country size (≈ 10% of efficient). – With international cooperation and bottom-up treaties without sanctions, have small coalition paradox: Stability can sustain only a small number of countries (2 or 3). • Climate Club: Top-down treaty with penalties for nonparticipants: Can lead to high participation with efficient abatement. 11 International Treaties as “Clubs” Clubs are agreements where: 1. Have economies of scale or public goods 2. Members pay dues 3. Can exclude non-members (avoid free riders) 4. Stability issues (next slide) Examples of effective club: Why did Greece stay in EU? Kyoto Protocol defective club: membership cost > membership value 12 Should Greece stay in the EU? The Times (London) 13 International Treaties as Games • Climate policy without penalties is repeated n-person prisoners’ dilemma (PD) game. – Presumption is that high discount rate (or low frequency of decisions) will lead to PD rather than cooperative equilibrium. • By adding penalties for non-participants, payoffs change so that stage game has (relatively) efficient Nash equilibrium. – Presumption is then that the repeated game has the stagegame efficient Nash equilibrium. – In Scott Barrett’s language, treaties are “self-enforcing” at efficient level. • Key issue is “coalition stability” of high-participation treaty. 14 Penalties are necessary for effective climate treaties • Need penalties on non-participants to induce participation in deep abatement treaties • History and law suggest the most practical penalty is trade sanctions • What kind of sanctions? – Standard approach: Countervailing duties on carbon content of imports (US and EU legislation) – Climate Club tariffs: Simple ad valorem tariff on all imports of non-participants into climate-club regions. 15 Modeling Climate Clubs with the TRICE model • Designed a new model to study properties of Climate Club with realistic country parameters. – TRICE model (Trade in a Regional Integrated Model of Climate and the Economy) • Model assumptions: – A standard one-period regional model. – Key variables are the social cost of carbon (SCC), national carbon prices, tariff rates, and national income. – Countries can form Carbon Club to set carbon prices jointly at international carbon price target. – Clubs can impose penalty tariffs on imports of nonparticipants. 16 Objectives of modeling 1. Examine different Club structures or regimes (carbon prices and penalty tariffs). 2. Determine whether regimes contain stable coalitions (Nash coalition stability). 3. Determine effectiveness of regimes (whether actual carbon price approaches target price). 17 Algorithmics • Thought to be a NP-hard problem to find optimal coalition. • Designed “evolutionary” algorithm to find coalition which usually find the stable coalition in < 500 mutations. • Decision criterion is “coalition Nash.” No sub-coalition can improve its welfare by leaving and/or joining. 18 Data for model for 2011 • Damage functions: Simplified from Nordhaus survey of estimates (JAERE, 2014) • Abatement functions: From different models for aggregate and McKinsey estimates for regions. • GDP, emissions, population from World Bank • Trade data from UNCTAD. • Parameters for trade model from Ralph Ossa (AEA, forthcoming, 2014). • 15 regions (US, EU, China, India, Japan, Brazil, Russia, Canada, and other aggregates). 19 Experiments with the TRICE model 1. Kyoto Protocol 2. Climate Clubs – Tariff rates from 0% to 10%. – Carbon tax target is from $25 to $100 per ton CO2 (rough range of proposals). 20 With no penalty, Kyoto regime disintegrates to NC 14 Number participating regions 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1 101 201 301 401 501 601 701 801 901 1,001 Iteration number - Assumes carbon tax = $25 and tariff rate = 0% 21 Now look at results for positive tariffs: What are results for different Climate Clubs? • Penalty tariffs are uniform on all non-participants • Rates from 0% to 10% • Global social cost of carbon $12½ , $25, $50, $100 22 Participation by tariff rate for $50 carbon price Tariff rate 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% 10% Number participants (of 15 regions) 0 1 8 13 14 14 14 15 15 15 15 Today’s free-riding! 23 Participation by tariff rate for $50 carbon price Number participating regions 15 Bars are tariff rates: 0% at left to 10% at right 12 9 6 3 No (zero) participants at 0% tariff 0 24 Number participants by tariff and carbon price 25 Carbon price by tariff and target price 26 Net income gain (% of potenital) Gain from regime (% of cooperative) 100% 0.00 0.01 90% 0.02 0.03 80% 0.04 0.05 70% 0.06 0.07 60% 0.08 0.09 50% 0.10 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 12.500 25.000 50.000 Target carbon price ($/tCO2) 100.000 27 Where are the votes? For heterogeneous countries with differing national SCC, abatement costs, and damages, what level of international target carbon price would then vote for? 28 What Climate Club would countries prefer? Region Global target carbon price that maximizes domestic welfare for club of 15 ($/tCO2) Global averages Non-cooperative price 3 Global SCC 25 Median preferred price 28 Country preferred prices China 14 US 28 India 31 Canada 34 EU 46 29 Summary 1. Strong international free-riding leads to minimal abatement with Kyoto Protocol structure of no penalties. 2. Strong incentive-compatible agreements can be supported with penalties such as tariffs on nonparticipants. 3. Most important takeaway: With Club structure, countries acting in their national self-interest can produce (reasonably) efficient global climate policy. 30