Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Business Research journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbusres Peer directors’ effort, firm efficiency and performance of diversified firms: An efficacy-based view of governance Punit Arora a, Ajai Gaur b, * a City University of New York, Colin Powell School for Civic and Global Leadership, 160 Convent Ave, NAC 5/141, New York, NY 10031, United States Rutgers Business School - Newark and New Brunswick, Department of Management and Global Business, One Washington Park, Room 1098, Newark, NJ 07102, United States b A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T Keywords: Diversification Benchmarked firm efficiency Strategy implementation costs Peer CEO directors Director effort Studying how boards contribute to firm performance and examining implementation costs associated with diversification strategy are domains of growing interest to strategy scholars. We integrate these incipient liter­ atures to examine the role of Peer Independent Executive Directors’ (PIED) effort in improving the performance of diversified firms. The efficacy-based view of governance that we propose in this paper contributes to both corporate governance and diversification research by highlighting the contextual role of director domain expertise and effort in improving firm performance. Using a longitudinal sample of US firms, we show that the PIED effort is progressively beneficial for firm performance with successive increases in diversification levels, irrespective of diversification type. In case of diversified firms, PIED effort helps a firm better manage internal dynamics and opportunism among various business segments within a firm to benefit from complex diversifi­ cation strategies. 1. Introduction “Nothing is more important to the well-being of a corporation than its board of directors. … To the extent that the directors acting collectively as a board make wise decisions, the corporation will prosper…” (Leblanc & Gillies, 2005, p. 6). “Much of the scholarship on boards of directors has examined either the control (i.e., monitoring) role or the resource dependence role that boards fill. Relatively little has examined the service role, wherein directors provide advice and guidance to management” (Krause et al., 2013, p. 1628). The Board of directors is the apex decision-making body for a firm to make its strategic choices. A key aspect of the strategic decision making in large diversified firms is to exploit economies of scope and synergies among various businesses to obtain superior performance (Kuppuswamy & Villalonga, 2016; Villalonga, 2004). However, research has yet to establish a clear relationship between board characteristics, diversifi­ cation, and firm performance (e.g., Mackey et al., 2017). While the research on boards of directors has examined different aspects of board governance, we lack clarity on how boards can effectively guide organizations in strategy implementation (Krause et al., 2013; Shrop­ shire, 2019). Board members fulfill multiple roles, ranging from monitoring, to resource provisioning and advising the top management (Hillman et al., 2009; Hillman & Dalziel, 2003). However, boards often fail in these roles, which could be due to a lack of ability, motivation, or in some cases, due to role confusion (e.g., Arora, 2018; Boivie et al., 2012, 2016; Feldman, 2016). Building on the previous work that views board of di­ rectors as a critical strategic resource for organization (Carpenter & Westphal, 2001; Hambrick et al.; 2015; Hillman & Dalziel, 2003), we propose an efficacy-based view of governance. The efficacy-based view of governance suggests a more contextualized perspective on how governance improves firm performance. In this vein, we highlight the role of Peer Independent Executive Directors (PIEDs) as a governance resource that helps diversified firms in managing their business portfolio and thereby enhancing the operational efficiency and performance. The importance of PIEDs is highlighted in the work of Hambrick, Misangyi, & Park (2015), who proposed the quad qualifications comprising independence, ability, bandwidth and motivation for assessing the effectiveness of a board member in the monitoring role. Combining the four quad dimensions into a single construct, we focus on the effort by PIEDs, i.e., CEOs of other firms, who are independent * Corresponding author. E-mail address: ajai@business.rutgers.edu (A. Gaur). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2022.07.035 Received 26 September 2021; Received in revised form 13 July 2022; Accepted 16 July 2022 Available online 21 July 2022 0148-2963/Published by Elsevier Inc. P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 directors on the board of the focal firm, to assist it in a strategic and advisory role.1 Specifically in the context of diversified firms, we argue, and provide substantial evidence, on the critical advisory role played by the PIEDs in managing these relationships and enhancing the effec­ tiveness of diversification strategy. Our research makes three important contributions to governance and diversification literature. First, we argue that the research on board of directors needs to focus on specific director characteristics, rather than looking at the boards in generic terms using the typical measures of size and independence. Building on the quad-qualification model (Hambrick et al., 2015), we suggest that not all directors have the time and expertise necessary to help firms manage its internal dynamics. We further argue that PIED directors, with their experience and social dis­ tance in running peer firms, are in a better position to help firms manage complex diversification strategies. Second, we argue and show that it is not just the managerial opportunism highlighted by the agency theorists that causes diversifi­ cation costs to rise, but also the lack of expertise relevant to harmonizing the interests of various business segments. More specifically, even when managerial opportunism is absent or minimal, the relationship between core — the largest and often historically the most important business segment — and noncore segments, directly or indirectly (through corporate parent), can result in considerable diversification costs (Kumar, 2013). These costs arise not only because firms have rigid or complex processes and structures or because their managers are selfserving, but also because of the divergence in the interests of core and noncore segments (Feldman, 2014). Firms need a governance structure that allows them to effectively manage multiple divergent interests. Presence of PIED directors on the boards provide such a governance arrangement as PIED are uniquely placed to help manage these diver­ gent interests. However, firms may not always have access to such expertise. Thus, the theoretical model developed in this paper shows how some firms may incur high implementation costs and dissipate any potential synergistic benefits that may have been otherwise available. As this may help resolve the long-standing puzzle on the performance ef­ fects of diversification, our study helps advance the diversification literature. Third, we argue that in determining exploitable coordination costs, the degree of relatedness between business segments is only one part of the equation. While managers at the core and noncore segments attempt to advance their own interests, it is incumbent on the corporate parent to manage their relationship in a manner that provides synergistic benefits to the whole firm. The efficacy-based view of governance suggests that PIEDs, with their expertise and detachment from organizational politics may play the role of neutral arbiters among various segments, especially in situations of conflict. In doing so, our study contributes to better understanding the role of ‘parenting’ dynamics in deriving benefits from diversification. (Amihud & Lev, 1981, 1999; Denis et al., 1997). Managers are believed to pursue such value-destroying diversification to inflate firm size and reduce risk (Meyer et al., 1992). Other scholars suggest that diversifying firms, in general, outperform non-diversifying ones, and that within those that diversify, related diversifiers outperform unrelated di­ versifiers (Li & Greenwood, 2004; Rumelt, 1974; Villalonga, 2004). From this perspective, firms diversifying into related businesses obtain synergistic benefits and improve their performance, while those diver­ sifying into unrelated businesses flounder in their performance. Yet others find that related diversification may cause firms to perform poorly as well (Shaver, 2006). There have been numerous attempts to reconcile these conflicting findings. Some scholars (Aupperle et al., 2014; Campa & Kedia, 2002; Graham et al., 2002) suggest that diversified firms traded at a discount before diversifying, implying that diversification, as such, had no sub­ sequent impact on firm value. Likewise, some believe that the confusion surrounding the agency-diversification link is largely an artifact of the methodologies and the measurement approaches used (Boyd et al., 2005). Risk-return trade-off has also been pointed out as a potential confounding factor. Amit and Livnat (1988a, 1988b), for example, suggested that while related diversifiers had a high return-high risk profile, unrelated diversifiers had a low return-low risk profile. Scholars have also tried to identify contingencies for diversification to succeed. Thus, some assert that strategic relatedness is superior to market relatedness (Markides & Williamson, 1994) and that related diversification enhances performance only when it allows a business preferential access to strategic resources and is accompanied by the right organizational structure (Markides & Williamson, 1996). Similarly, research has suggested that for firms to fully capture the economic benefits from related diversification, they need to manage complex in­ terdependencies among multiple levels of strategy (Kor & Leblebici, 2005; Singh, Gaur, & Schmid, 2010; Xu, Hitt, & Dai, 2020). However, research until recently has not paid much attention to unraveling strategy implementation costs (Kumar, 2013). In other words, while research highlights the benefits from enhanced economies of scale, purchasing power, marketing channel coordination, and such other synergies associated with related diversification (Mackey et al., 2017), it largely ignores bureaucratic costs owing to coordination needs and constraints imposed on various business segments by virtue of being a part of a diversified firm (Lee & Gaur, 2013; Xu et al., 2020). The efficacy-based view of governance that we propose in this paper looks at the specific aspect of managing the internal coordination and other challenges in diversified firms. 