INTRODUCTION OF THE MODULE Course Code: CWORLD1 Course Title: The Contemporary World Credit: Three (3) Units Course Description: This course introduces students to the contemporary world by examining the multifaceted phenomenon of globalization. Using the various disciplines of the social sciences, it examines the economic, social, political, technological, and other transformations that have created an increasing awareness of the interconnectedness of peoples and places around the globe. To this end, the course provides an overview of the various debates in global governance, development, and sustainability. Beyond exposing the student to the world outside the Philippines, it seeks to inculcate a sense of global citizenship and global ethical responsibility. Requirements of the Course: 1. Three (3) Major Examinations 2. Regular Attendance 3. Scheduled Quizzes, Seat-works, Home-works/ Assignments, Classroom-Based Recitations 4. Critique Papers, Synthesis Papers, Essay Writing 5. Group Power-Point Presentations, Video Presentations 6. Research Paper Writing Learning Competencies: As the course progresses, the students are expected to: 1. write a personal definition of globalization based on a concept map 2. differentiate the competing conceptions of globalization 3. identify the underlying philosophies of the varying definitions of globalization 4. agree on a working definition of globalization for the course 5. define economic globalization 6. identify the actors that facilitate economic globalization 7. define the modern world system 8. articulate a stance on global economic integration 9. explain the role of international financial institutions in the creation of a global economy 10. narrate a short history of global market integration in the twentieth century 11. identify the attributes of global corporations 12. explain the effects of globalization on governments 13. identify the institutions that govern international relations 14. differentiate internationalism from globalism 15. identify the roles and functions of the United Nations 16. identify the challenges of global governance in the 21st century 17. explain the relevance of the state and globalization 18. define the term “global south” 19. differentiate the “global south” from the “third world” 20. analyze how a new conception of global relations emerged from the experiences of Latin American countries 21. differentiate between regionalization and globalization 22. identify the factors leading to a greater integration of the Asian region 23. analyze how different Asian states confront the challenges of globalization and regionalization 24. synthesize knowledge concerning globalization 25. analyze how various media drive various forms of global integration 26. explain the dynamics between local and global cultural production 27. explain how globalization affects religious practices and beliefs 28. analyze the relationship between religion and global conflict and, conversely, global peace 29. identify the attributes of a global city 30. analyze how cities serve as engines of globalization 31. explain the theory of demographic transition as it affects global population 32. analyze the political, economic, cultural, and social factors underlying the global movements of people 33. display first-hand knowledge of the experiences of OFWs 34. write a research paper proposal with proper citation 35. critique research proposals of classmates 36. differentiate stability from sustainability 37. articulate models of global sustainable development 38. define global food security 39. critique existing models of global food security 40. articulate a personal definition of global citizenship 41. appreciate the ethical obligations of global citizenship 42. write a research paper on a topic related to globalization with proper citations LESSON 1 INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF GLOBALIZATION Learning Objectives: 1. To differentiate the competing approaches to the study of globalization 2. To understand the varying processes of globalization 3. To explain the different ideological dimensions of globalization 4. To appreciate the core claims of market globalism 5. To agree on a working definition of globalization for the course SOURCE: https://www.pinterest.ph/christine06295/advantages-of-globalisation/ LESSON 1 INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF GLOBALIZATION The first part of this lesson discusses the summary of the “Approaches to the Study of Globalization” as presented by Manfred B. Steger (2014) which was adopted from the “SAGE Handbook of Globalization” edited by Manfred B. Steger, Paul Battersby, and Joseph M. Siracusa (2014). The succeeding discussion presents the work of Manfred B. Steger (2014) entitled “Market Globalism” which was also adopted from the “SAGE Handbook of Globalization”. A. Approaches to the Study of Globalization There are many different approaches to the study of globalization. The purpose of this chapter is to provide a general overview of the various approaches to the concept as espoused by several scholars since the 1990s. Various scholars have advanced the concept of globalization by analyzing the changing economic, political, and cultural processes that happened since the 1970s. Some of the accepted definitions of