The Theory and Practice of Directors’ Remuneration New Challenges and Opportunities This page intentionally left blank The Theory and Practice of Directors’ Remuneration New Challenges and Opportunities Edited by Alexander Kostyuk Ukrainian Academy of Banking of the National Bank of Ukraine, Sumy, Ukraine Markus Stiglbauer Friedrich-Alexander-Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg, Nuremberg, Germany Dmitriy Govorun Ukrainian Academy of Banking of the National Bank of Ukraine, Sumy, Ukraine United Kingdom North America Japan India Malaysia China Emerald Group Publishing Limited Howard House, Wagon Lane, Bingley BD16 1WA, UK First edition 2016 Copyright r 2016 Emerald Group Publishing Limited Reprints and permissions service Contact: permissions@emeraldinsight.com No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, transmitted in any form or by any means electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise without either the prior written permission of the publisher or a licence permitting restricted copying issued in the UK by The Copyright Licensing Agency and in the USA by The Copyright Clearance Center. Any opinions expressed in the chapters are those of the authors. Whilst Emerald makes every effort to ensure the quality and accuracy of its content, Emerald makes no representation implied or otherwise, as to the chapters’ suitability and application and disclaims any warranties, express or implied, to their use. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library ISBN: 978-1-78560-683-0 ISOQAR certified Management System, awarded to Emerald for adherence to Environmental standard ISO 14001:2004. Certificate Number 1985 ISO 14001 Contents List of Contributors xi Introduction from Editors xiii Practitioners’ Outlook xvii Academic Outlook xxiii Director Remuneration is a Matter of Growing Importance in the EU xxiii Legislation on Directors’ Remuneration xxiv Corporate Governance Codes xxiv Remuneration Should Be Guided by Market Demands and Linked to the Company’s Results xxv EU Commission Recommendation xxvi Some of the Experience of Member States xxvii Three Recommendations on Disclosure of Remuneration Policy xxviii Remuneration Should Promote the Long-Term Sustainability xxix Remuneration Policy xxx Remuneration Policies in the Financial Services Sector xxxi Section I Theory of Corporate Governance and Directors’ Remuneration CHAPTER 1 Corporate Governance and Remuneration Udo C. Braendle and Amir Hossein Rahdari Introduction The Theory of the Firm The Theory of Transaction Costs? Beyond the Firm and Market Dichotomy Incomplete Remuneration Contracts Agency Theory Adverse Selection Moral Hazard Different Agency Conflicts 3 3 6 8 9 11 13 14 15 v vi CONTENTS Management and Collective Production Outlook and Conclusion References 16 18 19 CHAPTER 2 Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation Udo C. Braendle and John E. Katsos Introduction Agency Theory and Managerial Compensation Base Salary Bonus Stock Options Employee Motivation Current Intrinsic Motivator: Takeover Threats Well-Balanced Packages Conclusion References 21 21 23 26 26 27 29 30 31 32 32 CHAPTER 3 Executive Compensation in the 21st Century: Future Directions Udo C. Braendle and Amir Hossein Rahdari 35 The 21st Century Compensation and Motivation Compensation Plans: Pay-Performance Link Redefining Performance Evaluation in the Age of Sustainability Conclusion References 35 36 37 38 41 41 Section II Cross-Industrial Remuneration Practices Analysis CHAPTER 4 Financial Companies Regina W. Schröder Introduction The Crisis and Its Effects on Remuneration Governance in Financial Institutions Elements of the Corporate Governance of Financial Institutions Pre- and Post-Crisis Remuneration Governance European Initiatives for Enhanced Governance and Remuneration Corporate Governance 47 47 48 48 50 50 50 Contents Remuneration Structuring Variable Bonuses over Time Discounting Alternative Discounting Functions Exponential Discounting Hyperbolic Discounting Quasi-Hyperbolic Discounting Evaluation Conclusion and Prospects References 51 52 52 53 53 54 54 55 55 56 CHAPTER 5 Industrial Companies Yusuf Mohammed Nulla Introduction Background Literature on CEO Compensation Research Design Results Directors Remuneration Policy Directors Remuneration Design Directors Remuneration Factors Board’s Role in Directors Remuneration Accounting Regulation Conclusion References Section III 59 59 59 60 62 62 64 65 66 67 67 68 69 Cross-Country Remuneration Practices Analysis CHAPTER 6 Directors’ Remuneration in the United States Andrew J. Felo Introduction Remuneration Regulation and Reporting Remuneration Design Empirical Evidence on Director Remuneration The Determinants of Director Remuneration Characteristics of Firms Adopting Outside Director Stock-Option Plans Director Remuneration and Compensation Committees Director Remuneration and Compensation Consultants Director Remuneration and Board Independence from CEO Director Remuneration and Board Overlaps 73 73 75 78 81 81 81 82 83 83 84 vii viii CONTENTS Summary of Determinants of Director Remuneration The Impact of Director Remuneration on the Firm and Its Stakeholders Market Reaction to Adding Equity to Director Remuneration Plans Director Remuneration and Financial Reporting Director Remuneration and Dividend Paying Director Remuneration and Shareholder Lawsuits Director Remuneration and Corporate Social Performance Summary of the Impact of Director Remuneration on Stakeholders Remuneration Challenges References 84 85 85 87 89 89 90 90 91 92 CHAPTER 7 Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom Jean J. Chen and Zhen Zhu Remuneration Regulation The Greenbury Report 1995 The Combined Code on Corporate Governance 1998 and Its Subsequent Revisions The UK Corporate Governance Code 2010 The UK Corporate Governance Code 2012 Remuneration Design (Schemes) Remuneration Reporting Directors’ Remuneration Report Regulations 2002 The 2012 Directors’ Remuneration Reporting Reform Remuneration Challenges Problems in UK Executive Remuneration Challenges for Remuneration Policy Acknowledgements References 95 95 96 98 99 101 103 110 110 111 113 113 115 115 116 CHAPTER 8 Directors’ Remuneration in Germany Markus Stiglbauer, Julia Wittek and Sven Thalmann Remuneration Regulation The German Two-Tier System Remuneration Regulation of the Management Board and Supervisory Board Remuneration Design (Schemes) Remuneration of the Management Board Remuneration of the Supervisory Board Remuneration Reporting 119 119 119 120 122 122 126 127 Contents Remuneration Challenges References 128 130 CHAPTER 9 Directors’ Remuneration in Italy Marco Artiaco Introduction Remuneration Regulation Listed Companies Bank and Banking Holdings Government-Owned Unlisted Companies Unlisted Companies Remuneration Design Schemes Remuneration Reporting Conclusions References 133 133 134 135 139 141 142 142 146 152 154 CHAPTER 10 Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Montserrat Manzaneque, Elena Merino and Regino Banegas Remuneration Regulation Regulation for Listed Companies Regulation for Financial Institutions Remuneration Design (Schemes) The Remuneration Policy for Directors in Spain. A Question Linked to the Board Structure Remuneration Systems’ Elements in Spanish Companies Practice Regarding Remuneration Systems in Spain (20042011) Remuneration Reporting Remuneration Challenges References 157 157 157 163 166 166 169 175 176 180 181 CHAPTER 11 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia Hussein Ahmed Tura Introduction Profile of Ethiopian Companies The Emerging Separation of Ownership and Control in the Ethiopian Share Companies Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopian Share Companies Remuneration Regulation Remuneration Design (Scheme) Remuneration Reporting Remuneration Challenges 185 185 186 187 190 190 192 194 195 ix x CONTENTS Participation of Employees Other than Directors on Annual Share in Profits Conclusion References 207 210 211 CHAPTER 12 Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements: From European Legislation to German Implementation Oliver Kruse, Christoph Schmidhammer and Erich Keller Introduction Prerequisites of an Incentive-Compatible Remuneration System Regulative Remuneration Standards of the EU The Implementation of Remuneration Regulations in Germany Incentive-Compatibility of the European and German Regulation of Remuneration Systems Conclusion and Perspectives References 213 213 215 216 219 220 220 222 CHAPTER 13 The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration Roberta Provasi and Patrizia Riva 225 Introduction 225 Literature Review 228 European Approach to the Regulation of Directors’ Remuneration 231 Recommendation 2004/913/EC 232 Remuneration Policy 233 Remuneration of Individual Directors 234 Share-Based Remuneration 235 Recommendation 2005/162/EC 235 Additional EU Interventions 237 Evidence on the Actual Compliance of the Italian Remuneration Reports to the CG Code 244 References 252 Index 255 List of Contributors Marco Artiaco University of Rome Tre, Rome, Italy Regino Banegas University of Castilla-La Mancha, Cuenca, Spain Udo C. Braendle American University in Dubai, Dubai UAE; University of Vienna, Vienna, Austria Jean J. Chen University of Southampton, UK Andrew J. Felo Nova Southeastern University, Fort Lauderdale, FL, USA Amir Hossein Rahdari Tarbiat Modares University, Tehran, Iran; Corporate Governance and Responsibility Development Center (CGRDC), Tehran, Iran John E. Katsos American University of Sharjah, Sharjah, UAE Erich Keller Deutsche Bundesbank University of Applied Sciences, Hachenburg, Germany Oliver Kruse Deutsche Bundesbank University of Applied Sciences, Hachenburg, Germany Montserrat Manzaneque University of Castilla-La Mancha, Cuenca, Spain Elena Merino University of Castilla-La Mancha, Ciudad Real, Spain Yusuf Mohammed Nulla Monarch University, Hagendorn-Zug, Switzerland Roberta Provasi Bicocca Milan University, Milan, Italy Patrizia Riva Piemonte Orientale University, Novara, Italy xi xii LIST OF CONTRIBUTORS Christoph Schmidhammer Deutsche Bundesbank University of Applied Sciences, Hachenburg, Germany Regina W. Schröder Herdecke University, Witten, Germany; Libera Università di Bozen-Bolzano, Bozen, Italy Markus Stiglbauer Friedrich-Alexander-Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg, Nuremberg, Germany Sven Thalmann Friedrich-Alexander-Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg, Nuremberg, Germany Hussein Ahmed Tura Addis Ababa University, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia Julia Wittek Friedrich-Alexander-Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg, Nuremberg, Germany Zhen Zhu University of Surrey, Guildford, UK Introduction from Editors D ear readers and friends! We are happy to present to you our new book The Theory and Practice of Directors’ Remuneration: New Challenges and Opportunities. Corporate governance faced critical new challenges during and after the world financial crisis and this book focuses on one of these: remuneration practices. Both practical and theoretical fundamentals needed urgent review. International organizations, researchers, and practitioners have all pointed out the necessity for reform and change. The excessive remuneration of executive directors and the ineffective remuneration of non-executives are seen as key problems and reasons for the financial crisis. The main objective of this book is to outline the practical and theoretical issues and discuss and analyze new approaches to directors’ remuneration due to changes made in corporate governance practices during the post-crisis period. Its secondary purpose is to ignite a new debate on the issue. The book is divided into three parts to give readers a full understanding of remuneration issues the theoretical foundations, a cross-sectoral view, and a cross-national analysis of current practice. The book is the result of a great deal of work done by our international network of corporate governance professionals, many colleagues, and friends. We are pleased to deliver our warm regards to Markus Stiglbauer (Germany). His contribution to editing the book adds great value to our project. We would also like to thank Philip J. Weights (Switzerland), who is a well-known expert in corporate governance and banking in Europe and worldwide. The academic outlook written by our colleague Rado Bohinc (Slovenia) sheds light on the scholarly discussions around the topic as well as debates among practitioners. Our contributors are, of course, worthy of special thanks. But the most important words of acknowledgment should be addressed to our families who consistently supported us in undertaking this major work. Alexander Kostyuk Ukrainian Academy of Banking, Ukraine Dmitriy Govorun Ukrainian Academy of Banking, Ukraine xiii xiv INTRODUCTION FROM EDITORS The recent financial crisis has led to a loss of trust in the quality of corporate governance and the balance of the European financial market. Banks play a key role in modern economies and perform integral functions. These issues have also affected Germany especially as financial companies play a major role in the German corporate governance system (“German bank-based system”). This is made apparent by a traditionally dominant creditor protection within commercial law accounting, which by its nature undervalues assets and overvalues debt in financial accounting. A sound banking and financial system is critical for the performance of the German economy, particularly in the wake of the financial crisis that began in 2007. Since then, remuneration issues and practices in combination with extraordinary appetite for risk have been much criticized and the implementation of the “pay for performance” principle without any doubt represents a basic standard for “good” corporate governance. Thus, the German government passed two laws concerning remuneration. The first was the Act Regarding the Disclosure of Management Board’s Remuneration. Its main purpose is to provide companies an incentive toward establishing appropriate, performance-based management compensation. Nevertheless, against all expectations, management salaries have been leveled and, unfortunately, even boosted. Companies commonly argue that one cannot separately evaluate the performance of individual board members, said Müller, Head of the German Corporate Governance Code Commission, in a heavy criticism. Consequently, the German government passed the act regarding the Appropriateness of Management Board’s Remuneration in 2009. It aims to link the variable remuneration of the management board to the company’s development based on several years’ assessment data, as well as the implementation of a “cooling off period” for former members of the management board before they are able to become members of the supervisory board. As a result, for example, Allianz SE, now assesses the short-, middle- and long-term elements of managers’ variable remuneration equally and enforces its malus system in case of bad performance, as does Deutsche Bank AG. Despite these positive reactions, one must differentiate the argumentation when examining general empirical findings on German listed companies’ reaction toward these new regulations. Between 2007 and 2009, German companies reduced overall management reward (−16 percent) and approximately 55 percent pay less than h500 tsd. to a member of the management board, and only 19 percent pay over 1 million euro to an individual board member this limit is psychologically important. Nevertheless, with regard to the payment structure, we rate the development as negative. We found that companies in general, and particularly those in the financial Introduction from Editors sector, increased fixed managerial pay within the payment structure and reduced variable bonus pay. Moreover, considering the economic upswing in Germany in 2010, we are observing that the current structure and overall management compensation is comparable to the beginning of the financial crisis, with a slight increase in longterm incentives. Overall, these measures don’t seem to be appropriate to motivate managers to act in companies’ and shareholders best interest because such remuneration structure lowers managers’ individual consequences in the event of a severe financial/economic situation by reducing their personal income risk on one hand and fires “normal” workers or reduces their working time (and consequently their income) on the other hand. Additionally, higher fixed managerial pay makes companies less flexible in a further crisis and generally does not lower company risk, but rather possibly increases managerial risk taking. Further, the regulatory requirements of an appropriate management board’s remuneration are not yet well implemented. Bonus pay and share-based pay are still short-term oriented in many cases. Further, in the case of negative firm development, bonus programs often do not involve managers sufficiently. With regard to the act regarding the Disclosure of Management Board’s Remuneration, there are only few listed companies that choose to “opt out” and not publish management and supervisory board members’ remuneration individually. A company may use this option for five years when 75 percent of the shareholders represented at the shareholder’s meeting vote for this exception. Shareholders are able to renew the decision to opt out after five years. In summary, this is a clear mandate for a thorough and critical discussion of existing remuneration structures for management board members by supervisory boards and remuneration committees. Markus Stiglbauer Professor at Friedrich-Alexander-Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg (Germany); German Association of University Professors (DHV); European Academy of Management (EURAM); Association of University Professors of Management (VHB); Virtus Global Center for Corporate Governance (VGCCG) xv This page intentionally left blank Practitioners’ Outlook I t was with great pleasure that I accepted the invitation from Dr. Alexander Kostyuk, Chairman of the Board of the International Center for Banking and Corporate Governance, to write a Foreword to this important new book The Theory and Practice of Directors’ Remuneration: New Challenges and Opportunities. This topic is of interest to many people, including employees, investors, executives, auditors, regulators, and politicians. We have witnessed the devastating effect of the global financial crisis which began in 20072008. This evolved into a Sovereign Debt Crisis by 2010, and caused the loss of millions of jobs worldwide. The effect is still felt today, as illustrated by the collapse of one of Portugal’s largest banks, Banco Espírito Santo, as recently as August 3, 2014. Post-crisis analysis by the World Bank and the International Finance Corporation has identified Corporate Governance failures as the main contributing factor to the crisis. The failures are in four main areas: “Risk Governance”; “Remuneration and alignment of incentive structures”; “Board independence, qualifications and composition”; and “Shareholder engagement”. This book addresses perhaps the most emotional and controversial of these, the remuneration issue. The news headlines post-crisis routinely discussed “Corporate Greed”, “Market Abuse”, with Banks “Too Big to Fail”, and bankers “Too Big to Jail”. Public outrage led to the birth of the “Occupy Wall Street” protest movement in September 2011. The main issues raised were social and economic inequality, greed, corruption and the perceived undue influence of corporations on government, particularly from the financial services sector. Greed is reinforced in popular culture, as illustrated in the movie “Wall Street” where Gordon Gekko, a corporate raider played by the actor Michael Douglas, says “The point is, ladies and gentleman, that greed, for lack of a better word, is good. Greed is right, greed works.” In the real world of business, politicians, voters, and investors want to control excessive greed. On October 13, 2014, Thomson Reuters published a press release from their subsidiary Incomes Data Services with the headline “FTSE 100 Directors’ Total Earnings Jump by 21% in a Year.” It explains that share-based xvii xviii PRACTITIONERS’ OUTLOOK incentive payments and bonuses are driving the increase. IDS points out that the median total earnings for a FTSE 100 director is now £2.4 million. The median total earnings for FTSE 100 Chief Executives are £3.3 million. This is 120 times more than a full time employee in 2014, compared to 47 times more than a full time employee in 2000. Such an increasing gap is causing great concern, and measures are now being taken in the United Kingdom to make directors and executives more accountable, introduce Remuneration Governance, curb bonuses, and establish mandatory bonus clawback periods. The same reaction to corporate greed is felt in Switzerland. In March 2013, Swiss voters approved a plan to severely limit executive compensation. This national referendum, commonly referred to as the “Initiative against rip-off salaries” was prompted by the public outrage against the executives of Swissair, the flagship airline that collapsed in 2001, and the political storm when Novartis, the pharmaceutical company, agreed to a $78 million severance pay-out for its departing chairman. The intense criticism from investors forced Novartis to scrap the pay-out. The Swiss vote gives shareholders of companies listed in Switzerland a binding say on the overall pay packages for executives and directors. Swiss companies are no longer allowed to give bonuses to executives joining or leaving the business or to executives when their company is taken over. Violations can result in fines equal to up to six years of salary and a prison sentence of up to three years. In the United States, executive remuneration is also a major concern. It is reported that by 2006, CEOs made 400 times more than average workers, a gap 20 times bigger than it was in 1965. To address this situation, on January 25, 2011, the SEC adopted rules for Say-on-Pay and Golden Parachute Compensation as required under the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. Say-on-Pay votes must occur at least once every three years, and Companies must disclose on an SEC Form 8-K how often it will hold the Say-on-Pay vote. Under the SEC’s new rules, companies are also required to provide additional disclosure regarding “golden parachute” compensation arrangements with certain executive officers in connection with merger transactions. Despite the new rules, a report titled “2013 CEO Pay Survey” produced by Governance Metrics International Ratings grabs attention when it states that the first two executives named in their Top Ten List of Highest Paid CEOs earned more than $1 billion in a single year, and all 10 CEOs made at least $100 million. Historically, Oracle has one of the highest paid US executives. For the past two years, shareholders voted down the CEOs pay package. However, the resolution is non-binding. Most of the votes “for” were cast by the CEO himself as he owns a quarter of the company (CNNMoney (New York), Practitioners’ Outlook 2013). This illustrates two Corporate Governance issues, one being that shareholders in the United States do not yet have the right to “approve” the remuneration of top executives. The second issue is that a Chairman (who may also be the CEO) can vote in favor of a compensation issue, despite the obvious conflict of interest. The European Union has taken significant measures to deal with the remuneration issue. This includes issuing “Directive 2013/36/EU of 26 June 2013 on Access to the Activity of Credit Institutions and the Prudential Supervision of Credit Institutions and Investment Firms.” In point 53 of the introductory text, there is a clear statement that weaknesses in corporate governance contributed to excessive and imprudent risk-taking in the banking sector which led to the failure of individual institutions and systemic problems in Member States. The Directive also recognizes that the general provisions on governance and the non-binding nature of a substantial part of the corporate governance framework, based essentially on voluntary codes of conduct, did not sufficiently facilitate the effective implementation of sound corporate governance practices. Articles 9296 cover the specific new rules regarding Remuneration. Of particular interest from a transparency and reporting perspective is Article 96 titled “Maintenance of a website on corporate governance and remuneration.” Here the Directive requires Financial Institutions to explain on their website how they comply with Articles 8895 dealing with all the “Governance Arrangements” including the new remuneration rules. Corporate Governance is of universal importance. Remuneration Governance is one of the key challenges to ensure the correct balance between risk and reward, and ensure that Directors’ compensation is equitable to all parties and stakeholders. It seems clear that the trend is to enhance the Remuneration Governance. Increasingly, this is via a formal and transparent policy and procedure for implementing executive remuneration and for fixing the remuneration packages of individual directors. Many countries are introducing regulations for Companies to include the remuneration figure for top executives and directors in their annual financial report, along with the introduction of binding shareholder votes on boardroom remuneration. It is therefore timely and relevant that this new book The Theory and Practice of Directors’ Remuneration: New Challenges and Opportunities has been written. The book examines the current theories, practices, and regulations and explains them in detail. Section I, Theory of Corporate Governance and Directors’ Remuneration, is written by Prof. Udo Braendle of the American University in Dubai, UAE, and covers in Chapter 1 the key topic of “Corporate Governance and Remuneration,” followed by Chapter 2 (co-written with Prof. John E. Katsos of the American xix xx PRACTITIONERS’ OUTLOOK University in Sharjah) covering “Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation.” Professors Braendle and Katsos suggest that the failure of Remuneration Governance can be remedied by switching the balance of compensation packages from extrinsic motivators such as pay-for-performance bonuses and stock options, to intrinsic motivators such as firing and prestige. In Section II, Cross-industrial Remuneration Practices Analysis, Regina W. Schröder provides an analysis of the practices in the Financial Services sector. She argues that attention has not been paid to the present value of remuneration, and the discounting method by which this value should be calculated. The discounting method and its disclosure are important elements of the corporate governance, allowing stakeholders to anticipate the amount of the incentives and rewards paid, and evaluate the associated risk. The Industrial Sector analysis is provided by Dr. Yusuf Mohammed Nulla who explores the energy, metal, mining, and health industry’s effects on Directors’ remuneration in Canada and the United States. Section III, Cross-country Remuneration Practices Analysis, provides an analysis of Director’s Remuneration in various countries. The US perspective is covered by Dr. Andrew J. Felo, Associate Professor of Accounting, Nova South-Eastern University in Florida who highlights the two main challenges regarding Directors Remuneration. The first is that directors have significant input into their own pay packages, while the second challenge is to make the remuneration package attractive enough to attract quality directors to the board. Prof. Jean J. Chen provides an excellent analysis of the regulations, challenges for Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom. She notes that two problems in UK remuneration practices have been highlighted in recent scrutiny, the divergence of executive pay from firm performance and decreased clarity and transparency caused by increasingly complex remuneration reporting. She explains that in response to the failings in the corporate governance framework for executive remuneration, the UK government has announced a comprehensive package of reforms including binding shareholder votes and greater transparency in the directors’ remuneration reports. Prof. Dr. Markus Stiglbauer and his Corporate Governance team at the University of ErlangenNuremberg present a comprehensive analysis of the German remuneration regulations and how the system functions within the two-tier Board framework of a management board and a supervisory board. One of the key challenges is noted as the failure in 2013 of the German Government to pass a proposed new Act to improve the Supervision of Board Remuneration. This Act included empowering the annual general shareholder meeting to review and approve management board remuneration as proposed by the supervisory board. The remuneration situation in Italy is explained by Practitioners’ Outlook Dr. Marco Artiaco, Professor of Economy and Management at the Universita di Roma Tre. He argues that the Italian Corporate Governance system still seems weak, and remuneration polices of Italian regulated firms, seem to be oriented to finding solutions in order to acquire and retain top managers. In his view, the solutions selected by authorities in order to regulate financial firms such as transparency, remuneration system structure, incentive mechanism control, and risk management should be extended to all the companies in which remuneration is a critical issue. Directors’ remuneration in Spain is addressed by Prof. Montserrat Manzaneque, together with Elena Merino Madrid and Regino Banegas Ochovo of the University of Castilla-La Mancha in Spain. They mention the Spanish government is currently considering new measures to limit variable remuneration and allowances, and changing the advisory vote of the General Shareholders’ Meeting regarding the remuneration of Directors to a binding vote. Dr. Hussein Ahmed Tura of the Ambo University in Ethiopia critically analyzes Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia. He explains that the Ethiopian Commercial Code of 1960 is outdated, unchanged, and lacks rules and principles on many aspects of company governance including adequate provisions on directors’ remuneration. He also mentions that National Bank of Ethiopia recently adopted a directive limiting the directors’ remuneration in the banking industry to approximately US$2500 per year. He argues this may have an adverse effect on the independence of directors, and the retention of talented experts. Chapter 12 deals with remuneration requirements from European legislation to German implementation. It is written by Professors Oliver Kruse, Christoph Schmidhammer, and Erich Keller at the Deutsche Bundesbank University of Applied Sciences. Their chapter analyzes the implementation of remuneration policies in German banking institutions starting from European legislation standards. They mention that BaFin surveys illustrate some institutions try to undermine regulatory requirements by not fully defining risk takers or implementing asymmetric variable remuneration components. It is suggested that some German institutions are investing significant efforts to avoid regulatory remuneration standards. Chapter 13 is written by Roberta Provasi from Bicocca Milan University, Italy and Patrizia Riva from Piemonte Orientale University, Italy and deals with European specifics of directors’ remuneration regulation. Professor Alexander Kostyuk, Virtus Interpess, and the Global Center for Corporate Governance are to be commended for this comprehensive review and analysis of the international state of Governance and Directors’ Remuneration. Philip J. Weights ACIB, CIA, CISA, CRMA, Founder and Managing Partner, Enhanced Banking Governance LLC, Zurich, Switzerland xxi This page intentionally left blank Academic Outlook R emuneration, compensations, and other benefits of directors is rather new and not much publicly discussed and even not much researched topic. However it is, especially in times of crisis, very relevant for successful and efficient corporate governance. Without a doubt, it is a legitimate concern and expectations of the shareholders that directors’ remuneration should not exceed the agreed levels and that it should be disclosed for public scrutiny. This book makes more familiar the issues, related to remuneration, compensations, and other benefits of directors. It is very topical issue, relevant to a wide range of readers, like scholars from a variety of disciplines, professionals outside academia and also students for use in courses. The book is also recommended to general readers interested in the field of business, economy, law, corporate governance, finance, accounting, and management; it is on one hand of great theoretical interest and on the other currently needed to the practitioners in this field. In the Section III of this book (Cross-Country Remuneration Practices Analysis), the presentation of practices analysis in some individual EU member states and in addition the EU regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies is presented. Director Remuneration is a Matter of Growing Importance in the EU Director remuneration is a matter of growing importance in most of the EU countries and at the level of EU as well. According to European Commission, experience over the last years, and more recently in relation to the financial crisis, has shown that remuneration was focused on short-term achievements and in some cases led to excessive remuneration, which was not justified by performance. Also remuneration policies in the financial services sector showed inappropriate remuneration practices in the financial services industry and also induced excessive risk. xxiii xxiv ACADEMIC OUTLOOK EU Commission Recommendation of April 30, 2009, complementing Recommendations 2004/913/EC and 2005/162/EC as regards the regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies and Commission Recommendation on remuneration policies in the financial services sector SEC(2009) 580 SEC(2009) 581, Brussels, 30.4.2009 C(2009) 3159 imposed several approaches and practices. Legislation on Directors’ Remuneration Legislation and corporate governance codes mostly apply to all types of companies; however, in some countries they apply only to listed companies. There are often stricter rules on transparency and disclosure for listed companies. Most of the rules on executive directors’ remuneration apply only to domestically incorporated companies, whereas prospectus regulation and ongoing disclosure rules and regulations apply to all companies, the securities of which are listed on the Stock Exchange. Directors’ remuneration in EU countries is regulated by different Laws (Acts), Decrees, Supreme Court decisions, Case law, Regulations of the Ministries, Stock Exchange or Financial Services Authority rules and recommendations and best practices. As for laws, most often directors’ remuneration would be regulated by Public Limited Companies Acts or Stock Corporations Acts (Austria, Germany, Spain) or just Companies Acts (Finland, UK, Ireland, Luxembourg, Portugal), Civil Codes (Italy, Netherland), Accounting Laws, Capital Markets Acts, Securities Trading Acts, Stock Exchange Acts and rules (like Disclosure Obligations for Issuers, Stock Exchange Admission Regulation, Listing Rules, etc.), Commercial Codes, like in France, etc. Corporate Governance Codes Best practices would normally be described in private ethical codes mostly called Corporate Governance Codes or Principles of Good Governance and Code of Best Practice or Code of Ethics for Companies’ Boards of Directors and different other non-binding recommendations. A so-called “comply or explain” principle is often applicable to compliance with the relevant provisions by companies. Where the “comply or explain” principle applies, the evidence whether companies generally comply with best practices is in some countries available in companies’ annual reports. However, there are countries where the Code is only applied if a company is ready to accept the rules, expressing that by way of declaration to accept Academic Outlook and to obey to the rules. In some other countries, there is a legal obligation to report on compliance of the companies’ rules and behavior with the code. It is recommended by most corporate governance codes that the Board create a Remuneration Committee with the powers to propose to the Board of Directors the amount of the Directors’ annual remuneration to review the remuneration programs and consider their appropriateness and results, and to ensure transparency in remuneration. The Remuneration Committee’s mission is also to assist the Board in setting and supervising the remuneration policy. In general, these committees’ role is basically informative and consultative, although they may exceptionally be given decision-making powers. Remuneration is a key aspect of corporate governance where conflicts of interest may arise and a strong control right for shareholders can significantly improve the accountability of boards. Unlike in other areas of corporate governance for which soft-law measures remain appropriate, the Commission’s efforts to improve governance on pay through soft-law measures (three Recommendations on directors’ remuneration, in 2004, 2005, and 2009) have not led to significant improvement in this area. It is therefore necessary to proceed with a more prescriptive approach involving binding rules on remuneration. Remuneration Should Be Guided by Market Demands and Linked to the Company’s Results Generally, the company is free to establish the remuneration; yet it should be guided by market demands and having regarded to the responsibility and commitment of the role which each Director plays. Director remuneration should be set so as to offer sufficient incentives to dedication by the Director while not compromising his independence. On the other hand, Directors’ remuneration, should be linked to the company’s results, since this will bring the Directors’ interests more into line with those of the shareholder, which it is sought to maximize. It is recommended that remuneration comprising shares of the company or group companies, stock options or options referenced to the share price be limited to executive or internal directors. There are different advantages or disadvantages of the various forms of remuneration (incentives, payments in stock, stock options, etc.), some of which face tax obstacles in some countries, which do not exist in other countries. xxv xxvi ACADEMIC OUTLOOK It is the responsibility of the Boards’ directors to adjust the remuneration to each company’s individual circumstances. It is important to review remuneration policies periodically in order to ensure that the amounts and structure are commensurate with the Directors’ responsibilities, risks, and duties. Accordingly, it is advisable for the Board itself, with the help of reports drafted for this purpose by the Remuneration Committee, to evaluate these matters at least once per year and disclose information on this area in the annual report. EU Commission Recommendation According to EU Commission Recommendation of April 30, 2009,1 experience over the last years, and more recently in relation to the financial crisis, has shown that remuneration was focused on shortterm achievements and in some cases led to excessive remuneration, which was not justified by performance. That is why the existing regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies should have been strengthened by principles which are complementary to those contained in Recommendations 2004/913/EC and 2005/162/ EC. The structure and level of executive pay is a key tool to ensure that directors’ incentives on how to run a company are aligned with those of the company and its owners. In the past years, there were repeated cases of mismatch between executive pay and performance of the company. Shareholders often face difficulties in being properly informed and in exercising control over directors’ pay (i.e., the management of the company). Transparency on pay and oversight thereof is insufficient; only 15 EU Member States require disclosure of the remuneration policy and 11 Member States require disclosure of individual directors’ pay. In addition, only 13 Member States give shareholders “a say on pay” through either a vote on directors’ remuneration policy and/or report. Shareholders need information and rights to challenge pay, particularly when it is not justified by long-term performance. The lack of proper oversight on remuneration leads to unjustified transfers of value from the company to directors.2 1 Commission Recommendation of April 30, 2009, complementing Recommendations 2004/913/EC and 2005/162/EC as regards the regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies (Text with EEA relevance) (2009/385/EC) (Recommendation of 2009). 