2.2. Strategy implementation costs In the context of challenges of managing diversified firms, three studies made breakthrough contributions. Rawley (2010) showed co­ ordination costs (the costs of managing task interdependencies) and organizational rigidity costs (the costs of changing or failing to change established routines and practices) to be significant in limiting the scope of the firm. The coordination costs “offset economies of scope for di­ versifiers, particularly in related diversification when achieving syn­ ergies depends upon coordinating activities across divisions” and that such coordination costs increase in the presence of organizational ri­ gidities that make institutionalized organizational routines costly to change (Rawley, 2010, p. 873). Zhou (2011) built on this concept of synergy as a propellant for, and coordination costs as a limit, to firm scope, and proposes complexity as a mechanism that potentially causes both synergy and coordination costs to rise simultaneously with increased relatedness in diversification. She views complexity both as a cause and source of organizational rigidity, and suggests that complexity aggravates coordination problems as “it increases the amount of existing interdependencies that must be adjusted when a new business imposes its own requirements” on a shared pool of inputs (Zhou, 2011, p. 625). From this perspective, 2. Literature and theory development We first encapsulate the diversification literature (See also Table 1) before outlining the advisory role of PIEDs in this process. 2.1. The context of corporate diversification The diversification-performance linkage has emerged as one of the more complex relationships that have been examined in the strategy field (Arikan & Stulz, 2016; Kuppuswamy & Villalonga, 2016; Miller, 2006). Some scholars argue that diversified firms underperform relative to focused firms, which is cited as an evidence of agency problems 1 As we focus on their advisory roles as independent peers, we chose to call them PIEDs rather than external CEO directors, which, as in prior research, emphasizes their monitoring role rather than the advisory role. 594 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Table 1 Overview of the literature on boards and diversification. Authors (year) Foundation Type Findings Limitations Bureaucratic costs Kumar (2013) Agency theory Empirical Core business may provide benefits such as scope economies to a related segment, but it may also exert power and constrain the segment to act in its interests in various internal and external transactions. Zhou (2011) Diversification Empirical Rawley (2010) Diversification Empirical To realize synergies, a firm needs to actively manage the interdependencies between different business lines, which, in turn, increases its coordination costs. The coordination costs may increase faster than synergy and set a limit to related diversification. This paper shows that coordination and organizational rigidity costs are significantly related. No direct measures and test of managerial opportunism/ agency relationships. It also does not include any mechanisms (e.g., boards) by which firms may manage relationship between core and non-core segments. The article recognizes complexity as a challenge to diversification, but it does not explore strategies firms may use to manage them. Natividad & Rawley (2016) Diversification Empirical A reduction in the scope of activities causes the productivity of firms’ legacy operations to fall sharply, before recovering in the long run. The results are most pronounced for firms with the strongest interdependencies. The article recognizes rigidity as a challenge to diversification, but it does not explore strategies firms may use to manage them. The article recognizes dependence as a challenge to diversification, but it does not explore strategies firms may use to manage them. Diversification Kuppuswamy & Villalonga (2016) Villalonga (2004) Agency theory Empirical The value of diversification varies with financial constraints and economic conditions. No standard corporate governance measures. Agency theory Empirical No standard corporate governance measures. Mackey et al. (2017) Diversification strategy Empirical Found evidence for diversification premium, instead of discount. Firms maximize value by choosing strategies that exploit their heterogeneous resources and individual situation. Information processing Theoretical/ review Moving beyond the logic of incentives and ability, it conceptualize a model based on the premise of boards as groups of individuals obtaining, processing and sharing information and explain how variation in informationprocessing demands at the director, board and firm level may challenge effective monitoring. The presence of “dual directors” (i.e., shared director between parent and spun-off firm) is positively associated with the average stock market returns of parent and spinoff firms. A director’s likelihood of being an effective monitor in any given domain is greatly increased when s/he has all four of the following qualities: independence, expertise in that domain, bandwidth, and motivation. The incentive to deliver must be paired with the ability to deliver. The presence of directors who lack top-level experience, but own large shareholdings, is negatively associated with firm value. Combining intrinsic and extrinsic motivations, it finds that the prestige associated with being a director, the ability to have influence, and identification with the director role make directors less likely for directors to quit; however, demotivating factors related to the time commitment required, such as holding other board appointments or serving as a CEO at another company, increase the likelihood of director exits. Theoretical. Does not discuss how increased director involvement (e.g., by meeting attendance) may help obtain, process and share information. Boards Boivie et al. (2016) Feldman (2016) Transaction costs Hambrick, Misangyi & Park (2015) Quad model Theoretical Feldman & Montgomery (2015) Agency & resource-based view Empirical Boivie et al. (2012) Self-determination Empirical diversification is an endogenous decision that firms make on the basis of perceived market opportunities, synergies, and coordination costs. Lastly, Kumar (2013), drawing on traditional agency and transaction cost theories, proposed managerial opportunism, rather than purely adaptation, as the mechanism by which coordination costs arise. He showed that “the power and influence exerted by the core business — and concomitantly, the subsidization of the core business by related segments — is an important source of costs borne by segments in a related diversified firm” (Kumar, 2013, p. 3). In contrast to previous agency theory literature that regards much of unrelated diversification to be a result of managerial opportunism, his study is the first to show the prevalence of opportunism in related diversification. He suggests that under certain conditions, core business segments are not too averse to exploit other related business segments for their own benefit. Power games, coalition dynamics, subjectivity, and bounded Recognizes the role of strategies, but does not include any mechanisms (e.g., boards) for implementing these strategies. Highlights the role of knowledge exchange but misses the role of opportunism and price-fixing. Difficult to test propositions as motivation is hard to observe, except by examining actual effort. The focus is on using demographic variables rather than director motivation or effort. Advances board research, but the focus is still on using characteristics variables (e.g., audit committee chair to measure influence and firm performance and media coverage for reputation) rather than observable director effort. rationalities, all play a prominent role, and as a result, strategic de­ cisions may not always embody the best possible outcomes, giving rise to friction and avoidable implementation costs that impact firm effi­ ciency, and ultimately, firm performance. Thus, in addition to a firm’s diversification profile — degree of diversification as well as its relat­ edness — we need to account for the manner of its implementation in studying firm performance. In the following section, we present the efficacy-based view of governance, discussing how boards, and PIEDs in particular, can help firms manage challenges associated with diversification. 2.3. The role of pier independent executive directors (PIED) and their effort Boards as the “apex of the firm’s decision control system” (Fama & 595 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Jensen, 1983, p. 311) have a critical role to play in effective strategic planning and implementation. As independent directors are responsible primarily for monitoring, resource-provisioning and influencing strat­ egy, but not for day-to-day administration or for implementing strategic decisions, the involvement of this elite and episodic decision-making group with the firm is periodic in nature (Forbes & Milliken, 1999; Klarner et al., 2018). Independent directors have the benefit of distance from the internal coalitions and politics of the firm, however this dis­ tance can reduce their firm-specific knowledge and disadvantage them in dealing with strategic issues such as diversification (Farjoun, 1994; Nonaka, 1994; Sirower, 1997). The quad-qualification model (Hambrick et al., 2015) recognizes this fact, and suggests that the effectiveness of a board member is contingent not just on their independence, but also on their expertise, bandwidth, and motivation. Klarner and colleagues argue that “the underlying capabilities required to govern effectively remain understudied” (2018, p. 1). Other researchers, similarly, argue that directors need specific capabilities to be able to contribute to strategic activities of a firm (Carpenter & Westphal, 2001; Singh & Delios, 2017). These capabilities include knowledge on how to manage key stakeholders, integrate new and existing strategic activities, and allocate resources to various units to compete effectively. Together, these capabilities are expected to assist focal firms adapt better in ever-evolving markets (Feldman, 2016; Feldman & Montgomery, 2015; Ponomareva et al., 2022). We build on this work to focus on the effort of a certain type of in­ dependent directors, viz., Peer Independent Executive Directors (PIEDs). We suggest that PIEDs bring certain expertise to the table that is helpful in effectively managing a diversified firm. Two of the four quad quali­ fications, independence and expertise are satisfied by their independent status, and by their being peer CEOs, respectively. Attending board meetings provides some indication that these directors have the moti­ vation and time to contribute to the success of the focal firm. As outlined below, PIEDs can play a useful role in helping managers negotiate the treacherous terrain of coalition dynamics (Dalton et al., 1998; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978). PIEDs with their managerial and leadership experience can help exploit synergies and reduce bureaucratic costs through several mech­ anisms. First, in the more diversified firms, the key executives may not understand all the different businesses and may make suboptimal de­ cisions for different business segments as well as the firm as a whole. PIEDs, with