4 THE ECONOMICS OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR 10 Externalities Market Failure • Recall from Chapter 7: – Adam Smith had argued that the “invisible hand” of the marketplace leads self-interested buyers and sellers to an outcome in which the total surplus of society is maximized. But markets can fail. Why? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 3 EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY • An externality is the uncompensated impact of one person’s actions on the well-being of a bystander. – Al’s action may affect the well-being of Betty, a bystander. – If Al pays no compensation (when his action has a negative effect on Betty) nor receives a reward (when his action has a positive effect on Betty), the effect of Al’s action on Betty is called an externality. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 4 • In this case, Al will ignore the effects of his action on Betty when deciding whether or not to take the action • Therefore, Al may take this action even if it is undesirable for society • And, conversely, Al may refuse to take this action even if it is desirable for society • In other words, when actions have external effects, society’s total surplus might not be maximized in the free market equilibrium • Government intervention may be able to increase total surplus CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 5 EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY • When the impact of a person’s action on a bystander is harmful, the externality is called a negative externality. • When the impact on the bystander is beneficial, the externality is called a positive externality. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 6 Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity • To figure out the extent of an activity that is ideal for society, we need to compare the benefits and costs—to society—of an additional unit of that activity Individually desirable activity • To figure out the extent of an activity that is ideal for an individual, we need to compare the benefits and costs—to the individual—of an additional unit of that activity Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is socially desirable if and only if its social benefit exceeds its social cost Individually desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is individually desirable if and only if its individual benefit exceeds its individual cost Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is socially desirable if and only if its social benefit exceeds its social cost Social benefits Social costs Individually desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is individually desirable if and only if its individual benefit exceeds its individual cost Individual benefits Individual costs Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is socially desirable if and only if its social benefit exceeds its social cost Individually desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is individually desirable if and only if its individual benefit exceeds its individual cost When there are no externalities, there is no difference between social benefits and individual benefits, and no difference between social costs and individual costs. Social benefits Social costs Individual benefits Individual costs Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is socially desirable if and only if its social benefit exceeds its social cost Individually desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is individually desirable if and only if its individual benefit exceeds its individual cost When there are no externalities, there is no difference between social benefits and individual benefits, and no difference between social costs and individual costs. Individual benefits Individual costs Individual benefits Individual costs Therefore, in this case, what’s individually ideal is also what’s socially ideal. Therefore, the equilibrium quantity is also the optimum quantity, as Adam Smith had argued. Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is socially desirable if and only if its social benefit exceeds its social cost Individually desirable activity • An additional unit of an activity is individually desirable if and only if its individual benefit exceeds its individual cost But when there are positive and negative externalities, social benefits = individual benefits + positive externalities, and social costs = individual costs + negative externalities. Individual benefits + positive externalities Individual costs + negative externalities Individual benefits Individual costs Therefore, what’s ideal for the individual may not be what’s ideal for society. Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity Individually desirable activity When there are positive externalities, social benefits = individual benefits + positive externalities, and social costs = individual costs. Individual benefits + positive externalities Individual costs Individual benefits Individual costs Therefore, the individual ignores positive externalities that affect bystanders. Therefore, an activity may be undesirable to the individual but desirable to society. Therefore, when there are positive externalities, the equilibrium quantity of an activity will be less than the optimum quantity of that activity. Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity Individually desirable activity When there are positive externalities, social benefits = individual benefits + positive externalities, and social costs = individual costs. Individual benefits + positive externalities Individual costs Individual benefits Individual costs Therefore, the individual ignores positive externalities that affect bystanders. Therefore, an activity may be undesirable to the individual but desirable to society. Therefore, when there are positive externalities, the equilibrium quantity of an activity will be less than the optimum quantity of that activity. But this problem can be fixed (a) with corrective subsidies and (b) bargaining among the affected private parties. Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity Individually desirable activity When there are negative externalities, social benefits = individual benefits, and social costs = individual costs + negative externalities. Individual benefits Individual costs + negative externalities Individual benefits Individual costs The individual ignores negative externalities that affect bystanders. Therefore, an activity may be desirable to the individual but undesirable to society. Therefore, when there are negative externalities, the equilibrium quantity of an activity will be more than the optimum quantity of that activity. Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity Individually desirable activity When there are negative externalities, social benefits = individual benefits, and social costs = individual costs + negative externalities. Individual benefits Individual costs + negative externalities Individual benefits Individual costs The individual ignores negative externalities that affect bystanders. Therefore, an activity may be desirable to the individual but undesirable to society. Therefore, when there are negative externalities, the equilibrium quantity of an activity will be more than the optimum quantity of that activity. But this problem can be fixed (a) with corrective taxes and (b) bargaining among the affected private parties. Corrective Taxes and Subsidies • We have just seen that when externalities exist the equilibrium outcome may not be the same as the optimum outcome • But we have seen before that a tax reduces the equilibrium output and a subsidy increases the equilibrium output • Therefore, any gap between the equilibrium and optimum outputs can be closed with taxes and subsidies CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 17 Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity Individually desirable activity When the individual receives a subsidy equal to the positive external effects of the activity, … Individual benefits + positive externalities Individual costs Individual benefits + subsidy (positive externalities) Individual costs … the individual can no longer ignore the positive externalities that affect bystanders. Therefore, in this case, what’s individually ideal is also what’s socially ideal, and the equilibrium quantity is also the optimum quantity. A subsidy like this is unusual because it increases the total surplus. Such corrective subsidies are called Pigovian subsidies . Society and the Individual Socially desirable activity Individually desirable activity When the individual has to pay a tax equal to the negative external effects of the activity, … Individual benefits Individual costs + negative externalities Individual benefits Individual costs + Tax (negative externalities) … the individual can no longer ignore the negative externalities that affect bystanders. Therefore, in this case, what’s individually ideal is also what’s socially ideal, and the equilibrium quantity is also the optimum quantity. A tax like this is unusual because it increases the total surplus. Such corrective taxes are called Pigovian taxes. Coase Theorem: Private Bargaining • When private citizens can bargain with each other without too much difficulty, the equilibrium and optimum outcomes may be brought closer to each other without the need for government intervention (in the form of Pigovian taxes and subsidies). CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 20 Negative Externalities • • • • • Automobile exhaust Cigarette smoking Barking dogs (loud pets) Loud stereos in an apartment building The Club, an anti-theft device for cars CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 21 Dealing with negative externalities • Should we completely ban an activity that has negative externalities? – – – – – Should we ban all cars? Should we ban all smoking in public spaces? Should we muzzle all dogs? Should we ban stereos in apartment buildings? Should we ban The Club? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 22 Dealing with negative externalities • How should we determine the extent to which activities that have negative externalities should be tolerated? • We can evaluate virtually any policy proposal by asking how it would affect total surplus. – Recall from Chapter 7, the concept of total surplus. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 23 Positive Externalities • • • • • Immunizations Education Restored historic buildings Research into new technologies LoJack, an anti-theft device for cars CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 24 EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY • Externalities can cause markets to become inefficient. –We saw in chapter 7 that total surplus is maximized in a perfectly competitive economy. – But when there are externalities, this is no longer true: •total surplus might be less than the maximum achievable. • This might provide a justification for government intervention. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 25 EXTERNALITIES AND MARKET INEFFICIENCY • Negative externalities from the production or consumption of a good can cause markets to produce more than is socially desirable. • Positive externalities cause markets to produce less than is socially desirable. • If and when markets fail (to produce the socially desirable quantity), government intervention may be necessary. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 26 Figure 1 The Market for Aluminum When there are no externalities in aluminum production or consumption, the equilibrium quantity (QMARKET) maximizes social surplus. Price of Aluminum Supply (private cost) Equilibrium Demand (private value) 0 QMARKET Quantity of Aluminum Welfare Economics Without Externalities: A Recap • When there are no externalities, the equilibrium quantity: – is efficient – maximizes total surplus • Total surplus = total benefits – total costs – is the socially desirable quantity CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 28 Social, private, and external costs • When the production of aluminum causes pollution … • Social cost of aluminum = private cost + external cost • Private cost is the cost to aluminum producers of the raw materials and labor used in production • External cost is the cost to bystanders of having to deal with the effects of pollution CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 30 Figure 2 Pollution and the Social Optimum Price of Aluminum