2 As it is shown in the Commission’s impact assessment accompanying the Recommendations 2004/913/EC, 2005/162/EC and 2009/385/EC proposal. Academic Outlook An increase of the transparency on pay was therefore needed. It would have also given shareholders a right to approve the remuneration policy of the directors every three years and a right to vote annually on the remuneration report explaining the pay packages of directors in an advisory manner. Some of the Experience of Member States3 The experience of Member States demonstrates that there is often an insufficient link between pay and performance where shareholders do not have a “say on pay.” For instance, in France and Austria, where shareholders do not have a say on directors’ pay, the average remuneration of directors in the years 20062012 increased by 94% and 27% respectively, although the average share prices of listed companies in these countries decreased by 34% and 46% respectively. While executive pay should not depend only on short-term share price fluctuations, such fundamentally divergent trends are one indicator for a mismatch between pay and performance. In Italy and Spain, before the introduction of an advisory say on pay in 2011, the average share price in the years 20062011 went down by 130% and 40% respectively, while the average remuneration of directors of listed companies increased by 29% and 26%. However, since the law was adopted in 2011, the average share price of listed companies has increased by 10% and decreased by 5% respectively, but the remuneration of directors has also increased by 1% and declined by 10%. Such links between pay and performance are even stronger in Member States where shareholders have a binding say on pay on remuneration policy, since their opinion cannot be overruled by the board of directors. In Sweden and Belgium, before the adoption of a binding say on pay in 2010 and 2011 respectively, the average share price from 2006 to 2009 and from 2006 to 2011 went down by 17% and 45%, while average pay of directors of listed companies increased by 18% and 95%. However, since the laws were adopted in 2010 3 Communication From The Commission To The European Parliament, The Council, The European Economic And Social Committee And The Committee Of The Regions Action Plan: European company law and corporate governance a modern legal framework for more engaged shareholders and sustainable companies (Action Plan 2012). xxvii xxviii ACADEMIC OUTLOOK and 2011, the share price has increased by 16% and 18% but the remuneration of directors has also increased by 18% and decreased (as a correction) by 10%. To conclude, currently, not all Member States give shareholders the right to vote on remuneration policy and/or the report, and information disclosed by companies in different Member States is not easily comparable. The Commission will propose in 2013 an initiative, possibly through a modification of the shareholders’ rights Directive, to improve transparency on remuneration policies and individual remuneration of directors, as well as to grant shareholders the right to vote on remuneration policy and the remuneration report.4 Three Recommendations on Disclosure of Remuneration Policy The main recommendations related to remuneration are disclosure of remuneration policy and the individual remuneration of executive and non-executive directors, the shareholders’ vote on the remuneration statement, an independent functioning remuneration committee and appropriate incentives which foster performance and long-term value creation by listed companies. Commission reports show that a number of Member States have not adequately addressed these issues.5 In 2009, the European Corporate Governance Forum (EUCGF) recommended that disclosure of remuneration policy and individual remuneration be made mandatory for all listed companies. It also recommended a binding or advisory shareholder vote on remuneration policy and greater independence for non-executive directors involved in determining remuneration policy.6 According to EUCGF, disclosure of the remuneration policy of listed companies and of the individual remuneration of directors (executive and non-executive) and any material change to it should 4 Communication From The Commission To The European Parliament, The Council, The European Economic And Social Committee And The Committee Of The Regions Action Plan: European company law and corporate governance a modern legal framework for more engaged shareholders and sustainable companies. 5 Commission Recommendations 2004/913/EC, 2005/162/EC and 2009/ 385/EC. 6 The Commission also consulted on this issue in the 2010 Green Paper on Corporate Governance in Financial Institutions. Academic Outlook be mandatory for all listed companies in the EU.7 Disclosure of the remuneration policy, its structure and individual director pay is necessary in order for shareholders to have an appropriate level of control over director remuneration.8 In 2004, the Commission issued a Recommendation9 to Member States dealing with remuneration disclosure and the role of shareholders and non-executive directors. According to the remuneration Recommendation, listed companies would have to disclose a remuneration policy statement that could include details about performance criteria. The remuneration policy statement should include among other things information related to the importance of fixed and variable remuneration, information on performance criteria and the parameters for annual bonus schemes. Remuneration Should Promote the Long-Term Sustainability The remuneration of executive directors is an important element of the governance regime of companies. In the last two decades, a fundamental shift has occurred to introduce and increase the level of variable pay, both in cash and in shares and rights to acquire shares.10 As stipulated in this recommendation, the structure of directors’ remuneration should promote the long-term sustainability of the company and ensure that remuneration is based on performance. It is necessary to ensure that termination payments, the so-called “golden parachutes,” are not a reward for failure and that the 7 EUCGF, Statement March 23, 2009 Statement of the European Corporate Governance Forum on Director Remuneration; According to EUCGF, currently only about 60% of Member States require disclosure of the remuneration policy and about two thirds of Member States require disclosure of individual director pay (see the Commission Working Staff Document referred to above). 8 According to EUCGF, the effective impact of the Recommendation has been minimal: see the Commission Working Staff Document SEC (2007) 1022 of July 13, 2007. 527 68 Remuneration, Compensations and Other Benefits of Directors non-cash benefits. It should also explain the company’s policy on the terms of executive directors’ contracts. Information about the way the remuneration policy has been drawn up should also be made available. 9 Recommendations 2004/913/EC and 2005/162/EC as regards the regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies. 10 EUCGF, Statement March 23, 2009 Statement of the European Corporate Governance Forum on Director Remuneration. xxix xxx ACADEMIC OUTLOOK primary purpose of termination payments as a safety net in case of early termination of the contract is respected. Schemes under which directors are remunerated in shares, share options or any other right to acquire shares or be remunerated on the basis of share price movements should be better linked to performance and long-term value creation of the company.11 In order to facilitate the shareholders’ assessment of the company’s approach to remuneration and strengthen the company’s accountability toward its shareholders, the remuneration statement should be clear and easily understandable. Moreover, further disclosure of information relating to the structure of remuneration is said to be necessary.12 Remuneration Policy A remuneration policy also includes a maximum amount of remuneration. This should ensure that companies make a conscious choice as to what is the value of good management for their company. For new recruitments, the company will be able to deviate from the maximum, but only subject to prior or ex post approval by the shareholders. The remuneration policy approved by shareholders should explain how the pay and employment conditions of employees of the company were taken into account when setting the policy or directors’ remuneration by explaining the ratio between the average remuneration of directors and the average remuneration of full time employees of the company other than directors and why this ratio is considered appropriate. This ensures that companies make a conscious choice and reflect on the relative value of good management for the company and on the interaction between executive pay and a company’s general working environment. The policy may exceptionally be without a ratio in case of exceptional circumstances. In that case, it shall explain why there is no ratio and which measures with the same effect have been taken. The remuneration policy should be submitted to shareholders for a vote every three years. Executive remuneration can only be awarded or paid if it based on an approved remuneration policy. In view of the significant differences of Member States’ company law, it will be for Member States set out in detail how these principles 11 12 Recommendation of 2009. Recommendation of 2009. Academic Outlook will be complied with and what procedures would need to be followed if shareholders reject the remuneration policy. Remuneration Policies in the Financial Services Sector According to the Commission Recommendation on remuneration policies in the financial services sector,13 inappropriate remuneration practices in the financial services industry, also induced excessive risk14. Creating appropriate incentives within the remuneration system itself should reduce the burden on risk management and increase the likelihood that these systems become effective. Therefore, there is a need to establish principles on sound remuneration policies. The recommendation on remuneration in the financial services sector is presented in order to improve risk management in financial firms and align pay incentives with sustainable performance. The recommendation sets out general principles applicable to remuneration policy in the financial services sector and should apply to all financial undertakings operating in the financial services industry. Remuneration policy covers those categories of staff whose professional activities have a material impact on the risk profile of the financial undertaking. The governing body of the financial undertaking should have the ultimate responsibility for establishing the remuneration policy for the whole financial undertaking and monitoring its implementation. The framework is not the same as for credit institutions and investment firms. Directive 2013/36/EU, part of the CRD IV package (MEMO/13/690), has introduced, inter alia, a maximum ratio 13 Commission Recommendation on remuneration policies in the financial services sector SEC (2009) 580 SEC(2009) 581, Brussels, 30.4.2009 C (2009) 3159. Remuneration, Compensations and Benefits in the German AktG 68.2 taking and thus contributed to significant losses of major financial undertakings. 14 Financial undertaking’ according to the recommendation, means any undertaking, irrespective of its legal status, whether regulated or not, which performs any of the following activities on a professional basis: (a) It accepts deposits and other repayable funds; (b) It provides investment services and/ or performs investment activities within the meaning of Directive 2004/39/ EC; (c) It is involved in insurance or reinsurance business; (d) It performs business activities similar to those set out in points (a), (b) Or (c). A financial undertaking includes, but is not limited to, credit institutions, investment firms, insurance and reinsurance undertakings, pension funds and collective investment schemes. xxxi xxxii ACADEMIC OUTLOOK of 1:1 between the fixed and the variable component of the total remuneration, with some flexibility provided for shareholders to approve a higher ratio, up to 1:2. Dr. Rado Bohinc Professor of corporate law at University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Section I Theory of Corporate Governance and Directors’ Remuneration This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 1 Corporate Governance and Remuneration Udo C. Braendle and Amir Hossein Rahdari C oase (1937) was one of the first scholars who asked why firms exist and what precisely a firm was. Both questions are fundamental to understand corporate governance and remuneration. Before the 1930s the firm was often seen as a ‘black box’ which was assumed to behave like any other self-interested utility maximising economic actor. Although Adam Smith already cited the problems like the separation of ownership and control in firms, it took more than 150 years before economists such as Coase and Williamson put theories around these questions. In the meantime catchwords like agency theory try to explain what corporate governance is and what part remuneration plays. This chapter lays the basis by examining the different theories of the firm, legal and economic ones, how they are connected and what they mean for the corporate governance and remuneration discussion. But this chapter shall also show the limitations of these theories and present some outlook for new theories of the firm. Introduction The directors of such companies [joint stock companies] however being the managers rather of other peoples’ money than of their own, it cannot well be expected, that they 3 4 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI should watch over it with the same anxious vigilance [as if it were their own]. Smith (1776) Theories of the firm are ways of conceptualising the firm and understanding why remuneration matters (Braendle & Katsos, 2013). The answers to the questions why firms exist and what precisely a firm is are fundamental for the understanding of corporate governance. Theories of the firm not only try to answer why businesses are organised in firms but how the relationships within the firm as well as between the firm and society at large look like. Since the seminal article of Ronald Harry Coase on the nature of the firm (Coase, 1937), these questions were brought to the attention of a large number of economists and a growing number of lawyers, mainly in the area of Law and Economics. Many economists (still) use the tool of neo-classical economics to explain why business activities are carried out with the structure of a firm and to develop policy implications in corporate governance and compensation. Company law and corporate governance proposals are based on particular understandings of what firms are for and whose interests they should serve. Therefore the theory of the firm is an indispensable starting point for corporate governance and remuneration studies. Before the 1930s, the firm was very often seen as a ‘black box’ which was assumed to behave like any other self-interested utility maximising economic actor. This view was based on the belief about the firm’s ability to almost instantaneously adjust itself to a changing environment. Consequently, resources of a firm were assumed to be put to their most efficient use without having to look ‘inside’ the firm. It was treated as an entity competing with other firms in the market. Although the limitations of this macroeconomic view have already been cited by authors like Adam Smith (17231790), the contemporary legal concept of separate legal personalities of companies supports this theory. Only this broad and abstract perspective of firms can identify problems such as monopolies and oligopolies, where one or a group of firms is able to drive competitors out of the market. Antitrust law is a response to these sorts of market failures. But at the same time firms are a collection of individuals as well all having their own preferences and values (highly relevant in terms of compensation) tied together in legal relationships within the legally constructed black box of the firm. Although this microeconomic view of firms is less abstract than the black box perspective, it does not explain why these individuals prefer organising themselves into business structures rather than remaining independent and making contracts on their own. Corporate Governance and Remuneration In a free market environment the answer must lie in significant economic benefits of organisation within the structure of a firm compared with contractual relationship on a market. In his seminal 1937 article, Coase developed a theory of the firms which was against the mainstream literature at this time and put emphasis on these relationships within the firm. Coase challenged economists and was the starting point of various theories of the firm. What was originally a research area for a few economists has, in the meantime, become a playing field for lawyers and economists interested in corporate governance. Reviews of the theories of the firm and catchwords like the separation of ownership and control, agency theory and corporate social responsibility make this research area very prominent. This chapter will, starting from Coase, present the transactioncost economics of the firm (see section ‘The Theory of the Firm The Theory of Transaction Costs?’). Theories look at the firm as an alternative to markets. Oliver Williamson, an institutional economist, further developed Coase’s theory of the firm through a deeper analysis of different forms of contracts (see section ‘Beyond the Firm and Market Dichotomy’). As most theories of the firm are based on the idea of a firm being a nexus of incomplete contracts (which will be dealt with in section ‘Incomplete Remuneration Contracts’), opportunism may influence the relationships within firms and highlight compensation issues. The latter are based on asymmetric information, where one party like the directors of a company can misuse the informational advantage to exploit another party like the shareholders. Remuneration and monitoring are two measures to reduce this agency problem, which will all be discussed in section ‘Agency Theory’. Agency theory developments can be bifurcated into two major literature bodies of principal-agent theory and positive agency theory (Fama & Jensen, 1983). Principal-agent theory models principal-agent relationship based on logical deduction, mathematical evidence and viable assumptions (Eisenhardt, 1989). While, positive agency theory examines the manager-owner relationship and focuses on areas of interest divergence and develops instruments to align their interests and curb opportunistic behaviour. Ownership structure (Jensen & Meckling, 1976), efficient capital markets and controlling opportunistic behaviour (Fama, 1980), and separation of ownership-control and monitoring mechanisms (Fama & Jensen, 1983) have been investigated in positive agency theory. This is called ‘Alternative Mechanism’. There are various notable theories of alternative mechanisms. The definition of ‘classical firm’ looks at a firm as a ‘production function’ personified by an entrepreneur. These theories of firms are merely theories of markets 5 6 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI that look at firms as important entities as they explain why a firm exists but fail to elucidate on the significance of a firm as an organizational structure. That is why they refer to firms as ‘black box constructions’ (Mäntysaari, 2012). According to Smith (1776) firms exist to motivate and coordinate economic activity of specialists. Common resource pools (Ostrom, 1999) and set-of-contracts theory of the firm (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972) are other theories of firm. These theories are influential in the study of incentives within the firms. The principal has a responsibility to compensate the agent for their efforts but conflict arises when determining the amount, type and timing of these compensations (Spulber, 1990). But this chapter will not only present theories of the firm but also try to highlight the relevancy of each of these theories for the corporate governance and remuneration debate and what practical importance they have for policy makers. The Theory of the Firm The Theory of Transaction Costs? The theory of the firm was traditionally one branch of Microeconomics, which studied the supply of goods by profit-maximising agents. In this theory, production costs played a crucial role. Coase (1937) was one of the first to point out that in addition to production costs of the usual sort, one must also consider transaction costs in explaining institutions like the firm. He focused on the comparative transaction costs of alternative organisational structures, such as firms and markets. This theory was later extended by Oliver Williamson and became widely known as transaction-cost economics (Williamson, 1979) or more broadly the economics of organisation. Transaction costs are costs (e.g. in terms of money or time) incurred when making an economic exchange. If we extend this term, transaction costs do not only include bilateral transactions but subsume contractual relationships between individuals. In general, transaction costs symbolise ‘friction losses’, that is the lost resources for the involved parties, but which are inevitable to reach certain goals. In firms, transaction costs may include the costs of organising business activity over time, planning the future and limiting as well as allocating risks which may arise in the future. It therefore includes the elements of uncertainty and opportunism, which are both indispensable for debates in corporate governance. Coase argued in his 1937 article that transaction costs explain both the existence of firms and their optimal size. In ‘The Nature of the Firm’ he identified certain transactions which are prohibitively Corporate Governance and Remuneration costly if the parties involved could only deal with instant market transactions. In order to carry out a market transaction it is necessary to identify the party one wishes to deal with, establishing terms and conditions, conducting negotiations and concluding a contract. After the conclusion of the contract, monitoring is needed to make sure that all terms and conditions are fulfilled. If slight changes are wished, the whole transaction process needs to be initiated again. Or, to put it in other words, Coase emphasised that making contracts and purchasing assets and other property in markets incurred costs that were not accounted for by the ‘price mechanism’. Individuals would therefore organise firms and maintain them when the organisational entity provided implicit savings in terms of assembling resources, assets and labour internally. This describes situations in which market transactions would show their relative inflexibility to re-contracting when changes in the existing relationship arise. Regularly recurring transactions and long-term transactions might be good examples. In such situations longer, incomplete contracts, which are typical for firms, provide much more flexibility for the parties in a world of uncertainty. These contracts can be left open to be flexible in case of a changing environment. On the other hand, dissimilarities of transactions, the probability of changes in the market prices for the relevant resources as well as the spatial distribution of the relevant resources and transactions highlight factors which increase the costs of using a firm. One might argue in this context that transaction costs would be minimised in a world without transactions. This could be achieved if rights and duties would initially be assigned in the ‘right’ way. Based on this idea Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz built their theory of property rights. Property can be tangible (e.g. equipment in a firm) and intangible (intellectual property), and property rights theory argues that the ownership, which includes residual rights to the benefits of ownership, of productive assets provides a foundation for explaining firms. According to Oliver Hart, one of the leading scholars in this area, a firm without property is just a phantom (Hart, 1995). In situations where ordinary contractual relationships fail, firms arise and the ownership of capital assets puts (collection of) persons in the position to organise production through the purchase of economic factors, including labour (Hart, 1995). Applied to corporate governance and remuneration, this theory provides a supplement to contract theories. The theory claims that legal systems should assign and secure property rights and additionally explains that those who invest in or own productive property and capital of the firm have a privileged position as legal agents to 7 8 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI bargain with other parties such as directors, employees, suppliers and other constituencies. Coase, in his theory of the firm, built a connection between the above discussed property rights and transaction costs. In a world without the latter, the initial assignment of property rights would be irrelevant as each ‘error’ in the assignment of these rights could easily be rescinded by additional transactions. This is the idea of the Coase Theorem for property rights. The applicability of the Coase Theorem to companies is questionable as the idea rests on the assumptions that there are no legal, strategic and informational barriers to bargaining. But in modern firms all these barriers normally exist and make transactions more expensive, that is incur transaction costs. Beyond the Firm and Market Dichotomy Institutional economists like Williamson have further developed Coase’s theory of the firm through a deeper analysis of different forms of contracts. He developed governance structures which can be seen as a spectrum of contracts between the extremes of Coase’s market versus firm analysis. His theory of transaction costs provides answers why firms change organisational structures over time. Modern phenomena such as competition law, merger control as well as outsourcing can be explained with the help of this theory. Concerning the latter, a firm may find that it is cheaper in terms of direct and administrative costs as well as legal liability to conclude an arms-length contract for labour services rather than bearing the cost of hiring employees directly. This influences the size of a firm (which won’t grow) but the outsourced services will expand the general market for those services. In a broader context this has implications on merger control. By suggesting circumstances in which integration (or outsourcing) might be efficient, transaction costs theory influences decisions of firms. This in turn has implications on competition law as vertical and horizontal mergers may disrupt competitive markets and lead to market structures which need regulation to enforce competition. In his theory, Williamson presented the firm and instant market transactions as lying on a spectrum of forms of organisations (‘governance structures’) rather than as simple alternatives. The three forms of intermediate structures are the classical, neo-classical and relational contracts. The classical contract is characterised by full contingency, that is the contract should be as complete as possible, looking for regulations for each uncertainty. The contract should provide a complete guide to the terms of all consequential transactions. Corporate Governance and Remuneration A neo-classical contract, however, leaves some terms open. Here the goal of the parties is not completeness of contracts, but to establish mutually acceptable mechanisms to minimise the costs of leaving contractual terms open. To put it in other words, leaving parts of a contract open about an uncertain future should allow efficient renegotiations at a later stage. But this incompleteness of contracts opens room for exploitation of one of the contractual parties. To assure flexibility whilst minimising the risk of opportunism, special legal devices were developed. These include referees and arbitrators as third parties to resolve disputes as well as external reference points such as stock indices or interest rates. All these devices have one common feature, namely reducing the risk of exploitation of one of the parties. The relational contract as a third governance structure stands for future decision making rather than attempting to make decisions in advance. For the parties involved, the goal is a trade-off in terms of maximising the gains of the transaction whilst trying to minimise transaction costs. The contract itself prescribes the governance structure, its operations and may restrict and place boundaries on its discretion. To avoid a wide degree of discretion, some of the neoclassical safeguards mentioned above may be used. Compared to Coase and his extremes of firms and markets, Williamson’s governance structures can be seen as a spectrum between these boundaries. Given a certain set of transactions, Williamson identified factors for the optimal choice of governance structure. This is influenced by the frequency of transactions as well as the transaction-specificity. Concerning frequency there are likely to be efficiency gains in making long-term arrangements if one party needs a particular resource. A transaction-specific investment arises when one party requires an unusual or idiosyncratic resource. Consequently alternative sources of supply are unlikely to be readily available. As one or both parties make greater investments in the transaction, they are more vulnerable to opportunism by the other party and therefore will try to make satisfactory arrangements covering the future. Incomplete Remuneration Contracts One might now argue that all problems could easily be avoided by writing a complete contract between shareholders and managers. A complete contract is a concept in contract theory that describes an agreement that would specify the respective rights and duties for every possible future state of the world. As it would be prohibitively expensive to write such a complete contract, contracts in the real world are usually incomplete. Just think about a typical employment 9 10 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI contract of a chief executive in a company. It would be impossible to write a contract which makes clear what this executive should do in each future situation. Furthermore, not only that the future remains uncertain, even if a detailed contract could be written, it would be very costly. To avoid confusion, it is necessary to point out that this concerns a contract from an economic perspective. As should be evident from our contract law classes, a contract is a binding agreement between two or more parties to perform certain obligations, whereas a complete contract is one which includes all essentialia negotii. From an economic perspective, a contract is everything which pictures observable states, or, to put it in other words, an instrument which facilitates an exchange of property rights. It is fairly obvious that the definition of an economic contract is much broader and therefore a complete contract more difficult to achieve. It would need explicit regulations to cover every possible state in the future, and to highlight the rights and duties of each party. A complete contract therefore remains a fiction. Basically, there are six reasons why a contract (in economic terms) remains incomplete: firstly, ambiguous diction within the contract. In addition, the parties may have forgotten about regulations for certain points of the contract. Thirdly, despite the awareness of the parties, the costs of bargaining for some issues might be prohibitively high. Asymmetric information is another reason for incompleteness, an area we will discuss in more detail in the next section. Bounded rationality is a concept based on information economics which gives an explanation why contracts are incomplete. It rests on the idea that economic actors do not have perfect information and/or may not be able to process all available data adequately. Therefore, the amount of information plays a crucial role. Think again about the employment contract with the chief executive of a company. Even if it would be possible to foresee the future and write a complete contract for every possible state that may occur, it