globalization include the following: “increasing global interconnectedness”; “the expansion and intensification of social relations across world-time and world-space”; “the compression of time and space”; “distant proximities”; “a complex range of processes, driven by a mixture of political and economic influences”; and “the swift and relatively unimpeded flow of capital, people, and ideas across national borders” (Giddens, 1990; Harvey, 1989; Held & McGrew, 2007; Lechner & Boli, 2011; Robertson, 1992; Steger, 2013; Waters, 2001). Globalization as “Globaloney”. Three groups of scholars argue that the existing accounts of globalization are incorrect and imprecise. Their arguments fall into three differing categories. The first group disagrees with the usefulness of globalization as a precise analytical concept. The second group contends that the world is not really integrated as many proponents believe. The last cluster disputes the novelty of the process while acknowledging the presence of moderate globalizing tendencies. Rejectionists. These scholars believe that the term “globalization” is an example of a vague word employed in academic discourses. Just like the term “nationalism”, “globalization” is a complex and ambiguous phenomenon, thus both are hard concepts to define (Calhoun, 1993). Sceptics. This group stresses the limited nature of current globalizing processes. According to Hirst and Thompson (2009), our international economy is not really a global phenomenon, since it only centered on Europe, Eastern Asia, and North America. They also emphasized that most of the economic activities are still national in terms of origin and scope. Modifiers. They entail that “globalization” has often been applied in a historically inaccurate manner. Gilpin (2000) argues that our international economy in the late 1990s was even less incorporated before the outbreak of World War I. According to the neo-Marxist proponents of World-System Theory (Wallerstein, 1979; Frank, 1998), the modern capitalist economy today has been global five centuries ago. Thus globalization can be drawn back to the political and cultural relations that developed the ancient empires of Persia (Iran), China, and Rome. Globalization as an Economic Process The evolution of global markets and international corporations led to global economic interdependence among nation-states. The development of international economic institutions such as the European Union, the North American Free Trade Association, and other regional trading blocs are some of the examples (Keohane & Nye, 2000). This only shows that economic globalization increases the linkage of national economies through trade, financial flows, and foreign direct investment (FDI) by multinational or trans-national corporations (MNCs/TNCs) (Gilpin, 2000). Globalization as a Political Process Political globalization includes the discussion and analysis of political processes and institutions. Thus two questions are asked: (1) what are the political grounds for the immense flows of capital, money, and technology across territorial boundaries?; (2) do these flows create a serious test to the power of the nation-state? These dilemmas imply that economic globalization might lead to the reduced control of national governments over restrictive policies and economic regulations. Globalization as a Cultural Process According to Tomlinson (1999), cultural globalization signifies a growing linkage of intricate cultural interconnections and interdependencies that define our modern social life. These can be made possible through the emergence of powerful global media corporations that develop new communication technologies which promote the Anglo-American value system. This global dissemination of American values (Americanization), consumer goods, and lifestyles promote the objectives of American “cultural imperialism” which is also termed by Ritzer (1993) as “McDonaldization” which describes the ideals of the fast-food business that dominate the American society and the rest of the globe. According to Barber (1996), a type of cultural imperialism that was assembled in the 1950s and 1960s promoted an American culture of popular consumerism which he termed as “McWorld”. This was driven by expansionist commercial interests which was evident in its choice of music, video, theater, books, and theme parks which create exports that center around common logos, advertising slogans, stars, songs, brand names, jingles, trademarks, and the like. As argued by Robertson (1995) global cultural flows also take place in local contexts which result to “glocalization”. This refers to an intricate collaboration of the global and local cultures characterized by cultural borrowing. These interactions lead to a complex mixture of both cultures often referred to as “hybridization” or “creolization” which signifies processes of cultural mixing that are replicated in music, film, fashion, language, and other types of social expression. B. Market Globalism The Ideological Dimension of Globalization During the early 1990s, the emphasis of globalization was dominated by the economic and technological features of globalization. Later, the role of incorporating markets and new information know-hows became part of understanding the process of globalization. This