“ECONOMICS for Christian Schools” By Alan J. Carper Bob Jones University Press. 1998 Unit V: Economics of the Government “Fiscal Policy” A.P. Macroeconomics Chapter 12 Economics/Honor Econ Chapter 14 Biblical Integration We need to remember God is the power behind a nation, state, county, township, or individual who makes them wealthy or poor. (I Sam. 2:7) Objectives: Define fiscal policy Explain Keynes' solution to the business cycle Describe the marginal propensity to consume and its effect on the money supply List and explain the problems of using government spending as a tool of fiscal policy List the major source of the government's tax revenue Contrast proportional taxes. Progressive taxes and regressive taxes List and explain the problems with using taxation as a tool of fiscal policy Explain the Keynesian concept of "pump priming" List and explain the problems with using government borrowing as a tool of fiscal policy A.P. Objectives: What fiscal policy is and why it is an important tool in managing economic fluctuations. Which policies constitute expansionary fiscal policy and which constitute a contractionary fiscal policy. Why fiscal policy has a multiplier effect and how this effect is influenced by automatic stabilizers. Why tax and transfer multipliers are less than the government purchases multiplier. Why government calculate the cyclically adjusted budget balance. Why a large public debt may be a cause for concern. Why implicit liabilities of the government are also a cause for concern. Sources of Tax Revenue in the United States, 2004 Personal income taxes, taxes on corporate profits, and social insurance taxes account for most government tax revenue. The rest is a mix of property taxes, sales taxes, and other sources of revenue. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis. (Erbil) Government Spending in the United States, 2004 Social insurance programs are government programs intended to protect families against economic hardship. The two types of government spending are purchases of goods and services and government transfers. The big items in government purchases are national defense and education. The big items in government transfers are Social Security and health care programs. (Erbil) Expansionary and Contractionary Fiscal Policy Expansionary Fiscal Policy Can Close a Recessionary Gap Expansionary fiscal policy increases aggregate demand. At E1 the economy is in short-run equilibrium where the aggregate demand curve AD1 intersects the SRAS curve. At E1, there is a recessionary gap of YE − Y1. An expansionary fiscal policy—an increase in government purchases, a reduction in taxes, or an increase in government transfers—shifts the aggregate demand curve rightward. It can close the recessionary gap by shifting AD1 to AD2, moving the economy to a new short-run equilibrium, E2, which is also a long-run equilibrium. Recessionary gap (Erbil) Expansionary and Contractionary Fiscal Policy Contractionary Fiscal Policy Can Eliminate an Inflationary Gap At E1 the economy is in short-run equilibrium where the aggregate demand curve AD1 intersects the SRAS curve. At E1, there is an inflationary gap of Y1 − YE . A contractionary fiscal policy— reduced government purchases, an increase in taxes, or a reduction in government transfers—shifts the aggregate demand curve leftward. It can close the inflationary gap by shifting AD1 to AD2, moving the economy to a new short-run equilibrium, E2, which is also a long-run equilibrium. (Erbil) Contractionary fiscal policy decreases aggregate demand. Inflationary gap Lags in Fiscal Policy In the case of fiscal policy, there is an important reason for caution: there are significant lags in its use. Realize the recessionary/inflationary gap by collecting and analyzing economic data takes time Government develops an action plan takes time Implementation of the action plan takes time (Erbil) Fiscal Policy and the Multiplier Fiscal policy has a multiplier effect on the economy. Expansionary fiscal policy leads to an increase in real GDP larger than the initial rise in aggregate spending caused by the policy. Conversely, contractionary fiscal policy leads to a fall in real GDP larger than the initial reduction in aggregate spending caused by the policy. (Erbil) The Multiplier Effect of an Increase in Government Purchases of Goods and Services A $50 billion increase in government purchases of goods and services has the direct effect of shifting the aggregate demand curve to the right by $50 billion. However, this is not the end of the story. The rise in GDP causes a rise in disposable income, which leads to an increase in consumer spending, which leads to a further rise in GDP, which leads to a further rise in consumer spending, and so on. The eventual shift, from AD1 to AD2, is a multiple of the rise in GDP. What happens if government purchases