would be impossible to write such a voluminous contract in time and no party would be able to process all of the information in the contract. Bounded rationality asserts that decision makers are intended to be rational, that is they are goal-oriented and adaptive, but because of human cognitive and emotional architecture, they sometimes fail to be so, even when it comes to important decision making. Finally, the heterogeneity of the market serves an explanation for incompleteness of contracts. If we assume that the firm is a nexus of contracts, that is emphasising the network of different kind of contract made by individuals to compose a firm, the incompleteness of contracts has substantial consequences. As contracts are incomplete, parties have to agree on the allocation of control rights for all situations that are not Corporate Governance and Remuneration specified in the contract. The resulting institutional design constitutes what we describe as corporate governance. It assigns control rights for the use of the firm’s assets. Agency Theory One of the key elements of agency theory is opportunism, a point stressed heavily by Williamson. If one party (the agent) has discretion which she is supposed to exercise for the benefit of another (the principal), she may exercise it to maximise her own utility instead. This is inefficient where the resulting loss to the principal exceeds the benefits of the agent. If the agent is rewarded by the principal on a basis which does not correlate her effort to the reward, the agent may not have the incentive to exercise the highest effort. The costs resulting from this agency problem includes both the loss of potential benefits and the costs of measures designed to reduce the loss of potential benefits. Michael Jensen and William Meckling (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) identified these costs and termed them agency costs. Applied to corporate governance, legal protection against fraud and other forms of dishonesty may provide some protection. But economic analysis suggests that internalising some of these market transactions into a firm may substantially reduce the risks of opportunism. But despite reducing some of the costs of opportunism in the market, the special structure of firms creates other forms of opportunism in those entrusted with economic responsibility to manage the firm. Agency theory is based on the incompleteness of contracts and the separation of ownership (shareholders) and control (management), which is the main characteristic of corporations nowadays. Though the resulting problems were already mentioned by Adam Smith in the 18th century, they were prominently highlighted by Adolf Berle and Gardiner Means in the 1930s. They argued that a company does not behave in accordance with the classical model, which assumed that despite the management of companies by agents, these agents act in the best interest of the owners of the firm. As a consequence the owners would ensure that the agents do act in their interest. But this idea, the stewardship theory, assumes that managers do not necessarily work only in their personal interest. Managers are seen as ‘honorable wealth builders’ and can therefore be instructed with the management of corporations. Berle and Means argued that the interests of managers and shareholder may diverge and that shareholders would not act as owners, exacerbating the agency problem. Concerning the first 11 12 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI argument, the stockholders (principals) want their agents (managers) to maximise the value of the shares. But the manager may be better off pursuing some other strategy and therefore acting opportunistically. Despite the law asserting that an agent has a fiduciary duty to serve the principal’s interest, the agent will also tend to serve their own self-interests. If we think about staff, sales, size of the firm, remuneration, etc., being an input-vector, we can assume that the vector which maximises the profits of the firm does not necessarily maximise the manager’s wealth. We can assume that most managers will choose the vector which maximises their own wealth. The recent financial scandals with stories about greedy managers all over the world confirm this picture. On the other hand, the second point of Berle and Means should not be forgotten. Due to the shareholders’ perceived ‘limited liability’ and the shareholders’ inability in practice to control the management, the agency conflict is exacerbated. Limited liability means that a company is responsible for its own debts and liabilities. Shareholders are only liable to the company to pay up their share capital. In other words, they are sharing the company’s profits, but they are not responsible for all of its losses. Limited liability, so the argument goes, shifts the risk of business failure from the company’s shareholders to its creditors. Both, the companies’ owners and managers therefore may have too much of an incentive to take risks, as the creditors would be the party which would suffer most in case of a bankruptcy. This could result in an inefficient use of resources. The diversity and large number of shareholders in a typical public company cannot or will not exert effective control over the management for various reasons such as the existence of a coordination problem. This includes problems of different interests of shareholders as well as bringing together shareholders with the same beliefs. In general we refer to the collective action problem, where it might be rational for each of the shareholders not to engage in control. Just think about yourself being one of many small shareholders of a public company. Your incentive for attending the general meeting of the company or exercising control in any other way is minimised as the transaction costs of controlling (in monetary terms as well as time) exceed the benefits. You need to spend time in reading bulky reports of the company, the general meeting might not be close to your home, you have to spend a whole day at the meeting and all of these costs might exceed the benefits you get from voting your rights. It is therefore rational not to engage in the control of the company. With the imminent problem of free riding, that is each shareholder wants to avoid the costs of control by hoping that the other shareholders are exercising the necessary control, this leads to a collective action problem. Each of the shareholders is acting Corporate Governance and Remuneration rational, when not exercising control. But this leads to a situation where nobody controls the management at all. All this means that management’s incentive as to how they exercise their powers of management may not be aligned with the interests of the company’s shareholders, giving rise to manifold economic problems, such as various forms of opportunism. Due to the consequent danger of the inefficient use of resources there is a justification for correction. To reinforce the classical model of the company where the interests of the owners and managers of the company are aligned, regulatory measures mainly in the form of laws and codes are used. These include strengthening shareholders’ voting rights, for example with the help of minority shareholder rights. In addition the accountability of the management to shareholders is achieved by imposing penalties on managers when they behave wrongly. Furthermore, enforced publicity and disclosure should reduce the asymmetric information between the parties and therefore lead to better control. All of these measures are reflected in corporate governance reforms around the world (Mallin, 2012). As it is impossible to write complete contracts between the different parties, a first best contract does not exist and leaves a gap which should be filled by corporate governance. All control forms involve agency costs; therefore, corporate governance revolves around finding the control which minimises agency costs. Agency theory relies on the idea of writing a contract to align the incentives of both parties involved. In other words, it tries to strike a balance between providing incentives for managers and guaranteeing a maximisation of shareholder value. To achieve this goal, monitoring refers on the one hand to strategies of managerial supervision and oversight to improve performance. This explains the existence of board systems and other external monitoring such as rating agencies and institutional investors. On the other hand, highpowered incentive contracts such as shares and stock-options to remunerate directors were implemented in most companies over the last years. In Chapter 2 we will have a closer look at the pitfalls of these remuneration schemes. For the moment being, two problems of asymmetric information in firms shall be presented. We distinguish between moral hazard (hidden action) and adverse selection (hidden information). ADVERSE SELECTION Adverse selection describes an agency problem where asymmetric information exists before the transaction occurs, leading to an inefficient allocation of resources. Originally, the term adverse selection 13 14 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI came from the insurance industry. It describes a situation of private information where the insured are more likely to suffer a loss than the uninsured. As an example, think of two groups of car drivers. On the one hand, the careful and risk-averse drivers and on the other hand the reckless, risk-taking drivers. An insurer selling car policies cannot easily assign the different drivers to these groups, so each of them pays the same premium. But reckless, risk-taking car drivers are much more likely causing damages than the careful, riskaverse ones. Consequently, the car insurance is a better deal for the beneficiaries of the reckless drivers. As the insurance companies do not want to lose money, they will set the premiums accordingly high. This in turn may result in a situation where careful drives may want to go uninsured (as the premium is too high for them) and only the high-risk drivers remain on the market, as they benefit from the insurance. Economists like George Akerlof applied the concept of adverse selection into markets other than insurance, where similar asymmetries of information may exist. Applied to corporate governance, investors very often face problems of adverse selection. When buying a share an investor usually has incomplete information about the management of the company in which she intends to invest. In his seminal 1973 article Michael Spence (born in 1943) proposed a way how two parties could get around the problem of adverse selection. The idea is having the informed party sending a signal that would reveal some piece of relevant information to the uninformed party. The latter interprets the signal and adjusts her purchasing behaviour accordingly. In our example, the disclosure of information from companies could be interpreted as signals to the stock market. Another way to overcome adverse selection is screening. Here the uninformed party takes actions to separate different types of informed parties. In the example, the investor could try to collect data about the risk of each company and adjust the investment accordingly. MORAL HAZARD Compared to adverse selection, moral hazard describes an agency problem which exists after a transaction is made, leading to an inefficient allocation of resources. The term moral hazard as well has its origin in the insurance industry. Applied to corporate governance, the shareholder-manager agency relationship is a good example of moral hazard. Directors of a company may, after signing their employment contract, start acting in a way which benefits themselves but not the shareholders. Corporate Governance and Remuneration This leads to all of the problems discussed above with managers acting opportunistically. Monitoring and incentive compatible contracts are two ways to overcome moral hazard. Monitoring builds on the straightforward idea that opportunistically acting managers will stop doing so if they are detected and penalised. But monitoring itself is on the one hand very costly and consequentially reduces the flexibility of companies, a fact which is very often neglected. Incentive compatible contracts, however, are a cheaper way to reduce the moral hazard problem. With the help of incentives, managers should be motivated to align their interests to the ones of their shareholders. Bonuses and stockoptions are just two measures to achieve this goal. Unfortunately, these measures are themselves subject to new problems like shortterm profit maximisation of managers to cash-in their bonuses and stocks, without thinking too much about the longer term. Another problem, which became especially immanent during the financial scandals, is that managers used their creativity in accounting to reach their bonus threshold. Although most of the literature puts emphasis on this ‘classical’ agency problem between the suppliers of equity the shareholders and management, agency conflicts can arise between various groups of stakeholders in a firm. DIFFERENT AGENCY CONFLICTS In addition to this relationship, the conflicts between majority and minority shareholders as well as between shareholders and other stakeholders should be mentioned. The latter became prominent in the literature as the shareholder-stakeholder debate or Corporate Social Responsibility. The conflict between majority and minority shareholders is typical for companies with a concentrated ownership structure. The conflict revolves around the term of ‘private benefits of control’, highlighted by Lucian Bebchuk in 1994. The question is to what extent the majority shareholders of a company can enjoy additional benefits from the company which are not shared with the other shareholders. In this context the purchase of shares below market value or the change of a product mix should be mentioned. Mark Roe describes in his 2003 book the effects of corporate governance in social democracies and illustrates how political ideas can be used to identify the conflicts between majority and minority shareholders. Traditionally, some corporate governance systems have to deal with this conflict if we just think about the power of banks or the state. Both, banks and the state as owners of companies may follow other interests than the rest of the shareholders do. 15 16 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI The third conflict is between shareholders and other interest groups such as employees and creditors and concerns the classical shareholder versus stakeholder differentiation. The stakeholder model claims that the firm should serve wider interests of stakeholders rather than shareholders only. Stakeholders such as employees, creditors, suppliers, customers and local communities have long-term relationships with the firm and therefore affect its long-term success. The company is seen as an entity embedded within the society it operates and therefore should take care of it. In the meantime there is a huge debate all over the world about whether it is the duty of company law in general and corporate governance in particular to solve this conflict between shareholders and other stakeholders or, what the Anglo-Saxon literature and practice favours, that the legislator should deal with this problem exclusively within labour law and other social legislation. Management and Collective Production Whatever one might think about agency theory, the separation of the two functions, shareholder and management, makes economic sense. The shareholders on the one hand provide equity capital together with subsequent risk-bearing, whereas professional managers on the other hand do not have to possess capital and riskbearing expertise but provide managerial expertise. As management can be performed more efficiently in a small, cohesive body, it is better to have a professional management than let a large number of shareholders decide on the day-to-day business. The risks associated with providing equity capital, however, can be borne more efficiently when shared among a large number of people. These, in turn, can protect themselves by holding diversified portfolios of investment. Armen Alchian and Harold Demsetz took up the structure of companies and drew attention to the analysis of team production (1972), itself an extension of the earlier work by Coase. According to this theory, the firm is preferred to the market because of the benefits of team production. Nevertheless, team production always involves a metering problem. Where parties are engaged in some form of collective business activity, there may be difficulties in measuring the contribution made by each participant and matching their reward to their actual contribution. The rewards of the participants of the team may be, to a greater or lesser extent, determined not by their individual effort, but by their collective effort as a team. The metering problem therefore presents a fertile soil for a form of opportunism known as ‘shirking’. In a team where each member’s reward is not fully related to their actual input, the member has too Corporate Governance and Remuneration little incentive to contribute fully to the team’s activities. However, the incentive to obtain utility in other ways (to shirk) is increasing. As the members enjoy the full benefit of their shirking, but share the costs with other members of the team, shirking is a common moral hazard problem in many firms. Obviously this theory is based on certain assumptions about people’s motivation in working and their affinity to shirk. As a result, shirking is more likely to be a problem for larger ‘teams’ where shirking is less likely to be detected and where members are less motivated by a sense of loyalty to their entity. Corporate governance, in this context, should try to minimise the scope for shirking by all participants and conserve the gains from using a firm. In theory, this should be easy to implement as the team members are likely to gain more from less shirking by other team members than they lose from their resulting inability to shirk. Responses to shirking are the reduction or removal of the metering problem and monitoring in the form of management. The former may be possible if we think about many modern trends in organisation such as outsourcing, franchising and the replacement of employees with self-employed contractors. In these entire organisation forms, the traditional team and the problems related to it are reduced. If shirking undermines the gains from team production, Alchian and Demsetz argue, the efficient solution is monitoring with the help of a hierarchical management structure. This includes a central manager who coordinates the individual contributions or inputs. Being the recipient of the team’s residual income, she takes all the surplus profits and bears any losses. Under these conditions the manager has the optimum incentive to maximise the output of the team. To explain management hierarchies with the help of team production we assume that the monitors themselves are opportunistic and therefore exposed to shirking. Consequently the monitors need monitoring themselves. To avoid problems with the implication that the monitors at the top of the hierarchy have no monitors, incentive systems need to be established. This is one of the tasks of a good corporate governance system. For company law implications the theory of team production is useful in highlighting problems in the hierarchical structure of companies. If the different monitors do not keep in mind what is best for the company but misuse monitoring to gain private benefits, shareholders should enjoy some rights. They should be able to replace individuals or whole boards that are not monitoring on their behalf. To impede fraudulent and unethical managerial behaviour, levers of control are implemented. Four levers of control are mentioned in literature (Horngren, Datar, & Rajan, 2012). Diagnostic control systems are implemented to discover fraudulent activities, 17 18 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI unethical behaviour and misappropriation of funds. Boundary systems are codes of conduct that dictate ethical behaviour. Belief systems are the mission, purpose and core values of a company. Interactive control systems are formal information systems used by managers to focus the attention and learning of the company on key strategic issues using different analyses and tools like Strength, Weaknesses, Opportunities, and Threats analysis and Critical Success Factors analysis. Outlook and Conclusion The market and the firm are two alternative forms of allocating scarce resources. The firm exists because in many cases it is more efficient to organise production in a non-price environment. Coase’s transaction-cost theory was one of the first neo-classical attempts to define the firm theoretically in relation to the market. This theory was later extended by Williamson through a deeper analysis of different forms of contracts. He developed governance structures which can be seen as a spectrum of contracts between the extremes of markets and firms. Alchian and Demsetz’s analysis of team production is another extension of the earlier work by Coase. By looking at the common elements of all of these theories it is obvious that they provide negative reasons for the existence of the firm. All theories revolve around the existence of firms to overcome inefficiencies. None of these offer a positive theory of the firm, with functions like generating value. But Demsetz himself in his 1988 article considered the positive function of the firm as an efficient device for accumulating, storing and using information. Whereas most theories of the firm are primarily concerned with predicting the behaviour of firms in external markets, the last two decades brought forward a knowledge-based theory of the firm as an alternative view. Knowledge is seen as the most important resource of a firm. This includes all the intellectual abilities and knowledge possessed by employees, as well as their capacity to learn and acquire more knowledge. Thus, knowledge resources include what employees have mastered, as well as their potential for adapting and acquiring new information. These resources are seen as being extremely important for sustaining competitive advantage in today’s environment. Participants and ‘input-providers’ are viewed as assets rather than sources of inefficiency. Based on the idea that the firm is a nexus of contracts, the incomplete contract literature helps us to understand the need for corporate governance and remuneration. If it would be possible to fix the relationships between the owners and the managers of a company contractually and consistently, there would be no divergences Corporate Governance and Remuneration between the two parties. But as the costs of writing such contracts are prohibitively high, the abstract structure of corporate governance has to be introduced. Complete contracts, which do not exist in the real world, would also provide a solution to the agency theory. If one party (the agent) has discretion which one is supposed to exercise for the benefit of another (the principal), they may instead exercise it to maximise their own utility. The shareholder-manager relationship is the classical example for such an agency relationship. Agency theory results from information asymmetries between parties, where especially the concepts of adverse selection and moral hazard are of relevance in a corporate governance and remuneration framework. References Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for “Lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488500. Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777795. Bebchuk, L. (1994). Efficient and inefficient sales of corporate control. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 957993. Berle, A., & Means, G. (1932). The modern corporation and private property. New York, NY: Macmillan. Braendle, U., & Katsos, J. (2013). How to control the controller CEO compensation and motivation. Corporate Ownership and Control, 11(1), 2431. Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386405. Demsetz, H. (1988). The theory of the firm revisited. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4, 141161. Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 5774. Fama, E. (1980). Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88, 288307. Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983, June). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 301325. Hart, O. (1995). Firms, contracts, and financial structures. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Horngren, C. T., Datar, S. M., & Rajan, M. (2012). Cost accounting: A managerial emphasis. Boston, MA: Prentice Hall. Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal Financial Economics, 3, 305360. Mallin, C. (2012). Institutional investors: The vote as a tool of governance. Journal of Management and Governance, 16(2), 177196. Mäntysaari, P. (2012). Organising the firm: Theories of commercial law, corporate governance and corporate law. Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag. Ostrom, E. (1999). Coping with tragedies of the commons. Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 493535. 19 20 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI Roe, M. (2003). Political determinants of corporate governance: Political context, corporate impact. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Smith, A. (1776). The wealth of nations. London: Methuen & Co., Ltd. Spence, M. (1973). Job market signalling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 355374. Spulber, D. F. (1990). Market microstructure: Intermediaries and the theory of the firm. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Williamson, O. (1979). Transaction-cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22, 233261. CHAPTER 2 Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation Udo C. Braendle and John E. Katsos M oney may not be everything, but it is certainly something that can easily be measured, in contrast to power or prestige. One of the main control mechanisms that shareholders have used to rein in rogue managers is compensation. Through a combination of intrinsic and extrinsic incentives, shareholders have tried to provide the right balance to motivate senior managers to perform at their best. Shareholders have often failed in achieving this balance through compensation. In this chapter, we argue that this failure is not the result of compensation packages as such, but on the focus of compensation packages on extrinsic motivators such as pay-for-performance bonuses and stock options. Instead, the focus of compensation packages should be on cultivating intrinsic motivators such as firing and prestige. Introduction Money may not be everything, but it is certainly something that can easily be measured, in contrast to power or prestige. Executive contracts are supposed to provide explicit and implicit incentives that align the interests of managers with those of shareholders. The empirical literature has focused on the sensitivity of pay (explicit incentives) and the dismissal of executives (implicit incentives) to corporate performance. The high payments were justified with the extraordinary gains in wealth shareholders received through most of the 1990s. Incentive pay was characterised as one of the 21 22 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS driving forces for the high market valuation of US corporations (Kaplan and Holmstrom, 2001). But recently, while stock prices decrease and executive pay does not, a rethinking of the compensation scheme is needed. Switzerland with its successful ‘people’s initiative against fat-cat pay’ is the latest example of this trend (The Economist, 2013). All forms of control by shareholders over management involve agency costs; therefore, corporate governance revolves around finding control mechanisms that reduce agency costs. To achieve this goal, monitoring refers, on the one hand, to strategies of managerial supervision and, on the other, oversight to improve performance (Braendle & Noll, 2004). This explains the existence of board systems (Kostyuk, 2006) and other external monitoring such as rating agencies and institutional investors. On the other hand, highpowered incentive contracts, such as shares and stock options, were implemented to remunerate directors in most companies over the last years (Armstrong, Ittner, & Larcker, 2012). One of the main control mechanisms that shareholders have used to rein in rogue managers is compensation. Through a combination of intrinsic and extrinsic incentives, shareholders have tried to provide the right balance to motivate senior managers to perform at their best. Shareholders have often failed in achieving this balance through compensation. In this chapter, we argue that this failure is not the result of compensation packages as such, but on the focus of compensation packages on extrinsic motivators such as pay-forperformance bonuses and stock options. Instead, the focus of compensation packages should be on cultivating intrinsic motivators such as firing and prestige. We begin by examining the existing literature and paradigms on agency theory and managerial compensation. Next, we examine the existing literature on employee motivation. This literature indicates that intrinsic motivation leads to higher performance in non-programmable tasks and that extrinsic motivators like pay very often ‘crowd-out’ the effect of intrinsic motivators on the performance of employees, leading to poorer performance in spite of higher pay. In the third section, we analyse how the employee motivation literature might inform the current agency theory debate. We find that, based on the existing literature, shareholders may obtain better performance from their managers by reducing their level of pay, but increasing extrinsic motivators through compensation packages. In the final section, we suggest some areas for further research in the field to empirically establish connections between intrinsic motivation and performance among senior managers. We also note several limitations and how they might be addressed in future studies. Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation Agency Theory and Managerial Compensation The principal-agent model is based on economic models related to the employment relationship (Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1990)). The underlying concept is that the principal wants the agent to do something on her behalf and therefore must motivate the agent to do so. That motivation can come in two forms: extrinsic and intrinsic. Extrinsic motivation is what we traditionally think of in the agency theory context and it takes the form of motivators outside of an individual such as pay. Intrinsic motivation is inside of an individual and usually derives from goal identification or task involvement (Fuller & Jensen, 2002). Managers do not necessarily maximise shareholder value (Mueller, 2003). As most of them own only tiny fractions of their companies’ shares (if at all), the separation between ownership and control leads to a principal-agent problem (Bebchuk, Cremers, & Peyer, 2011). The stockholders (principals) want their managers (agents) to maximise the value of the company and its shares. But managers may be better off pursuing a different strategy. We can expect the utility-maximising manager to increase those elements in an input vector that gives him/her personal utility (Conyon, 2006). In other words, he/she will use some of his/her residual income to engage in on-the-job consumption, up to a point where the marginal utility from additional discretionary expenditures is near zero. The managerial-discretion literature put forward some hypotheses concerning what it is that managers consume in excess: leisure (Edmans & Gabaix, 2009), sales (Baumol, 1967), staff and emoluments (Williamson, 1979), growth (Marris, 1963, 1998) and income (Melis, Carta, & Gaia, 2012). One of the key elements of agency theory is opportunism, a point stressed by Williamson (1979). If the agent has discretion which he/she is supposed to exercise for the benefit of another (the principal), he/she may exercise it to maximise his/her own utility instead. This is inefficient where the resulting loss to the principal exceeds the benefits to the agent. If the agent is rewarded by the principal on a basis which does not correlate his/her effort to the reward, the agent may not have the incentive to exercise the highest effort. The costs resulting from this agency problem includes both the loss of potential benefits and the costs of measures designed to reduce the loss of potential benefits. Jensen and Meckling (1976) identified these costs and termed them ‘agency costs’. Agency theory is based on the incompleteness of contracts and the separation of ownership and control. Though the resulting 23 24 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS problems were already mentioned by Adam Smith in the 18th century, they were prominently highlighted by Berle and Means (1932). Due to the shareholders’ perceived ‘limited liability’ and the shareholders’ inability in practice to control the management, the agency conflict is exacerbated. In academic circles, the shareholder and stakeholder visions of the firm have been battling for supremacy since at least the 1930s (Coase, 1937; Dodd, 1932). In general, the shareholder vision of the firm sees managers as being entrusted with large amounts of ownership money and that regulation and shareholder control through directors are the only means to stop management from abusing this trust (Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Muth & Donaldson, 1998). Again, generally, the stakeholder, or ‘otherregarding’, vision of the firm sees managers and directors as intermediaries among different groups with interest beyond just financial in the firm (Evan & Freeman, 1988). Shareholders are only liable to the company to pay up their share capital. In other words, they are sharing the company’s profits, but they are not responsible for all of its losses. Limited liability, so the argument goes, shifts the risk of business failure from the company’s shareholders to its creditors. Both, the companies’ owners and managers, therefore may have too much of an incentive to take risks, as the creditors would be the party which would suffer most in case of a bankruptcy. This could result in an inefficient use of resources (Bris & Welch, 2005). The diversity and large number of shareholders in a typical public company cannot or will not exert effective control over the management for various reasons such as the existence of a coordination problem (Ingley, Mueller, & Cocks, 2011). This includes problems of different interests of shareholders as well as bringing together shareholders with the same beliefs. In general, we refer to the collective action problem, where it might be rational for each of the shareholders not to engage in control (Braendle & Noll, 2004). Due to the consequent danger of the inefficient use of resources there is a justification for correction. To reinforce the classical model of the company, where the interests of the owners and managers of the company are aligned, regulatory measures mainly in the form of laws and codes are used. These include strengthening shareholders’ voting rights, for example bolstering minority shareholder rights (Braendle, 2006). In addition, the accountability of the management to shareholders is achieved by imposing penalties on managers when they behave wrongly (Bergstresser & Philippon, 2006). Furthermore, enforced publicity and disclosure should reduce the asymmetric information between the parties and therefore lead to better control (Braendle & Noll, 2005). All of these measures are reflected in corporate governance reforms around the world (Mallin, 2012). Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation Public companies are not required to have shareholders personally vote their shares because the number of shareholders is too large and their locations too diverse. As a result, shareholders instead often vote by proxy. Traditionally, access to the proxy ballot was only provided to senior management and board of directors. Recently, however, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) granted shareholders access to the proxy ballot in order to nominate at most one director (SEC, 2010). So-called ‘say on pay’ votes are a means of giving shareholders the ability to challenge management compensation packages. The recently passed Dodd-Frank Financial Reform bill (2010) requires public companies to have ‘say on pay’ votes. These votes are advisory in that directors are not bound by the decision of shareholders with respect to executive compensation. The major goals of allowing proxy access to shareholders and ‘say on pay’ votes were to increase shareholder democracy and make management more responsive to the needs of others whether these are shareholders or stakeholders (SEC, 2010, p. 331). The purpose of increasing shareholder democracy and making management more responsive is presumably to reduce the amount of excessive risk-taking and poor ethical and legal decisions made by executives of public companies over the past decade. Yet the poor decisions of company management and their excessive risk-taking seem to be more directly attributed to short-termism. Short-termism is ‘the obsession with short-term results by investors, asset management firms and corporate managers’ (Krehmeyer, Orsagh, & Schacht, 2006). Theorists of multiple persuasions see short-termism as a major problem that might be fixed through changing executive compensation structure, likely via ‘say on pay’ and proxy access rule changes (along with other proposals). Theorists traditionally associated with the shareholder (Fuller & Jensen, 2002) and stakeholder (Evan & Freeman, 1988) visions agree not only that short-termism is a problem, but also that it must urgently be fixed. Though law and management theorists have come up with a variety of proposals to solve short-termism, most relate, in some way, to simply adjusting the criteria by which senior management is incentivised (Bebchuk et al., 2011). Though executive compensation is certainly not the only facet of corporate governance, it is easier to measure compensation of executives than the relative power or prestige of being the CEO of one company or another. So it is not surprising that much of the literature which has tested for the effects of managerial discretion has looked at managerial compensation. Executive compensation in the United States has risen continuously since 1970, with the bulk of the increase stemming from granted option plans (Conyon & Murphy, 2000). 25 26 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS BASE SALARY The base salaries for executive officers are in most cases determined by benchmarks based on industry salary surveys. These surveys typically adjust for company size, reinforces the observed relation between compensation and firm size. Even though base salaries only make up a declining percentage of the total compensation, they are key component of executive employment contracts. As these salaries are fixed, risk-averse executives will naturally prefer a dollar increase in the base salary than in the variable bonus compensation. BONUS Almost any company offers an annual bonus plan based on performance over the year, covering all of its top executives. Despite heterogeneity across industries and companies, executive bonus plans can be categorised in terms of three basic components: performance measure, performance standards and the structure of the pay-performance relation (Murphy, 1999). Usually no bonus is paid until a minimum performance hurdle is reached commonly 80% of a budgeted target. Exceeding this hurdle, the manager receives a bonus, which increases as performance mounts. Target bonuses are paid for achieving the performance standard, and there is usually a ‘cap’ on bonuses paid 120% of the target is common. The value between the minimum hurdle bonus and the cap is named the ‘incentive zone’. The target is normally somewhere in the middle of this incentive zone. Companies normally use accounting elements, like revenues, net income, EBIT (earnings before interest & tax), etc., to measure the performance. The most common non-financial performance measures used in annual incentive plans is to quantify the deviation from ex-ante specified objectives, customer satisfaction or plant security. As long as the managers believe they can make the minimum hurdle, they will naturally try to increase performance by legitimate means or, if push comes to shove, by illegitimate ones. According to the point on the pay line, they will do this either by pushing expenses into the future or by shifting profits from present to the future. Some companies even went further. The Swiss bank UBS implemented in 2008 the bonus-malus plan to remunerate its top executives (UBS, 2013). The main characteristic of the plan is that the bonus pay out is spread over several periods and that in the case underperformance a delayed pay out can be reduced or even set to zero. Underperformance is mostly based on the profit and loss results of the bank. Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation STOCK OPTIONS Stock options are contracts which give the management the right to buy a share of stock at a pre-specified exercise price for a perspecified term. Stock options are a form of deferred compensation, that is, an arrangement in which a portion of an employee’s income is paid out at a date after which that income is actually earned. These options normally become ‘vested’, that is exercisable, over time: for example, 20% might become vested in each of the five years following grant. These options are non-tradable, and the exercise price is often ‘indexed’ to the industry or markets. The mechanical explanation for the explosion in stock options, although unsatisfactory to economists, is rooted in institutional details on granting practices and exacerbated by the bull markets at the end of the 1990s and the beginning of the 21st century. Therefore stock options which are not indexed to the relevant industry are in the line of fire, as managers can free ride on the positive temper on stock markets and profit from an environment where their own performance does not matter, or the managers will try to increase the stock price in short term to cash in instead of implementing a longterm strategy. Agents can game the competition system when they have multiple instruments at their control. This incentive problem has become known as multitasking (Baker, 1992; Holmstrom & Milgrom, 1990), where compensation on any subset of tasks will result in a reallocation of activities towards those that are directly compensated and away from the uncompensated activities. Using ratios like sales margin or return on assets as performance measure is dangerous, as it motivates gaming. That is because managers can increase the measure in two ways: by either increasing the numerator or decreasing the denominator. As we can see, both schemes are not incentive-compatible and therefore lead to manipulations. The only way to solve the problem is according to Jensen (2001) to remove all the kinks from the payfor-performance line shown above. His solutions are linear incentives and he convicts nonlinearly, especially convex incentives as those will increase the variability. But it is not easy to make a switch to adopt a linear compensation system. Target-based bonuses are deeply ingrained in minds of managers. For incentive compensation to work, corporate boards must choose both the right measures and the right levels of performance. In principle, stock options employ the right measure of performance for corporate executives, but they do not set the right level. Shareholders expect boards to reward management for achieving superior returns that is for returns equal or better than those earned by the company’s peer group or by broader market indexes. Stock options are often not indexed and therefore do not provide this possibility. 27 28 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS In the early 1990s it was the consensus view in the literature that the sensitivity of pay to performance in the United States was too low (Jensen & Murphy, 1990). According to these studies, executives did not receive enough cash after good corporate performance and did not incur sufficient losses, through dismissal, after poor performance. The same result was observed in other countries like Japan (Kaplan, 1994). The change in executive wealth normalised by the change in firm value appears small and falls by a factor with firm size, but the value of the CEO’s equity stake is large and increases with firm size. But the probability of dismissal remained unchanged between 1970 and 1995 (Murphy, 1999). The use of equity-based compensation and pay-performance sensitivity has risen in other countries as well, and in the United Kingdom the percentage of companies with an option plan has risen from 10% in 1979 to over 90% in 1985 (Main, 1999). It is hard to see just how changing executive compensation requirements to be more closely linked to actual performance through ‘say on pay’ votes (Bebchuk et al., 2011) will have any effect on the ‘vicious cycle’ created by short-termism (Lipton, Lorsch, & Mirvis, 2009). It is also hard to see why boards, shareholders and legal theorists alike have largely ignored the rather large body of social psychology research that suggests that monetary rewards for performing a task (e.g. achieving the highest quarterly profit for a firm) actually decreases the effort put into a job that requires the accomplishment of multiple tasks by a performer for example a CEO (Deci, Koestner, & Ryan, 1999). If we accept the agency theory of the firm, that is that management is simply the agent to its principals (Jensen & Meckling, 1976), that is shareholders, then we would also, by extension, apply the research that relates to compensation of other employees in agency relationships. Social science research has also produced fairly convincing evidence that rewarding non-manual workers with explicit rewards for explicit tasks decreases performance for any non-rewarded task (Baker, 1992; Holmstrom & Milgrom, 1990). Furthermore, incentivebased contracts for agents specifically reduce an agent’s motivation to succeed in fulfilling their contract (Sliwka, 2003). It shouldn’t be surprising then that when management is paid largely in accordance with the success or failure of a company’s stock price, it would do so to the detriment of other important needs such as long-term shareholder wealth maximisation and the interests of stakeholders. This research thus suggests that management and law scholars might be focusing on fixing a system that is unable to actually capture what actually motivates senior management to act in the best Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation interests of shareholders or stakeholders. Employees who are intrinsically motivated to do their jobs well do not need extrinsic motivators to succeed in their jobs. They simply need sufficient pay. During the 1950s and 1960s, senior management pay at public companies was substantially less linked to performance than it is today, yet firm growth was substantially stronger then than now (Frydman & Saks, 2007). If we take all of the research in this context seriously, we could easily come to a conclusion that is directly opposite from existing proposals to re-focus senior management on ‘better’ priorities eliminate pay-for-performance entirely and simply provide pay that is commensurate with the job. Employee Motivation Research on motivation within the psychology and social science literature has been pursued since at least the 1940s (Fuller & Jensen, 2002; Maslow, 1947). The prevailing view regarding motivation is that incentives are often a great motivator. Motivators themselves fall into two categories. Extrinsic motivation is that which comes from outside an individual. Extrinsic motivation has been found to sharpen focus on individuals and allow them to accomplish manual tasks substantially faster than without incentives targeting extrinsic motivation (Deci, Koestner, & Ryan, 1999). The most common incentive in the principal-agent relationship is an external motivator, namely, salary. In fact, all or most of the executive compensation and economics literature focus on extrinsic motivators. Only recently have economists and agency theorists had their attention drawn to the potential power of intrinsic motivation, the second category of motivation. Intrinsic motivation is most often based on social norms, like reciprocity and fairness, that drive individuals to achieve some goal or task internal to themselves, even if the perceived benefits are to one’s community or society (Fehr et al., 2007). A robust set of research in psychology and behavioural economics indicates that extrinsic motivation (i.e. pay-for-performance) is counter-productive to success in a non-manual (i.e. thinking) task (Deci, Koestner, & Ryan, 1999). A linked finding is that intrinsic and extrinsic motivation ‘crowd’ one another out and individuals only have a certain ‘pool’ of motivation that they can draw from and too much of one type of motivation will force out the other. In other words, too much extrinsic motivation, like pay, will reduce the likelihood that individuals will be motivated intrinsically, for instance by a desire to reciprocate goodwill. 29 30 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS Current Intrinsic Motivator: Takeover Threats Managers may behave opportunistically as we have seen above. In addition, agents in agent-principal relationships, including corporate executives, are often only motivated with extrinsic incentives, such as salary and stock options. However, takeover, as one major intrinsic motivational tool to encourage executives to do their best work, does not exist within current executive pay contracts. In a zero transaction costs world even a slight deviation of a company’s market value from its potential maximum would lead someone to purchase a controlling interest in it and remove the management, alter its policies and claim the wealth gain from bringing the company to its maximum value (Mueller, 2003). This threat of a takeover was the chief constraint on managerial pursuit of growth, but sufficiently loose to allow managers to deviate significantly from shareholders’ wealth-maximising policies (Marris, 1963). The term ‘market for corporate control’ was introduced later on to describe this process, and it was argued that this ‘market’ did provide sufficient discipline to constrain managers effectively. When Marris discussed this process, one of the most radical mechanisms for disciplining managers, hostile takeovers (Becht, Bolton, & Roell, 2002), were sufficiently rare. This mechanism is highly disruptive and costly and therefore seldom used. On this issue, the analysis by Scharfstein (1988) stands out. Building on insights of Grossman and Hart (1986), one considers the ex-ante financial contracting problem between a financier and a manager. This contract specifies a state-contingent compensation scheme for the manager to induce optimal effort provision. In addition the contract allows for ex-post takeovers. The important observation made by Scharfstein is that even if the firm can commit to an ex-ante optimal contract, this contract is generally inefficient and will induce too few hostile takeovers on average. If hostile takeovers are a disciplining device for management, they should predominantly affect poorly performing firms. But this prediction is not borne out by the empirical literature. Successful US takeover targets are smaller than other companies, but that’s the only difference from their peers (Comment & Schwert, 1995). Furthermore, if hostile takeovers should correct managerial failure and enhance the efficiency, the value of the bidder and the target under joint control should be larger than the value of the bidder and the target separately. The empirical literature neither supports this prediction (Andrade, Mitchell, & Stafford, 2001; Burkart, 1999). Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation Therefore, takeovers do not seem to be an efficient measure to guarantee behaviour of the management in the sense of the shareholders. Well-Balanced Packages Agency theory predicts that incentive pay and takeover threats are substitutes (Kole, 1997). This finding matches the findings of motivation theory which suggest that intrinsic and extrinsic motivators ‘crowd’ one another out. Moreover, agency theory predicts that incentive pay should be tied to performance relative to comparable firms, not to absolute performance. Early studies found that changes in the CEO cash compensation were negatively related to market performance, but positively related to firm performance (Gibbson & Murphy, 1990). Equity-based compensation, in contrast, is not corrected most of the time for market stock index movements, consequently leading to a solid rejection of the relative performance evaluation hypothesis in all recent surveys due to accounting problems, tax considerations, difficulties in obtaining performance date from competitors (Abowd & Kaplan, 1999; Bebchuk, Fried, & Walker, 2001; Murphy, 1999). Agency theory can be used to determine the optimal exercise price of granted options. The options with an exercise price equal to the company’s stock price, which are very common in practice, are a clear contradiction of the predictions of this theory (Bebchuk et al., 2001). Theory also predicts that incentive schemes and the adoption of the latter should result in an increase in shareholder wealth. The latest empirical literature generally rejects this prediction, whereas earlier event studies generally support it (Habib & Ljungqvist, 2001). Furthermore, firms subject to blockholder monitoring are less likely to implement stock option plans (Kole, 1997), because more discipline substitutes for more sensitivity of pay. Managements protected by anti-takeover laws or anti-takeover amendments provide more incentive pay to compensate for less discipline from hostile takeovers, while in the United Kingdom takeover threats are higher while incentive pay and the level of pay are lower than in the United States (Conyon & Murphy, 2000). However, this theory is not consistent with what we observe. Companies in industries with more disciplining takeovers should therefore pay less, while in fact they pay more. In addition to these explicit incentives, implicit incentives take the form of executive dismissal or post-retirement board services. In the United States, this latter point seems to be true, as 75% of the CEOs are holding at least one directorship after retirement. This is a point which is opposed by many corporate governance codes. 31 32 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS Conclusion It has become difficult to maintain the widely held view of the 1990s that US pay practices provide explicit and implicit incentives for aligning the interests of managers with those of the shareholders. On the contrary, it seems that the managers have got the possibility and the power to set their own wage at the expense of shareholders (Bebchuk et al., 2001). Long-standing debates all over the world show that the opinions are controversial. We therefore suggest a new approach with the help of penalties for the management. Instead of designing a ‘standard’ contract with a base salary and a bonus if a certain given project is successfully enforced, the shareholder can think about a contract with a higher bonus for a successful project and a penalty for failure. Such a system could go even further than the bonus-malus system of executive compensation introduced by UBS. References Abowd, J., & Kaplan, S. (1999). Executive compensation: Six questions that need answering. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13, 145168. Andrade, G., Mitchell, M., & Stafford, E. (2001). New evidence and perspectives on mergers. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 103120. Armstrong, C., Ittner, C., & Larcker, C. (2012). Corporate governance, compensation consultants, and CEO pay levels. Review of Accounting Studies, 17(2), 322351. Baker, G. (1992). Incentive contracts and performance measure. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 598614. Baumol, W. (1967). Business behavior, value and growth. New York, NY: Macmillan. Bebchuk, L., Cremers, M., & Peyer, U. (2011). The CEO pay slice. Journal of Financial Economics, 102, 199221. Bebchuk, L., Fried, J., & Walker, D. (2001). Executive compensation in America: Optimal contracting or extraction of rents? NBER Working Paper No. 8661. Becht, M., Bolton, P., & Roell, A. (2002). Corporate governance and control. ECGI Working Paper No. 02/2002, Series in Finance. Bergstresser, D., & Philippon, T. (2006). Performance pay and top management incentives. Journal of Financial Economics, 80(3), 511529. Berle, A., & Means, G. (1932). The modern corporation and private property. New York, NY: Macmillan. Braendle, U. (2006). Shareholder protection in the USA and Germany — “Law and Finance” Revisited. German Law Journal, 7, 257278. Braendle, U., & Noll, J. (2004). The power of monitoring. German Law Journal, 5, 13491371. Braendle, U., & Noll, J. (2005). A fig leaf for the naked corporation. Journal of Management and Governance, 9(1), 7999. Directors’ Remuneration and Motivation Bris, A., & Welch, I. (2005). The optimal concentration of creditors. Journal of Finance, 60(5), 21932212. Burkart, M. (1999). The economics of takeover regulation. Stockholm School of Economics Working Paper (discussion paper). Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386. Comment, R., & Schwert, W. (1995). Poison or placebo? Evidence on the deterrence and wealth effects of modern antitakeover measures. Journal of Financial Economics, 39, 343. Conyon, M. (2006). Executive compensation and incentives. Academy Management Perspectives, 20(1), 2544. Conyon, M., & Murphy, K. (2000). The prince and the pauper? CEO pay in the US and UK. Economic Journal, 110, 640671. Deci, E., Koestner, R., & Ryan, R. (1999). A meta-analytic review of experiments examining the effect of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation. Psychological Bulletin, 125, 627668. Dodd, E. (1932). For whom are corporate managers trustees? Harvard Law Review, 45, 1145. Dodd-Frank. (2010). Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. 111203, H.R. 4173, §§ 951 and 971 (2010). Retrieved from http://docs. house.gov/rules/finserv/111_hr4173_finsrvcr.pdf. Accessed on September 2, 2011. Edmans, A., & Gabaix, X. (2009). Is CEO pay really inefficient? A survey of new optimal contracting theories. European Financial Management, 15(3), 486496. Evan, W., & Freeman, R. E. (1988). A stakeholder theory of the modern corporation: Kantian capitalism. Ethical Theory and Business, 97, 101. Fehr, E., Schmidt, K., & Klein, A. (2007). Fairness and contract design. Econometrica, 75, 121–154. Frydman, C., & Saks, R. E. (2007). Executive compensation: A new view from a long-term perspective. 19362005, FEDS Working Paper No. 200735; AFA 2008 New Orleans Meetings Paper. Retrieved from http://ssrn.com/abstract=972399 Fuller, J., & Jensen, M. (2002). Just say no to Wall Street: Putting a stop to the earnings game. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 14(4), 4146. Gibbson, R., & Murphy, K. (1990). Relative performance evaluation for chief executive officers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, 3051. Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691719. Habib, M., & Ljungqvist, A. (2001). Underpricing and entrepreneurial wealth losses: Theory and evidence. Review of Financial Studies, 14, 433–458. Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1990). Regulating trade among agents. Journal of Institutional Theoretical Economics, 146, 85105. Ingley, C., Mueller, J., & Cocks, G. (2011). The financial crisis, investor activists and corporate strategy: Will this mean shareholders in the boardroom? Journal of Management and Governance, 15(4), 557587. Jensen, M. (2001). Corporate budgeting in broken — let’s fix it. Harvard Business Review, November, 94103. Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal Financial Economics, 305360. Jensen, M., & Murphy, K. (1990). CEO incentives: It’s not how much you pay, but how. Harvard Business Review, 68(May/June), 138153. 33 34 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND JOHN E. KATSOS Kaplan, S. (1994). Top executive rewards and firm performance: A comparison of Japan and the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 510546. Kaplan, S., & Holmstrom, B. (2001). Corporate governance and merger activity in the U.S.: Making sense of the 1980s and 1990s. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 121144. Kole, S. (1997). The complexity of compensation contracts. Journal of Financial Economics, 43, 79104. Kostyuk, A. (2006). Corporate board practices. Sumy: Virtus Interpress. Krehmeyer, D., Orsagh, M., & Schacht, K. (2006). Breaking the short-term cycle. Charlottesville, VA: The CFA Institute and Business Roundtable Institute for Corporate Ethics. Lipton, M., Lorsch, J., & Mirvis, T. (2009). Schumer’s shareholder bill misses the mark. Wall Street Journal, May 12, 2009, 253(110), A15. Main, B. (1999). The rise and fall of executive share options in Britain. In J. Carpenter & D. Yermak (Eds.), Executive compensation and shareholder value: Theory and evidence (pp. 83113), Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Press. Mallin, C. (2012). Institutional investors: The vote as a tool of governance. Journal of Management and Governance, 16(2), 177196. Marris, R. (1963). A model of managerial enterprise. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 77, 185209. Marris, R. (1998). Managerial capitalism in retrospect. London: Macmillan. Melis, A., Carta, S., & Gaia, S. (2012). Executive remuneration in blockholderdominated firms. How do Italian firms use stock options? Journal of Management and Governance, 16(3), 511541. Maslow, A. (1947). A symbol for holistic thinking. Persona, 1, 24–25. Mueller, D. (2003). The Corporation. London: Routledge. Murphy, K. (1999). Executive compensation. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics. Amsterdam: North Holland (pp. 24852563). Muth, M., & Donaldson, L. (1998). Stewardship theory and board structure: A contingency approach. Corporate Governance, 6(1), 5. Scharfstein, D. (1988). The disciplinary role of takeovers. Review of Economic Studies, 55, 185200. SEC. (2010). Facilitating shareholder director nominations, Exchange Act Release No. 3462764, Investment Company Release No. 29, 384 (August 25, 2010). Retrieved from http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/2010/33-9136.pdf. Accessed on September 12, 2011. Sliwka, D. (2003). On the hidden costs of incentive schemes. IZA Discussion Paper Series no. 844, 1419. The Economist. (2013). Fixing the fat cats. The Economist, March 9. UBS. (2013). Compensation report. Retrieved from http://www.ubs.com. Accessed on June 9, 2013. Williamson, O. (1979). Transaction-cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22, 233261. CHAPTER 3 Executive Compensation in the 21st Century: Future Directions Udo C. Braendle and Amir Hossein Rahdari The 21st Century It has become difficult to maintain the widely held view of the 1990s that US pay practices provide explicit and implicit incentives for aligning the interests of managers with those of the shareholders. On contrary, it seems that the managers have got the possibility and the power to set their own wage at the expense of shareholders (Bebchuk et al., 2001). Long-standing debates all over the world show that the opinions are controversial. Recently, Malcolm McIntosh (McIntosh, 2015), in his book “Thinking the 21st Century: Ideas for a New Political Economy,” supported capitalism but castigated the current institutions, structures, and interpretations of neoliberal capitalism. He proposed five system changes necessary for the emergence of a new political economy in the 21st century. One of the fundamental changes is about the transformation and reorganization of the current model of capitalism and its constituting institutions into more balanced and harmonious ones that take into account connectivity, accountability, transparency, networks, values, relationships, enablement, entrepreneurship, and rethinking the meaning of capital (economic, social, environmental, cultural, etc.). This change is based on one fundamental question: “how can we make enterprise a spur to ingenuity serving all humanity and not simply a conduit for individual greed?”. Visser (2011) suggested a transformative approach to 35 36 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI corporate social responsibility (CSR) that goes beyond CSR as a managerial strategy (strategic CSR).1 Such transformative ideas are questioning the rationale for the theories of the firm, the place of business within society, and the raison d’être behind the existence of these institutions (Piketty, 2014). Moreover, they call for a new approach toward all managerial strategies including executive remuneration and compensation plans. At the middle of 19th century, there were around ten laws related to executive compensation and now there are more than a hundred (Ellig, 2007). The ever-increasing complexity of business environment in the 21st century suggests more changes to the executive compensation schemes to raise to the occasion. Compensation and Motivation As a general view, remuneration by fixed salaries does not in any class of functionaries produce the maximum amount of zeal. John Stuart Mill (1871) As identified by John Stuart Mill (1873) that fixed salaries are not enough for incentivizing managers in the 19th and the 20th centuries, we must reach a similar turning point in the 21st century. The recruitment, training, and retaining process of employees need to be aligned with the social culture and objectives of the organization. The training processes need to motivate the employees to be socially responsible and to enable them to put forward their innovative ideas that have positive economic and social implications. The incentive system should be revolutionized as the mere economic carrot and stick and reinforcement of punishment are not effective anymore as a series of experiments in the science of motivation, such as the candle problem presented posthumously by Karl Duncker, showed that these kinds of incentives only work for simple tasks that do not need sophisticated cognitive skills; however, for tasks with higher cognitive abilities, most of the tasks of the 21st century, that require innovation, creativity, and out-of-box thinking, not only financial incentives do not improve performance but they have also led to poorer performance in some cases (Ariely, Gneezy, Loewenstein, & Mazar, 2005; Pink, 2006). Google and a throng of other companies have utilized more intrinsic motivators, and the higher performance of their employees 1 Epitomes of transformative CSR can be found in companies like Unilever, Patagonia, and Interface. Executive Compensation in the 21st Century: Future Directions showed that extrinsic motivators are not any more the sole player of the incentive game. For example, Atlassian, an Australian software company, has a program called FEDEX days in which the company gives its employees free days so that they can work on whatever project they want and the results were so startling that the company is planning to expand FEDEX days to include 20% of the employees working hours like Google. This is also true in case of managers and senior executives. These new models of incentivizing are taking over in the 21st century and are expedient in providing an environment where intrapreneurship and entrepreneurship can burgeon. Compensation Plans: Pay-Performance Link Management compensation plans are policies and procedures for compensating managers that includes one or more of the following: salary, bonus, and benefits or perks. There are numerous compensation plans that are used to link pay and performance. The “Bonus-Malus”2 system, which is prevalent in insurance industry, penalizes managers for poor performance and rewards them for strong and positive performance (implemented by UBS). This system allows for bonuses to be held in escrow or not be immediately vested and to be clawed back or reduced retroactively in case of losses in the future. Phantom stock, for instance, is a type of stock-based compensation plan and a contractual agreement that promised to pay the grantee, at a designated time, an amount of cash tied to the market value of an equivalent number of shares of the corporation. This will motivate managers to put the company on a path to better performance so when the time for their compensation come, they will be compensated at the market value. These types of compensations attempt to resolve the hot-hand fallacy like performance evaluations schemes in compensation plan design, that is, better compensation for managers who were fortuitously successful in the past. These managers usually take tail risks or peso risks,3 as termed by Raghuram G. Rajan, in the expense of investors (Rajan, 2005). Compensation tied to performance also provides incentive to manipulate earnings. Another example can be Big BathCap earnings manipulation. Bogey is a low-performance stage for a firm and therefore the performance-based compensation would be also low. At this stage, 2 3 In Latin: Good and Bad. The risk or probability of Black Swan events occurrence. 