section incorporates the ideological aspect of globalization and the roles and purposes of political ideologies. It also integrates ideas on the six central claims of market globalism. Political Ideologies and the Global Imaginary According to Steger (2014), “ideology” is a structure of broadly shared ideas or philosophies, patterned beliefs, guiding norms, values, and ideals recognized as fact by some collections of people. Every ideology is organized around core claims which differentiates it from other contrasting ideologies. The concept “ideology” was first introduced by Antoine Destutt de Tracy in the 18th century. For this Enlightenment thinker, the term means a positivistic “science of ideas” using the empirical tools borrowed from the natural sciences. According to Paul Ricoeur (1986), the first functional level of ideology (Ideology as Distortion) refers to the construction of contorted descriptions of social truth. This process obscures the difference between things as they are perceived in theory and things as they are viewed in reality. Political Ideologies and the “Social Imaginary” According to Charles Taylor (2004), “social imaginaries” are neither theories nor ideologies, but are implied “background understandings” of a group’s shared customs. The social imaginary explains how a group of people fit as one and their expectations of every member within the community. Each ideology organized its core concepts based on liberty, progress, race, class, rationality, tradition, community, welfare, security, and others. The ideologies of liberalism, conservatism, socialism, communism, and Nazism/fascism are all “nationalist” in character and are promoted by the elites within the group which are evident in their political goals through the concept of “national imaginary”. The Core Claims of Market Globalism With the downfall of Soviet-style command economy in Eastern Europe, power elites from the global north (i.e., corporate managers, CEOs of multinational corporations, corporate lobbyists, high-ranking military officials, remarkable journalists, public-relations experts, scholars writing to a large public audience, state administrators and leading politicians) introduced their idea of market globalism. For them, market globalism means an advocacy that advances the deregulation of markets, trade liberalization, the privatization of government-owned and controlled corporations, and the upkeep of the global “War on Terror” spearheaded by US (Steger, 2014). Claim 1: Globalization is about the Liberalization and Global Integration of Markets This claim is buttressed in the neo-liberal philosophy of the laissez faire self-regulating market economy as the foundation for a global market economy. According to Steger (2014), the focal roles of the free market in order to foster more societal integration and material advancement are only possible in a democratic society that values and protects individual rights and freedoms. Claim 2: Globalization is Inevitable and Irreversible This claim contends that globalization promotes the expansion of unalterable market forces motivated by technological improvements that facilitate the unavoidable worldwide integration of state economies. Nation-states, political parties, and civil society organizations have no option but to adapt to the inevitable forces of globalization. Claim 3: Nobody is in Charge of Globalization This argues that globalization is manifested through a “self-regulating market”. According to Hormats (1998), what is attractive with globalization is that nobody is in control of the process. Thus it is not regulated by any individual, any nation-state, or any organization. In addition, Friedman (1999) contends that the international market is an Electronic Herd of anonymous stock, bond and money traders and transnational foreign investors, integrated by global screens and networks. Claim 4: Globalization Benefits Everyone (... in the Long Run) The benefits for all relate to material aspects such as “economic growth” and “prosperity”. These benefits were according to the participating heads of state of the 1996 G-7 Summit in Lyons, France, consisting of the world's seven most influential highly-developed countries that issued a joint Economic Communique (1996) that exemplified the implications of this claim. Claim 5: Globalization Furthers the Spread of Democracy in the World This claim links the concepts on globalization and market with that of democracy which provides individuals with economic choices. According to Freeden (1996), globalists treat freedom, free markets, free trade and democracy as identical concepts. Claim 6: Globalization Requires a War on Terror The neo-conservatives who are committed to the American values of freedom, security, and free markets added this sixth claim of market globalism. According to Kaplan (2003), you need to possess both military and economic supremacy in order to spread your ideas worldwide. This claim integrates idea of market globalism with militaristic and nationalistic ideas linked with the American-headed global “War on Terror”. As asserted by Barnett (2004), the globe is divided into three diverse regions: The Functioning Core or Core. This is categorized by global network connectivity, financial transactions, liberal media, cooperative