Nominal GDP Futures Targeting Scott Sumner, Bentley University Neoliberal revolution • After 1980 there was a worldwide move toward deregulation, privatization, and other marketfriendly policies. • Monetary policy has remained centrally planned. • Monetary policy failed in 2008-09, allowing the sharpest drop in aggregate demand since 1938. • Lars Svensson—Target internal Fed forecasts • Alternative approach, NGDP futures targeting NGDP futures targeting, one step at a time • Set policy instrument at the level of the median vote of the FOMC • Reward or punish FOMC members based on the accuracy of their vote. • Allow anyone to vote on the FOMC. • Switch from “one-man-one-vote” to “onedollar-one-vote,” as in financial markets. Four types of NGDP futures targeting • NGDP futures targeting—base adjusted daily via parallel OMOs. • Policy instrument forecasting—multiple auctions contingent on various instrument settings. Only those bids contingent on equilibrium in futures market are executed. • Indexed Interest on reserves (Robert Hall, 1983.) • Index Futures convertibility (Bill Woolsey, 1992, 2013.) Mechanics of one form of NGDP futures targeting • Assume 3.65% annual NGDP growth target, level targeting. Increase NGDP target by one basis point daily. • Estimate daily NGDP by weighted average of consecutive periods (months or quarters.) Target second revision—ignore revisions that reflect definitional changes in NGDP. • Have the Fed create an NGDP futures market, and stand willing to buy and sell unlimited quantities at the target price. Mechanics of NGDP futures targeting, continued • Have traders put 10% into market accounts. Pay enough interest on margin accounts to assure market liquidity. I.e., pay an amount equal to the interest rate on one year T-bills, plus $1,000,000/number of contracts traded. • Increase the monetary base by a fixed proportion to all short sales of NGDP futures. Decrease the monetary base by a fixed proportion to all long positions taken. NGDP futures targeting mechanics, continued • After second revision of NGDP data, pay investors their margin account balance, plus interest, plus or minus the percentage difference between actual NGDP and target NGDP, times the value of the contract. • Assume contracts are for $1000, and margin accounts are 10%, and earn a rate of 4% plus the bonus. Assume 500,000 contracts are traded. The bonus is $2 per contract. Total interest is $6 ($4 plus $2). If NGDP came in 1% below target, then an investor who went long would receive $96 dollars back when NGDP is announced. That’s $100 plus $4 plus $2 minus $10. An investor who went short would receive $116. Criticisms of NGDP futures targeting • The “circularity problem:” (Bernanke and Woodford 1997, also Garrison and White, 1997.) Does not apply to the four regimes considered here. Applies to regimes where the central bank adjusts the base in an attempt to stabilize NGDP futures market. The key is to have the market predict the base setting that stabilizes NGDP, and not predict NGDP itself. • First mover problem; why would investors trade before the end of the period? (Garrison and White, 1997) Key is to make periods very short, perhaps one day. Set base at the beginning of each period at level expected for final equilibrium, taking account of predictable day of week and seasonal factors. Criticism, continued • Revisions to NGDP: Target the second revision. Use Gross Domestic Income, which (conceptually) is identical, but is subject to smaller revisions. Use old methodology when there are conceptual changes (such as adding the underground economy, or intellectual capital.) Then allow “base drift” to transition to new system. • Market liquidity? Studies show that small prediction markets can be surprisingly effective. Small subsidies are probably not needed, but can be added by paying above market rates on margin accounts. No one worries about lack of trading when the central bank targets gold prices, or forex prices. Think “guardrails.” Criticism, continued • Risk premium? It’s a good thing that no NGDP futures market currently exists—suggests little interest in hedging NGDP risk. Small risk premium. Studies suggest that risk premium is unlikely to be of macroeconomic importance, especially if not time-varying. • Bubbles? Put aside the fact that “bubbles” probably don’t exist. If they do, it’s probably due to “groupthink,” which is likely to be much worse on a small FOMC than a large FOMC. Markets vastly out-performed the Fed in late 2008. Criticism, continued • Market manipulation? Studies suggest it is not generally a problem, but it could be for NGDP futures. Initially we should allow Fed to offset suspicious trades, over time we can look at the Fed’s track record. • Balance sheet risks: Probably not a major factor, but can be reduced by leveraging NGDP futures trades, so that the base moves by many times the net short or long position in the futures market. Criticism, continued • Too radical? For the moment. But the Fed should set up an NGDP futures market anyway, if only for study purposes. Over time it will play an increasingly large role in policy decisions, just as the TIPS spreads are playing an increasingly large role. Woolsey’s approach is the most politically feasible in the short run, Hall’s in the long run (when paper currency has disappeared.) Other advantages • Overcomes zero bound problem, or perhaps it’s more accurate to say it more clearly identifies what the real problem is---large central bank balance sheets at zero nominal rates. • Eliminates need for corporate bailouts, fiscal stimulus. • Stable NGDP expectations are a good thing, in and of themselves, regardless of actual NGDP movements. Stable NGDP expectations lead to more stable asset prices, and hence less instability in actual NGDP. Concluding remarks • Similar to gold standard, except it stabilizes expectations of Hayek’s preferred target (nominal income), rather than the price of gold. • Future research may find even better targets. I suspect the “total nominal wages and salaries” aggregate is better than NGDP, especially for small economies susceptible to large real shocks. • It’s a scandal that the federal government has not created and subsidized trading in a NGDP futures market, which could provide essential real time data on expected demand growth at low cost.