their experience of managing other businesses, may bring deeper insights and expertise to help the management of the focal firms make optimal decisions (Carpenter & Westphal, 2001; Johnson et al., 1993). Second, PIEDs may act as arbitrators between different interest groups. The CEO of the focal firm may rely on PIEDs to make decisions that would be otherwise seen as unfair by different interest groups within the firms. Third, the CEO can tap into the network of PIEDs to get a better understanding of the market trends, which helps in future planning and resource allocation for different business segments in a diversified firm. Finally, as peers CEOs, they not only have a high degree of authority and relevant expertise, but also often have deep social ties with the incumbent CEO, which enables them a level of access that the typical independent directors do not have (Fahlenbrach et al., 2010; Westphal & Zhu, 2019). The PIEDs thus satisfy the two QUAD conditions of being independent2 and having the required knowledge and experi­ ence to provide strategic guidance for managing diversified firms. We argue that the other two QUAD qualifications – bandwidth and moti­ vation – can be best gauged by the effort put in by these directors. Extant research suggests that having capabilities may be a necessary but not a sufficient condition (Arora, 2018; Freixanet & Renart, 2020; Nicholson & Kiel, 2007). These researchers question the validity of the assumption that directors necessarily put their capabilities to use to advance the interests of the firm, which relies on the expectation of reputational penalties for directors, who fail to deliver on their direc­ torial obligations. As important differences in directors’ motivation levels based on factors such as firm prestige, directors’ identification with the firm and the required time commitment (Boivie et al., 2012; Hambrick et al., 2015; Masulis & Mobbs, 2014) are unearthed, scholars realize that di­ rectors do not always perceive or incur reputational penalties for suboptimal effort (Arora, 2018). Moreover, as motivation is hard to infer in large-scale archival studies, by focusing on their actual effort, we can more effectively capture their bandwidth and motivation as it can ac­ count for the fact that while some directors may have the time but not a real desire to assist the firm, others may possess the motivation but lack in available time. Thus, we suggest that the effort put in by the PIED directors is in line with the quad-qualification outlined by Hambrick and colleagues (Hambrick et al., 2015). In the context of diversification and strategy implementation, for reasons outlined above, the effort made by PIED directors helps the firm harmonize the interests of different business units in diversified firms. This is line with a survey by McKinsey consulting (2018) indicated that board members with high impact, on an average, invested eight (8) extra days a year on work pertaining to firm’s strategy. Such work included three additional days on in­ vestments, executions and mergers and acquisitions.3 Accordingly, we propose that PIED effort is beneficial for enhancing performance of diversified firms, leading to the following hypothesis: Hypothesis 1. There is a positive relationship between PIED effort and financial performance of diversified firms. The costs of organizing a diversified set of businesses likely to be more pronounced in more diversified firms than in less diversified ones. Diversified firms take advantage of the synergistic benefits, and thereby improve both segment efficiency as well as profitability when compared to single-segment firms in the same industry. However, as level of diversification increases, the potential benefits of this coordination could easily be overcome by the costs of coordination. In other words, highly diversified firms may be less profitable and efficient as the costs of internal coordination start to outweigh the benefits of the synergies. While managers at the core and noncore segments attempt to advance their own interests, it is incumbent on the corporate parent to manage their relationship in a manner that provides synergistic benefits to the whole firm. The degree to which CEOs and directors can play the role of neutral arbiters among various segments, therefore, is an important part of this puzzle. As managing highly diversified firms requires substantial control and coordination in order to take advantage of the synergies across different business segments, the role of corporate headquarters in shaping critical decisions becomes more and more important (Pattnaik, Lu, & Gaur, 2018). However, the managerial ability to extract greater economies of scale under conditions of uncertainty can easily translate into greater bureaucratic costs in practice. This may occur if the resource transfers between the core and the peripheral segments of the diversified firm are managed in a way that leads to higher bureaucratic costs. Thus, for highly diversified firms, CEOs are more likely to need the help of PIEDs. When PIEDs put in the requisite effort, it can translate into firms better managing their diverse portfolios. Hence, we argue that while PIED effort is valuable for all diversified firms, their utility is likely to increase with increased diversification levels as decision making becomes more 2 As discussed in the next section, the independence, as referred to here, pertains to their independence from various business segments. As these di­ rectors have deep social ties to the CEO, their effectiveness at typical moni­ toring may be debatable. However, their effectiveness at advising on managing various business segments is likely not compromised by such ties. 3 This is also in line with the results in Faleye, who found that CEO-directors are “associated with higher acquisition returns, especially for complex deals (2011, p. 241). 596 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 and more complex. Accordingly, we propose that PIED effort is likely to be more beneficial in enhancing firm performance in the case of more diversified firms than less diversified firms, leading to the following hypothesis: likely to differentiate between the needs of the core business and the firm as a whole. Resultantly, they are in a position to better harmonize the interests of various segments in accordance with the needs of the firm. The effectiveness of PIED effort is likely to depend on how effi­ ciently the focal firm is managing its current business portfolio. In the case of firms that are managing their portfolio efficiently, they can focus their effort on helping the firms realize their synergistic potential. However, if the firm is struggling to do so, their attention may be diverted to managing conflicts and fixing efficiency problems first. In general, if a firm is operating with a high level of efficiency (when benchmarked against its single-segment counterparts that require no inter-segment coordination), there may be little scope for PIEDs to contribute and further improve efficiency. On the other hand, if firm is operating with low benchmarked efficiency, PIEDs may help the CEO better organize and harmonize the interests of different segments to­ wards improved firm performance. Hence, Hypothesis 2. PIED effort and diversification positively interact in affecting firm performance such that the benefit of PIED effort is greater for more diversified firms than less diversified firms. 2.4. Strategy implementation costs, firm efficiency, and PIED effort As argued before, when compared with single business firms, different business segments in a firm are subject to several constraints as they coordinate their activities with other segments, especially those that form the core of their firms. The core business segments not only share critical resources with other segments but may also provide the backbone of a firm’s critical know-how, human capital, and cultural identity. Because a firm likely owes its origin, existence, stability, cul­ ture, identity, and growth at various points to its core business, it likely enjoys higher legitimacy among firms’ internal and external stake­ holders, as well as a greater representation in the firms’ upper echelons. As the core segment of the diversified firm is most likely the segment that drives firm behavior, its performance would be crucial to the per­ formance of the entire firm. If the core segment is relatively more profitable and efficient than other firms, it is more likely to transfer positive practices to other segments and also manage the coordination costs more effectively. If, on the other hand, the core segment itself is not very efficient, it is unlikely that it will manage the internal coordination costs very effectively. If a diversified firm is not managed properly, it is more likely that the influence of the core business manifests in the form of the core’s interests subordinating the interests of other business segments, making them pliant to the core’s needs (Kumar, 2013). For example, they may feel compelled to source their inputs from the core despite the availability of better-quality suppliers or to offer discounts to the customers they share with the core business to help the latter increase its sales. If the core segment improves its profitability or efficiency at the expense of the noncore segments, then the firms will begin to incur higher bureaucratic costs that will outweigh the benefits of coordination. To the extent that the core segment increases its efficiency at the expense of non-core segments, diversified firms are more likely to suboptimize their performance.4 Thus, the conflicts between core and non-core segments could determine the overall efficiency of the focal firm. In other words, the synergies that potentially provide competitive advantage to a firm could also turn out to be an albatross for its per­ formance (Kumar, 2013). Firms whose managers ensure that the bene­ fits from such coordination and constraints outweigh the costs are more likely to be high performers. However, just because there are potential synergies does not mean that managers always succeed in exploiting them. PIEDs can play a salient role in helping managers actualize potential synergies. Internal directors have a close association with managers of core business segments, they may themselves have been promoted from within these segments, and even when hired from outside, they are likely to be influenced by the dominant logic prevalent in their firms. As a result of these close associations, they are more likely to perceive the needs of core segments to be synonymous with the needs of their firms, which may or may not be true. PIEDs (i.e., active CEOs of other firms), on the other hand, are neither deeply vested in the prevailing dominant logic nor are entrenched in their relationships with division managers. They are, therefore, more Hypothesis 3. PIED effort and benchmarked efficiency negatively interact in affecting firm performance such that the benefit of PIED effort is greater for firms with lower benchmarked efficiency than for those with higher bench­ marked efficiency. 