security, nations having stable democratic governments, practice of transparency, increasing standards of living, and more deaths by suicide than by killings. The Non-Integrating Gap or Gap. This refers to regions where globalization is thinning or if not, absent. These regions are plagued by authoritarian political regimes, government regulated markets, mass killings, prevalent poverty and diseases, and the breeding ground of global terrorists. Seam States. These states lie along the Gap's bloody borders. LESSON 2 THE GLOBAL ECONOMY This chapter discusses the summary of “The Globalization of Economic Relations” as presented by Istvan Benczes (2014) which was adopted from the “SAGE Handbook of Globalization” edited by Manfred B. Steger, Paul Battersby, and Joseph M. Siracusa (2014). Introduction This chapter discusses the definition, foundation, and effects of economic globalization. While the second section tackles on the development of the key global monetary regimes that include the gold standard, the Bretton Woods System, and European Monetary Integration. The last segment talks about trade rules and relations, which will focus on the unilateral trade system of the late 19th and early 20th centuries and the multilateral trade agreements of the post-World War II period (Benczes, 2014). According to Held et al. (1999), globalization may be claimed as the broadening, deepening, and rapid global interconnectedness in all facets (political, technological, cultural, and economic) of modern-day social life (Giddens, 1999). Thus globalization is a multidisciplinary course. What is Economic Globalization? According to the International Monetary Fund (2008), this refers to a historical progression, which is the consequence of humanity’s modernization and technological development. It may also denote a growing interconnection of global economies via the mobility of goods, services, knowledge, and all forms of capital around the world. The following are the various interrelated scopes of economic globalization: (a) the globalization of goods and services in trade; (b) the globalization of monetary and capital markets; (c) the globalization of know-how and communication; and (d) the globalization of production. Economic globalization differs from internalization since the former refers to functional interconnectedness between globally isolated activities while internationalization speaks of the extension of economic activities of one country to another (Dicken, 2004). For hyperglobalists, nation-states are no longer the key economic institutions in the global market. Humanity is now consuming extremely standardized international products and services created by multinational corporations (Ohmae, 1995). According to Reich (1991), globalization converts the local economy into an international one, thus products, technologies, corporations, and industries are no longer treated as national. The new actors of political and cultural globalization today refer to the United Nations (UN) and non-governmental organizations (NGOs) or civil society organizations (CSOs). While the key actors of this modernday global market economy are the multinational corporations (MNCs) or transnational corporations (TNCs). This MNCs or TNCs are the key motivating powers of economic globalization for the last 100 years, and they account for about 67% of world exports (Gereffi, 2005). For realists, they argue that these MNCs/TNCs still represent national interests (Gilpin, 2001). However, for the pioneers of the Dependency School, they assert that these are the vehicles through which the rich can exploit the underprivileged majority (Feenstra, 1998). On the other hand, Gereffi (1999) introduced the idea on the “global commodity chains” which emphasizes on the growing significance of international buyers in a global market of dispersed production. Is Economic Globalization a New Phenomenon? Gills and Thompson (2006) assert that the process of globalization began since Homo sapiens started moving from the African continent to the rest of the globe. Frank and Gills (1993) argued that the foundation of globalization dates back about 5,000 years ago as manifested by the Silk Road which linked Asia, Africa and Europe. When Adam Smith wrote his book “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations in 1776, he regarded the rediscovery of the Americas by Christopher Columbus in 1492 and the rediscovery of the direct maritime route to India by Vasco de Gama in 1498 as the two ultimate accomplishments in humanity’s historical accounts. Other significant accomplishments were the technological developments of the British Industrial Revolution after the Napoleonic Wars which spread to European and North American continents. Monopolized trade during this period were controlled by the first transnational corporations, the British East India Company (1600) and the Dutch East India Company (1602). However, these TNCs did not favor global economic integration due to their idea of nationalism (Gereffi, 2005). The real global economic break-through came in the 19th century due to the transport innovations via the use of steamships and railroads which decreased transaction expenses and boosted both local and global economic exchanges (Held et al., 1999). The relatively short