What finance functions add the most to firm value?
2
Corporate Financing
We have been focusing on investment decision
What should the firm buy?
Now we are turning to the financing decision
How does the firm pay for it?
3
How do Firms Pay for Stuff
Companies prefer to use the cash they generate
This account for about 70-90% of all purchases
If cash is insufficient they sell securities
4
The Capital-Structure
Addresses: What securities should the firm sell
This determines how the firm’s cash flows are divide
S G
Capital Structure becomes important if the division affects the size of the cash flows
B
Remember: A firm is simply worth the PV of its expected future cash flows to investors
5
The Value of E and D
E: The PV of cash flows to equity holders
If a company pays $1.5 mil. in dividends each year (r e
=8%) E =
D: The PV of the cash flows to debt holders
If a company pays $0.75 mil. in interest each year (r d
=4%) D =
V =
6
Cap Structure and Value
While capital structure appears to influence firm value in the real world to understand how/why we need to start with a situation where it doesn’t
7
Modigliani-Miller Proposition 1
V
L
= V
U
8
MM1: The Simplest of Worlds
Perfect capital markets
No taxes or transaction costs
No Bankruptcy Costs
Everyone borrows at the same rate
Investment decisions are fixed
Operating cash flow is independent of capital structure
9
MM Investment Intuition Set up
Suppose you have two firms that each make
$50/ year
The firms are identical except that one has $50 of debt and the other has no debt
10
MM Intuition
Suppose V l
< V u
Consider a 1% investment in E
U
Cost = 1% E
U
=
Payoff = 1% Earnings =
Now buy 1% of E
L
& 1% of D
L
Cost = 1% E
L
+1%D
L
=
Payoff
Receive 1%*Interest=
Receive 1%*(Earnings -Int)=
Total dollar payoff =
Can V l
< V u
?
V
E
V u
$100
$100
D $0
Earnings $50
Int $0
Cost
Payoff
V l
$90
$40
$50
$50
$10
11
If V l
< V u then
An investor can purchase a claim in the levered firm with the same payoff as a claim in the un-levered firm, for a lower price!
This situation is impossible in a well functioning capital market (arbitrage)
Investors will buy V l and sell it for V u until V l
= V u
12
MM Intuition the Other Way
Suppose V l
> V u
Consider a1% investment in E l
Cost = 1% E
L
=
Payoff = 1%(Earnings –Int)=
Alt. buy 1% E
U
, & borrow1% of D
L
Cost= 1%V u
-1%D
L
=
Payoff
Owe 1%*Interest=
Receive 1%* Earnings =
Total dollar payoff =
V
E
V u
$90
$90
D $0
Earnings $50
Int $0
Cost
Payoff
V l
$100
$50
$50
$50
$10
13
If V l
> V u then
In perfect capital markets the inequality cannot hold. Since both strategies have the same payoff, they should cost the same.
14
On balance
We showed how we can take positions in the levered and un-levered company that generate the same payoff, but which only costs the same if the two firms have the same firm value
The law of one price states that investments with the same payoffs need to cost the same, therefore the two firms must be equally valuable
15
MM 1 Cash Flow Proof
Un-Levered
Two firms
Earn $1,000
Unlevered
r e
= 10%
Levered
r e
r d
= 15%
= 5%
D= 5,000
Earn
Interest
Equity
E
Levered
$1,000 $1,000
D
V
16
Main result in this “perfect world”
The value of the firm is independent of its capital structure
V
D/V
17
Investors and Capital Structure
While leverage does not affect the risk of the overall firm, it does affect investors’ risks
Leverage increases:
18
MM Proposition 2: D/E and r e
, β e
As leverage increases so does financial risk
D/E relation with r e
, β e r a
= D/V * r d
+ E/V*r e
r e
= r a
+ D/E * (r a
- r d
)
a
e
= D /V *
=
a d
+ E/V*
e
+ D /E * (
a
-
d
)
19
β e
Break-Down
e
=
a
+ D /E * (
a
-
d
)
a
:
D /E * (
a
-
d
):
20
MM 2: Graph
23%
18%
13%
R a
8%
3%
Look familiar?
D/V (5%)
Re Rd WACC
R e
R d
21
Question 1
Shareholders demand a higher rate of return than bondholders. As debt is cheaper, we should increase the D/V ratio as it reduces r a
True or False?
.
22
Question 2
As the firm borrows more and debt becomes riskier, both shareholders and bondholders demand a higher rate of return. Thus by reducing the debt-equity ratio, we can reduce the cost of debt and the cost of equity. This makes everybody better off. True or
False?
23
Cash flows and Firm Value 1
A firm is only worth the PV of it’s cash flows to investors
Consider an un-levered firm, which has an
EBIT of $1,500.
The company’s investors require a return on
12%.
Assume no taxes, what is the firm worth?
24
Cash flows and Firm Value 2
Consider a levered firm, which has an EBIT of
$1,500.
The firm owes $1,000 in interest payments/year
The company’s investors (equity and debt) require a return on 12%.
Assume no taxes, what is the firm worth?
25
More Realistic World
MM showed us that in the theoretical world capital structure does not matter
But by relaxing the MM assumptions and allowing for a more realistic world, we can see how capital structure affects firm value
26
Corporate Taxes
When we include taxes will the firm be more or less valuable than in a world without taxes?
27
Who gets paid first?