3. Data and methodology 3.1. Data and sample The Compustat USA is the primary source for the financial and business segments data. This dataset has a panel structure with obser­ vations spanning the years 2001–2018. We started with all the firms included in Compustat segments data, which was then merged with MSCI Directors and governance datasets. The intersection of these datasets yielded initial sample of 11, 418 observations. Missing obser­ vations on various control variables result in a final sample of 7084 observations for 1096 diversified, i.e., multi-business-segment, firms in the United States.5 3.2. Variables of main interest Firm performance. We compute the Return on Assets (ROA) and Total Shareholder Return (TSR) as alternative measures of firm performance. ROA — net income to total assets — is commonly used accounting measure of performance (e.g., Nielsen & Nielsen, 2013). Following prior research (e.g., Conyon et al., 2001; Dalton & Aguinis, 2013), we compute annual TSR, a market-based measurement of performance, as follows: TSR = (StockPricen − StockPricen− 1 ) + Dividendn StockPricen− 1 (Benchmarked) firm efficiency. Following prior research (Arora, 2011; Kumar, 2013), we first compute the segment efficiency (SEGEFF) of all of firm’s business segments at the 3-digit SIC code level as follows: ) ( z ∑ Salesm SEGEFF A = Sales of Segment A − *Assets of SegmentA Wm * Assetsm m=1 where m = 1,…z denotes single segment firms in the same 3-digit SIC as segment A and wm is the sales weight or the proportion of sales contributed by firm m among these z firms. Assuming a hypothetical industry (SIC code 737) has only two firms: Orange, which has only one business, and Mango, which has other businesses as well, and their sales, 5 If we exclude CEO characteristics, we get a final sample of 8287 observa­ tions for 1140 firms. Our results are identical to those reported here. Note that for benchmarking the performance of these firms, we use all single-segment firms included in the Compustat segments-dataset. 4 This may be especially true in case managers of related diversified firms, who can impose more constraints than managers of unrelated diversified firms in order to exploit the synergies associated with diversification. 597 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 assets and SEGEFF are given as follows: assessed as = (0.875*2 + 0.375*1) *8 = 17. We use attendance at the board meetings as it is the only observable measure of director effort, which is legally mandated for reporting. While advising can and does also happen outside board meetings, if directors are not even willing to put in the bare minimum effort required towards attending board meetings, they likely are not very active beyond these meetings either. In other words, their board meeting attendance can be used to gauge their interest in putting in a required minimum level of effort. It is true that some directors may show up for the meetings, but not put in any effort beyond it. However, board meeting attendance is still a very good indication on whether directors are willing to put in at least some degree of effort for the firm (Arora, 2018). Moreover, those, who show up for meetings, likely feel some peer pressure to contribute what is promised at the meetings. 3.3. Sales assets Single business firm: Orange 20 15 Multi-business firm: segment 737: Mango 80 85 In this case, efficiency for Mango 737 segment equals –33.33 [80(85*20/15)]. As is apparent from the formula and example above, all singlesegment firms in that segments’ industry are used as the benchmark (weighted-averages) for calculating the segment efficiency of diversified firms. Such a comparison of efficiency between the single segment and diversified firms allows us to impute bureaucratic costs to business segments in a diversified firm. We then compute firm efficiency, which is the weighted average of all of firm’s segments, wherein segment sale is used as the weight. This methodology — calculating firm efficiency at the segment level — is advantageous in that it does not allow aggregate measures to obscure the performance of various business segments, which is critical in investigating diversification effects. Moreover, this measure does not also call for information on segment profitability, which in any case, is rarely, if ever, reported. For supplementary analysis, we also compute (benchmarked) core and noncore segment efficiency measures. Benchmarked core efficiency (BCE) captures the efficiency of the largest segment, whereas bench­ marked noncore efficiency (BNE) computes the weighted average of all noncore segments of a diversified firm. Diversification profile. Following previous research, we use the en­ tropy index (Jacquemin & Berry, 1979) to capture three alternative measures of diversification, viz. total, related and unrelated diversifi­ cation. The related component of the entropy index can be derived by a partition of total entropy into its related and unrelated parts, wherein total diversification entropy (DT), unrelated diversification (DU) and related diversification (DR) are given by: ( ) N ∑ 1 DT = Pi ln P i i=1 3.4. Control variables Firm size and age. Prior research (Dahiya et al., 2003; Lee & Weng, 2013; Moulton & Thomas, 1993) suggests that older and more estab­ lished firms have better access to human and financial resources. Therefore, it is important to control for firm size and age. We measure firm size by the (logged values of) number of employees working for the firm. As firm efficiency involves total assets as its denominator, it can potentially cause the problem of multicollinearity if we used total assets as a measure of firm size also. The use of the number of employees averts this problem without any loss of information. We control for firm age, which is computed by subtracting the year of formation from the year of current reporting. R&D and advertisement intensity. Prior research (McWilliams & Siegel, 2001) suggests the need to control for effect of R&D and advertisement intensity to avoid upwardly biased estimates of the financial impact of various product differentiation initiatives. Therefore, we control for R&D expenditure to sales ratio and advertisement expenditure to sales ratio. Capital intensity. As capital intensity can cause rigidities in imple­ menting and changing corporate strategy (Finkelstein & Boyd, 1998), we used the ratio of the total plant, property and equipment assets to the number of employees as a control variable. Financial condition. To preclude the effect of firm’s financial health (Altman, 1993; Arora, 2018), we control for three financial ratios, viz., (1) Cash and accounts receivables/ total assets, (2) Current assets/ Fixed assets, and (3) total debt to equity ratio. Corporate governance. Previous research (Yermack, 1996) shows that larger boards become too unwieldy, unproductive, and unmanageable, and therefore provide lower social incentives for directors and encourage more free riding. Hence, board size is included as one of the control variables. As greater independent director representation has been shown to improve monitoring and external legitimacy of the firm (Ahmed & Duellman, 2007; Chhaochharia & Grinstein, 2007), we include the number of independent directors in my regression model. Following prior research, we also include CEO age, CEO tenure and CEO duality to control for career horizon, entrenchment and power respec­ tively. (Boyd, 1995; Chen & Nadkarni, 2016; Hill & Phan, 1991) CEO tenure refers to the length of the time CEO had been in his or her po­ sition. CEO duality is a dichotomous measure, which equals 1 if CEO was also the chair of the board.6 Levels of Diversification. We control for absolute levels of a firm’s diversification portfolio by including segment count in our regression models (Villalonga, 2004). where Pi = Proportion of sales in SIC code (i) for a corporation with “N” different 4-digit SIC business segments. DU is computed in a similar manner except using 2-digit SIC business segments. Finally, DR is simply computed as: DR = DT- DU. As previous research has shown “moderate levels of diversification yield higher levels of performance than either limited or extensive diversification” (Palich et al., 2000), we include square terms of entropy measures mentioned above in our robustness test. PIED effort. We start by identifying independent directors who are active CEOs of other firms as we expect them to bring their experience, resources, and networks to help the focal firm pursue diversification strategy successfully. We also expect them to act as neutral arbiters among core and noncore business segments. After identifying peer in­ dependent executive directors, following prior research (Arora, 2018), we compute PIED effort as below: PIEDeffort = (w1*N1 + w2*N2)*M N1 and N2 are, respectively, the number of active (attended at least 75% of board meetings) and non-active (attended less than 75%) PIEDs; M is the number of board meetings, and w1 and w2 are the proportion of meetings attended by active and non-active PIEDs. Note that firms are only required to report which of their directors attended at least 75 percent of board meetings. Assuming that the percentage of meetings of the active directors is uniformly distributed between 75 and 100%, and for the non-active ones between 0 and 75%, we set w1 = 0.875 and w2 = 0.375 (i.e., at mean values for each category). Thus, if a firm held 8 meetings the year prior to reorganization and 2 of its 3 PIEDs attend­ ed>75% of the meetings, but one did not, this board’s total PIED effort is 6 We did not include proportion of busy directors (i.e., directors who sit on more than three other boards) out of concerns about potential multicollinearity. However, the inclusion of this variable does not alter the results reported in this paper. 