period from 1870 to 1913 before World War I (1914 to 1919) is often regarded to as the “Golden Age of Globalization”. This period is characterized by the presence of peace, free trade, and financial and economic permanence (O'Rourke & Williamson, 1999). The Neoclassical Solow Growth Model Bairoch (1993) argues that the industrial revolution and global trade relations strengthened economic growth and development among developed parts of the globe, the rest of the world did not achieve such accomplishments. Thus, the industrialization of the developed regions led to the de-industrialization of the poorer regions. Structuralism Structuralism is a set of models which emerged from the 1950s to the 1970s and affirm the notion that the North and South regions are in a structural association (Brown, 2001). The most recognized critical theory to the prevalent social partition of labor and global inequities is presented by the “World-Systems Analysis”, which argues that capitalism under globalization strengthens the structural arrangements of unequal change. According to Wallerstein (1983), capitalism produced the differing historical level of wages in the global economic stage of the global system. Thus, rising disparity, coupled with economic and political dependency, are not independent from economic globalization. For Rostow (1960), underdevelopment (i.e. the absence of economic growth and development, coupled with poverty and malnourishment) is not the primary phase of a historical and evolutionary uni-linear progress, rather the effect of colonialism and imperialism. Wallerstein (1983) acknowledged imperialism as the product of the global capitalist structure which propagated imbalanced exchange. The present capitalist structure produced political systems that ensure an infinite appropriation and amassing of surplus products from less developed countries (the periphery) to the industrializing countries (the semi-periphery) and the highly industrialized or highly developed countries (the core or metropole) (Arrighi, 2005). The International Monetary Systems An international monetary system or regime (IMS) denotes the policies, practices, tools, services, and institutions for carrying out global payments (Salvatore, 2007). In the liberal custom, the key responsibility of an IMS is to assist international transactions on trade and investment. An IMS is more than just money or currencies it also mirrors economic supremacy since money is essentially political and is also considered as a vital aspect of “high politics” of diplomacy (Cohen, 2000). The Gold Standard The foundations of the first IMS dates back to 19th century, when Britain assumed gold mono-metallism in 1821. In 1867, the European countries, including United States, shifted to gold at the International Monetary Conference in Paris. Gold was viewed to ensure a noninflationary, constant economic atmosphere, and a vehicle for hastening global trade (Einaudi, 2001). When Prussia won over France in 1872, Germany joined the global system. France decided to join six years later. The gold standard developed to be the global monetary regime by 1880 when United States joined in 1879. In 1894, Italy decided to participate and Russia followed in 1897. About 70% of the countries took part in the gold standard prior to the eruption of World War I (Meissner, 2005). The gold standard operated as a fixed exchange rate system, which made gold as the lone global reserve. Member countries ascertained the gold content of their national currencies which defined fixed exchange rates (or mint parities). Monetary authorities were mandated to exchange their national currencies for gold at the authorized exchange rate without restrictions on global markets (Bordo & Rockoff, 1996). Due to the outburst of World War I, the gold standard came to an end. Member countries gave up convertibility and stopped gold export in order to halt the exhaustion of their national gold reserves. The 1930s turn out to be the gloomiest era of modern economic history (Eichengreen & Irwin, 2009). The Bretton Woods System and its Dissolution According to Destler and Henning (1989), the allied nations started to negotiate on a new global monetary regime under the structure of the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire (US), in July 1944. Forty-four countries decided to adopt the gold-exchange standard. At that time, the US dollar was the lone exchangeable currency of the time. Thus, United States devoted itself to trade and buy gold without limitations at US$35 per ounce. All participating countries having non-convertible currencies were pegged to the US dollar. The participating countries also established two global monetary institutions: (a) The International Banks for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) which was responsible for post-war reconstruction and development; and (b) The International Monetary Fund (IMF) which encouraged global financial collaboration and international trade. The IMF also provided shortterm monetary assistance to countries in cases of transitory balance of payments difficulties. During the middle part of the 1960s, the US dollar became overvalued along with other major currencies. As a reaction, foreign nations started to exhaust the US gold reserves. This forced the