Social cost Unit Cost of pollution Supply (private cost) Optimum Equilibrium Demand (private value) 0 QOPTIMUM QMARKET Quantity of Aluminum Figure 2 Pollution and the Social Optimum Price of Aluminum Social cost Unit Cost of pollution Optimum A Supply (private cost) Total Surplus G B E F C D H I J K Equilibrium Equilibrium ABCD – G Optimum ABCD L Demand (private value) 0 QOPTIMUM QMARKET Quantity of Aluminum Public Policies for Negative Externalities • What can be done to get the market to reduce production to the socially optimal level? Price of Aluminum Social cost Supply (private cost) Optimum Equilibrium Demand (private value) 0 CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES QOPTIMUM QMARKET Quantity of Aluminum 35 Market-Based Policy: Put a Tax on Negative Externalities • Either the producers or the consumers (or both) of aluminum can be taxed – We saw in chapter 6 that a tax reduces the equilibrium output, and that is exactly what we want. • A tax solves the problem by forcing the consumers and producers of aluminum to internalize the externality of aluminum – Internalizing an externality involves altering incentives so that people take account of the external effects of their actions. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 36 Recall: The Effect of a Tax Price Price buyers pay Supply Tax Price without tax Price sellers receive Demand 0 Quantity after tax Quantity before tax Quantity Negative externalities should be taxed • When there are negative externalities, the free market equilibrium output exceeds the socially optimum output • Therefore, it is socially desirable to reduce output • A tax would reduce output • Therefore, a tax is a socially desirable response to a negative externality • But how big should the tax be? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 38 Tax > External Cost is too much Price of Aluminum Social cost Unit Cost of pollution Supply (private cost) Optimum Tax Equilibrium Desired output reduction Demand (private value) 0 The tax is too large and reduces output too much QOPTIMUM QMARKET Quantity of Aluminum Tax < External Cost is too little Price of Aluminum Social cost Unit Cost of pollution Supply (private cost) Optimum Tax Equilibrium Desired output reduction The tax is too small and reduces output too little 0 QOPTIMUM QMARKET Demand (private value) Quantity of Aluminum Tax = External Cost solves the problem! Price of Aluminum Social cost Unit Cost of pollution Optimum Tax Equilibrium Now the tax is exactly equal to the external cost. It reduces the quantity by exactly the ideal amount. 0 QOPTIMUM QMARKET Supply (private cost) We saw earlier that reducing output from QMARKET to QOPTIMUM increases total surplus. Now we see that a tax can do this. (So, unlike what we saw in Chapter 8, not all taxes reduce total surplus.) This is a Pigovian tax. Demand (private value) Quantity of Aluminum Figure 2 Pollution and the Social Optimum Price of Aluminum Social cost Unit Cost of pollution Optimum Equilibrium Supply (private cost) Another way to ensure that QOPTIMUM is produced is to use tradable pollution permits. Demand (private value) 0 QOPTIMUM QMARKET Quantity of Aluminum Tradable Pollution Permits • The government can do the following: – require permits for aluminum production – issue QOPTIMUM permits by auctioning them off • Each permit will sell for a price equal to the unit cost of pollution • The effect will be identical to a Pigovian tax equal to the unit cost of pollution CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 43 Tradable Pollution Permits • The price of each tradable pollution permit will be equal to the unit cost of pollution • Why? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 44 Positive Externalities: Examples • A technology spillover is a positive externality that is created when a firm’s innovation not only benefits the firm, but enters society’s pool of technological knowledge and benefits society as a whole. • Education benefits the student and also all members of society who are affected by the student CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 46 Figure 3 Education and the Social Optimum Price of Education Supply (private cost) Optimum Equilibrium Demand (private value) 0 QMARKET QOPTIMUM Social value Quantity of Education Total Surplus Figure 3 Education and the Social Optimum Price of Education Equilibrium AB Optimum ABF Supply (private cost) A F E Equilibrium B Optimum C D Demand (private value) 0 QMARKET QOPTIMUM Social value Quantity of Education Supply-Demand and Positive Externalities • The intersection of the supply curve and the social-value curve determines the optimal output level. – The optimal output level is more than the equilibrium quantity. – The market produces a smaller quantity than is socially desirable. – The social value of the good exceeds the private value of the good. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 50 Subsidies for positive externalities • What can be done to get the market to increase education to the optimal level? • A subsidy for either students (buyers of education) or educational institutions (sellers) will work. • A subsidy will make students and educational institutions internalize the positive externality of education CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 51 Subsidies for Positive Externalities: example • Recall that technology spillovers are positive externalities • Therefore, the equilibrium level of spending on research will be less than the socially desirable level • Government intervention may promote technology-enhancing industries – Patent laws are a form of technology policy that give the individual (or firm) with patent protection a property right over its invention. – The patent is then said to internalize the externality. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 52 PRIVATE SOLUTIONS TO EXTERNALITIES • Government action is not always needed to solve the problem of externalities. • In some cases, the free market ends up maximizing total surplus even when there are externalities CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 53 PRIVATE SOLUTIONS TO EXTERNALITIES • • • • Moral codes and social sanctions Charitable organizations Integrating different types of businesses Contracting (bargaining, negotiations) between those causing the externalities and those affected by the externalities CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 54 The Coase Theorem • The Coase Theorem is the proposition— due to Ronald Coase—that if people can bargain without transaction costs over the allocation of resources, they can solve the problem of externalities on their own. – Transaction costs are the costs that people incur in the process of agreeing to and following through on a bargain. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 55 Bob, Spot, and Jane and Ronald Coase Bob and Jane are room mates. Bob gets Spot, a noisy dog, as a birthday gift. Benefit = $500; Cost = $800 Benefit = $1000; Cost = $800 Social optimum Bob returns Spot Bob keeps Spot Government solution Bob forced to pay $800 tax. No action required. Bob Bob returns Spot keeps Spot Private solution: Jane has right to quiet Jane sues to enforce her right. Bob can’t afford to pay Jane a big enough bribe. Bob returns Spot Bob pays Jane $800. Bob keeps Spot Private solution: Bob has right to keep Spot Jane pays Bob $500. Bob returns Spot Jane can’t afford to pay Bob a big enough bribe. Bob keeps Spot Coase Theorem: Private solutions to externalities can work 56 Dick, Spot, and Jane and Ronald Coase • Note that when the free market outcome is not optimal, bargaining between Bob and Jane will bring about the optimal outcome, irrespective of who is favored by the law – The law is important in other ways, however. For example, in one case in which the law favors Bob , Jane has to pay a $500 compensation to Bob to get him to return Spot CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 57 Coase Theorem: Exercise • In the case of pollution by an aluminum factory, how might production of the socially desirable amount be brought about without taxation by the government? • Why might Coase’s solution fail, as a practical matter, in this case? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 58 Why Private Solutions Do Not Always Work • Sometimes the private solution fails because transaction costs are so high that private agreement is not possible. – Bob might get greedy and try to haggle with Jane for more than $500 – Change the story by substituting three people (Jan, Jeanne and Joan) instead of Jane. Jan, Jeanne and Joan may find it hard to raise $500 for Bob’s compensation. Each might try to free ride on the others. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 59 PUBLIC POLICY TOWARD EXTERNALITIES • When externalities are significant and private solutions are not found, government may attempt to solve the problem through… – command-and-control policies. – market-based policies. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 60 PUBLIC POLICY: Command-and-Control Policies – Such policies usually take the form of regulations: • Forbid certain behaviors. • Require certain behaviors. – Examples: • Requirements that all students be immunized. • Stipulations on pollution emission levels set by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 61 PUBLIC POLICY: MARKET-BASED POLICIES • Taxes and subsidies can align private incentives with social efficiency. – We have seen this already – These corrective taxes and subsidies are called Pigovian taxes and subsidies. • They were originally proposed by the British economist, A. C. Pigou. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 62 PUBLIC POLICY TOWARD POLLUTION: Command-and-Control • If the EPA decides it wants to reduce the amount of pollution coming from a specific plant, it could… – tell the firm to reduce its pollution by a specific amount (i.e. regulation). – levy a tax of a given amount for each unit of pollution the firm emits (i.e. Pigovian tax). CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 63 PUBLIC POLICY TOWARD POLLUTION: Market-Based • Pigovian Taxes on the producers or consumers of pollution • Tradable pollution permits that allow the voluntary transfer of the right to pollute from one firm to another. – A firm that can reduce pollution at a low cost may prefer to sell its permit to a firm that can reduce pollution only at a high cost. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 64 Figure 4 The Equivalence of Pigovian Taxes and Pollution Permits (a) Pigovian Tax Price of Pollution Pigovian tax P 1. A Pigovian tax sets the price of pollution . . . Demand for pollution rights 0 Q 2. . . . which, together with the demand curve, determines the quantity of pollution. Quantity of Pollution Figure 4 The Equivalence of Pigovian Taxes and Pollution Permits (b) Pollution Permits Price of Pollution Supply of pollution permits P Demand for pollution rights 0 2. . . . which, together with the demand curve, determines the price of pollution. Q Quantity of Pollution 1. Pollution permits set the quantity of pollution . . . Policy Exercises • Should we punish the use of SUV’s and promote the use of smaller cars? • Should we force car makers to sell cars with higher mileage? • Should we limit the use of gasoline by each car owner? • Should we tax gasoline? • Should we tax all fuels based on the damage each fuel causes? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 67 Any Questions? CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 68 Summary • When a transaction between a buyer and a seller directly affects a third party, the effect is called an externality. • Negative externalities cause the socially optimal quantity in a market to be less than the equilibrium quantity. • Positive externalities cause the socially optimal quantity in a market to be greater than the equilibrium quantity. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 69 Summary • Those affected by externalities can sometimes solve the problem privately. • The Coase theorem states that if people can bargain without a cost, then they can always reach an agreement in which resources are allocated efficiently. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 70 Summary • When private parties cannot adequately deal with externalities, then the government steps in. • The government can either regulate behavior or internalize the externality by using Pigovian taxes or by issuing pollution permits. CHAPTER 10 EXTERNALITIES 71