598 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 3.5. Methodology Hypothesis 2 predicted that the benefit of PIED effort is greater for more diversified firms than less diversified firms. As seen in Table 2, the interaction of PIED effort and total diversification is significant (β = 0.02, p = 0.031 in Model 6). However, to interpret interaction effects, following the best practice recommendations of prior research (Arora & De, 2020; Brambor et al., 2006; Clark et al., 2021), we use marginsplot in Stata to depict predicted values along with 95% confidence intervals, at various plausible values (+/- 1 standard deviations from the mean as per standard practice) of interacting variables. Note that lastly, following the best practice recommendations (Dawson & Richter, 2006), we use standardized independent variables (mean = 0, s.d. = 1) in our regressions to help with interpretation of interaction effects. In support of hypothesis 2, we notice in Fig. 1 that as the level of diversification increases, the significance of PIED effort becomes more apparent. At low levels of diversification, PIED effort does not make much of a difference to firm performance, as indicated by a flat blue line with a negligible upward slope. However, at high levels of diversifica­ tion, PIED effort helps firms close the gap with lesser diversified firms. In fact, there are essentially no differences among firms, irrespective of their diversification levels, at the very high PIED effort. In Hypothesis 3, we predicted that the benefits of PIED effort is greater for firms with lower benchmarked efficiency than for those with higher benchmarked efficiency. While the interaction term was not significant (β = 0.01, p > 0.10 in Model 6), recall that the significance of these interactions only implies whether (or not) interactions are signif­ icant at the mean values of the interacting variables. It is more important to depict their marginal values to better understand the nature of their relationship. Fig. 2 provides the marginsplot for the interaction between BFE and PIED effort. While we expected that the benefits of PIED effort would be greater for firms with lower benchmarked efficiency, our findings yield the results that are slightly to the contrary. Although PIED effort benefit all firms, we find that these are most helpful for firms with higher benchmarked efficiency: A combination of high BFE and high PIED effort leads to the highest firm performance (Marginal effect = 0.10, p = 0.00). While at low levels of BFE, we do not notice statistically significant effect of PIED effort. This could suggest there may be more than one channel by which PIEDs help the firm or that a sequential process exists in which PIEDs first help the firm raise their efficiency, which, in turn, leads to performance benefits at a subsequent time period. We use a longitudinal research methodology to avoid biased and misleading estimates from cross-sectional snapshots (Finkelstein & Boyd, 1998; George, 2005; Maddala, 2002). We first examined the appropriateness of fixed v. random-effects models using the Hausman test, which indicated fixed-effects (FE) models to be more appropriate (χ2 = 248.18; p < 0.001) for our sample (Greene, 2003; Hausman, 1978). FE regressions, which use “within-firm variation to identify co­ efficient estimates, advantageous for mitigating certain endogeneity concerns and ruling out spurious relationships” (Shaver, 2019: 1), help control for firm and time-specific heterogeneity and produce unbiased regression coefficients (Greene, 2003). FE regressions also return esti­ mates that are not biased by omitted time-invariant control variables (Baltagi, 2008; Stock & Watson, 2007). We lagged independent vari­ ables by a year to better establish causality (Hambrick, 2007). Lastly, we also conducted explicit endogeneity tests by employing Hausman-Taylor regressions (xthtaylor in Stata) for endogenous cova­ riates (J. Hausman & Taylor, 1981). This technique has been found to be particularly effective at deriving robust estimates when several explanatory variables may be endogenously correlated (Baltagi et al., 2002). For the purpose of our empirical design, we assumed all main variables of interest — diversification, efficiency, PIED effort, and firm performance — to be endogenous covariates. 4. Results We report the descriptive statistics and correlations in Table 1. The mean values for ROA, PIED effort, and firm efficiency are 0.13, 5.03, 0.08 with standard deviations of 0.08, 8.03, and 0.48 respectively. The descriptive statistics, including the correlation matrix, with respect to the other measures, also appear in the table. To ensure that multi­ collinearity is not affecting our results, we examined the variance inflation factors (VIF) scores. All VIF scores are below 3, with a mean of 1.72, well within the commonly specified rule of thumb of a score of 10 indicating no evidence of multicollinearity problems (Cohen et al., 2003). In Table 2, we provide the results of our FE regression models with ROA as the dependent variable and PIED effort, benchmarked firm ef­ ficiency (BFE), and total diversification (DT) and as the variables of main interest. We standardized all variables before running our regression models. Model 1 in Table 2 shows the results for the regression with control variables alone, whereas Model 2 introduces DT and Model 3 in­ corporates PIED effort and BFE.7 Models 4 and 5 introduces individual interactions and Model 6 presents the complete regression models with all hypothesized direct and indirect (interaction) effects. The table shows that many of the control variables, such as firm size, firm age, advertisement intensity, capital intensity, cash ratio and CEO tenure are significantly — positively or negatively — associated with the ROA. More interestingly, however, Table 2 lends strong support for our predictions. Hypothesis 1 predicted that the PIED effort is positively associated with the ROA. We notice that PIED effort is indeed positively associated with the ROA across the entire regression table (β = 0.02, p = 0.009 in Model 6). Hence, Hypothesis 1 is supported.8 4.1. Post-hoc robustness tests As prior research distinguishes between related (DR) and unrelated diversification (DU) in terms of expected impact on firm performance, we decompose total diversification (DT) into DR and DU, and rerun the regression models reported above. We replace DT with DR in Model 7, and with DU in Model 8 in Table 3. As seen from Models 7 & 8, the results are essentially identical to those reported in Model 6 in Table 2 above. The marginsplots in Figs. 3 and 4 also very similar except for slightly steeper slopes. Even when we include both DR and DU in the same regression model (unreported), these patterns persist.Table 4. In Models 9–10 in Table 3, we similarly replace firm efficiency with the core segment (Model 9) and noncore segment efficiency (Model 10) measures. These models, once again, reproduce identical results. Figs. 5 and 6 also reveal patterns similar to those reported above. We, next, re-run this regression model by replacing ROA with Total Shareholder Return (TSR) as our dependent variable, and we find even stronger results with respect to variables of main interest (See Model 11). Lastly, in Model 12, we run Hausman-Taylor regressions (xthtaylor in Stata) for endogenous covariates by assuming all our main variables, i.e., diversification, efficiency, PIED effort, and firm performance, to be endogenously related. We find results with respect to PIED effort (β = 0.03, p <=0.001), DT (β = -0.09, p = 0.000), PIEDEFF × DT (β = 0.02, p = 0.026), PIEDEFF × BFE (β = 0.01, p > 0.10) to be identical to those 7 We ran regressions by introducing each of the direct effects separately and found identical results. These are not included in the table for the sake of brevity but are available on request. 8 Note that we repeated this regression model with non-PIED effort instead of PIED effort. Our results showed a statistically insignificant result (β = 0.02, p > 0.10). Further, we also ran regressions with proportional PIED effort (PIED effort/ Board effort) to capture the effect of PIED effort in relation to total board effort. We obtained results that are materially identical to those reported in Table 2. 599 P. Arora and A. Gaur 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 600 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 22 23 24 25 24 23 22 21 20 19 18 17 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Return on Assets 0.13 0.08 Total shareholder 0.12 0.41 0.14 return PIED Effort 4.76 8.03 − 0.01 − 0.03 Benchmarked firm 0.08 0.48 0.12 0.03 0.01 efficiency Benchmarked core 0.08 0.57 0.12 0.02 0.01 0.97 efficiency Benchmarked 0.08 0.31 0.06 0.02 0.04 0.47 noncore efficiency Total diversification 0.84 0.43 − 0.05 − 0.01 0.09 − 0.09 Unrelated 0.20 0.17 − 0.04 − 0.01 0.06 − 0.06 diversification Related 0.64 0.36 − 0.04 − 0.01 0.07 − 0.08 diversification Firm size 1.76 1.47 0.10 − 0.02 0.19 0.00 (employees) Firm age 32.11 18.52 − 0.03 − 0.02 0.18 0.03 R&D intensity 0.02 0.10 − 0.16 − 0.02 − 0.01 0.01 Advertisement 0.01 0.02 0.04 − 0.01 0.02 0.02 intensity Capital intensity 4.38 1.47 − 0.11 0.00 0.05 − 0.14 Cash Ratio 0.63 1.03 − 0.06 0.01 − 0.04 0.04 Current assets to 0.92 0.96 − 0.01 0.03 − 0.07 0.31 Fixed assets Total debt to equity 1.75 2.80 − 0.09 0.03 0.03 − 0.02 Board size 9.22 2.18 0.00 − 0.02 0.19 − 0.05 # of independent 6.73 2.31 − 0.01 − 0.03 0.26 − 0.02 directors CEO age 61.89 7.24 0.00 0.01 − 0.05 − 0.04 CEO-chairman 0.54 0.50 0.02 − 0.01 0.06 − 0.01 duality CEO tenure 5.54 5.65 0.01 0.01 − 0.11 0.00 # PIEDs 1.09 1.71 − 0.01 − 0.05 0.50 − 0.02 # of business 4.16 1.61 − 0.06 − 0.01 0.09 − 0.04 segments Herfindahl index 0.52 0.21 0.05 0.01 − 0.08 0.10 0.32 − 0.11 − 0.08 0.09 0.03 0.55 − 0.10 0.10 0.92 0.18 − 0.01 0.04 0.29 0.17 0.04 0.01 0.01 0.26 0.00 0.18 0.06 0.18 0.30 0.02 − 0.02 0.00 − 0.02 − 0.09 − 0.06 0.06 − 0.01 − 0.03 0.00 0.00 − 0.08 0.00 − 0.14 − 0.16 − 0.07 − 0.04 − 0.06 − 0.27 0.18 − 0.06 − 0.13 0.04 0.02 − 0.10 − 0.05 − 0.10 − 0.30 − 0.15 0.36 0.06 − 0.08 0.31 0.21 − 0.11 − 0.06 − 0.11 − 0.17 − 0.10 0.14 0.06 − 0.43 − 0.02 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.03 − 0.01 − 0.03 0.02 0.18 0.19 0.01 0.07 0.09 0.02 0.18 0.18 0.34 0.12 0.43 0.38 0.04 − 0.04 − 0.06 0.37 − 0.04 0.00 0.43 − 0.05 − 0.03 0.14 − 0.15 − 0.13 0.19 − 0.17 − 0.23 0.20 − 0.18 − 0.21 − 0.03 − 0.04 − 0.02 − 0.04 − 0.01 − 0.02 0.00 − 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.12 0.06 − 0.03 − 0.07 0.16 0.00 − 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.01 − 0.02 − 0.01 − 0.04 0.01 − 0.02 − 0.01 0.00 0.05 0.12 0.07 0.08 0.77 0.26 0.01 − 0.01 − 0.07 − 0.08 − 0.05 − 0.08 − 0.06 0.04 − 0.02 − 0.07 0.12 0.09 − 0.02 − 0.14 − 0.16 0.33 − 0.01 0.00 0.09 0.06 0.08 0.20 0.16 0.01 − 0.01 0.02 − 0.06 − 0.06 0.03 0.23 0.27 − 0.09 − 0.05 0.04 0.80 0.40 0.76 0.23 0.19 − 0.03 − 0.02 0.06 − 0.09 − 0.12 0.05 0.20 0.19 − 0.02 0.13 − 0.13 − 0.96 − 0.55 − 0.88 − 0.26 − 0.16 0.02 0.02 0.09 0.11 0.11 − 0.01 − 0.15 − 0.16 0.21 0.07 − 0.07 0.05 − 0.06 0.02 − 0.03 0.10 0.07 − 0.08 − 0.67 Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 20 21 S.D. Mean Table 2 Descriptive statistics and correlation Matrix. P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Fig. 1. Interaction effect of total diversification (DT) and PIED effort on firm performance. Fig. 2. Interaction effect of Benchmarked Firm Efficiency (BFE) and PIED effort on firm performance. Note: As these interaction graphs use standardized variables, the values plotted above correspond to one standard deviations above (+) or below (-) mean values of depicted variables. reported in Table 2. Thus, despite running regression models with various permutations and combinations of control measures as well as alternate specifications with regard to variables of main interest, we find very robust support for our predictions. which suggests that firms can structure their board of directors in such a way that the board members help manage the internal dynamics and enhance efficiency of operations in diversified firms. Presence and active participation of PIEDs offers such governance setup and helps in navi­ gating the challenges associated with diversification strategies. Besides clarifying the governance antecedents of diversification costs, this study makes three important contributions to the literature. First, we illustrate the need for research to focus on specific expertise and effort of directors rather than merely examining generic de­ mographic characteristics such as independence. Building on recent work on director expertise and motivation (Arora, 2018; Boivie et al., 2012; Hambrick et al., 2015; Masulis & Mobbs, 2014), we demonstrate that not all directors have the time and expertise to help a firm manage its internal dynamics. PIED effort can provide the quad-qualification necessary for firms in managing complex diversification portfolio. This sets the stage for researchers not just to focus on specific domain 4.2. Discussion and conclusion This study provides a robust examination of the relationship between PIED effort and performance of a diversified firm. Recent research has highlighted the fact that despite potential economies of scope, firms do not automatically reap synergistic benefits from relatedness as they need to carry out extensive coordination to serve the greater good of the overall firm. This stream of research suggests that while relatedness may be a necessary condition for firms to enjoy economies of scope, it is not sufficient by itself. We propose an efficacy-based view of governance 601 P. Arora and A. Gaur Table 3 DT, Benchmarked Firm Efficiency, PIED Effort and Return on Assets: Panel data, fixed effects (F.E.) regression results. Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 602 DV: ROA β se p β se p β se p β se p β se p β se p Firm size (employees) Firm age (years) R&D intensity Advertisement intensity Capital intensity Cash ratio Current Assets to Fixed Assets Total debt to equity Board size Number of independent directors CEO age CEO tenure CEO-chairman duality Number of business segments Total diversification (DT) Benchmarked firm efficiency (BFE) PIED Effort (PIEDEFF) DT × PIEDEFF BFE × PIEDEFF Constant − 0.42 0.05 − 1.92 − 0.15 − 0.36 − 0.05 0.04 − 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.00 0.01 0.03 − 0.02 − 0.04 (0.086) (0.075) (1.518) (0.047) (0.090) (0.036) (0.027) (0.014) (0.031) (0.021) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.017) [0.000] [0.494] [0.207] [0.002] [0.000] [0.174] [0.105] [0.975] [0.179] [0.923] [0.514] [0.078] [0.614] [0.031] − 0.41 0.05 − 1.85 − 0.15 − 0.36 − 0.05 0.04 − 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.00 0.01 0.03 − 0.02 0.02 − 0.09 (0.086) (0.074) (1.538) (0.046) (0.089) (0.036) (0.027) (0.014) (0.031) (0.021) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.030) (0.038) [0.000] [0.512] [0.228] [0.002] [0.000] [0.150] [0.112] [0.925] [0.186] [0.874] [0.548] [0.076] [0.623] [0.431] [0.020] − 0.39 0.03 − 1.80 − 0.15 − 0.35 − 0.05 0.03 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.01 0.01 0.04 − 0.02 0.02 − 0.08 0.05 0.03 (0.087) (0.074) (1.509) (0.046) (0.090) (0.036) (0.027) (0.014) (0.031) (0.021) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.029) (0.037) (0.020) (0.009) [0.000] [0.650] [0.233] [0.001] [0.000] [0.138] [0.236] [0.984] [0.212] [0.720] [0.590] [0.058] [0.600] [0.431] [0.026] [0.020] [0.001] − 0.41 0.05 − 1.83 − 0.15 − 0.36 − 0.05 0.04 − 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.01 0.01 0.03 − 0.02 0.02 − 0.09 (0.086) (0.074) (1.532) (0.046) (0.089) (0.036) (0.027) (0.014) (0.031) (0.021) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.030) (0.038) [0.000] [0.519] [0.233] [0.001] [0.000] [0.140] [0.123] [0.985] [0.230] [0.668] [0.552] [0.067] [0.624] [0.432] [0.019] − 0.40 0.03 − 1.86 − 0.15 − 0.34 − 0.05 0.03 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.01 0.01 0.04 − 0.02 − 0.03 (0.086) (0.074) (1.497) (0.046) (0.091) (0.036) (0.028) (0.014) (0.031) (0.021) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.017) [0.000] [0.645] [0.214] [0.002] [0.000] [0.160] [0.236] [0.934] [0.203] [0.776] [0.555] [0.060] [0.586] [0.053] 0.03 0.02 (0.009) (0.008) [0.008] [0.039] 0.05 0.03 (0.020) (0.009) [0.012] [0.001] 0.00 (0.027) [0.911] − 0.00 (0.027) [0.972] 0.01 0.00 (0.012) (0.026) [0.635] [0.999] − 0.39 0.03 − 1.83 − 0.15 − 0.35 − 0.05 0.03 0.00 − 0.04 − 0.01 0.01 0.04 − 0.02 0.02 − 0.08 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00 (0.086) (0.074) (1.539) (0.046) (0.090) (0.036) (0.027) (0.014) (0.031) (0.021) (0.018) (0.019) (0.038) (0.029) (0.037) (0.020) (0.009) (0.008) (0.012) (0.027) [0.000] [0.665] [0.235] [0.001] [0.000] [0.138] [0.238] [0.982] [0.215] [0.714] [0.575] [0.061] [0.592] [0.449] [0.025] [0.018] [0.009] [0.031] [0.504] [0.952] Observations R-squared Number of unique firms F-test 7,084 0.041 1,096 5.427 − 0.00 (0.026) [0.936] 0.00 7,084 0.044 1,096 5.464 (0.027) [0.957] 7,084 0.048 1,096 5.932 7,084 0.047 1,096 6.081 7,084 0.046 1,096 5.624 7,084 0.049 1,096 5.922 Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Notes: (1) We excluded the number of Peer Independent Executive Directors (PIED) from our regression out of concerns regarding potential multicollinearity. However, its inclusion does not affect the results reported above. (2) While following prior research, we tested for non-linear effects of DT by including its squared term in our regression models. As its inclusion or exclusion had no substantial impact on the nature of relationships depicted above, we did not use it in our main regression results reported above. (3) All variables were standardized (0,1) before running regressions above. P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Fig. 3. Interaction (margins) effect of related diversification (DR) and PIED effort. Fig. 4. Interaction (margins) effect of unrelated diversification (DU) and PIED effort. expertise in evaluating directors’ contributions, but also considering their willingness to expand effort on behalf of the focal firm. Our results suggest that only some directors have the time and expertise relevant to managing its internal dynamics. In showing the relevance of PIED di­ rectors quad-qualification and effort for firms seeking to manage com­ plex diversification strategies, we address a gap in the literature on the importance of independent directors’ knowledge, skills, abilities, and motivations that has received limited attention (Klarner et al., 2018; Kor & Sundaramurthy, 2009), even though some research has shown it to be of great significance. Thus, for example, Carpenter & Westphal (2001) argue that directors’ ability to contribute to focal firms could depend on knowledge schemata developed in similar roles. Second, we show that even when managerial opportunism is absent or minimal, divergent interests of core and noncore segments can result in considerable diversification costs (Kumar, 2013). Thus, harmonizing the interests of various business segments is critical for not dissipating potential synergistic benefits from diversification. For management scholars to resolve the long-standing puzzle on the performance effects of diversification, we need to account for the way these relationships are managed. Third, we show that PIEDs, by virtue of their expertise and neutrality, can be the impartial arbiters needed to harmonize the divergent interests of these business segments. While managers at the core and noncore segments are invested in advancing their own in­ terests, it is incumbent on the corporate parent to harmonize their divergent interests for the benefit of the whole firm. PIEDs with their 603 P. Arora and A. Gaur Table 4 Diversification, benchmarked efficiency, PIED effort and ROA: alternate measures. Method: DV: Model 7 FE ROA β 604 All control variables Industry effects Yes PIED Effort Related diversification (DR) PIEDEFF × DR Benchmarked firm efficiency (BFE) PIEDEFF × BFE Total diversification (DT) PIEDEFF × DT Unrelated diversification (DU) PIEDEFF × DU Benchmarked core efficiency (BCE) PIEDEFF × BCE Benchmarked noncore efficiency (BNE) PIEDEFF × BNE Constant 0.02 − 0.04 0.02 0.05 0.01 Observations R-squared Number of unique firms F-test 7,084 0.048 1,096 5.684 0.00 Model 8 FE ROA se p β Model 9 FE ROA se p Yes (0.009) (0.027) (0.008) (0.020) (0.012) (0.027) [0.008] [0.143] [0.024] [0.013] [0.544] [0.997] (0.009) [0.002] 0.05 0.01 (0.021) (0.012) [0.015] [0.591] − 0.02 0.01 (0.014) (0.007) [0.224] [0.287] 7,084 0.047 1,096 5.374 se p Yes 0.03 − 0.00 β Model 10 FE ROA (0.026) [0.996] 0.02 se p Yes (0.009) [0.009] − 0.08 0.02 (0.037) (0.008) [0.026] [0.026] 0.04 0.01 (0.017) (0.011) [0.029] [0.334] 0.00 (0.027) [0.964] 7,084 0.048 1,096 5.975 β Model 11 FE TSR 0.03 β se p Yes (0.010) β se p Yes Yes [0.004] 0.16 (0.015) [0.000] 0.03 (0.008) [0.001] (0.025) (0.015) (0.035) (0.012) [0.594] [0.001] [0.233] [0.069] 0.06 0.01 − 0.09 0.02 (0.013) (0.009) (0.023) (0.007) [0.000] [0.339] [0.000] [0.026] (0.027) [0.118] − 2.41 (1.023) [0.019] − 0.09 0.02 (0.034) (0.008) [0.009] [0.070] 0.01 0.05 0.04 − 0.02 0.03 − 0.01 − 0.07 (0.016) (0.007) (0.027) [0.044] [0.254] [0.007] − 0.04 6,677 0.057 1,042 7.538 Model 12 xthtaylor ROA 7,407 0.036 1,118 11.41 7,084 1,096 7.832 Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Notes: 1. All models above used the same control variables as in Table 2. They are not reported above for parsimony. 2. Fixed effects models do not allow inclusion of industry control effects as any time invariant variable is dropped out. Moreover, we also benchmark firm efficiency against all single-segment firms in the same industry. 3. Model 12 summarizes results from Hausmann Taylor regression for endogenous covariates. All other models use fixed effects regressions. 4. Model 11 uses total shareholder returns as the dependent variable. All other models use return on assets as the dependent variable. P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Fig. 5. Interaction (margins) effect of Benchmarked Core Efficiency and PIED effort. Fig. 6. Interaction (margins) effect of Benchmarked Noncore Efficiency and PIED effort. expertise and distance from organizational politics are in a unique po­ sition of playing the role of neutral arbiters among various segments, especially in situations of conflict. In doing so, we highlight the importance of examining ‘parenting’ dynamics in diversification. Overall, our study develops an efficacy-based view of corporate governance for increased clarity on the nature of the relationship be­ tween governance, diversification, and firm performance. For directors, it highlights the significance of their advisory role on top of their normal monitoring duties to the firm. 4.4. Limitations and future research Despite its methodological advances, our study is not without its own limitations. First, we use measures of segment efficiency to proxy for bureaucratic costs. We do not distinguish between bureaucratic costs originating from coordination among business segments and parenting costs (e.g., planning and reporting) imposed by corporate headquarters (Campbell et al., 1995; Goold et al., 1998). In multi-segment businesses, the existence of a corporate parent entails significant costs and benefits, which ideally should be explicitly considered (Mukherjee et al., 2018). Parsing these bureaucratic costs will help further gain a contextual un­ derstanding into the governance systems. Given the lack of this infor­ mation for our sample, we leave it for future research. 