United States to abandon the gold-exchange standard on August 15, 1971. In 1973, developed countries agreed to float their currencies (prices of currencies were determined by demand and supply forces). This arrangement in the exchange rate policy was mandated by the Jamaica Accords in 1976 (Destler & Henning, 1989). The Plaza Accord In 1985, the G7 countries decided to devaluate the US dollar as a consequence of the heightening pressure of local US manufacturers and farmers to reinstate their global competitiveness in the world market. The Louvre Accord In 1987, the Louvre Accord was agreed upon in order to protect the US dollar from further devaluation in the world market. The United States might have profited from these internationally, however, one of the main losers was Japan. The appreciation of the Japanese yen proved to be devastating for the Japanese local economy (Destler & Henning, 1989). The Washington Consensus The neoliberal, pro-market Washington Consensus became successful in the 1990s. Its agenda were promoted and disseminated by the IMF as part of its conditionalities in exchange for financial assistance. The IMF and the Washington Consensus (and its free-market ideology) have been blamed for the unsuccessful progress of the periphery. For Wallerstein (2005), the way for the periphery to develop is not to “import-substitute” but to export orient productive activities. The Morgenthau Plan After World War II, the United States sought to carry out the Morgenthau Plan. The idea was to downscale Germany’s economy to become a pastoral and agricultural one. This was a reaction to USSR's (specifically, Russia) thrust for communism in the East European region coupled with the growth of socialist and communist parties in the West. However, the plan did not materialize and was abandoned by US. In contrary, United States shifted its plans and promoted an economically and militarily powerful Germany and Western Europe. The Marshall Plan and the European Monetary Integration This was United States’ post-war reconstruction and development program in 1948 for Western Europe, which was managed by the Organization for European Economic Cooperation, the forerunner of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). The astonishing growth and development of Western Europe encouraged a closer collaboration of Western European countries which consequently gave birth to the European Coal and Steel Community in 1951. The ECSC was followed by the signing of the Rome Treaty in 1957, which founded the European Economic Community (EEC) which consequently became the European Union (EU). The six founding member-countries (West Germany, France, Italy, Netherlands, Belgium and Luxembourg) aimed at the formation of a common market for the freer movement of goods, services, capital and labor. The downfall of the Bretton Woods System pressured the membercountries in 1979 to establish their own regional monetary regime (the European Monetary System, EMS). Here, neither the US dollar, nor gold can function in the stabilization process of exchange rates. Instead, the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (EERM) was created (Gros & Thygesen, 1998). In 1992, with the help of the late French President Francois Mitterrand and German Chancellor Helmut Kohl, the foundations of a new European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) were established under the Maastricht Treaty. As early as 1999, member-countries of the EMU replaced their national currencies and deputized monetary policies to a supranational stage, managed by the European Central Bank (ECB). Consequently, trade and capital transactions increased; local economies became more interconnected; macroeconomic stability was reestablished, and the euro grew to become the second most globally used currency (European Commission, 2008). David Ricardo’s Comparative Advantage Theory According to Ricardo (1817) as cited in Samuelson (1995), a country such as Britain could profit from a voluntary trade with Portugal even if Portugal is more effective in producing both wine and clothing. For Britain, it should concentrate in the production of the product with less disadvantage and let Portugal produce the other product. The theory argues that every country must possess a comparative (relative) advantage in the production of something irrespective of its original situation. International Trade and Trade Policies Reformist and radical (new left and neo-Marxian) theorists, such as Emmanuel (1972) or Amin (1976), argued that the social partition of labor adds to the economic development of the highly developed countries (HDCs or core) and hampers progress of the less developed countries (LDCs or periphery). The economies of HDCs have the finest of two worlds (as buyers of cheap primary commodities and as sellers of costly manufactured products. On the other hand, LDCs have the worst of both worlds, as buyers of expensive industrial products and as producers of cheap raw materials (Singer, 1964). According to Amin (1993), if this global economy only benefits the HDCs at the loss of the LDCs, then the periphery countries must implement a protectionist policy in its extreme form of de-linking (i.e. to cut their ties with the HDCS or core countries). Unilateral Trade Order During the 17th