37 38 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI Cap Maximize earnings Minimize earnings Bogey Big Bath Figure 1: Big Bath and Cap [The Horizontal Axis Represents Performance Measure (e.g., Return on Investment) and Vertical Axis Represents Compensation (e.g., Bonus)]. some managers make poor results look even worse by manipulating company’s income. This is called Big Bath. The big bath is often implemented in a low-performing year to enhance next year’s earnings artificially (Healy, 1985). A more formal definition of “big bath accounting” generally refers to accounting choices made by management to reduce current reported earnings in order to increase future earnings (Ståhl & Appelkvist, 2014). The imminent big rise in the subsequent year’s earnings may lead to a larger compensation for executives, especially considering the low performance of the previous year. If the level of earnings and performance pass a particular threshold, usually specified in the compensation plan, then executives will try to increase the earnings in that particular year that will lead to a higher compensation for them. If the level of earnings and performance reach a particular threshold on top also known as the Cap, usually specified in the compensation plan, then executives will try to minimize the earnings for the current year to save up for the next year. Figure 1 depicts Big Bath and Cap earnings manipulation strategies. Redefining Performance Evaluation in the Age of Sustainability There are many instances of pay without performance. Golden hellos, golden parachutes, gratuitous bonuses, and most of the nonequity based compensations are epitomes of pay without performance (Bebchuk & Fried, 2004). Even when the pay has a link with performance, there are still some challenges that need to be addressed. The whole body of executive compensation literature is predicated upon financial performance of the firm. However, companies have social and environmental impact beside their economic Executive Compensation in the 21st Century: Future Directions performance which is not accounted for in the executive compensation schemes. A rapidly growing body of literature on sustainable development has been developed since the 1970s and revolves around the fact that the current trends in economic development, population growth, resource consumption, biodiversity, social injustice, and pollution are unsustainable and in appropriate circumstances, they can lead to social fiasco and catastrophic planetary system failure (Rockström, Steffen, Noone, Persson, & Chapin, 2009; Steffen et al., 2015). The financial scandals, such as the collapses of Enron, WorldCom, Global Crossing, and Qwest, that resulted from corporate governance failures (Neubaum & Zahra, 2006) have also informed the stakeholders of business social responsibility and the demands for a stronger corporate governance system and as a result a more comprehensive performance evaluation. This has led to a widespread frustration that current financial measures (including accounting such as Return on Investments, Return on Equity, Return on Capital Employed, and Return on Sales and market measures such as Market Value Added and Total Shareholder Return (Yalcin, Bayrakdaroglu, & Kahraman, 2012), non-financial measures (customer satisfaction) (Zeithaml, 1988, 1987), and Balanced Scorecard measures (Kaplan & Norton, 2001, 1996)) cannot offer a viable and comprehensive measurement solution to the unsustainability problem (Gray, 2010). The significant role of management accounting information in developing and improving CSR is well established (Contrafatto & Burns, 2013). However, the literature emphasizes on the inadequacy of accounting measures, as the ubiquitous means of performance evaluation, in the age of sustainable development and highlights the significance of looking at Environmental, Social, and Governance performance alongside financial performance in an organizational context often referred to as CSR. Nonetheless, it is worth noting that recently some measures have been taken to revitalize accounting and sustainability relationship (Bebbington & Larrinaga, 2014). One important strand of literature is that of corporate social performance. Since its introduction, the literature has been focused on finding a link between corporate financial performance and corporate social performance (Wood, 2010). By establishing this relationship, beside stakeholders, shareholders will also be interested in pursuing CSR as it will financially pay off. Despite numerous studies conducted to find such a relationship, the results are still mixed. One possible explanation is the dynamic and complex environment of a firm that cannot be explained with the current simple models. Another explanation can be embedded in the idea that managers 39 40 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI pursue social responsibility with different motivations and for different reasons. Preston and O’Bannon (1997) proposed six hypotheses that explained the relationship between CSR and corporate financial performance based on causal sequence and relationship direction: Social Impact Hypothesis, Trade-off Hypothesis, Available Funds Hypothesis, Managerial Opportunism Hypothesis, Positive Synergy Hypothesis, and Negative Synergy Hypothesis. These hypotheses expatiate on the rationale behind pursuing CSR. Notwithstanding the rapid development in the scholarly field of CSR, there is no definition of CSR that is widely accepted (Rexhepi, Kurtishi, & Bexheti, 2013). Dahlsrud (2008) identified five common dimensions in CSR definitions: the environmental dimension, the social dimension, the economic dimension, the stakeholder dimension, and the voluntariness dimension. Moreover, CSR has many important accompanying concepts that have helped its development. Corporate Sustainability and Responsibility (Visser, 2010), stakeholder theory (Freeman, 1984; Freeman, Harrison, Wicks, Parmar, & Colle, 2010), Communicating Sequential Processes (Wood, 1991), Corporations and citizenship (Crane, Matten, & Moon, 2008), Shared Value (Porter & Kramer, 2011), Triple Bottom Line (Elkington, 1994), and conscious capitalism (Mackey, Sisodia, & George, 2013) are only some of the concepts. This has rendered widespread confusions among professionals and academics alike. In the past decades, especially since the 1990s, a growing number of companies around the world started reporting on the nonfinancial aspects of their business to “discharge their accountability efforts” with varying levels of disclosure in contents across industries and countries (Skouloudis, Evangelinos, & Kourmousis, 2010). To do so, the majority of these companies have adopted non-financial reporting frameworks like Global Reporting Initiative’s sustainability reporting frameworks and International Integrated Reporting Council’s integrated reporting framework. With the emergence of sustainability as a new paradigm in the business world, the attempts to develop a set of indicators for comprehensive performance evaluation system are increasing. Puma innovative accounting system for sustainability is an archetype of mainstreaming non-financial measures in accounting systems. Puma introduced its Environmental Profit & Loss account to financially measure for its environmental impacts in terms of land use, air pollution, waste, and Green House Gas Emissions emissions. The results showed a staggering $125 million in environmental impact. This trend has highlighted the need for the recognition of other types of capitals besides financial capital: human capital, environmental capital, and so on and so forth (Hawken, Lovins, & Lovins, 2008). Executive Compensation in the 21st Century: Future Directions Conclusion As the corporate social and environmental responsibilities are increasingly coming to attention, the demand for the development of new compensation schemes that evaluate executives’ performance based on financial, environmental, governance, and social performance is rising swiftly. References Ariely, D., Gneezy, U., Loewenstein, G., & Mazar, N. (2005). Large stakes and big mistakes. Working Paper No. 05-11, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Bebbington, J., & Larrinaga, C. (2014). Accounting and sustainable development: An exploration. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 39, 395413. Bebchuk, L., & Fried, J. (2004). Pay without performance: The unfulfilled promise of executive compensation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Bebchuk, L., Fried, J., & Walker, D. (2001). Executive compensation in America: Optimal contracting or extraction of rents? University of California Program in Law and Economics Working Paper Series No. 50. Contrafatto, M., & Burns, J. (2013). Social and environmental accounting, organisational change and management accounting: A processual view. Management Accounting Research, 24, 349365. Crane, A., Matten, D., & Moon, J. (2008). Corporations and citizenship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dahlsrud, A. (2008). How corporate social responsibility is defined: An analysis of 37 definitions. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management, 15, 113. Elkington, J. (1994). Towards the sustainable corporation: Win-win-win strategies for sustainable development. California Management Review, 36(2), 90100. Ellig, B. R. (2007). The complete guide to executive compensation. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. Freeman, E. (1984). Strategic management: A stakeholder approach. London: Pitman. Freeman, R. E., Harrison, J. S., Wicks, A. C., Parmar, B., & Colle, S. D. (2010). Stakeholder theory: The state of the art. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Gray, R. (2010). Is accounting for sustainability actually accounting for sustainability … and how would we know? An exploration of narratives of organisations and the planet. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 35, 4762. Hawken, P., Lovins, A., & Lovins, L. H. (2008). Natural capitalism: Creating the next industrial revolution. Washington, DC: US Green Building Council. Healy, P. M. (1985). The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(13), 85107. Kaplan, S. R., & Norton, P. D. (1996). Linking the balanced scorecard to strategy. California Management Review, 39(1), 5379. Kaplan, S. R., & Norton, P. D. (2001). Commentary Transforming the balanced scorecard from performance measurement to strategic management: Part I. Accounting Horizon, 15(1), 87104. 41 42 UDO C. BRAENDLE AND AMIR HOSSEIN RAHDARI Mackey, J., Sisodia, R., & George, B. (2013). Conscious capitalism: Liberating the heroic spirit of business. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press. McIntosh, M. (2015). Thinking the twenty-first century: Ideas for new political economy. Sheffield: Greenleaf Publishing. Mill, J. S. (1871). Principles of political economy: With some of their applications to social philosophy (7th ed., Vol. 1). London: Longmans, Green, Reader. Mill, J. (1873). Principles of political economy: With some of their applications to social philosophy. London: Longmans, Green, Reader. Neubaum, D. O., & Zahra, S. A. (2006). Institutional ownership and corporate social performance: The moderating effects of investment horizon, activism, and coordination. Journal of Management, 32, 108131. Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Pink, D. H. (2006). A whole new mind: Where right-brainers will rule the future. New York, NY: Riverhead Books. Porter, M. E., & Kramer, M. R. (2011). Creating shared value. Harvard Business Review, 89, 117. Preston, L. E., & O’Bannon, D. P. (1997). The corporate social-financial performance relationship: A typology and analysis. Business and Society, 36, 419429. Rajan, R. G. (2005). Has financial development made the world riskier? Washington, DC: IMF. Rexhepi, G., Kurtishi, S., & Bexheti, G. (2013). Corporate social responsibility (CSR) and innovation the drivers of business growth? Procedia — Social and Behavioral Sciences, 75, 532541. Rockström, J., Steffen, W. L., Noone, K., Persson, Å., & Chapin III, F. S. (2009). Planetary boundaries: Exploring the safe operating space for humanity. Ecology and Society, 14(2), 32. Skouloudis, A., Evangelinos, K., & Kourmousis, F. (2010). Assessing non-financial reports according to the global reporting initiative guidelines: Evidence from Greece. Journal of Cleaner Production, 18, 426438. Ståhl, S., & Appelkvist, M. (2014). CEO succession and big bath accounting: A study of how succession and compensation affects a CEO’s discretionary accounting decisions. Stockholm: Stockholm School of Economics. Steffen, W., Richardson, K., Rockström, J., Cornell, S. E., Fetzer, I., Bennett, E. M., & Sörlin, S. (2015). Planetary boundaries: Guiding human development on a changing planet. Science Express, 347, 1–15. Visser, W. (2010). CSR 2.0: From the age of greed to the age of responsibility. In W. Sun, J. Stewart, & D. Pollard (Eds.), Reframing corporate social responsibility: Lessons from the global financial crisis (Vol. 1, pp. 231–251). Critical Studies on Corporate Responsibility, Governance and Sustainability. Bingley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Visser, W. (2011). The age of responsibility: CSR 2.0 and the new DNA of business. Chichester: Wiley. Wood, D. (1991). Corporate social performance revisited. Academy of Management Review, 16(4), 691718. Wood, D. J. (2010). Measuring corporate social performance. International Journal of Management Reviews, 12, 5084. Executive Compensation in the 21st Century: Future Directions Yalcin, N., Bayrakdaroglu, A., & Kahraman, C. (2012). Application of fuzzy multicriteria decision making methods for financial performance evaluation of Turkish manufacturing industries. Expert Systems with Applications, 39, 350364. Zeithaml, V. (1987). Defining and relating price, perceived quality and perceived value. Cambridge: Marketing Science Institute. Zeithaml, V. (1988). Consumer perceptions of price, quality and value: A means-end synthesis of evidence. Journal of Marketing, 52, 222. 43 This page intentionally left blank Section II Cross-Industrial Remuneration Practices Analysis This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 4 Financial Companies Regina W. Schröder Introduction Ever since corporate governance crossed the Atlantic Ocean, it has been broadly and multifacetedly discussed. Amongst other governance-related subjects its implementation in various fields has been an issue. As a remedy, different forms of corporate governance (such as industrial and the social governance) were developed. Financial governance, which is not part of industrial, or social governance, became a topic of discussion later. However, since the recent financial crisis, the literature has paid particular attention to it, as the number of publications dealing with financial governance shows (Hopt, 2011, 2013; Kirton, 2005; OECD, 2009; Underhill & Zhang, 2008). In their analysis of financial firms that experienced the financial crisis in 2007 and 2008, Erkens, Hung, and Matos (2012) found, for example, that companies with more independent boards and higher institutional ownership suffered worse stock returns. The interplay between financial governance and remuneration has so far received little attention. This chapter contributes to closing this gap, at least in part. In particular, the chapter focuses on the question of how to evaluate remuneration over time, and how to discount payments received in different time periods. The chapter is structured into five sections. Following this introduction, the second section first highlights the elements of corporate governance in financial institutions, focusing on stakeholders’ interests. The following section then elaborates on European initiatives for enhanced governance and remuneration and is split into two 47 48 REGINA W. SCHRÖDER subsections, dealing with (a) corporate governance and (b) remuneration. The fourth section is concerned with the chapter’s leading question and is structured into two subsections, of which the second is itself divided into four sections. The chapter finally ends with a conclusion and the highlighting of further research opportunities. The Crisis and Its Effects on Remuneration Governance in Financial Institutions Corporate governance practices started to receive increased interest due to corporate scandals such as that involving Enron. The financial crisis strengthened this interest. This is true for companies but also for financial institutions, with responsibilities for the implementation or oversight of corporate governance practices in companies. In the first subsection, the elements of corporate governance will be explained, before the following subsections focus on remuneration governance before and after the crisis. ELEMENTS OF THE CORPORATE GOVERNANCE OF FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS As Gillan’s (2006) search of Social Science Research Network abstracts containing the term “corporate governance” reveals, research in corporate governance dramatically increased in the 10 years up to 2006. Corporate governance is, however, an ambivalent concept, as can be seen by the diversity of existing definitions for it. Turnbull (1997), for example, understands corporate governance as “all the influences affecting the institutional processes.” Moreover, Gillan proposes distinguishing between internal and external corporate governance. While the former encompasses the board of directors, the management and a balance sheet model, consisting on the one hand of the assets, and on the other hand of the debts and the equity, with all three elements subsequently aligned, the external view relates to creditors and the shareholders, that is, integrates more stakeholders, who influence the two stakeholder groups and the balance sheet model mentioned. This chapter concerns itself with internal corporate governance. In addition, the focus here is not on corporate governance in general, but on governance in financial institutions, which to Hopt’s (2011, 2013) mind differs considerably from general corporate governance. The differences are twofold: the stakeholders, considered together with their interests; and the policies, methods, and other Financial Companies instruments integrated into governance practice. The following section primarily explores the interests of the stakeholders involved in the corporate governance of financial institutions. As illustrated in Figure 1, there are nine stakeholder groups: corporate employees; board members; community; creditors; shareholders; customers; suppliers; governments; and managers. Each of these stakeholder groups strives for its own interests and focuses on different topics. The board, for example, is amongst those interested in institutional corporate governance. Hopt (2012, 2013) finds that a bank’s scope of corporate governance goes beyond equity governance, that is, shareholders, and includes debt governance, that is, debt holders. Hopt formulates theses on (a) the corporate governance of firms and its relevance for banks, (b) the corporate governance of banks, and (c) the banks’ internal corporate governance, for which Hopt makes proposals for corporate and supervisory reform. Surely, these theses can be read as challenges, the biggest challenge however how a financial institution should design the remuneration of its employees, managers, and the board remains disregarded. Firm Shareholders Dividends Capital growth Safe investment Figure 1: Stakeholders’ Interests. Source: Doyle (1994). 49 50 REGINA W. SCHRÖDER Two corporate governance forms which are of importance in particular for financial institutions have been mentioned before, that is, the equity and the debt governance. Due to the subject of this book and this chapter, the following focuses on another governance form, the remuneration governance. PRE- AND POST-CRISIS REMUNERATION GOVERNANCE A key element of corporate governance is how remuneration is dealt with, which has been discussed in numerous publications in the last (Ungureanu, 2013; Lloyds, 2013). Barontini et al. analyzed directors’ remuneration before and after the crisis and concluded that the remuneration received by board members of financial institutions reduced markedly after the crisis. In non-financial corporations, however, the reverse was true. Moreover, for the pre-crisis period the authors observed little or only minor variations regarding the remuneration disclosures between financial and non-financial firms. Yet after the crisis the disclosure in financial firms increased, and, thus, exceeded the remuneration reporting and management of such issues in non-financial firms. While the remuneration structure has changed in terms of its weighting of fixed and variable payment elements and in the amounts of these, no attention has been paid to the present value of the remuneration or on the discounting method to be applied. European Initiatives for Enhanced Governance and Remuneration Though the crisis cannot be said to have been caused by deficiencies in corporate governance practices or by mistakes in the design of remuneration systems, the European Union considers some improvements in corporate governance to be essential. These initiatives, together with discussion on the design of remuneration systems, will be presented in the following. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE This section focuses on the changes made in corporate governance between 2010 and 2013 as illustrated in Figure 2. In June 2010, the European Commission published a Green Paper on corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies. This paper examined multiple aspects of corporate governance and sought out stakeholders’ opinions on several issues, for example, on the functioning of boards of directors, Financial Companies 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 December: Release of an action plan for enhancement and modernization of the EU Corporate Governance framework Over the year: Several additions to and changes in the codes database (e.g., France released in June a revised version of the corporate governance code of listed corporations) -not yet known- 51 t June: Green Paper on Corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies April: Release of a new consultation paper on Corporate Governance Framework September: Submission of comments on the papter by Lloyds November: Release of responses and a feedback statement Figure 2: till 2013. Changes in Corporate Governance within Financial Institutions from 2010 remuneration, and co-operation with supervisory institutions and auditors. In response to the comments made by individuals, public authorities, and registered organizations, the commission released a feedback statement in November, 2010. Just one year after the release of the Green Paper, in April 2011, another consultation paper on the corporate governance framework was published. In addition, in May a conference on “European Company Law: the way forward” took place, focusing on the modernization of company law. In December 2012, an action plan for an EU Corporate Governance framework was released. Since then, several changes in the corporate governance codes of European countries have been made, and the European discussion on corporate governance is still in progress. Remuneration After the financial crisis, not only has overall corporate governance attracted debate, but also remuneration practices, which the green paper on corporate governance also dealt with. 52 REGINA W. SCHRÖDER Due to the experiences in the crisis, the European Commission adopted a recommendation on the remuneration in the financial service sector in the second quarter of 2009. This recommendation urged financial institutions to establish remuneration policies for all responsible employees involved in risk management, and declared guidelines for the design and implementation of remuneration policies and for the review of remuneration policies of financial institutions by supervisory authorities. Though a subsequent report on the application of the recommendation revealed that some progress had already been made, much more needed to be done. One year later, in June 2010, the European Parliament released a report on the remuneration of directors of listed companies and on remuneration policies, in which it demanded binding principles for remuneration policies in the financial sector. In the following year, amendments to the Capital Requirements Directive III took effect, with which the European Commission implemented rules on the relationship between executive pay and corporate risk management. These should ensure that the interests of all the financial institutions’ stakeholders are aligned. While advances regarding the regulation of remuneration and its relationship to risk management have been made, questions regarding the design of incentive schemes remain. For instance, the question of how variable bonuses one important element of the boards’ and top managers’ remuneration should be structured over time remains unanswered. STRUCTURING VARIABLE BONUSES OVER TIME As the remuneration report of Deloitte (2013) illustrates, employees, chief officers, and directors, who are not explicitly named, receive annual and long-term variable payments. Little or nothing is said about the net value of such incentives, though this information is essential to evaluate the present value of the entire remuneration. Thus, I now deal with the different discounting forms, before next focusing on the effects of the chosen discounting method on remuneration and on corporate governance more generally. DISCOUNTING To evaluate the sum of (potential) payments their net present value (NPV) is calculated. This value represents the sum of all payments (here the remuneration) at a specific point in time. Normally, the value is either calculated for the initial point in time, that is, when the present period started, or for the period’s end. The use of the NPV is subject to several conditions. For instance, the capital market needs to be perfect, and the discounting rate has to be consistent. Financial Companies To decide on the total remuneration offered, any payment is multiplied by the reciprocal of the discounting factor. This factor can assume different forms. Three of these forms are characterized and considered below. ALTERNATIVE DISCOUNTING FUNCTIONS As explained before, various discounting functions exist: the exponential, the hyperbolic, and the quasi-hyperbolic discounting methods. After their short presentation, they are compared and evaluated regarding their contribution to good corporate governance. EXPONENTIAL DISCOUNTING The exponential discounting method is based on Samuelson’s model of discounted benefit and is the most commonly referred to in the literature. The model’s idea is that the total value of all future cash flows is equivalent to the sum of all discounted revenues (R) and payments (P), if an over-the-time constant discounting rate dr (with dr = 1 + i) is assumed. The following equation for the NPV illustrates this discounting form. NPV = T X ðRt − Pt Þ⋅dr − t ð1Þ t=0 This formula attributes a smaller value to differences between revenues and payments that was incurred later than cash differences that are realized closer to the date, for which the NPV is calculated. Cash differences which are realized at time t** (with t* < t**) consequently contribute less to the NPV than an earlier-occurring revenue-payment difference, because it is discounted over a longer time. Although many methods and applications resort to exponential discounting, which is indicative of this model’s acceptance, the method possesses many deficiencies: • For example, the discounting rates are diminished over time, as the mathematical formulation shows (dr−t). • Moreover, losses are discounted with a smaller rate than profits (“sign effect”). • Often greater amounts are discounted with smaller discount rates than higher differences between revenues and payments. • If values are discounted single-handedly, that is, just one difference is taken into account, the discount rates applied vary less than in the case of an analysis of the entire difference progression. 53 54 REGINA W. SCHRÖDER As an answer to the first deficiency hyperbolic discounting was developed and proposed. HYPERBOLIC DISCOUNTING According to Frederick, Loewenstein and O’Donoghue (2002) the best documented deficiency of the exponential discounting is its assumption of an over-the-time unchanged discount rate. As an answer thereto the hyperbolic discounting assumes an over-the-time decreasing discount rate which is more in accord with multiple empirical analyses: There is [...] strong empirical evidence that people discount the future hyperbolically, applying larger annual discount rates to near-term returns than to returns in the distant future. (Cropper and Laibson, 1998, p.1) For shorter time periods, consequently, a smaller discount rate is applied than for longer periods. Rasmusen (2008) also calls hyperbolic discounting, non-exponential discounting, to focus on the differences between this and the formerly illustrated discounting. Hyperbolic discounting, however, does not assume a hyperbolic function (like the sinus hyperbolicus). Rather, it applies to a discounting function (dfh) as illustrated in Eq. (2). df h = γ 1 þ α⋅t ð2Þ This formula encompasses three variables, namely two coefficients (α and γ) and the time factor t. It is valid for any points in time except for the starting point in time (t = 0). QUASI-HYPERBOLIC DISCOUNTING Often the hyperbolic discounting function is not applied, but just approximated. In many cases then a quasi-hyperbolic discounting function (dfqh) is used, because it reproduces some of the qualitative characteristics of a hyperbolic discounting function and regarding its structure is similar to an exponential discounting function, at least, as long as the coefficient β is equal to or even larger than zero and at the same time not larger than one. The discounting function then has the following form: df qh = β⋅δt ð3Þ Financial Companies Exponential Discounting Quasi-hyperbolic Discounting Hyperbolic Discounting 1.0 Value of the discounting function 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 Time Figure 3: Comparative Illustration of the three Discounting Functions Considered. For the first time span (t = 0) no discounting is necessary, because the value of the discounting function is assumed to be equal to one. EVALUATION Due to the three discounting functions presented above, the question arises how these functions are related. Surely it is possible to find an example, that is, assume values for all variables and coefficients used, and then make the necessary calculations. But a comparison of calculated values is difficult, as the time frame assumed in all functions supposedly varies. Figure 3, however, illustrates the three functions assuming a comparable time frame for all three discounting functions. As this figure shows, none of the discounting functions considered always lead to the highest present value of all revenues and payments considered. Thus, it is essential to declare which function is used in order to correctly anticipate the consequences of any reward offered and remuneration paid. This information should be integrated in the governance concept and report. It then constitutes an element of the governance concept that might be integrated in Figure 1 in the form of a surrounding frame. Conclusion and Prospects As the former elaborations revealed, the financial crisis has affected corporate governance not only in non-financial firms, but even more 55 56 REGINA W. SCHRÖDER importantly in the financial sector. However, so far no attention has been paid to the present value of remunerations and by which discounting method this value should be calculated. To contribute to a closure of this gap, this chapter reviewed three discounting practices, that is, exponential, hyperbolic, and quasi-hyperbolic discounting. As none of these approaches always leads to an exemplary high value, it has to be chosen by the firm and the remuneration’s receiver and/or disclosed in corporate reports. Then, all stakeholders are able to anticipate the amount of the incentives and rewards paid, and the financial institutions with a relationship to the company are better able to evaluate any encountered risk. Accordingly, the discounting method used and its disclosure are important elements of corporate governance. As such, the presented discounting approaches should also be critically considered regarding all other governance methods, for example, risk governance and total risk. References Barontini, R., Bozzi, S., Ferrarini, G., & Ungureanu, M. C. (2013). Directors’ remuneration before and after the Crisis: Measuring the impact of reforms in Europe. In M. Belcredi & G. Ferrarini (Eds.), Boards and shareholders in European listed companies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com/ sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2250677 Cropper, M., & Laibson, D. (1998). The implications of hyperbolic discounting for project evaluation. Retrieved from http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/ 1813-9450-1943 Deloitte. (2013). Directors’ remuneration report: Overview of new Disclosure Requirements. Retrieved from http://www.deloitte.com/assets/Dcom-United Kingdom/Local%20Assets/Documents/Services/Tax/uk-tax-overview-new-disclosurerequirements.pdf Doyle, P. (1994). Setting business objectives and measuring performance. European Management Journal, 22(2), 123132. Erkens, D. H., Hung, M., & Matos, P. (2012). Corporate governance in the 20072008 crisis: Evidence from financial institutions worldwide. Journal of Corporate Finance, 18, 389411. Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351401. Gillan, S. L. (2006). Recent developments in corporate governance. An overview. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12, 381402. Hopt, K. J. (2011). Comparative corporate governance: The state of the art and international regulation. American Journal of Comparative Law, 59(1), 173. Hopt, K. J. (2012). Corporate governance of banks after the financial Crisis. In E. Wymeersch, K. J. Hopt, & G. Ferrarini, (Eds.), Financial regulation and supervision, a post-crisis analysis (pp. 337367). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Financial Companies Hopt, K. J. (2013). Corporate governance of banks and other financial institutions after the financial Crisis: Regulation in the light of empiry and theory. Journal of Corporate Law Studies, 13(Pt.2), 219253. Kirton, J. (2005). From G7 to G20. Capacity, Leadership and Normative Diffusion in Global Financial Governance. Paper prepared for a panel on “Expanding Capacity and Leadership in Global Financial Governance. From G7 to G20.” Retrieved from http://www.g8.utoronto.ca/scholar/kirton2005/kirton_isa2005.pdf Lloyds. (2013). Corporate governance and remuneration. Retrieved from http://www. lloyds.com/the-market/operating-at-lloyds/regulation/government-policy-and-affairs/ international/corporate-governance-and-remuneration OECD. (2009). Corporate governance and the financial Crisis: Key findings and main messages. Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/corporate/ca/corporategovernanceprinciples/43056196.pdf Rasmusen, E. (2008). Some common confusions about hyperbolic discounting. Retrieved from http://www.rasmusen.org/special/hyperbolic-rasmusen.pdf Turnbull, S. (1997). Corporate governance, its scope, concerns and theories. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 5(4), 180205. Underhill, G. R. D., & Zhang, X. (2008). Setting the rules: Private power, political underpinnings and legitimacy in global monetary and financial governance. International Affairs, 84(3), 535554. 57 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 5 Industrial Companies Yusuf Mohammed Nulla Introduction This chapter will explore the industry’s effects on Directors’ remuneration, particularly focusing on the effect of energy, metal, mining, and health industries on CEO compensation in Canada and United States. In the beginning of this chapter, the background and the role of principal-agent problems in CEO compensation will be discussed. The core of the chapter presentation will be based on discussing the impact of primary benchmarks, variables used in CEO contract, firm size, firm performance, and CEO power (corporate governance) on CEO compensation. It will be a comparative study which includes Canadian and United States public companies traded on the Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX/S&P) and New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) indexes. The later parts of the chapter will discuss the impact of policy, design, factors, board’s role in directors’ remuneration, and accounting regulation on directors’ remuneration. This chapter will then conclude with a summary. Background The CEO compensation system has been greatly misunderstood by the public for some time but it has emerged as a concern during the period of the global credit crunch from 2007 to 2009. The general, social, ethical belief is that CEOs should be rewarded based on accounting performance and should be penalized if companies perform below market expectations. This belief resulted in numerous single studies conducted in the United States and United Kingdom, 59 60 YUSUF MOHAMMED NULLA yet these studies have failed to arrive at robust conclusions on the relationship between CEO pay and performance. As such, great scholars in the field of executive compensation, such as GomezMejia, Eugene F. Fama, Michael Jensen, and Kevin Murphy, have expressed concerns: why are robust conclusions not achieved; why these studies have arrived at divergent or inconsistent results; and why it has failed to establish defining factors that influenced CEO compensation system. Tosi, Werner, Katz, and Gomez-Mejia (2000) have blamed these concerns to different methods of collection, different statistical techniques, different samples, different moderator variables, and differences in how constructs of interest have been used in various studies. As such, these reasons have hampered to reach definite and consistent conclusions among previous studies. In addition, CEO compensation has rarely been studied as a separate study despite it is believed to be a strong proxy toward determining CEO’s total compensation. That is, CEO compensation which includes salary and bonus is sufficient to represent CEO total compensation which comprised of salary, bonus, stock options, pensions, and other long-term benefits. Agarwal (1999), Finkelstein and Boyd (1998), and Finkelstein and Hambrick (1989, 1996) concluded that simple measures of cash compensation are an excellent proxy for CEO total pay. Similarly, Mehran (1995) reported that CEOs took 67 percent of total pay in the form of salary and bonus and 22 percent in the form of equity-based incentives. The literature indicated that most of the previous studies have either focused on the particular industry, or sample sizes that have ranged from fifty to eight hundred,or use of different proxy for the firm size, firm performance, and CEO power. Therefore,the results are incomparable or inconsistent. In addition, from a timing perspective, previous studies have ranged from one to ten year period, therefore, has affected the quality and consistency of the statistical results. Literature on CEO Compensation Agency theory deals with the relationship between a principal (shareholder) and an agent (company’s CEO or managers). It tries to resolve problems arising from conflict of goals and desires between them. It tries to resolve a problem of a principal’s inability to verify an agent’s output. It tries to resolve a problem of risk sharing which arises when a principal and an agent have different attitudes toward risk. In addition, it points to the fact of minimizing the moral hazard problem between owners and managers by Industrial Companies way of control. However, since the monitoring is costly, the owners then try to develop incentive contracts to align their interest with those of employee managers. According to Jensen and Meckling (1976), agency theory is directed at the ubiquitous agency relationship, in which one party, the principal, delegates work to another party, the agent, who performs that work. Thus, it attempts to describe this relationship using the metaphor of a contract. The compensation plans are a form of contract designed to link the goals of shareholders with those of the CEO or other key executives. According to agency theory, compensation plans should be designed so that managers have sufficient incentives to make decisions that maximize shareholder wealth and thus, reduce manager shareholder agency problem. Watts and Zimmerman (1978) pointed out that CEO compensation contract may be viewed as an important means of resolving this conflict; in particular, compensation plans may be designed to maximize shareholder returns by tying pay to performance. However, Dalton, Hitt, Certo, and Dalton (2007) argued that there is a potential for managerial mischief when the interests of the firms’ owners (principals) and managers (agents) diverge. This is explained in the earlier study conducted by Jensen and Meckling (1976), who believed that the conflict between them may arise because the shareholders’ primary goal is to receive maximum returns for their investments, while managers may have a wider set of preferences. According to Eisenhardt (1989), CEO compensation is influenced by agency theory in the form of governance structure whereby a weaker governance structure leads to relatively greater CEO compensation. That is, it is believed that CEO will act on his best interest by adopting a maximum power approach through controlling board and taking advantage of operational expertise than rely on the firm’s performance. Similarly, Pratt and Zeckhauser (1985) argued that because agents control organizational resources and are likely to know more about the tasks that they perform for the principal, information asymmetry that exists could give advantage to agents. On the other hand, principal usually wishes to counter this asymmetry and seeks to devise ways to prevent agents from making decisions to divert resources away from the principal’s interests. This is supported by Jensen and Ruback, (1983), who believed that principals define the rule of the game for senior management team including a system for monitoring and reward structure which includes the degree to which managerial incentives are aligned with the interests of the owners. Jensen and Meckling (1976), and Hart (1983) believed that agency problems are controlled by the market for corporate control, managerial labor market, and product market control. 