4.3. Practical implications The role of directors is contextual in nature. Our study highlights the significance of managing internal dynamics, i.e., the relationship be­ tween core and non-core segments, for reaping rewards from diversifi­ cation. Managers leading multi-business firms can use this understanding for better firm performance. This study can also help them understand how to assemble and use their boards in this endeavor. 605 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Second, despite its elaborate research design, this study is missing other important variables that can potentially influence the nature of these relationships. For instance, we do not consider ownership struc­ ture in our research design. Block ownership, family ownership, and founders’ presence can all influence the nature of this relationship. Future research may wish to explicitly account for these factors as well to understand if various governance systems can compliment or sub­ stitute the advisory role of directors proposed in this study. For example, is directors’ advisory role more important in family firms? Are firms with dispersed more ownership more likely to need direct monitoring, while those with concentrate ownership more reliant on directors’ resource-provisioning and service roles? Third, our sample consists of mostly large firms from the United States. For generalizing our results beyond this single institutional context, we recommend future research to use a multi-country context and present more conclusive evidence (Bhaumik et al., 2019; Mukher­ jee, et al., 2021). Replicating this study in other contexts will help reveal the factors that support or impede directors’ efficacy in various insti­ tutional settings (Singh & Gaur, 2009). Fourth, our findings suggest that there may be more than once channel by which PIED effort may benefit firms or that these benefits may be realized sequentially in a process that first results in raising implementation efficiency, before it leads to a broader increase in firm performance. We recommend future research to explore these avenues further. Lastly, Upper echelons theory has been used as a foundation for studying the impact of top managers and directors on firm outcomes since Hambrick & Mason’s (1984) groundbreaking paper on organiza­ tion as a reflection of its top managers. This theory surmises that exec­ utives’ experiences, values, and personalities greatly influence their interpretations of the situations they face, which in turn affects firm choices and outcomes. As it is extremely difficult to observe executives’ thoughts, values and processes, research relies on observable charac­ teristics such as age, education, and functional background. While UET research claims that these more readily observable characteristics can adequately surrogate for executives’ cognitive pro­ cesses (Talke et al., 2010), it cannot be confirmed with any degree of certainty. Hambrick (2007, p. 337) laments that very few studies have attempted to confirm whether and how executive characteristics affect information processing, and that “psychological and social processes by which executive profiles are converted into strategic choices still remain largely a mystery — the proverbial black box.” Much like previous research on the board of directors, this study also relies on directors’ demographic markers to proxy for their behavior. Despite the challenges involved in collecting primary data for a large-scale study of this nature, it will be worth its while for future research to explore that option. In particular, it will be interesting to understand what motivates directors to expand their effort in support of a focal firm. Further, as PIEDs also expect to use their learning from their directorship in their regular managerial roles (Carpenter & Westphal, 2001), how do they and focal firms balance these somewhat divergent needs? In conclusion, this study examined the role of quad-qualified PIED effort in improving the performance of diversified firms. Using a longi­ tudinal sample of US firms, we show that the PIED effort become increasingly beneficial to firms with every successive increase in diversification level. Our results hold irrespective of the diversification type used by firms. We also find that while the benefit of PIED effort is apparent for all firms, it is especially useful for firms with high bench­ marked efficiency. This suggests that PIEDs are in a better position to contribute to firm performance when firms succeed at raising their implementation efficiency. More broadly, by showing the relevance of directors’ domain expertise and effort in corporate diversification, we provide a path forward for corporate governance and diversification research. CRediT authorship contribution statement Punit Arora: Writing – review & editing, Writing – original draft, Methodology, Formal analysis, Data curation, Conceptualization. Ajai Gaur: Writing – review & editing, Writing – original draft, Conceptualization. Declaration of Competing Interest The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper. Data availability The authors do not have permission to share data. Acknowledgment We thank seminar participants at Rutgers Business School for their feedback on earlier versions of this paper. References Ahmed, A., & Duellman, S. (2007). Accounting conservatism and board of director characteristics: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 43(2), 411–437. Altman, E. (1993). Why businesses fail. Journal of Business Strategy, 3(4), 15–21. Amihud, Y., & Lev, B. (1981). Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 605–617. Amihud, Y., & Lev, B. (1999). Does corporate ownership structure affect its strategy towards diversification? Strategic Management Journal, 20(11), 1063–1069. Amit, R., & Livnat, J. (1988a). Diversification and the risk-return trade-off. Academy of Management Journal, 31(1), 154–166. Amit, R., & Livnat, J. (1988b). Diversification strategies, business cycles and economic performance. Strategic Management Journal, 9(2), 99–110. Arikan, A., & Stulz, R. (2016). Corporate Acquisitions, Diversification, and the Firm’s Life Cycle. Journal of Finance, 71(1), 139–194. https://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12362 Arora, P. (2018). Financially Linked Independent Directors and Bankruptcy Reemergence: The Role of Director Effort. Journal of Management, 44(7), 2665–2689. Arora, P. (2011). Corporate diversification, bureaucratic costs and likelihood of bankruptcy. Academy of Management Annual Meeting, 1–6. Arora, P., & De, P. (2020). Environmental Sustainability Practices and Exports: The Interplay of Strategy and Institutions in Latin America. Journal of World Business, 55 (4), Article 101094. Aupperle, K., Acar, W., & Mukherjee, D. (2014). Revisiting the fit–performance thesis half a century later: A historical financial analysis of Chandler’s own matched and mismatched firms. Business History, 56(3), 341–371. Baltagi, B. (2008). Econometric analysis of panel data. John Wiley & Sons. Baltagi, B., Bresson, G., & Pirotte, A. (2002). Comparison of forecast performance for homogeneous, heterogeneous and shrinkage estimators: Some empirical evidence from US electricity and natural-gas consumption. Economics Letters, 76(3), 375–382. Bhaumik, S., Driffield, N., Gaur, A. S., Mickiewicz, T., & Valler, P. (2019). Corporate governance and MNE strategies in emerging economies. Journal of World Business, 54 (4), 234–243. Boivie, S., Bednar, M., Aguilera, R., & Andrus, J. (2016). Are Boards Designed to Fail? The Implausibility of Effective Board Monitoring. The Academy of Management Annals, 10(1), 319–407. Boivie, S., Graffin, S. D., & Pollock, T. G. (2012). Time for Me To Fly: Predicting Director Exit At Large Firms. Academy of Management Journal, 55(6), 1334–1359. Boyd, B. (1995). CEO Duality and Firm Performance: A Contingency Model. Strategic Management Journal, 16(4), 301–312. Boyd, B., Gove, S., & Hitt, M. (2005). Construct measurement in strategic management research: Illusion or reality? Strategic Management Journal, 26(3), 239–257. Brambor, T., Clark, W., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82. Campa, J., & Kedia, S. (2002). Explaining the Diversification Discount. The Journal of Finance, 57(4), 1731–1762. Campbell, A., Goold, M., & Alexander, M. (1995). Corporate Strategy : The Quest for Parenting Advantage. Harvard Business Review, 120–132. Carpenter, M., & Westphal, J. (2001). The strategic context of external network ties: Examining the impact of director appointments on board involvement in strategic decision making. Academy of Management Journal, 44(4), 639–660. Chen, J., & Nadkarni, S. (2016). It’s about Time! CEOs’ Temporal Dispositions. Temporal Leadership, and Corporate Entrepreneurship., 1. Chhaochharia, V., & Grinstein, Y. (2007). Corporate governance and firm value: The impact of the 2002 governance rules. The Journal of Finance, 62(4), 1789–1825. Clark, C., Arora, P., & Gabaldon, P. (2021). Female Representation on Corporate Boards in Europe: The Interplay of Organizational Social Consciousness and Institutions. 606 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Kumar, M. V. S. (2013). The Costs of Related Diversification: The Impact of the Core Business on the Productivity of Related Segments. Organization Science, 24(6), 1827–1846. Kuppuswamy, V., & Villalonga, B. (2016). Does Diversification Create Value in the Presence of External Financing Constraints ? Evidence from the 2007–2009 Financial Crisis. Management Science, 62(4), 905–923. Leblanc, R., & Gillies, J. (2005). Inside the boardroom: How boards really work and the coming revolution in corporate governance. John Wiley & Sons. Lee, J.-H., & Gaur, A. S. (2013). Managing multi-business firms: A Comparison between Korean Chaebols and Diversified US firms. Journal of World Business, 48(4), 443–454. Lee, S., & Weng, D. (2013). Does bribery in the home country promote or dampen firm exports? Strategic Management Journal, 34(12), 1472–1487. Li, S., & Greenwood, R. (2004). The effect of within-industry diversification on firm performance: Synergy creation, multi-market contact and market structuration. Strategic Management Journal, 25(12), 1131–1153. Mackey, T., Barney, J., & Dotson, J. (2017). Corporate diversification and the value of individual firms: A Bayesian approach. Strategic Management Journal, 38(2), 322–341. Maddala, G. (2002). Introduction to Econometrics. Prentice Hall. Markides, C., & Williamson, P. (1994). Related Diversification, Core Competences and Corporate Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 149–165. Markides, C., & Williamson, P. (1996). Corporate Diversification and Organizational Structure : A Resource-Based View. Academy of Management Journal, 39(2), 340–367. Masulis, R., & Mobbs, S. (2014). Independent director incentives: Where do talented directors spend their limited time and energy?? Journal of Financial Economics, 111 (2), 406–429. McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (2001). Corporate Social Responsibility : A Theory of the Firm Perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 26(1), 117–127. Meyer, M., Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Organizational prospects, influence costs, and ownership changes. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 1(1), 9–35. Miller, D. (2006). Technological diversity, related diversification, and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 27(7), 601–619. Moulton, W., & Thomas, H. (1993). Bankruptcy As a Deliberate Strategy: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Evidence. Strategic Management Journal, 14(2), 125–135. Mukherjee, D., Kumar, S., Donthu, N., & Pandey, N. (2021). Research published in management international review from 2006 to 2020: A bibliometric analysis and future directions. Management International Review, 1–44. Mukherjee, D., Makarius, E., & Stevens, C. (2018). Business group reputation and affiliates’ internationalization strategies. Journal of World Business, 53(2), 93–103. Nicholson, G. J., & Kiel, G. C. (2007). Can Directors Impact Performance? A Case Based Test of Three Theories of Corporate Governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15(4), 585–608. Nielsen, B., & Nielsen, S. (2013). Top management team nationality diversity and firm performance: A multilevel study. Strategic Management Journal, 34(3), 373–382. Nonaka, I. (1994). A dynamic theory of organizational knowledge creation. Organization Science, 5(1), 14–37. Palich, L., Cardinal, L., & Miller, C. C. (2000). Curvilinearity in the Diversification – Performance Linkage : An Examination of Over Three Decades of Research. Strategic Management Journal, 21(2), 155–174. Pattnaik, C., Lu, Q., & Gaur, A. S. (2018). Group affiliation and entry barriers: The dark side of business groups in emerging markets. Journal of Business Ethics, 153, 1051–1066. Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. (1978). The external control of organizations: A resource dependence approach. Harper and Row Publishers. Ponomareva, Y., Uman, U., Bodolica, V., & Wennberg, K. (2022). Cultural diversity in top management teams: Review and agenda for future research. Journal of World Business, 57(4). Article # 101328. Rawley, E. (2010). Diversification, coordination costs, and organizational rigidity: Evidence from microdata. Strategic Management Journal, 31(8), 873–891. https://doi. org/10.1002/smj.838 Rumelt, R. (1974). Strategy, Structure, and Economic Performance. Harvard Business School Press. Shaver, J. M. (2006). a Paradox of Synergy : Contagion and Capacity Effects in Mergers and Acquisitions. Academy of Management. The Academy of Management Review, 31 (4), 962–976. Shaver, J. M. (2019). Interpreting Interactions in Linear Fixed-Effect Regression Models: When Fixed-Effect Estimates Are No Longer Within-Effects. Strategy Science, 4(1), 25–40. Singh, D., & Delios, A. (2017). Corporate governance, board networks and growth strategies. Journal of World Business, 52(5), 615–627. Singh, D., & Gaur, A. S. (2009). Business group affiliation, firm governance and firm performance: Evidence from China and India. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(4), 411–425. Singh, D., Gaur, A. S., & Schmid, F. (2010). Corporate diversification, TMT experience and performance: Evidence from German SMEs. Management International Review, 50 (1), 35–56. Sirower, M. (1997). The synergy trap: How companies lose the acquisition game. Simon and Schuster. Stock, J., & Watson, M. (2007). Introduction to econometrics. Pearson Addison Welseley. Talke, K., Salomo, S., & Rost, K. (2010). How top management team diversity affects innovativeness and performance via the strategic choice to focus on innovation fields. Research Policy, 39(7), 907–918. Villalonga, B. (2004). Diversification Discount or Premium? New Evidence from BITS Establishment-Level Data. Journal of Finance, 59(2), 475–502. Journal of Business Ethics. https://doi.org/https://link.springer.com/content/pdf/ 10.1007/s10551-021-04898-x.pdf. Cohen, J., Cohen, P., West, S., & Aiken, L. (2003). Outliers and Multicollinearity Diagnosing and Solving Regression Problems II. Applied Multiple Regression/ Correlation Analysis for the Behavioral Sciences, 390–430. Conyon, M., Peck, S., & Sadler, G. (2001). Corporate tournaments and executive compensation: Evidence from the UK. Strategic Management Journal, 22(8), 805–815. Dahiya, S., John, K., Puri, M., & Raḿrez, G. (2003). Debtor-in-possession financing and bankruptcy resolution: Empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(1), 259–280. Dalton, D., & Aguinis, H. (2013). Measurement malaise in strategic management studies: The case of corporate governance research. Organizational Research Methods, 16(1), 88–99. Dalton, D., Daily, C., Ellstrand, A., & Johnson, J. (1998). Meta-Analytic Review of Board Composition, Leadership Structure, and Financial Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 19(3), 269–290. Dawson, J., & Richter, A. (2006). Probing three-way interactions in moderated multiple regression: Development and application of a slope difference test. Journal of Applied Psychology, 91(4), 917–926. Denis, D. J., Denis, D. K., & Sarin, A. (1997). Agency problems, equity ownership, and corporate diversification. The Journal of Finance, 52(1), 135–160. Fahlenbrach, R. diger, Low, A., & Stulz, R. M. (2010). Why do firms appoint CEOs as outside directors? Journal of Financial Economics, 97(1), 12–32. Fama, E., & Jensen, M. (1983). Agency Problems and Residual Claims. The Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 327. Farjoun, M. (1994). Beyond Industry Boundaries: Human Expertise, Diversification and Resource-Related Industry Groups. Organization Science, 5(2), 185–199. Feldman, E. (2014). Legacy divestitures: Motives and implications. Organization Science, 25(3), 815–832. Feldman, E. (2016). Dual directors and the governance of corporate spinoffs. Academy of Management Journal, 59(5), 1754–1776. Feldman, E., & Montgomery, C. (2015). Are incentives without expertise sufficient? Evidence from Fortune 500 firms. Strategic Management Journal, 36(1), 113–122. Finkelstein, S., & Boyd, B. (1998). How much does the CEO matter? The role of managerial discretion in the setting of CEO compensation. Academy of Management Journal, 41(2), 179–199. Forbes, D., & Milliken, F. (1999). Cognition and Corporate Governance: Understanding Boards of Directors as Strategic Decision-making groups. Academy of Management Review, 24(3), 489–505. Freixanet, J., Renart, G. (2020). A capabilities perspective on the joint effects of internationalization time, speed, geographic scope and managers’ competencies on SME survival. Journal of World Business, 55(6). https://doi.org/10.1016/j. jwb.2020.101110. George, G. (2005). Slack resources and the performance of privately held firms. Academy of Management Journal, 48(4), 661–676. Goold, M., Campbell, A., Alexander, M., Goold, M., & Alexander, M. (1998). Corporate strategy and parenting theory. Long Range Planning, 31(2), 308–314. Graham, J. R., Lemmon, M. L., & Wolf, J. G. (2002). Does Corporate Diversification Destroy Value? The Journal of Finance, 57(2), 695–720. Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis ((5th ed.).). Prentice Hall. Hambrick, D. (2007). Upper Echelons Theory : An Update. Academy of Management Review, 32(2), 334–343. Hambrick, D., & Mason, P. (1984). Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection of its top managers. Academy of Management Review, 9(2), 193–206. Hambrick, D., Misangyi, V., & Park, C. (2015). The Quad Model for Identifying a Corporate Director’S Potential for Effective Monitoring: Toward a New Theory of Board Sufficiency. The Academy of Management Review, 40(3), 323–344. Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 38(2), 1251–1271. Hausman, J., & Taylor, W. (1981). Panel data and unobservable individual effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1377–1398. Hill, C., & Phan, P. (1991). CEO tenure as a determinant of CEO pay. Academy of Management Journal, 34(3), 707–717. Hillman, A., & Dalziel, T. (2003). Boards of directors and firm performance: Integrating agency and resource dependence perspectives. Academy of Management Review, 28 (3), 383–396. Hillman, A., Withers, M., & Collins, B. (2009). Resource Dependence Theory: A Review. Journal of Management, 35(6), 1404–1427. Jacquemin, A., & Berry, C. (1979). Entropy measure of diversification and corporate growth. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 359–369. Johnson, R., Hoskisson, R., & Hitt, M. (1993). Board of Director Involvement in Restructuring: The Effects of Board Versus Managerial Controls and Characteristics. Strategic Management Journal, 14(S1), 33–50. Klarner, P., Yoshikawa, T., & Hitt, M. (2018). A Capability-based View of Boards: A New Conceptual Framework for Board Governance. Academy of Management Perspectives, 1–48. Kor, Y., & Leblebici, H. (2005). Human-Capital Deployment, Development, and Diversification Strategies Affect Firms ’ Financial Performance ? Strategic Management Journal, 26(10), 967–985. Kor, Y., & Sundaramurthy, C. (2009). Experience-based human capital and social capital of outside directors. Journal of Management, 35(4), 981–1006. Krause, R., Semadeni, M., & Cannella, A., Jr (2013). External COO/presidents as expert directors: A new look at the service role of boards. Strategic Management Journal, 34 (13), 1628–1641. 607 P. Arora and A. Gaur Journal of Business Research 151 (2022) 593–608 Westphal, J., & Zhu, D. (2019). Under the radar: How firms manage competitive uncertainty by appointing friends of other chief executive officers to their boards. Strategic Management Journal, 40(1), 79–107. Xu, K., Hitt, M.A., Dai, L. (2020). International diversification of family-dominant firms: Integrating socioemotional wealth and behavioral theory of the firm. Journal of World Business, 55(3). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2019.101071. Yermack, D. (1996). Higher market valuation forfirms with a small board of directors. Journal of Financial Economics, 40(1494), 185–211. Zhou, Y. M. (2011). Synergy, coordination costs, and diversification choices. Strategic Management Journal, 32(6), 624–639. Punit Arora is an Associate Professor at City University of New York. He has a PhD from Syracuse University. His research examines corporate governance and social responsibility in various institutional settings. He is associate editor at Business & Society and Journal of Asia Business Studies. Ajai Gaur is a Professor at Rutgers University. He has a PhD from National University of Singapore. In his research, Ajai studies the distinct institutional influences on firms’ in­ ternational expansion strategies in different institutional contexts. Ajai is a Fellow of the Academy of International Business and currently serves as the Editor-in-Chief of Journal of World Business. He was the president of the Asia Academy of Management from 2015 to 2019. 608