to 18th century, global trade in Europe concentrated more on the accumulation of gold reserves which encouraged nation-states to export and limit imports. This mercantilist or protectionist policy was branded as a zero-sum game in global trade. Hence, trade and trade policies only furthered the interest of the monarchs (royal family) from Portugal to Great Britain (now UK), which utilized their accumulated bullions (gold) to support battles and consolidate power over their domestic supporters (Dunham, 1930). Bilateral Trade Agreements Bilateral Trade Agreements also succeeded in Europe, one example of these is the mostfavored nation (MFN) policy. This policy demonstrates the principle which stated that any negotiated mutual tariff cutbacks between two parties must benefit all other trading partners without conditions (Lampe, 2008). The United States adopted a protectionist policy (import substitution industrialization) which imposed tariffs on manufactured goods with an average of 45%. Even France, the Scandinavian countries, and UK from the 1860s onwards, imposed protectionist measures due to the entry of low-cost agricultural commodities from their foreign territories, Germany, and US. UK persisted to be hegemonic economically and militarily. It also depended on the massive reserves of its territories, especially India (Arrighi & Silver, 2003). After World War I (1914-1919), the two World Economic Conferences in 1927 and 1933 did not succeed in reducing tariffs due to the refusal of US to take the lead as the hegemonic descendant of a declining United Kingdom. In 1930, the Hawley Act in US amplified tariffs in the country. As a consequence, trading partners of US retaliated which lessened international trade by an average of 33 to 66 percent. To address the issue, US enacted the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act in 1934 which halted the further decline in global trade. This Law gave the US president the power to decide on trade policies and lessened the burden put on the Congress for determining protectionist trade policies. This trade policy was a return to the original notion of MFN policy prior to the eruption of World War II (Irwin, 1998). Multilateralism: From the GATT to the WTO In 1950, the US dollar became an international currency, supported by 67% of the world's gold reserve (Green, 1999). US was also the leading aid donor (i.e., the Marshall Plan). Owing to the downfall of the European and Japanese manufacturing industries after World War II, USA’s manufacturing industry amplified which accounted for about 60% of the world's total in 1950, and its export amounted to about 33% of the world's total (Branson et al., 1980). At that time, the latest international trade regime must have been driven by the International Trade Organization (ITO) agreement, which was one of the three pillars of the Bretton Woods System, aside from the IMF and the IBRD, however, a series of rejections in the US Congress obstructed its creation. In place of the ITO, nation-states dedicated to lower down tariffs agreed to create the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) (Branson et al., 1980). The GATT encouraged international trade through a sequence of multilateral trade negotiations called “rounds”. The first five rounds concentrated on tariff cuts: (1) 1947 Geneva Tariffs; (2) 1949 Annecy Tariffs; (3) 1951 Torquay Tariffs; (4) 1956 Geneva Tariffs; (5) 1960 Dillon Round Tariffs; (6) 1964 Kennedy Round Tariffs and anti-dumping measures; (7) 1973 Tokyo Round Tariffs, non-tariff barriers, and “framework agreements”; and (8) 1986 Uruguay Round Tariffs, non-tariff barriers, rules, services, intellectual, property, dispute settlement, textiles, agriculture, and creation of the WTO (WTO, 2012). The establishment of the European Economic Community (EEC) in 1957 forced US to implement the Trade Expansion Act of 1962 and demanded for a new round, the Kennedy Round. Its consequence was an across-the-board cutting (which replaced the practice of itemby-item cuts) and reduction of non-tariff barriers (i.e., anti-dumping measures) (Evans, 1971). During the 1970s, the Tokyo Round besides tariff cuts, also approved a series of codes of conduct (i.e., the “subsidies code” or the “government procurement code” (Deardorff & Stern, 1983). The most popular multilateral trade negotiations occurred under the Uruguay Round from 1986 to 1994. While previous trade arrangements were successful in reducing tariffs, a series of other corrective measures (i.e., non-tariff barriers) were also implemented by nation-states. The Uruguay Round stretched multilateral policies to current concerns and areas, such as agriculture which concluded in a harsh dispute between the US and the EU. According to Walter and Sen (2009), the foremost results of the trade arrangements were the agreements on trade-related investment measures (TRIMs); trade in services (GATS) and trade-related features of intellectual property rights (TRIPs). These agreements were promoted by highly developed countries (HDCs) and targeted less developed countries (LDCs) with massive service market potentials in finance and telecommunications. After 50 years of trade negotiations, the Uruguay Round came up with a genuine global trade institution, the World Trade Organization (WTO). The WTO was established on January 1, 1995 and become a formal forum for trade dialogs. Unlike the GATT, it is a formally constituted association with legal personality. However, in 1999, the developing nations epitomized a united movement for a new round of trade negotiations in Seattle. This event revealed the power of NGOs/CSOs and anti-globalization movements. These movements objected in favor of the LDCs and were against the current status quo of international trade affairs; the hegemony of the US economy; the personal interests of MNCs/TNCs; and the discriminatory mechanisms of the WTO in favor of HDCs (Narlikar & Tussie, 2004). In 2001, the quasi-official Doha Round must have become a round on economic development, however, it failed due to the interests of the opposing parties (HDCs vs. LDCs). LDCs asserted on the proper and full execution of the Uruguay Agreement (especially in the area of agriculture), however, US promoted to keep labor and environmental issues on the agenda. The deadlock between the two opposing sides, motivated LDCs to cooperate and strengthen their leverage within the WTO by creating a pressure group called the Group of 20 (G20). This conglomeration of countries accounts for almost 67% of the world's inhabitants and 25% of world-wide agricultural export (Narlikar & Tussie, 2004). Developing Countries and International Trade Developing (third world) countries did not partake aggressively in multilateral trade agreements for quite a long period of time. The so-called East Asian newly industrializing countries (NICs) embraced an outward-oriented development approach. However, a majority of these developing nations were not able to integrate successfully into this trading scheme. Rather, they promoted an inward-looking, import-substitution industrialization policy, which did not encourage trade liberalization (Findlay & O'Rourke, 2007). Meanwhile, the HDCs were also hesitant to open their markets to products (i.e., textile or agricultural) in which developing countries have a comparative advantage. The key transformation in this economic affairs occurred in 1964 when the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) was institutionalized with the collaborative stance of the developing countries. The objective of UNCTAD was to encourage trade and mutual aid between and among the HDCs and LDCs (Salvatore, 2007). However, due to the two oil crises dilemma which affected the economic activities of the HDCs, these countries adopted highly protectionist measures (both tariff and non-tariff) in order to address the damaging effects of the economic stagnation in the 1980s. Developing countries started to aggressively participate in trade with the advent of the Uruguay Round. This round was a grand bargain between the HDCs and LDCs (Ostry, 2002). The HDCs were projected to open their markets to agricultural and textile products, while the LDCs must accept the new rules on intellectual property rights and services. LDCS opened up their service markets, however, their export of agricultural commodities is still blocked by the HDCs. Agricultural products have a share of about 33% to 50% of the total economic production among HDCs. Without trade liberalization in agriculture, it is difficult for LDCs to entirely assimilate themselves into the international economy. For Khor (1995), he saw the WTO as a medium by the HDCs to gain entry to the markets of LDCs. While Wade (2003) criticized the three major trade agreements (i.e. TRIMS, GATS, and TRIPS) saying that they constrained the set of industrial policies to achieve development for the LDCS. CWORLD1_QUIZ Which among the following is not a part of the G-7 countries with advanced economy? - United States Which among the following is not a globalization phenomenon? Globalization is; an ambiguous phenomenon, old phenomenon, an irreversible phenomenon, not a global phenomenon - Globalization is an irreversible phenomenon Who among the following is not a pioneer of Globalization's ideological dimension? - Francis Fukuyama This is categorized by global network connectivity, financial transactions, liberal media, cooperative security, nations having stable democratic governments, practice of transparency, increasing standards of living, and more deaths by suicide than by killings. - Functioning Core This consists of shares, traders involved with currency, bonds, massive companies that are multinational and ready to get distributed worldwide. - Electronic Herd Seam States are regions plagued by authoritarian political regimes, government regulated markets, mass killings, prevalent poverty and diseases, and the breeding ground of global terrorists. - False According to Kaplan (2003), you need to possess both military and economic supremacy in order to spread your ideas worldwide. - True The evolution of global markets and international corporations led to global economic interdependence among nation-states. - True Fukuyama (2000) argues that our international economy in the late 1990s was even less incorporated before the outbreak of World War I. - False A complex mixture of both cultures is often referred to as “hybridization” which signifies processes of cultural mixing that are replicated in music, film, fashion, language, and other types of social expression. - True