61 62 YUSUF MOHAMMED NULLA Finkelstein and Boyd (1998) argued that the balance of power between the board and CEO is a major determinant of CEO compensation. This is explained by Core, Holthausen, and Larcker (1999), who believed that weaker governance structures have greater agency problems, CEOs at firms with greater agency problems receive greater compensation, and firms with greater agency problems perform worse. This is supported by Bebchuk, Fried, and Walker, (2002), who stated that executive compensation is consistent with executives who control their own boards and maximize their own compensation subject to an outrage constraint. Similarly, Weisbach (2007) stated that contracts that are negotiated between CEO and board are not likely to be those that maximize shareholder profits subject to the usual constraints in principal-agent problems; rather contracts are likely to reflect optimal rent grabbing by the CEO. Thus, focus of agency theory is on determining the most efficient contract governing principal-agent relationship. Research Design The qualitative study was conducted based on two hundred and forty companies from TSX/S&P and NYSE indexes focusing on energy, metal, mining, and health sectors. The duration of the study was from 2005 to 2010. The longitudinal study approach, random sample, and survey methods were selected. The linear regression equation was adopted for statistical calculations. The CEO compensation was assigned as the dependent variable. The firm size, firm performance, and CEO power were assigned as independent variables. The subvariables of CEO compensation where CEO salary, bonus, and total compensation. The subvariables of firm size were total sales and total number of employees. The subvariables of firm performance were return on assets, return on equity, net profit margin, earnings per share, cash flow per share, common stocks outstanding, book and market values of common stocks. The subvariables of CEO power were CEO age, CEO shares outstanding, CEO shares value, CEO tenure, CEO turnover, 5 percent management ownership, and 5 percent individual/institutional ownership. The 5 percent confidence interval was assumed in this study. Results The results found that among energy, metal, mining, and health industries there was a relationship between CEO compensation, firm Industrial Companies size, firm performance, and CEO power, indicating that all these variables have influenced the statistical models or toward model fitness. The TSX/S&P energy, metal, and mining index companies’ results1 indicated that regression was ranged from weak to strong ratios.2 The NYSE energy index companies’ results3 also have indicated that regression was ranged from weak to strong ratios. However, the NYSE index health companies’ results indicated that regression was ranged from weak to good ratios. It was therefore demonstrated that, in all these industries, model fitness was influenced by short- and long-term compensation structures, indicated that CEO contracts clearly outlined its benchmarks on time-frame basis. That is, in the TSX/S&P index companies, relative to NYSE index companies, the short-term CEO compensation models found to have high statistical model ratios. In contrary, in the NYSE index companies, relative to TSX/S&P index companies, the long-term CEO compensation models were found to have high statistical ratios. These interesting differences were perhaps due to the influence of respective market cultures in Canada and the United States. That is, CEO contracts in Canada are characterized as balanced between short- and long-term compensation systems. On the other hand, CEO contracts in the United States tended to promote retirement reward system in terms of pension, insurance, stock, medical, and other long-term benefits in the CEO contracts. In the TSX/S&P index energy, metal, and mining companies, the correlations between CEO compensation and firm size were characterized as good to strong positive ratios. In the NYSE index energy companies, the correlations between CEO compensation and firm size were characterized as moderate to good positive ratios. In the NYSE index health companies, the correlations between CEO compensation and firm size were characterized as weak to strong positive ratios. Although, in all these industries, the ratios were positive between CEO compensation and firm size, yet the ranges were different. For example, in TSX/S&P energy, metal, and mining companies, CEO salary, bonus, long-term benefits, and firm size have good to strong positive ratios. However, in the NYSE index energy and health companies, CEO salary and firm size have ranged from good to strong positive ratios yet CEO bonus and firm size have weak to moderate positive ratios. All these differences in correlations demonstrated that industry and market culture4 have an effect 1 Nulla (2013e). Weak ratio = 0.000.25; moderate ratio = 0.260.50; moderate ratio = 0.510.75; and strong ratio = 0.761.00. 3 Nulla (2013d). 4 Canada and United States. 2 63 64 YUSUF MOHAMMED NULLA on the design of CEO contract in terms of linking between CEO salary, bonus, long-term benefits, and firm size. In the TSX/S&P companies, the correlations between the CEO compensation and firm performance were characterized as weak to strong positive ratios. Similarly, in the NYSE index companies, the correlations between CEO compensation and firm performance were also characterized as weak to strong positive ratios. However, in the NYSE index health companies, the correlations between CEO compensation and firm performance were characterized as weak negative to good positive ratios. It therefore demonstrated that the ratio ranges were different. For example, in the NYSE and TSX/ S&P energy, metal, and mining companies, the CEO salary, bonus, long-term benefits, and firm performance were ranged from weak to strong positive ratios. In the NYSE index health companies, the correlations between CEO compensation and firm performance were characterized as weak negative to good positive ratios. In the TSX/S&P and NYSE companies, the correlations between the CEO compensation and CEO power were characterized as weak negative to moderate positive ratios. That is, in the NYSE and TSX/ S&P energy, metal, mining, and health companies, the correlations between the CEO salary, bonus, long-term benefits, CEO age, CEO shares outstanding, CEO shares value, CEO tenure, CEO turnover, five percent management ownership, and five percent individual/ institutional ownership were ranged from weak negative to moderate positive ratios. Thisindicated the weak influence of the non-financial factors,such as, corporate governance, CEO stock ownership, market price, the impact of management and ownercontrolled criteria, and CEO tenure (duration of the service), to the compensation models. Overall, CEO power had a weak influence on the CEO compensation, perhaps due to the strong influence of firm size and accounting performance to CEO compensation. Directors Remuneration Policy Salaries are determined with reference to market practice and market data, and reflect individual experience and role. The purpose is to reward skills and experience and provide the basis for a competitive remuneration package. Salaries are reviewed annually and increases are made to reflect market movements and change in job responsibilities. The compensation committee notes and manages the potential for salary increases to have a ratchet effect on total remuneration because of the linkage between salary and other elements of the remuneration package such as cash in lieu of pension, bonus, and long-term incentive awards. Industrial Companies Individual bonus decisions are based on executive directors’ performance in the year, measured against group and personal objectives. Performance measures are both quantitative and qualitative, and financial and non-financial. Bonus awards are made by the committee following discussion of recommendations made by the chair of the remuneration committee. The purpose is to reward the delivery of the near-term business targets set each year; the individual performance of the executive directors in achieving those targets; and contribution to the delivering company with strategic objectives. The executive directors receive an annual cash allowance in lieu of participation in a pension arrangement. The purpose is to enable executive directors to build long-term retirement savings. This is a common arrangement in executive remuneration, reflecting recent and continuing changes in respective Canadian and the US taxation of pension contributions. The rates of these allowances for executive directors exceed pension contribution rates for the broader employee population. This reflects market practice for senior executives. The rate of cash allowance in lieu of pension for any new executive director is appropriately benchmarked at the time of appointment. Executive directors’ benefits provision usually includes private medical cover, life and ill-health income protection, tax advice, the use of a company vehicle or the cash equivalent, and use of a company vehicle and driver when required for business purposes. The purpose is to protect against risks and provide other benefits. The long-term performance measurement, holding periods, and the malus conditions discourage excessive risk-taking and inappropriate behaviors, encourage a long-term view, and align executive directors’ interests with those of shareholders. The purpose is to reward execution of company strategy and growth in shareholder value over a multi-year period. Directors Remuneration Design The directors’ contract design is based on short- and long-term compensation factors. It varies with industry and market culture in terms of duration focus in the directors’ contract. In Canada, based on recent research study,5 the CEO compensation contracts are characterized as “balanced” between short- and long-term compensation. On the other hand, in the United States, the CEO contracts tend to 5 Nulla (2013b). 65 66 YUSUF MOHAMMED NULLA favor on long-term compensation such as pensions, stock options, insurance, and other benefits. As such, CEO cash compensation is higher in Canada relative to the United States. Directors Remuneration Factors From the analyses provided in previous sections, it has now been cleared that directors’ remuneration packages vary from industry to industry and perhaps company to company and firm size. The benchmark used in evaluating performance in particular accounting performance varies, perhaps based on implementation of the strategic plan and its successes and the milestones to be achieved by the CEO. The growing or emerging technology companies evaluate CEO compensation based on sales, research and development, and project successes rather than on net profit margin; retail and distribution industries evaluate CEO compensation based on sales and net profit margin; energy, metal, and mining companies, the highest paid CEO compensation among all industries, evaluate CEO compensation on the resource drilling and production successes, and market price of the stock; health and pharmaceutical companies’ CEO compensation is mostly based on sales, net profit margin, and research successes such as regulatory approval to manufacture new products. Other industries like financial and manufacturing, rely on accounting performance as a major benchmark in compensating CEOs. According to previous research,6 firm size has influenced CEO compensation. It is true from previous research findings conducted by scholars that the large firm size CEO received high compensation relative to CEOs in small and medium firm sizes. The primary rationales provided were that large firm size CEOs have to deal with high risk projects, manage large departments, have complex organizational structures, face more competition in the market especially globally, highly accountable for strategic results, and compliance with complex policies and procedures both domestically and internationally. However, recent research7 also has demonstrated that in small-size companies the correlations between CEO cash compensation and firm size were higher relative to other firm sizes. That is, CEOs’ increments (in terms of ratio) are higher in small-size companies than in large-size companies, perhaps due to quantum business growth and industry demand for services or products. 6 7 Nulla (2013a) and Nulla (2012). Nulla (2013b). Industrial Companies The ownership structure has an influence on the design of directors’ remuneration.8 For example, the nature and extent of influence of accounting performance to CEO compensation are depended on the selection of predictor variables and the ownership structure. It was found that accounting performance is more appreciated in owner-managed companies wherein owners demand more factual performance than qualitative assessment. In addition, it was found that firm size and CEO compensation have a good correlation; however, in management-controlled companies the correlations are stronger, indicates more qualitative criteria in the CEO contract. On the other hand, it was found that CEO power factors have a weak influence on CEO compensation under both owner and management-controlled scenarios perhaps due to the CEO contracts’ emphasis on accounting performance and strategic goals accomplishments. Other factors, in particular qualitative, have influenced directors’ compensation. For example, board members recruited or appointed by CEO, executive compensation consultant negotiating CEO contract on behalf of CEO with board, CEO/Chairman dual role status, CEO’s operational experience, outside CEO recruitment, organizations that have international subsidiaries, and compliance with management internal policies and procedures. Board’s Role in Directors Remuneration The board and the directors play a vital role in advancing the company’s strategic priorities and objectives and in providing oversight and supervision of the management of the business and affairs of the company. Appropriate remuneration for services performed by directors is part of good governance practices. Remuneration must reflect the importance and professional nature of board work, and attract and retain qualified individuals. Accounting Regulation Due to global expansion of North American companies, one unified accounting standard is demanded for financial reporting and analysis by investors, stockholders, and government. The emergence of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) globally has created a viable option to adopt in North America. As such, Canada has decided to adopt IFRS in 2011 from Canadian GAAP. Similarly, 8 Nulla (2013c). 67 68 YUSUF MOHAMMED NULLA the United States will soon (over the next several years) adopt IFRS from US GAAP. By adopting IFRS in North America, the financial reporting indeed has and will become more informative and market valued. The empirical research on directors’ compensation is in early stage under IFRS financial reporting. Through the adoption of IFRS in North America, indeed directors’ compensation will be more volatile if accounting performance criteria are weighted in the CEO contract, such as in owner-managed companies, and financial and manufacturing industries. Conclusion This chapter has explored the energy, metal, mining, and health industry’s effects on directors’ remuneration in Canada and United States. In addition, it has discussed the impact of policy, design, factors, board’s role in directors’ remuneration, and accounting regulation on directors’ remuneration. The results found that among energy, metal, mining, and health industries, there was a relationship between CEO compensation, firm size, firm performance, and CEO power. However, CEO contracts in Canada are characterized as balanced between short- and long-term compensation systems. On the other hand, CEO contracts in the United States tended to promote the retirement reward system in terms of pension, insurance, stock, medical, and other long-term benefits in the CEO contracts. The correlation results demonstrated that industry and market culture have an effect on the design of CEO contract in terms of linking between CEO salary, bonus, long-term benefits, and firm size. The correlation between CEO compensation and firm performance, although it was mostly positive, varies with industry due to different variables used in the CEO contract. As such, the correlations were ranged from weak negative to strong positive ratios. However, consistently, in all these industries, accounting net income/net profit margin has a positive influence on the CEO compensation in particular, CEO salary and bonus. In addition, it was found that CEO power has a weak influence on CEO compensation perhaps due to the strong influence of firm size and accounting performance as prime criteria toward determining CEO compensation. Despite the six decades of research in the area of executive compensation by many scholars, I came to the conclusion that the executive compensation research should be continuous, to improve the understanding the framework, and educate the public towards how the executives are evaluated to entitle mammoth amount of bonuses and pensions, far superior from the average worker lifetime Industrial Companies combined remunerations. Therefore, I highly encouraged to conduct new research to fulfill the zeal of obtaining robust results. For example, the new research may focus on the nature and extent of the market culture and IFRS on the executive compensation framework. References Agarwal, R., & Samwick, A. (1999). The other side of the trade-off: The input of risk on executive compensation. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 65105. Bebchuk, L. A., Fried, J. M., & Walker, D. I. (2002). Managerial power and rent extraction in the design of executives compensation. University of Chicago Law Review, 69(3), 751846. Core, J. E., Holthausen, R. W., & Larcker, D. E. (1999). Corporate governance, chief executive compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(3), 371406. Dalton, D. R., Hitt, M. A., Certo, S. T., & Dalton, C. M. (2007). The fundamental agency problem and its mitigation: Independence, equity, and the market for corporate control. Academy of Management Annals, 1, 164. Eaton, J., & Rosen, H. (1983). Agency delayed compensation, and the structure of executive remuneration. Journal of Finance, 5, 14891505. Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14, 5774. Finkelstein, S., & Boyd, B. K. (1998). How much does CEO matter? The role of managerial discretion in the setting of CEO compensation. Academy of Management Journal, 41, 179199. Finkelstein, S., & Hambrick, D. (1989). Chief executive compensation: A study of the intersection of markets and political processes. Strategic Management Journal, 10(2), 121134. Finkelstein, S., & Hambrick, D. (1996). Strategic leadership: Top executive and their effects on organization. New York, NY: West Publishing. Hart, O. D. (1983). The market mechanism as an incentive scheme. Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 366382. Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305360. Jensen, M. C., & Ruback, R. S. (1983). The market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics, 11, 550. Mehran, H. (1995). Executive compensation structure, ownership, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 38, 163184. Nulla, Y. M. (2012). The accounting relationship between CEO cash compensation and firm size in TSX/S&P companies. International Journal of Scientific and Engineering Research, 3(7) (July), 16. Nulla, Y. M. (2013a). A myth vs. fact, the influence of firm size on CEO cash compensation: A longitudinal study. International Journal of Scientific and Engineering Research, 4(10). Nulla, Y. M. (2013b). CEO cash compensation, firm size, firm performance, and CEO power: An empirical comparative study on TSX/S&P and NYSE indexes companies. D.Phil./Ph.D. Thesis, UGSM-Monarch Business School Switzerland. 69 70 YUSUF MOHAMMED NULLA Nulla, Y. M. (2013c). The comprehensive examination of the effect of ownership structure on CEO compensation in TSX/S&P index companies. International Journal of Scientific and Engineering Research, 4(2) (February), 110. Nulla, Y. M. (2013d). The examination of top manager compensation system of New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) energy companies’. Strategic Management Quarterly, 1(1), 4555. Nulla, Y. M. (2013e). A combined study of Canada’s top CEO compensation sectors Energy, metal, & mining An empirical study. Strategic Management Review, 1(1), 111. Pratt, W., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (1985). Principals and agents: The structure of business. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Tosi, H. L., Werner, S., Katz, J., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (2000). How much does performance matter? A meta-analysis of CEO pay studies. Journal of Management, 26, 301339. Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards. The Accounting Review, LIII(1), 112134. Weisbach, M. S. (2007). Optimal executive compensation versus managerial power: A review of Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried’s pay without performance: The unfulfilled promise of executive compensation. Journal of Economic Literature, 45, 419428. Section III Cross-Country Remuneration Practices Analysis This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 6 Directors’ Remuneration in the United States Andrew J. Felo Introduction Although executive compensation in the United States has received tremendous attention from politicians, investors, and regulators over the last several years, less attention has been paid to how firms remunerate members of their boards of directors. However, both types of remuneration confront similar issues. For example, how should firms structure (forms of compensation and amounts of each form of compensation) remuneration so that directors are encouraged to work on shareholders’ behalf and not on the behalf of executives or on their own personal behalf? Also, how do firms use remuneration to attract and retain experienced directors? In addition, both types of remuneration are regulated in similar ways in the United States, although director remuneration is not as highly regulated as is executive compensation. This chapter discusses various issues related to the remuneration of board of director members in the United States. One unique aspect of director remuneration is that directors essentially establish their own compensation, with little to no oversight. That is because director remuneration is typically established by the compensation committee (or its equivalent) of a firm’s board of directors. Any stock options paid to directors must come from a plan adopted by the board of directors and approved by shareholders, but shareholders rarely reject plans adopted by boards. Director elections also provide a potential check on director remuneration as shareholders can vote directors out of their positions if they are unhappy with the compensation they award themselves. 73 74 ANDREW J. FELO However, this is probably not much of a realistic threat, given that most directors run unopposed for their board seats in the United States. Therefore, shareholders must rely on the integrity of directors as well as rules and laws established by regulators and stock exchanges to ensure that director remuneration is in their best interests. Although regulators and stock exchanges do not tell firms how to structure director remuneration, they do establish rules concerning how compensation committees operate (including compensation committee composition and use of compensation consultants) and what kinds of information concerning director remuneration firms must disclose to their shareholders. In 1995, a Blue Ribbon Commission of the National Association of Corporate Directors (NACD) produced a report recommending that board of director members of firms listed in the United States should be paid in cash and stock only, with equity being the bigger component of total remuneration (NACD, 1995). In addition, it recommended that firms establish targets for how much company stock directors should own and that they should eliminate pension plans for directors. The reason for recommending that equity make up the majority of director remuneration is that compensating directors with equity does a better job of aligning the interests of directors with shareholders’ interests than other forms of compensation do. This is because as shareholder wealth increases, the value of equity remuneration increases. More importantly, director remuneration decreases if shareholder wealth decreases. Cash compensation may not provide such motivation to directors as they receive the same amount of compensation regardless of what happens to the firm’s stock price. While director remuneration may not increase if the stock price increases, there is no penalty to the director if the stock price decreases. Setting targets for stock ownership is another way to align the interests of directors and shareholders as it helps to ensure that directors will have some “skin in the game.” Last, a pension plan may give a director the incentive to “not rock the boat” so as to remain on the board long enough to qualify for the pension. This tendency is more than likely not in the best interests of shareholders. According to a recent survey jointly conducted by The Conference Board, NASDAQ OMX (owner of the NASDAQ stock market), and NYSE Euronext (owner of the New York Stock Exchange stock market), firms seemed to have generally taken these recommendations to heart. In the 2011 fiscal year (the most recent survey available), director remuneration packages included cash retainers, meeting attendance fees, shares of stock, and stock options (Tonello, 2013). I give more details on each of these components of director remuneration below. Directors’ Remuneration in the United States Remuneration Regulation and Reporting In the United States, corporate governance rules and regulations are determined in multiple ways. Bills that are passed by Congress and signed into law by the President impact public companies. For example, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 (hereafter referred to as the Dodd-Frank Act) contains several provisions related to corporate governance, including executive and director remuneration. In addition, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) has the legal authority and responsibility to regulate public capital markets (e.g., stock and debt markets). It does this by issuing rules and regulations that public firms must follow. Last, the exchanges where securities are traded (e.g., NYSE and NASDAQ) have rules that listed firms must abide by as a condition of having their securities traded on those exchanges. This section of the chapter will discuss how laws, rules, and regulations issued by these groups address corporate director remuneration in the United States. The NYSE and NASDAQ do not mandate that listed firms follow any particular compensation rules. That is, they do not tell firms how much compensation to offer or what forms of compensation they should offer to directors. What they do is promulgate general guidelines and principles that they believe firms should follow when determining appropriate director compensation. For example, the following statement is from Section 303A.09 of the NYSE (2013) Company listing requirements: Director compensation guidelines should include general principles for determining the form and amount of director compensation (and for reviewing those principles, as appropriate). The board should be aware that questions as to directors’ independence may be raised when directors’ fees and emoluments exceed what is customary. Similar concerns may be raised when the listed company makes substantial charitable contributions to organizations in which a director is affiliated, or enters into consulting contracts with (or provides other indirect forms of compensation to) a director. The board should critically evaluate each of these matters when determining the form and amount of director compensation, and the independence of a director. On July 26, 2006, the SEC passed new rules concerning executive and director compensation. Although these rules relate primarily to executive compensation, they also relate to director compensation. These rules require that firms provide information on all components of executive and director compensation in a single table in 75 76 ANDREW J. FELO their proxy statements. In addition, firms have to include a Compensation Discussion and Analysis (CD&A) in their proxy statements. Much like the Management Discussion and Analysis included in 10-K reports, the CD&A must include a discussion and analysis of the factors used in determining the figures presented in the compensation table, including the outcomes the firm is trying to reward. Firms must provide information in the table and CD&A related to compensation for the current fiscal year and two prior fiscal years, equity-related compensation that is at-risk and had been awarded in prior years, and retirement and change-in-control compensation. In 2009, these rules were modified to change how firms value stock and option grants made to directors. Notably, director compensation plans are not subject to the same “say on pay” shareholder votes that executive compensation plans are subject to. As with the stock exchanges, the SEC does not tell firms how they are to compensate their directors. Rather, the SEC directs firms to tell their shareholders how they decide on director remuneration plans. The SEC classifies directors as corporate insiders (similar to how firm executives are classified) with respect to insider trading regulations. In addition to prohibitions on trading on material non-public information (insider trading), insiders must report their stock holdings and transactions to the SEC when they first are classified as insiders and when these holdings change. When a person first becomes an insider (e.g., when first elected as a director), he or she must report stock holdings to the SEC on Form 3. Any subsequent transactions must be reported to the SEC within two business days on Form 4. If an insider fails to file Form 4 on time, he or she must report the transaction on Form 5 within 45 days of the end of the firm’s fiscal year. In addition, Section 955 of the Dodd-Frank Act requires the SEC to develop and propose rules mandating that firms disclose whether they allow directors (and executives) to hedge any risk related to owning company equity. As of the writing of this chapter, the SEC has not proposed any such rules. Director remuneration is typically determined by a board’s compensation committee (or its equivalent). Similar to audit committees, much attention has been placed recently on the independence of compensation committees. The logic is that independent compensation committee members are more likely to establish compensation that is in the best interests of shareholders, not in the best interests of executives and directors. Section 952 of the Dodd-Frank Act requires the SEC to direct the NYSE and NASDAQ to issue rules mandating that compensation committee members be independent. In implementing this requirement, the NYSE passed a rule that all compensation committee members be independent of management while NASDAQ requires that firms have compensation committees Directors’ Remuneration in the United States made up of at least two independent members. NASDAQ allows a firm to have one non-independent member on the committee under extraordinary circumstances. To qualify for this exception, the compensation committee must have at least three members and the nonindependent member cannot be a current executive or employee of the firm or a family member of a current executive of the firm. (I review evidence on compensation committee independence below.) In addition to independence requirements, both the NYSE and NASDAQ require that compensation committees adopt formal charters outlining committee responsibilities, membership requirements, and committee operating procedures. Both Exchanges require that the charter be reviewed for adequacy at least once per year. Compensation committees often use consultants to help them design appropriate remuneration plans for executives and directors. Although these consultants bring valuable expertise to the process, there is some concern that these consultants may be biased toward management or the board. That is, in order to continue being hired by the firm and compensation committee, the consultants may recommend remuneration packages that favor executives and directors at the expense of shareholders. This is similar to the issue raised when external auditors perform non-audit services for their audit clients. Under rules issued by the NYSE and NASDAQ in accordance with Section 952 of the Dodd-Frank Act, compensation committees have the sole authority to retain compensation consultants. If the committee chooses to retain a consultant, the committee decides what firm to retain, how much to pay the consultant, and the duration of the engagement. In other words, executive management has no say in whether a consultant is retained or how much the consultant is paid. This is similar to the requirement under the SarbanesOxley Act of 2002 that audit committees hire, fire, and decide the compensation for external auditors. However, in deciding to hire a compensation consultant, the compensation committee is required to explicitly consider whether a particular firm may not provide independent or unbiased advice. For example, if a consulting firm has been hired by management to help design compensation plans for employees, it may not be appropriate for the compensation committee to also hire that consulting firm. The SEC requires that firms disclose fees paid to compensation consultants if the consultant or its affiliates received in excess of $120,000 from the firm for additional services. It is important to stress that the SEC and Exchanges do not prohibit the compensation committee from hiring a firm that is retained by management. The SEC and Exchanges only require that the compensation committee considers whether this compensation consultant