of goods and services are instead reduced? The math is exactly the same, except that there’s a minus sign in front: if government purchases fall by $50 billion and the marginal propensity to consume is 0.6, the AD curve shifts leftward by $125 billion. (Erbil) How Taxes Affect the Multiplier Rules governing taxes and some transfers act as automatic stabilizers, reducing the size of the multiplier and automatically reducing the size of fluctuations in the business cycle. In contrast, discretionary fiscal policy arises from deliberate actions by policy makers rather than from the business cycle. (Erbil) Differences in the Effect of Expansionary Fiscal Policies (Source: economy.com) (Erbil) The Budget Balance as a Measure of Fiscal Policy Other things equal, discretionary expansionary fiscal policies— increased government purchases of goods and services, higher government transfers, or lower taxes—reduce the budget balance for that year. That is, expansionary fiscal policies make a budget surplus smaller or a budget deficit bigger. Conversely, contractionary fiscal policies—smaller government purchases of goods and services, smaller government transfers, or higher taxes—increase the budget balance for that year, making a budget surplus bigger or a budget deficit smaller. (Erbil) The Business Cycle and the Cyclically Adjusted Budget Balance Some of the fluctuations in the budget balance are due to the effects of the business cycle. In order to separate the effects of the business cycle from the effects of discretionary fiscal policy, governments estimate the cyclically adjusted budget balance, an estimate of the budget balance if the economy were at potential output. (Erbil) The U.S. Federal Budget Deficit and the Business Cycle The budget deficit as a percentage of GDP tends to rise during recessions (indicated by shaded areas) and fall during expansions. The U.S. Federal Budget Deficit and the Unemployment Rate Here, the unemployment rate serves as an indicator of the budget cycle, and we should expect to see a higher unemployment rate associated with a higher budget deficit. This is confirmed by the figure: The budget deficit as a percentage of GDP moves closely in tandem with the unemployment rate. There is a close relationship between the budget balance and the business cycle: A recession moves the budget balance toward deficit, but an expansion moves it toward surplus. (Erbil) Source: Congressional Budget Office, Bureau of Labor Statistics Long-Run Implications of Fiscal Policy U.S. government budget accounting is calculated on the basis of fiscal years. Persistent budget deficits have long-run consequences because they lead to an increase in public debt. (Erbil) Government Debt as a Percentage of GDP “Public debt as a percentage of GDP is a widely used measure of how deeply in debt a government is. The United States lies in the middle range among wealthy countries. Governments of countries with high public debt–GDP ratios, like Italy and Belgium, pay large sums in interest each year to service their debt. “ (Source: OECD.) (Erbil) Problems Posed by Rising Government Debt This can be a problem for two reasons: Public debt may crowd out investment spending, which reduces long-run economic growth. And in extreme cases, rising debt may lead to government default, resulting in economic and financial turmoil. (Erbil) Deficits and Debt in Practice A widely used measure of fiscal health is the debt–GDP ratio. This number can remain stable or fall even in the face of moderate budget deficits if GDP rises over time. (Erbil) U.S. Federal Deficit since 1939 The debt–GDP ratio is government debt as a percentage of GDP. The federal budget deficit as a percentage of GDP since 1939. The federal government ran huge deficits during World War II and has usually run smaller deficits ever since. (Erbil) The Federal Debt–GDP Ratio Since 1939 Comparing with the previous slide, one can see that many years the debt-GDP ratio has declined in spite of government deficits. This seeming paradox reflects the fact that the debt–GDP ratio can fall, even when debt is rising, as long as GDP grows faster than debt. Source: Economic Report of the President (2005). (Erbil) Implicit Liabilities Implicit liabilities are spending promises made by governments that are effectively a debt despite the fact that they are not included in the usual debt statistics. (Erbil) The Implicit Liabilities of the U.S. Government This figure shows current spending on Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid as percentages of GDP, together with Congressional Budget Office projections of spending in 2010, 2030, and 2050. Source: Congressional Budget Office. Due to the combined effects of the aging of the population and rising health care spending, these programs represent large implicit liabilities of the federal government. (Erbil)