28
Example
We have two identical firms
EBIT $1,000
L: debt of
$5,000 @ 6%
EBIT
Interest
EBT
Tax @ 40%
Net Income
NI + Interest
Tax Shield
Un-
Levered
Levered
$1,000 $1,000
29
Tax Shield’s Effect on Firm Value
The tax shield increases firm value by the present value of the tax reduction
Tax Shield = Tax Rate * Dollar Interest
PV (T.S.) = Tax Rate * Dollar Interest / r d
= Tax Rate * (Debt * r d
) / r d
= Tax Rate * Debt
= 0.4 * 5,000 = $2,000
30
V l with Corporate Taxes
V l
= V u
+ PV(Tax Shield)
V l
= V u
+ D*T c
As the tax shield increases company value, how should the company be financed?
31
Cash flows and Firm Value 3
Consider an un-levered firm, which has an
EBIT of $1,500.
The company’s investors require a return on
12%.
Taxes are 34%, what is the firm worth?
32
Cash flows and Firm Value 4
Consider a levered firm, which has an EBIT of
$1,500.
The firm owes $1,000 in interest
The company’s investors (equity and debt) require a return on 12%.
Taxes are 34%, what is the firm worth?
33
Personal Taxes
Investors also pay taxes
The firm is only worth the present value of the cash investors put in their pocket
The firm wants to minimize total taxes paid
Corporate and personal
34
Personal Taxes
CG $ Capital Gains
Div $ Dividends
T i
, T d
T cg
T e
Income Tax Rate (Personal)
Capital Gains Tax Rate
Personal Equity Tax Rate:
T e
=CG/(Div+CG)*T cg
+Div/(Div+CG)*T i
35
Personal Taxes and the Tax Shield
The inclusion of personal taxes generally reduces the value of the tax shield because interest is generally taxed more heavily than equity at the personal level
The preferential tax treatment of capital gains on the personal level reduces the value of the debt tax shield
PV(Tax Shield) < D*T c
36
Including Personal Taxes
V l
= V u
+ D {1-[(1-T c
)(1-T e
)/(1-T d
)]}
This account for the investor’s preference for equity income over debt income
(1-T c
)(1-T e
): Represents the after-tax return ($) from $1 in equity income
(1-T d
): Represents the after-tax return ($) from
$1 in debt income
37
Cash flows and Firm Value 5
Consider a levered firm, which has an EBIT of
$1,500. The firm owes $1,000 in interest. The company’s investors (equity and debt) require a return on 12%.
Taxes are: Corp 34%, Income 20%, Equity 15%
D =
E =
V l
=
38
Bankruptcy Costs
Direct Costs: Legal and Administrative costs
These are small
Indirect Costs: Impaired ability to conduct business
These are BIG
Start when a firm becomes Financially Distressed
Bankruptcy costs increase with debt, making more debt less attractive
Shareholders pay these costs
39
Agency Costs
In addition to bankruptcy costs, when a firm becomes financially distressed the conflict between bondholders and stockholders increases
This can result in managers playing games
Who is the manager likely to side with?
40
Asset Substitution
A firm has $6m in assets, and has $10m in debt outstanding → Financial Distress
The firm has a project requiring a $2m investment and pays $7m (PV) with a 10% probability or pays nothing with a 90%
Project NPV?
Will the firm take the project?
41
Potential Payoffs
If forgo the project: FV = $__
Debt gets $___, Equity gets $___
Take the project and it turns out bad: FV = $__
Debt gets $___, Equity gets $___
Take the project and it turns out good: FV = $_
Debt gets $___, Equity gets $___
42
Underinvestment
Now instead of taking –NPV projects the firm passes on +NPV projects
The same firm has a project requiring $2m investment and pays $5m (PV) with a 50% probability or pays $1m (PV) with a 50% probability
What is the NPV?
Will the firm take the project?
43
Potential Payoffs
If forgo the project: FV = $__
Debt gets $__, Equity gets $__
Take the project and it turns out bad: FV = $__
Debt gets $__, Equity gets $__
Take the project and it turns out good: FV= $_
Debt gets $__, Equity gets $__
44
Milk the Property (Cash out)
If the value of the firm is less than the value of the debt holders claims, then the shareholders have an incentive to sell off the assets pay themselves
45
Example, names changed to protect the guilty
Marriot Inc
Owes $1 billion and has $500 million in assets
Management creates a new firm Marriot Co
Every Inc shareholder receives shares in Co
The same shareholders own both firms
Inc sells its $500m in assets to Co for $1.00
Co has $499,999,999 in assets and no debt
Inc has $1 in assets and $1b in debt
How happy are debt holders?
46
Intelligent Bondholders
Bondholders know about these agency problems and act accordingly
Requiring: Higher r d
, covenants
Limit possible div payments, Restrict debt issuances or sales of assets
All of this requires costly monitoring of the firm
This is another costs borne by equity holders
47
Trade-Off
The firm trades off the benefits and costs associated with debt to maximize firm value
If we put everything we talked about together we get:
V l
= V u
+ PV (Tax shields) – PV (Bankruptcy costs) – PV (Agency costs)
48
Trade-Off Graph
Market
Value of the
Firm
PV of Tax Shield
Bankruptcy Costs
Agency Costs
Unlevered Firm
Debt
49
Trade-off Implications
Firms have an optimal level of debt
The amount will depend on the industry and firm
Safe, highly profitable firms with lots of tangible assets should have lots of debt
US studies finds that profitable firms have little debt
Risky, marginally profitable firms with lots of intangible assets should have little debt
50