can provide independent and unbiased advice. This is consistent with the SEC and Exchanges not telling firms how to compensate their executives and directors. I present empirical 77 78 ANDREW J. FELO evidence concerning the use of compensation consultants and compensation below. Remuneration Design A recent survey of firms on the Standard and Poor’s 500 Index shows that average remuneration for directors in 2013 was approximately $251,000 (Green & Suzuki, 2013). This represents the sixth consecutive year that average director compensation increased at these firms. Although the $251,000 is a 15 percent increase since 2007, average CEO compensation for these firms increased 33 percent over the same period. The same survey indicates that directors spent approximately 250 hours on board matters during the year at these firms. In a survey of firms listed on the NASDAQ and NYSE markets published by The Conference Board (a much broader sample of firms than the Standard and Poor’s 500), Tonello (2013) reports the median total director remuneration ranges from $53,300 in the smallest firms (based on revenue) to $240,000 in the largest firms (based on revenue). When classifying firms based on industry, energy firms report the highest median total remuneration ($202,555) and commercial banks report the lowest median total remuneration ($47,200). The survey also reports that director remuneration continues to increase. The author attributes the increase in remuneration to an increase in time directors spend on firm business, an increase in personal liability for directors, and a decrease in supply of potential directors due to increased independence and expertise requirements for board service. According to the survey, firms listed on the NYSE and NASDAQ typically compensate their directors with a combination of a cash retainer, meeting fees, full value shares of stock, and stock options (Tonello, 2013). Stock and stock options are used to incentivize directors to look out for the best interests of shareholders, while meeting fees are used to motivate directors to attend board and committee meetings. The cash retainer is the only component that is “guaranteed” to directors regardless of firm performance or meeting attendance. I expand on each component below. Survey results indicate that the median cash retainer in the 2011 fiscal year ranges from a low of $27,250 for commercial banks to $75,000 in the industrial and transportation equipment industry. As expected, larger firms (based on revenues or total assets) pay significantly higher cash retainers than do smaller firms. The median retainer for the smallest firms (based on revenues) is $30,000 while the median retainer for the largest firms is $90,000. The other percentiles (10, 25, 75, and 90 percent) show similar spreads, as do the Directors’ Remuneration in the United States results when measuring firm size based on total assets. A large majority of firms (approximately 75 percent) award additional cash retainers to directors chairing board committees (audit, compensation, nominating, etc.). In addition, 40.7 percent of firms award additional cash retainers to the chairman of the board and 50.8 percent award additional cash retainers to the lead director. Larger firms are less likely to pay the additional retainer to the chairman but more likely to pay it to the lead director (Tonello, 2013). Meeting fees are payments for attending board and board committee (audit, compensation, nominating, etc.) meetings. Some firms pay these fees whether directors attend meetings in person or electronically, depending on firm policy. Of the four components, meeting fees are paid by the least number of firms. For example, more than half of the manufacturing and non-financial services firms in the survey do not pay meeting fees. Median total meeting fees range from a low of $8,175 (business services industry) to a high of $26,000 (energy industry). Across all industries, median fees for individual meetings range from $500 to $2,000. In the retail trade industry, a firm at the 90th percentile paid meeting fees of $14,000 per meeting. A large majority of the firms in the survey compensate their directors with some form of equity. Approximately 95 percent of sample firms in the manufacturing and non-financial services industries and 88 percent of sample firms in financial services include equity in their director remuneration plans. The reason is obvious: By directly tying director remuneration to the price of the firm’s equity, directors will be motivated to work toward maximizing the firm’s share price. Equity compensation comes in two forms: full value shares and stock options. Stock options will be discussed in the following paragraph. Full value shares are forms of compensation where the recipient (the director in this case) receives the “full value” of the stock as compensation. Examples include unrestricted and restricted stock, deferred stock units, restricted stock units, performance shares, and performance units. If the stock price goes up, then the value received goes up. Likewise, the value received decreases as the stock price decreases. This differs from other forms of equity where value is received only if the stock price increases (e.g., stock options and stock-appreciation rights). As expected, the value of these full value shares is larger for larger firms. For firms having revenues below $100 million, the median value of these shares is $20,000, while the median is $145,000 in firms with revenues above $20 billion. Median award values range from $32,500 (commercial banks) to $125,000 (computer services). The second form of equity compensation includes stock options and stock-appreciation rights. Both of these compensation forms 79 80 ANDREW J. FELO allow holders to benefit from an increase in the firm’s stock price from a pre-determined level. For options, the pre-determined level is called the “strike price.” If the stock price does not increase beyond the pre-determined level before the instrument expires, then it becomes worthless. The rationale for this form of remuneration is that recipients only benefit if the firm’s stock price increases. Although this form of compensation was quite popular in the past, the evidence in the survey indicates that they are falling out of favor with most firms. Only about 36 percent of manufacturing firms, 27 percent of financial services firms, and 25 percent of non-financial services firms report including options or stock-appreciation rights in their director remuneration plans (Tonello, 2013). One possible reason for the decline in use is that they give managers an incentive to take actions that may increase a firm’s stock price in the short term but may decrease it in the long term (e.g., by cutting R&D or marketing spending or by committing financial statement fraud). Another possible reason is that when stock prices fall as a result of uncontrollable circumstances, these instruments provide little to no motivation to managers and directors. Actual stock grants still provide motivation if this happens as they retain some value, even if the stock price decreases. The only exception to the trend of less use of options is in relatively small manufacturing and non-financial services firms. Option use is still quite popular in these firms. This may be related to the fact that using options allows these small firms to conserve much needed and scarce cash while providing something of value to attract and retain directors. As mentioned above, the 1995 NACD Blue Ribbon Commission on Director Compensation recommends that firms establish targets for the minimum of amount the firm stock directors should own (NACD, 1995). The Conference Board survey shows that approximately 75 percent of firms have done this (Tonello, 2013). The targets are typically stated as a minimum number of shares, a minimum dollar amount of shares, or as a multiple of the annual cash retainer received (this is the most common form used). However, small firms are much less likely to have adopted minimum levels of stock ownership. For example, only 10.3 percent of firms with revenues of less than $100 million have adopted such targets. According to the survey, the most common perquisite for board members is for the firm to match personal contributions made to charitable organizations (approximately 24 percent of all firms offer this). Other perquisites include providing life, travel, or accident insurance to directors (approximately 11 percent), providing medical and dental benefits (approximately 3 percent), reimbursing directors for taxes incurred on compensation and benefits (approximately 2 percent), allowing directors to use corporate aircraft for personal purposes (approximately 2 percent), and providing tickets to Directors’ Remuneration in the United States sporting and other entertainment events (approximately 2 percent). Overall, not offering any perquisites to directors is the norm as 62 percent of firms in the survey do not provide any of these perquisites to directors. In addition to these benefits, virtually all firms (95 percent) reimburse directors for costs associated with attending meetings. Some firms put limits on reimbursements, but a large majority of firms have no such limits (Tonello, 2013). Empirical Evidence on Director Remuneration Although not as extensive as the literature on executive compensation, there has been a fair amount of empirical research on director remuneration practices in the United States. Past research on director remuneration has generally fallen into two categories. The first category involves the determinants of director remuneration. One topic in this area is the characteristics for firms adopting stockoption plans for outside directors. Other topics in this area include the relationship between director remuneration and compensation committee characteristics, the use of compensation consultants, board overlaps, and board independence from the CEO. The second category concerns the impact of director remuneration on the firm and its stakeholders. Topics in this category include market reactions to the adoption of equity compensation plans for directors, the link between director remuneration and financial reporting, the link between director remuneration and a firm’s dividend policy, the relationship between director remuneration and shareholder lawsuits, and the link between director remuneration and corporate social performance. I discuss research in both categories in this section of the chapter. The Determinants of Director Remuneration CHARACTERISTICS OF FIRMS ADOPTING OUTSIDE DIRECTOR STOCK-OPTION PLANS Fich and Shivdasani (2005) investigate the characteristics of firms adopting stock-option plans for outside directors for the first time. They find that the probability that a firm will adopt such a plan is positively related to the percentage of independent directors on the board and the percentage of equity owned by institutions. Since both of these are considered indicators of strong corporate 81 82 ANDREW J. FELO governance, they conclude that firms with strong corporate governance systems are more likely to compensate their outside directors with stock options. They also find that high-growth firms are more likely to adopt stock-option plans for outside directors than are lowgrowth firms. They speculate that by tying directors’ remuneration to stock price, outside directors are incentivized to ensure the firm realizes its high-growth potential. Last, they find that as the percentage of equity owned by outside directors increases, the less likely a firm is to adopt a stock-option plan for outside directors. This indicates that when outside directors own a relatively large amount of equity, a stock-option plan is not needed to incentivize outside directors to act in shareholders’ best interests. DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND COMPENSATION COMMITTEES Compensation committees are generally responsible for setting executive and director remuneration, although shareholders do need to approve stock-option plans. As noted above, the NYSE requires that all compensation committee members be independent of management while NASDAQ requires that firms have compensation committees made up of at least two independent members. These requirements are designed to increase the likelihood that executive compensation plans will be in shareholders’ best interest by having directors who are less likely to be biased toward company executives determine compensation plans. A compensation plan is in shareholders’ best interests if it strengthens the link between compensation and firm performance. Although the requirements relate primarily to executive compensation plans, it is possible that more independent compensation committees will also develop director remuneration plans that are in shareholders’ best interests. I am not aware of any published empirical studies investigating the relationship between compensation committee independence and director remuneration plans. There are, however, studies on executive compensation and compensation committee independence. Unfortunately, these studies provide contradictory evidence. While Vafeas (2003) reports that non-independent compensation committee members are associated with a weaker link between executive compensation and firm performance, Daily, Johnson, Ellstrand, and Dalton (1998) and Anderson and Bizjag (2003) fail to find evidence that non-independent compensation committees award more generous compensation packages to executives. Based on this equivocal evidence concerning executive compensation and compensation committee independence, it is difficult to imagine that there would be unequivocal results when considering director remuneration and compensation committee independence. However, the fact that it “looks” more appropriate for a firm to have an independent Directors’ Remuneration in the United States compensation committee, it is unlikely that regulators will change this requirement. DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND COMPENSATION CONSULTANTS Some critics of compensation consultants have argued that they have enabled firms to hide and justify exorbitant executive compensation contracts (Bebchuk & Fried, 2006). Others have argued that if a compensation consultant provides other services to the firm, the consultant’s independence could be impaired to the point that directors would not be protected from legal liability under the Business Judgment Rule (Brancato & Rudnick, 2006). As noted above, the SEC requires that boards or compensation committees using compensation consultants disclose the fees paid to such consultants if the firm paid the consultant in excess of $120,000 for services other than aiding the compensation committee. The Conference Board survey indicates that a large percentage of firms (approximately 70 percent across all industries) report the name or names of consultants used, with larger firms more likely to make such disclosures. However, the vast majority of firms do not meet the threshold for disclosing fees paid to compensation consultants. When disclosures are made, the highest median for compensation services is $155,831 in non-financial services and $650,000 for non-compensation services in the manufacturing industry. There is little published empirical evidence concerning the use of compensation consultants in US firms. (There are a number of unpublished working papers on the topic.) In addition, virtually there exists evidence involving executive, not director, remuneration. In a published study on the use of compensation consultants, Cadman, Carter, and Hillegeist (2010), report that firms using compensation consultants pay their executives more than do other firms. However, they do not find a weaker link between compensation and performance at these firms. In addition, they do not find evidence that non-independent consultants are associated with more lucrative pay packages. If we extrapolate this limited evidence on executive compensation to director remuneration, it does not appear that compensation consultants enrich directors at the expense of shareholders. DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND BOARD INDEPENDENCE FROM CEO Ryan and Wiggins (2004) investigate how board independence from the CEO impacts independent director remuneration. As mentioned above, directors are in the fairly unique position of having significant discretion in determining their own compensation. The authors hypothesize that directors can be more or less involved in 83 84 ANDREW J. FELO determining their compensation, depending on their power relative to the CEO. For example, relatively independent boards are more likely to rigorously monitor management because they do not feel beholden to management (especially the CEO) and they want to protect their reputations as board members. If this is the case, directors will be actively involved in setting their compensation in such a way that they have incentives to monitor management. In this situation, equity (stock and stock options) would be a relatively large component of director remuneration. On the other hand, non-independent directors may defer to the CEO on compensation issues. To keep directors from monitoring his or her activities, the CEO would insist on making equity a relatively small component of director remuneration. Their evidence supports this argument. Specifically, directors on boards with more outsiders (indicating higher director independence) receive more compensation in the form of equity, while firms where the CEO is more entrenched and also serves as the chairman of the board (indicating lower director independence) receive less compensation in the form of equity. If one accepts the idea that compensating directors with equity benefits shareholders by aligning the interests of directors and shareholders, this evidence supports the notion that board independence benefits shareholders through director remuneration. DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND BOARD OVERLAPS Farrell and Hersch (2012) analyze director compensation where two firms share an independent director. They refer to this situation as a “board overlap.” If all boards value a director’s expertise equally, then one would expect that a director would receive the same compensation for all boards he or she serves on. However, this is not the case. In fact, there are substantial differences in compensation for an independent director serving on multiple boards, although the difference in compensation for “overlap” firms is less than for “nonoverlap” firms. The authors speculate that boards find it more important to compensate all directors on the board similarly than to “match” the compensation a director receives from another board. SUMMARY OF DETERMINANTS OF DIRECTOR REMUNERATION What are the traits of firms that adopt stock-option plans for directors? Evidence shows that firms having relatively strong corporate governance mechanisms in place (higher percentage of independent directors on the board and a higher percentage of equity owned by institutions) and firms with high-growth expectations are more likely to compensate their outside directors with stock options than are other firms. In addition, stock-option grants appear to be a Directors’ Remuneration in the United States substitute for stock ownership because director stock-option plans are less likely as the percentage of equity owned by outside directors increases. Recent regulations issued by the SEC and Stock Exchanges require firms to have compensation committees that are comprised of only independent directors and to disclose if the committee uses a compensation consultant that also provides at least $120,000 in other services to the firm. Although the rules most likely target executive compensation, they also are related to director remuneration. Unfortunately, there is little empirical research on the impact of the rules on director remuneration. Although there are no published studies that I am aware of that investigate the relationship between the independence of compensation committees and director remuneration or the relationship between the use of compensation consultants and director remuneration, there are studies published about how these two factors relate to executive compensation. The evidence concerning executive compensation and independent compensation committees is mixed. Therefore, one cannot say with any confidence that the link between director compensation and firm performance will be stronger with independent compensation committees. The one published study on the use of compensation consultants and executive compensation indicates that although firms using consultants (whether the consultants are independent or not) tend to pay their executives more, the link between compensation and firm performance is not weaker when consultants are used. As shareholders and regulators tend to focus on strengthening the link between compensation and performance, it does not appear from this limited evidence that compensation consultants enrich directors at shareholders’ expense. Existing evidence does seem to indicate that more powerful CEOs use their power to reduce directors’ incentive to monitor their activities by influencing director remuneration plans. Last, it appears that firms look to compensate all their outside directors similarly, regardless of whether the director serves on another firm’s board. The Impact of Director Remuneration on the Firm and Its Stakeholders MARKET REACTION TO ADDING EQUITY TO DIRECTOR REMUNERATION PLANS Gerety, Hoi, and Robin (2001) investigate the stock market’s reaction when a firm adopts a plan to include equity in its remuneration 85 86 ANDREW J. FELO package for directors. They find that there is no statistically or economically significant impact to stock returns at the time of the adoption of the plan is announced. The authors investigate the strength of firms’ corporate governance for additional insights into these results. They focus on the role the CEO plays in nominating people to serve as directors. If the CEO is involved in the nominating process, then corporate governance is relatively weak, as directors may not be truly independent of the CEO. If they are not truly independent, they may be less likely to adequately monitor the CEO. They speculate that in this scenario, equity plans may not properly align the interests of shareholders and directors. This is similar to the general notion of the Ryan and Wiggins (2004) paper discussed above. The empirical results support this contention. Specifically, when the firm does not have a nominating committee, the stock market reaction to the announcement is significantly negative, but when there is a nominating committee, the reaction is insignificant. This evidence indicates the importance of corporate governance (specifically, director independence from the CEO) in determining whether equity remuneration for directors is in shareholders’ best interests. In addition to studying the characteristics of firms adopting stock-option plans for outside directors, Fich and Shivdasani (2005) also study the market’s reaction and analysts’ reaction to a firm adopting a stock-option plan for outside directors for the first time. If market participants believe that stock-option plans align the interests of shareholders and outside directors, then there should be a positive impact on firm value when firms adopt these plans. Similarly, if analysts believe these plans align the interests of shareholders and outside directors, then analysts may increase their earnings forecasts to reflect that they expect the board will do a more effective job of monitoring management. Using various measures of firm value (market-to-book ratio, stock returns, return on assets, return on sales, and asset turnover), they report evidence that adopting a stock-option plan for outside directors increases firm value. In addition, although the market reaction to the announcement that a firm is adding an independent director to the board is not significantly different from zero in this study, they find that the impact is significantly negative when the firm does not have a stock-option plan for directors. This is consistent with the notion that having a stock-option plan for outside directors is viewed as a positive development for shareholders. The authors also report that analysts revise earnings forecasts up when firms adopt a stock-option for outside directors, indicating that analysts expect these plans to improve firm performance. Taken together, evidence from this chapter indicates that the adoption of stockoption plans for outside directors is good news for shareholders. Directors’ Remuneration in the United States DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND FINANCIAL REPORTING Persons (2012) investigates the relationship between two forms of independent director compensation (cash and stock options) and fraudulent financial reporting. Evidence indicates a positive relationship between the inclusion of stock-option grants in independent director remuneration plans and the likelihood of fraudulent financial reporting. In fact, fraud firms are more likely to compensate independent directors exclusively with stock options than are nonfraud firms. There is no relationship between independent director cash compensation and the likelihood of fraudulent financial reporting. In addition, there is no relationship between stock ownership and fraudulent financial reporting. These results hold after controlling for audit committee characteristics, board characteristics, and CEO compensation. These results are consistent with the notion that compensating independent directors with stock options provides them with the incentive to “look the other way” concerning fraudulent financial reporting, while cash compensation and stock holdings do not provide these incentives. This may be the case as independent directors benefit (at least in the short term) when a firm’s stock price increases as a result of fraudulent financial reporting. Lynch and Williams (2012) study the relationship between the form of audit committee compensation and earnings management. An effective audit committee should reduce earnings management. Using discretionary accruals to measure earnings management, they find a positive relationship between earnings management and stock-option compensation (consistent with the results from Persons, 2012, discussed above) and a negative relationship between earnings management and compensation in the form of restricted stock. These results are consistent with the notion that stock options provide incentives to permit earnings management (as a way to increase the value of option grants by increasing the likelihood that the firm’s stock price will increase above the strike price prior to the expiration of the option) and that restricted stock reduces this incentive because audit committee members cannot benefit from short-term increases in the value of restricted stock. Using a sample of firms that are using equity to compensate directors for the first time, McClain (2012b) investigates whether compensating outside directors with stock options improves their monitoring of a firm’s financial reporting process. The rationale is that by tying at least part of a director’s remuneration to future stock performance, the director will pay closer attention to management than if his or her remuneration is guaranteed (in the form 87 88 ANDREW J. FELO of cash payments). He shows that three years after the introduction of equity remuneration, discretionary accruals (a measure of earnings management) are negatively related to the percentage of director remuneration paid in equity. Over the same period, stock returns are positively related to the percentage of director remuneration paid in equity. These results support the notion that equity remuneration, in the form of stock options, is related to higher stock returns, less earnings management, and more effective monitoring of management. How do we reconcile the seemingly contradictory results between Lynch and Williams (2012) and McClain (2012b)? After all, they both investigate the relationship between discretionary accruals and the use of equity to compensate outside directors. There are a few important differences between the studies. First, Lynch and Williams (2012) analyze audit committee compensation, while McClain (2012b) looks at compensation for all outside board members. Since the audit committee is directly responsible for overseeing a firm’s financial reporting process, the results of Lynch and Williams (2012) are probably more representative of overseeing financial reporting than are McClain’s (2012b) results. Second, McClain (2012b) only studies firms that adopt equity as part of their outside director remuneration packages for the first time. There may be something unique about firms adopting such plans for the first time that makes generalizing results to firms as a whole inaccurate. In addition, he does not observe his negative relationship between discretionary accruals and the use of equity to compensate outside directors until the third year after equity is added to the compensation package. In the first year, the relationship is statistically insignificant. Taken together, it seems that Lynch and Williams (2012) provide more persuasive evidence than does McClain (2012b). Jeong and Kim (2013) investigate whether compensating independent board members with equity is related to more conservative accounting. The logic is that compensating board members with equity provides them incentives to more closely monitor management, and the closer monitoring manifests itself in the form of more conservative accounting. Results show that the higher the proportion of director compensation paid in equity the more conservative is the firm’s accounting. In addition, the results are the same using the percentage of compensation paid in equity to audit committee members instead of to all independent board members. This evidence supports the notion that using equity to compensate independent board members provides them with incentives to more closely monitor a firm’s financial reporting process. Directors’ Remuneration in the United States DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND DIVIDEND PAYING McClain (2012a) investigates the dividend-paying behavior of firms that adopt equity compensation for directors for the first time. He finds that as the percentage of director remuneration paid in equity increases, firms are less likely to pay dividends. The amount of dividends paid is negatively related to equity compensation percentage. In addition, more profitable firms pay a lower amount of dividends. Since the paying of dividends tends to decrease stock price (since cash is removed from the business), this evidence supports the notion that directors with a financial stake in the company (in the form of equity compensation) tend to support policies that are expected to lead to future stock price growth. Boumosleh (2012) investigates the relationship between including stock options in the compensation for outside directors and a firm’s dividend-paying behavior. The author uses dividend-paying behavior to assess a firm’s appetite for risk. Specifically, firms paying relatively low dividends have a higher appetite for risk as they use funds to pay for “risky” items such as research and development expenditures. Evidence indicates that firms paying directors a relatively high amount of stock options have lower dividend payout ratios. This supports the notion that stock options encourage directors to approve more risky projects. Accepting more risky projects may or may not benefit shareholders. For example, directors could forgo dividend payments to fund projects with negative net present values but that personally benefit the director. Results indicate that the use of stock options encourages directors to more closely monitor management such that dividends are not forgone in order to fund projects with negative net present values. Taken together, this evidence indicates that compensating directors with stock options encourages less dividends (more risk), but the increase in risk-taking benefits shareholders. DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND SHAREHOLDER LAWSUITS Crutchley and Minnick (2012) study the relationship between director remuneration and shareholder lawsuits where the board of directors is named as a defendant. If equity compensation aligns directors’ interests with shareholders’ interests, increasing equity compensation could reduce shareholder lawsuits against the board of directors. Contrary to this expectation, though, the evidence from this paper indicates that shareholder lawsuits against directors are more likely as equity compensation increases and less likely as cash compensation increases. The authors speculate that equity compensation makes directors less independent as they focus more on their personal wealth than on the shareholders’ best interests. The 89 90 ANDREW J. FELO reduced independence then manifests itself as a lawsuit against the board as shareholders become displeased with the board’s performance. DIRECTOR REMUNERATION AND CORPORATE SOCIAL PERFORMANCE Deutsch and Valente (2013) investigate the impact that paying directors with equity has on corporate social performance. Even though equity is expected to more closely align the interests of shareholders and directors, the authors argue, it may also result in directors ignoring other stakeholders. Their empirical results support this idea. Although the amount of director compensation paid in equity is positively related to future financial performance, it is negatively related to various measures of future corporate social performance. These results indicate that if firms want directors to consider social issues when advising and evaluating management, then it will be necessary to include more than equity in their compensation packages. SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT OF DIRECTOR REMUNERATION ON STAKEHOLDERS Research reviewed in this section of the chapter investigates the results of director remuneration choices. One stream of research addresses whether using equity to compensate outside directors is good for shareholders. The evidence on this is mixed. While some researchers find that using equity is beneficial to shareholders (in the form of higher stock returns, higher accounting returns, and less earnings management), others find that using equity is not beneficial to shareholders (lower stock returns, more earnings management, and even greater likelihood of financial statement fraud). There seems to be two important issues to consider when looking at this contradictory evidence. One, there seems to be different results when equity is measured as stock options or as shares of stock (restricted or unrestricted). When stock options are considered, the results for shareholders tend to be negative, while the results tend to be positive when shares of stock are considered. One possible explanation is that stock options give an incentive to firms to increase their stock prices in the short term, which may not be good for shareholders in the long run. This may be why The Conference Board survey shows that stock options have become less popular at many relatively large firms. The second factor is the strength of a firm’s corporate governance system. It appears that when a firm has relatively weak corporate governance system, using equity to compensate outside directors is a negative for shareholders. When corporate governance is relatively strong, the impact of using equity is Directors’ Remuneration in the United States statistically insignificant. While insignificant may not increase a shareholder’s wealth, it is better than a negative impact. Another stream of research reviewed in this section addresses the relationship between compensating directors with equity and a firm’s dividend-paying activity. The results consistently show a negative relationship between using equity to pay outside directors and paying dividends. This relationship is consistent with directors who own equity in a company wanting to encourage behavior that can lead to an increase in stock price. Somewhat related to this is evidence that shareholder lawsuits against directors are more likely as equity compensation increases. Higher amounts of equity compensation could encourage directors to sanction greater risk-taking by management. If these riskier projects do not work out, though, shareholders may believe that the high amount of equity compensation encourages excessive risk-taking. Last, there is evidence that using equity to compensate outside directors encourages directors to pay less attention to corporate social performance. A possible explanation for this is that although equity aligns the interests of shareholders and directors, this alignment may result in directors encouraging management to ignore corporate social performance because focusing on corporate social performance may cost the firm money, at least in the short term. Remuneration Challenges There are a number of challenges firms in the United States face when attempting to determine director remuneration packages. One challenge is that directors have a large amount of input into their own pay packages. Therefore, they are subject to substantial criticism if people believe that their pay is excessive or unwarranted based on firm performance. A second challenge is to make the remuneration package attractive enough to enable the firm to attract quality directors to the board, but not so high that people find it excessive. As the responsibilities and workload of board members has increased, the number of board candidates has tended to decrease. There are at least three reasons why fewer people are candidates for board seats. First, the increased workload makes it difficult for current executives to serve on boards of other firms and for one director to serve on multiple boards. In fact, some firms do not allow their executives to serve on other boards because they fear board service may take up too much of their time. Second, individuals may be reluctant to serve on boards out of fear of legal liability issues. Even if a director is not successfully sued, it could be embarrassing and time consuming to be named in a lawsuit. Third, independence requirements for board 91 92 ANDREW J. FELO and committee membership (e.g., audit and compensation committees) reduce the pool of available directors. The bottom line is that most firms are probably competing for fewer and fewer independent board candidates. This makes it imperative that firms offer attractive director remuneration packages. At the same time, firms do not want to overpay their directors. In addition, director remuneration should provide incentives to monitor management and offer strategic advice to management. When discussing director remuneration, we tend to focus on the monitoring role of outside directors. In order to motivate directors to monitor management, it is probably necessary to pay directors at least partially in equity. As noted above, the NACD recommended in 1995 that the majority of director remuneration should be in stock (NACD, 1995). By doing this, directors benefit when shareholders benefit. This can at least partially address the challenge about how much pay is too much pay. If shareholders earn high returns, they are probably less likely to be concerned with director pay. The extant research reviewed above generally finds that paying directors in equity benefits shareholders. However, using stock options may not be as beneficial to shareholders as is using stock shares (restricted and unrestricted). As the recent survey by The Conference Board indicates that stock options are becoming less popular as a director remuneration tool (Tonello, 2013), possibly because of the potentially negative incentives stock options seem to provide to directors. The only exception to this trend is that stock options continue to be a significant component of director remuneration at small firms. References Anderson, R., & Bizjag, J. (2003). An empirical examination of the role of the CEO and the compensation committee in structuring executive pay. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27, 13231348. Bebchuk, L., & Fried, J. (2006). Pay without performance: Overview of the issues. Academy of Management Perspectives, 20(1), 524. Brancato, C. K., & Rudnick, A. (2006). A legal template for compensation committee oversight over consultants. The Corporate Governance Advisor, 14(2), 15–20. Boumosleh, A. (2012). Firm investment decisions, dividend policy, and director stock options. The Journal of Applied Business Research, 28(4), 753767. Cadman, B., Carter, M. E., & Hillegeist, S. (2010). The incentives of compensation consultants and CEO pay. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 49, 263280. Crutchley, C. E., & Minnick, K. (2012). Cash versus incentive compensation: Lawsuits and director pay. Journal of Business Research, 65, 907913. Directors’ Remuneration in the United States Daily, C. M., Johnson, J. L., Ellstrand, A. E., & Dalton, D. R. (1998). Compensation committee composition as a determinant of CEO compensation. Academy of Management Journal, 41(2), 209220. Deutsch, Y., & Valente, M. (2013). Compensating outside directors with stock: The impact on non-primary stakeholders. Journal of Business Ethics, 116, 6785. Farrell, K., & Hersch, P. L. (2012). Inter-board pay differentials for directors with multiple appointments. Applied Economic Letters, 19(14), 14011404. Fich, E. M., & Shivdasani, A. (2005). The impact of stock-option compensation for outside directors on firm value. Journal of Business, 78(6), 22292254. Gerety, M., Hoi, C.-K., & Robin, A. (2001). Do shareholders benefit from the adoption of incentive pay for directors. Financial Management, 30(4), 4561. Green, J., & Suzuki, H. (2013). Board director pay hits record $251,000 for 250 hours. Retrieved from http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-05-30/board-directorpay-hits-record-251-000-for-250-hours.html Jeong, K., & Kim, H. (2013). Equity-based compensation to outside directors and accounting conservatism. The Journal of Applied Business Research, 29(3), 885900. Lynch, L. J., & Williams, S. P. (2012). Does equity compensation compromise audit committee independence? evidence from earnings management. Journal of Managerial Issues, 24(3), 293320. McClain, G. (2012a). The impact of outside director equity compensation on dividend policy. The Journal of Applied Business Research, 28(4), 743751. McClain, G. (2012b). Outside director equity compensation and the monitoring of management. The Journal of Applied Business Research, 28(6), 13151329. National Association of Corporate Directors (NACD) (1995). Blue ribbon commission report on director compensation. Washington, DC: NACD. New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) (2013). The New York Stock Exchange listed company manual. New York, NY: New York Stock Exchange. Retrieved from http:// nysemanual.nyse.com/lcm/ Persons, O. S. (2012). Stock option and cash compensation of independent directors and likelihood of fraudulent financial reporting. Journal of Business and Economic Studies, 18(1), 5474. Ryan, H. E. Jr., & Wiggins III, R. A. (2004). Who is in whose pocket? Director compensation, board independence, and barriers to effective monitoring. Journal of Financial Economics, 73, 497524. Tonello, M. (2013). The 2013 director compensation and board practices report. The Conference Board. Vafeas, N. (2003). Further evidence on compensation committee composition as a determinant of CEO compensation. Financial Management, 32, 5370. 93 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 7 Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom Jean J. Chen and Zhen Zhu Remuneration Regulation The UK is widely recognised as a ‘world leader’ in corporate governance reform. In the wake of a series of corporate failures (e.g. the BCCI and Maxwell cases) in the early 1990s, the publication of the Cadbury Report (Cadbury Report, 1992) in the United Kingodm represents the first attempt to set out a specific set of recommendations on good corporate governance practices, which has significantly influenced the development of corporate governance codes around the world. Furthermore, the Cadbury Report has set the agenda for corporate governance reform in the United Kingodm, following which, more subsequent policy documents, principles, guidelines and codes of practices have been published in the United Kingodm, keeping Britain as ‘front runner’ in this field (FRC, 2011; Keasey, Short, & Wright, 2005; Tricker, 2009). Specifically, regulatory framework for directors’ remuneration in the United Kingodm are mainly set out in two places: The Greenbury Report in 1995 (note that the Greenbury recommendations have been incorporated into the Combined Code and its new version of the UK Corporate Governance Code 2012 with a few amendments, which will be discussed in more detail later), and the Directors’ Remuneration Report Regulations in 2002 (issued by the Department of Trade and Investment, DTI, and contained in the 95 96 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU relevant sections of Companies Act 2001) which will be discussed separately in section ‘Remuneration Reporting’.1 In line with the ‘comply or explain’ approach adopted by the UK corporate governance system, the regulatory framework is complemented by market Listing Rules2 and good practice principles issued by investor associations3 (BIS, 2012b). THE GREENBURY REPORT 1995 In response to growing concern about the excessive executive pay packages, especially in relation to share options and other additional sources of remuneration, the Greenbury Committee was set up in January 1995 to identify good practice in determining and accounting for directors’ remuneration. The committee reported in July 1995 (The Greenbury Report in 1995), calling for establishing a balance between executives’ rewards and their performance (Solomon, 2010). In particular, the Greenbury Report strengthened the role of independent non-executive directors in the pay-setting process, and significantly increases the amount of required disclosure on directors’ remuneration (Keasey & Watson 1991). The main recommendations of the Greenbury Report were as follows (Bruce & Buck, 2005; Keasey & Watson 1991; Tricker, 2009): • Remuneration committees should consist solely of independent non-executive directors. • The remuneration committee should report to shareholders annually. • The remuneration report should include: I. The company’s policy regarding the setting of executive remuneration. 1 For firms in financial sector, there are additional rules including FSA (the Financial Service Authority) Remuneration Code (2009, revised in 2010) and Remuneration Disclosure Requirements 2010. The revisions seek to align the Code’s provisions with recent international work on remuneration principles. In particular, the remuneration principles in the Third Capital Requirement Directive (known as CRD3), and the Committee of European Banking Supervisors’ (CEBS) Guidelines on Remuneration Policies and Practices (CEBS guidelines), provide guidance on the implementation and interpretation of the remuneration principles in CRD3, while Remuneration Disclosure Requirements 2010 is relating to the implementation of remuneration disclosure requirements based on those set out in the CRD3. 2 The Listing Rules 2004, issued by FSA (the Financial Service Authority). 3 For example, ABI Principles of Remuneration 2011, issued by the Association of British Insurers. Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom II. Full details of all elements of the remuneration package (including share options and pension entitlements) of each named individual director. III. Details and reasons for directors’ contracts exceeding one year, aimed at avoiding excessive golden handshakes (severance pay). • Shareholders’ approval is required for the adoption of long-term incentive plans (LTIPs), which should be linked to long-term performance criteria. • Share options should never be issued at a discount, should be phased in rather than issued in one large block and should not be exercisable in less than three years. • Firms might compare the merits of executive share options (ESOs) with alternative forms of long-term performancecontingent pay component. As it can be seen, the Greenbury Report focused solely on the process of determining director’s remuneration. It reemphasised the importance of independent non-executive directors (INEDs) in the governance of this process by recommending that remuneration committees should consist solely of INEDs. It also went further and prescribed the inclusion of three INEDs on the board in contrast to a minimum of two INEDs recommended by Cadbury Report (Cadbury Report, 1992; Keasey & Watson 1991). In addition to the emphasis on the role of INEDs in the remuneration committee, the Greenbury Report significantly increased the amount of required disclosures on directors’ remuneration (Keasey & Watson 1991). Specifically, an annual remuneration report made by the remuneration committee on behalf of the board should be provided, as part of company’s annual report, accounting to shareholders for company’s compensation policy, including: ‘levels, comparator groups of companies, individual components, performance criteria and measurement, pension provision, contracts of service, and compensation commitments on early termination’ (The Greenbury Report in 1995). Finally, it ‘echoed’ concerns over levels of ESOs by addressing the ‘potential drawbacks’ of ESOs, and highlighted a clear preference for LTIPs (Bruce & Buck, 2005; Conyon, Peck, Read, & Sadler, 2000), which have resulted in ‘a parallel decline in the relative significance of ESO schemes and increase in the uptake of LTIP schemes’ in large UK companies’ executive pay packages (Bruce & Buck, 2005). In general terms, these recommendations have seen widespread approval and rapid implementation among large UK listed companies. 97 98 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU THE COMBINED CODE ON CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 1998 AND ITS SUBSEQUENT REVISIONS Following the publication of the Hampel Report (1998), the Hampel committee issued the Combined Code (1998), consolidating the Cadbury, Greenbury and Hampel recommendations into a series of principles of good governance practice. Under each main principle, there was a list of code provisions, giving details of how the principles may be attained. Specifically, the 1998 Code consisted of 18 principles and 48 code provisions, setting out standards of good practice in relation to board leadership and effectiveness, remuneration, accountability and audit, and relations with shareholders. Requirements relating to directors’ remuneration were set out in the 1998 Code by three principles, including the level and composition of remuneration, procedure and disclosure, The 1998 Code retained all the recommendations made by the Greenbury Report (see the discussion above) except that it stated the board (rather than the remuneration committee should report to shareholders on remuneration; Keasey & Watson 1991). Therefore, the 1998 Code increased the disclosure requirement for remuneration and addressed that it was the responsibility of the board who should report to shareholders. Importantly, the Combined Code (from its 1998 version to the current 2012 version), which is incorporated into the London Stock Exchange’s Listing Rules, maintains the ‘apply or explain’ approach proposed by the Cadbury Report. As the Code (2012) stated, ‘the “apply or explain” approach is the trademark of corporate governance in the United Kingodm (the UK Corporate Governance Code 2012). All companies with a premium listing of equity shares on the Main Market4 are required under the Listing Rules to make a statement in their annual report, explaining how they have applied the main principles, and confirming that they have complied with the code provisions or providing explanation where they do not. This includes provisions on the make-up and the role of remuneration committees, the pay-setting process and the structure of pay. Additionally, the Listing Rules also require ‘shareholders to approve any new share-based reward schemes, for all employees and not just for directors. Companies typically seek approval every five to ten years for the broad structure of these schemes. This is done by means of a binding shareholder resolution at the AGM’ (BIS, 2012a, 2012b). Following the 1998 Combined Code, a series of revisions to the Code was subsequently issued by the Financial Reporting 4 The listing regime of London Stock Exchange includes two types of listing: a premium listing and a standard listing refer to LSE website for more details. Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom Council (FRC), which undertakes regular review of the impact and implementation of the Code and its associated guidance to ensure that it continues to work effectively. The last significant revisions to the Combined Code was made in 2003 when it was updated to incorporate recommendations from the Higgs Report (2003) on the role of non-executive directors and the Smith Report (2003) on audit committees. Further minor amendments were made in 2006 and 2008 following the reviews by the FRC. In particular, in the 2003 edition of the Code, the standard expectations of corporate governance had once again been sharpened including the increasing monitoring roles of remuneration committees. Specifically, the 2003 Code readdressed remuneration issue, aiming to avoid excessive remuneration which displays little relation to corporate performance, including new supporting principle relating to pay comparison (benchmarking), and the working procedures for remuneration committee; new provisions relating to remuneration committee composition, non-executive directors’ remuneration, and restriction for executive director to serve as non-executive director elsewhere; revised provisions relating to remuneration committee responsibilities, reducing compensation commitments in the event of early termination, and notice periods which should not be beyond one year (Keasey & Watson 1991; Tricker, 2009). THE UK CORPORATE GOVERNANCE CODE 2010 Following a review and consultation process undertaken in 2009, the FRC issued a new edition of the Code in June 2010, now renamed as the UK Corporate Governance Code (the 2010 Code)5 under the background of the global financial crisis and consequent decline in economic conditions since the publication of the previous 2008 Code. The changes involved two aspects: first, some structural changes to the Code were made to promote better board behaviour by focusing attention on the code principles rather than more detailed code provisions.6 Second, adopting those recommendations 5 The 2010 Code applies to accounting period beginning on or after 29 June 2010. 6 Refer to the appendix A of May 2010 consultation document of FRC for specific structural changes to the 2010 code. In particular, Section E in the 2008 Code, which was addressed to institutional investors, has been moved to Schedule C in the 2010 Code and then been removed entirely when the new Stewardship Code 2010 for institutional investors came into effect from July 2010. The Stewardship Code 2010 and its revised version of 2012, set out good practice for institutional investors on monitoring and engaging with investee companies and reporting to clients and beneficiaries. 99 100 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU of the Walker Review (2009)7 that the FRC considered should apply to all listed companies. As a consequence, the corporate governance standard in the United Kingodm has once again been improved significantly. The major changes to the content of the 2010 Code included (refer to the May 2010 consultation document of FRC): • To encourage boards to be well balanced and avoid ‘group think’, there are new principles on the composition and selection of the board, including the need for appointing members based on their merit, against objective criteria, and with due regard for the benefits of diversity, including gender diversity. • To promote proper debate in the boardroom, there are new principles on the leadership of the chairman, the responsibility of the non-executive directors to provide constructive challenge, and the time commitment expected of all directors. • To help enhance the board’s performance and awareness of its strengths and weaknesses, the chairman should hold regular development reviews with each director and board evaluation reviews in FTSE 350 companies should be externally facilitated at least every three years. • To increase accountability to shareholders, all directors of FTSE 350 companies should be re-elected annually and chairmen are encouraged to report personally on how the principles relating to the leadership and effectiveness of the board have been applied. • To improve risk management, the company’s business model should be explained and the board should be responsible for 7 The Walker Review is an independent review of governance in banking sector with specific focus on executive remuneration and the role of the board of directors carried out in early 2009 in reaction to the latest international financial crisis which came to a head in 20082009 in the UK. After a public consultation, the final version was published in November 2009, reaching a number of important conclusions that seem equally appropriate for other types of organisation: (i) addressing the effectiveness of the combined code and the comply or explain approach; (ii) weaknesses in board effectiveness and improvement measures; (iii) risk management role of the board; (iv) the role of core institutional investors; (v) improvements in the structuring of remuneration policy including more power for remuneration committees to scrutinise firm-wide pay; Remuneration committee to oversee pay of high-paid executives not on the board; Significant deferred element in bonus schemes for all high-paid executives; Increased public disclosure about pay of high-paid executives; Chairman of remuneration committee to face reelection if report gets less than 75% approval (Solomon, 2010, p. 62, The Telegraph, 16/07/2009). Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom determining the nature and extent of the significant risks it is willing to take. • Performance-related pay should be aligned to the long-term interests of the company and its risk policies and systems. In terms of compensation polices, they remained largely unchanged. There were only a few minor additional requirements as highlighted below (KPMG, 2010, p. 13, May 2010 consultation document of FRC): • It explicitly states as a principle that performance measures should be designed to support the long-term success of the company. • Non-financial performance measures should be used in incentive plans where appropriate. It is not suggested that this will always or generally be the case. • The proposal that bonuses should be linked to risk-adjusted performance measures is not included in the Code. However, incentives ‘should be compatible with risk policies and systems’. • Consideration should be given to the use of ‘clawback’ provisions which permit the company to reclaim variable remuneration in ‘exceptional circumstances of misstatement or misconduct’. The 2010 Code adopted the recommendations from the 2009 Walker Review where appropriate, and emphasised the need for performance-related pay to be aligned with the long-term interest of the company and with the company’s risk policies and control systems, and the use of clawback arrangement to enable the company to reclaim performance-related payments in certain circumstances. THE UK CORPORATE GOVERNANCE CODE 2012 In September 2012, the updated edition of the Code was published by FRC (the UK Corporate Governance Code 2012)8 following a consultation seeking views on whether to amend the 2010 Code and the associated ‘Guidance on Audit Committees’. Only limited changes were made to the 2010 Code (refer to the September 2012 consultation document of FRC, FRC news, reported on 28/09/2012 on FRC website). They included: • FTSE 350 companies are to put the external audit contract out to tender at least every ten years with the aim of ensuring a 8 The 2012 Code applies to reporting periods beginning on or 1 October 2012. 101 102 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU • • • • • high-quality and effective audit, whether from the incumbent auditor or from a different firm; Audit Committees are to provide shareholders information on how they carry out their responsibilities, including how they assess the effectiveness of the external audit process; Boards are to confirm that the annual report and accounts taken as a whole are fair, balanced and understandable, to ensure that the narrative sections of the report are consistent with the financial statements and accurately reflect the company’s performance; Companies are to disclose their policy on boardroom diversity, including gender, any measurable objectives that have been set for implementing the policy, and report the progress on achieving the objectives. This change was first announced in October 2011, also came into effect from 1 October 2012; Companies are to provide fuller explanations to shareholders as to why they choose not to follow a provision of the Code. The characteristics of an informative explanation are set out in the introductory section of the Code on the operation of ‘comply or explain’ as non-binding guidance for companies and investors in order to help companies understand what are expected of them when they choose to deviate from the provisions of the Code, and to provide shareholders with a benchmark against which to judge explanations; Companies are to disclose the use of board advisors including executive search consultancies, board reviewers and remuneration consultants. Companies that have made use of board advisors are required to disclose the identity of these advisors, and whether they have any other connections with the company. With regard to director’s remuneration, as outlined above, consistent disclosure requirements in relation to the use of board advisors including executive search consultancies, board reviewers and remuneration consultants have been introduced to the 2012 Code. Specifically, it is now clear that ‘where remuneration consultants are appointed, they should be identified in the annual report (newly added) and a statement made as to whether they have any other connection with the company’. Same disclosure requirements apply to executive search consultancies and board reviewers as well (September 2012 consultation document of FRC: 14). Accordingly, transparency in the use of remuneration consultants has been improved. It is consistent with the overall purpose of the 2012 revision which are improved information disclosure and strengthened role of audit committees so as to ‘give investors greater insight into what company boards and audit committees are doing to promote their interests’ (chairman of the FRC Baroness Hogg, reported by Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom FRC on 28/12/2012). Looking ahead, the FRC will carry out further consultation on whether changes are needed to those parts of the Code dealing with remuneration when the government’s legislation on remuneration reporting and voting has been finalised. Any changes following this consultation will be effected in the next edition of the Code. Remuneration Design (Schemes) Leaving aside perquisites, pension rights,9 and other additional benefits,10 executive directors’ pay packages in most of the large UK companies contain three basic elements: (i) base salary, (ii) bonus and (iii) long-term performance-contingent pay, that is equity-based compensation, principally ESOs and LTIPs (Bruce, 2005; Conyon & Murphy, 2000; Jenson, Murphy, & Wruck, 2004; Murphy, 1999).11 The key components of UK executive directors’ remuneration are discussed below: (1) Base salary Base salary is received by an executive ‘in accordance with the terms of his contract’ (Mallin, 2007). That is, it is the ‘fixed component’ in executive compensation contract, not related to any performance conditions. Base salary is usually determined through competitive ‘benchmarking’, based primarily on general industry and peer group salary surveys, typically adjusted for company size. Such method used in determining base salaries ‘formalizes and reinforces the observed relation between compensation and size’, and moreover, ‘contributes to a ‘ratchet effect in executive base salary levels’. Base salary is essential as most other components such as target bonus, option grants are measured relative to base salary levels (Murphy, 1999). (2) Annual Bonus An annual bonus plan typically ties to a firm’s single-year (usually the previous financial year) accounting performance. The payments may be made in cash or shares or a combination. While companies use a range of performance measures, almost all companies rely on some measure of accounting 9 Pension rights refer to both compulsory and voluntary company contributions to pension plans. 10 Sometimes executive compensation contract contains provision for severance pay as well, which is not considered in our discussion. 11 Among those pay components, base salary is also called fixed pay, and other components called variable pay or contingent pay. 103 104 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU profits, for example EBIT, ROE, EPS growth (Murphy, 1999). There is a trend that an increasing number of companies use multiple performance measures rather than a single measure in their annual incentive plan. Meanwhile, non-financial performance measures, such as individual performance, and broad strategic and operational targets, are increasingly adopted by companies as complements to financial measures. For instance, it is reported that in 2010, more than 60% of FTSE 100 companies use three or more measures for their annual bonus plans, while about 80% of FTSE 250 companies use either two or three measures, and the most common combination of performance measures is some form of profit measure in conjunction with personal performance and corporate/strategic targets (KPMG, 2010). For large UK companies, many of them may also have deferred annual bonus (DAB) plans, which involve deferral of part of the annual bonus into company shares (deferred shares), restricted for a period of time (most commonly three years). Some (but not all of) DAB plans provide for matching shares, which typically vested to the extent that performance conditions are met over the performance period, with EPS, TSR, or some forms of combination the most common performance measures (KPMG, 2010). (3) Share Option Plans Share option plans (ESOs) are contracts which give the recipient the right to buy shares of stock at a pre-specified ‘exercise’ price over a pre-specified time period, and therefore provide a direct link between executive pay and share-price performance (more specifically, a direct link between managerial rewards and shareprice appreciation) (Conyon & Murphy, 2000; Murphy, 1999). ESOs typically become ‘vested’ (exercisable) over time, that is ‘restricted’ share options (e.g. 25% might become exercisable in each of the four years following grant). In the United Kingodm, the structure of share option contract may be more complex because the vesting of the option often depends on meeting a specific performance condition (performance criteria) with ‘real EPS growth’ the most common measurement (KPMG, 2010, p. 57). As Conyon et al. (2000) commented that ‘unlike US CEO option contract, the stock options received by UK CEOs are often subject to performance criteria prior to vesting. That is, the right to exercise the executive option is contingent upon the achievement of company performance targets, and not simply elapsed time’. Interestingly, it is revealed in the United Kingodm, ‘there is little cross-sectional variation’ in the practice of option granting. Most options ‘expire in 10 years and are granted with Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom exercise prices equal to the fair market price on date of grant’. Consequently, in terms of the form of ESO schemes, there is a tendency towards ‘standardization’ (Bruce, 2005; KPMG, 2010; Murphy, 1999), which may be explained in part by favourable tax and accounting treatments (Murphy, 1999). The most widely used method for calculating the company’s cost of granting an executive option is the Black-Scholes formula 1973, which demonstrates that under the assumption of risk-neutrality, ‘option values can be estimated by computing the expected value of the option upon exercise and discounting this expected value to the grand date using the risk free-rate’ (Conyon & Murphy, 2000; Murphy, 1999). ESO plans now constitute the single largest component (on a Black-Scholes basis) of executive pay in the US owning to the explosion in stock option grants during the period of 1980s and 1990s, which was driven by a combination of political, economic, institutional and cultural factors (Murphy, 1999). By contrast, in the United Kingodm, the 1990s witnessed a significant decline in the relative importance of ESO schemes within executive pay packages due to institutional and cultural constrains imposed. This trend has been continuing and it is reported that by year 2010, less than 20% of the FTSE top 350 companies used ESO schemes to reward their executives (KPMG, 2010). (4) Long-Term Incentive Plans In the United Kingodm, LTIPs are typically grants of shares that become ‘vested’ (ownership is transferred to the executives) upon achievement of certain performance criteria (also known as LTIP share grants or performance share grants). In particular, for the performance-contingent UK grants, LTIPs may be regarded as ‘a conditional ESO scheme with a zero exercise price, whereby it is shares rather than a right to purchase shares which are rewarded to eligible executives’ (Bruce, 2005). Awards under LTIPs are contingent on the achievement of a level of relative performance evaluated against comparator groups over a specified period of time, commonly three years (there are essentially three bases for comparison, which may be employed individually or in combination: a given real growth in the chosen performance yardstick, e.g. RPI + n% growth in TSR, a published market/sector index, e.g. the FTSE 250 index, or a peer group, with peer groups the most common benchmark against which to evaluate performance) (Bruce, 2005; KPMG, 2010). There is a remarkable phenomenon that the decline in the relative significance of the ESO schemes within executive pay package ‘has been matched by the parallel increase’ in the role 105 106 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 2002 50% 2009 40% 2010 30% 20% 10% 0% LTIPs ESOs Figure 1: Percentage of Using LTIPs in FTSE 100 Companies 20022010. Source: The High Pay Commission (2011). of LTIPs since 1990s. The shift towards LTIPs in large UK companies has become significant after the Greenbury Report in 1995 (Bruce, 2005). By 2010, around 80% of the FTSE top 350 companies used LTIPs to make rewards to their executives (KPMG, 2010). And for FTSE 100 companies, this figure was even over 90%, while the proportion of using share options in FTSE 100 companies has declined to only around 30%, as shown in Figure 1. Interestingly, it is argued that the remarkable movement away from ESOs towards LTIPs raises a significant governance issue in the sense that ESOs may automatically guarantee rewards in a rising market irrespective of corresponding increased executive effort, whereas by focusing on relative performance conditions, LTIPs are relatively insensitive to broad market trends but critically, it may also have the potential to reward executives even when share-price performance is declining. Therefore, compared with ESOs, more complex, less standardised and transparent LTIP plans (partially owning to relatively less regulatory constrains) may be potentially ‘more susceptible … to abuse by self-serving executives’ (Bruce, 2005; Bruce & Buck, 2005). Finally, we look into the executive directors’ remuneration in the UK-listed companies based on a sample of FTSE All-Share nonfinancial companies over the period of 20022011. The remuneration data is collected from BoardEx database. Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics on CEO annual compensation, and the average Table 1: Variable N Executive Directors’ Compensation in UK Listed Companies. Mean S.D. Min 0.25 Median 0.75 Max 270.00 393.00 568.00 2671.00 Panel A. Descriptive statistics on CEO compensation (20022011) (£000’s) 2733 449.56 265.47 0.00 Bonus 2679 361.81 506.24 0.00 67.00 205.00 454.00 5137.00 Total Salary + Bonus 2739 802.46 680.28 0.00 378.00 600.00 985.00 5430.00 Total Equity Compensation 2179 1414.61 3332.41 0.00 236.00 541.00 1372.00 87901.00 Total Annual Compensation 2722 1939.88 3362.00 11.00 558.00 1018.00 2097.00 90151.00 203.50 287.00 411.17 2671.00 Panel B. Descriptive statistics on executive average compensation (20022011) (£000’s) Salary 2764 331.51 196.16 0.00 Bonus 2728 240.84 301.70 0.00 54.50 147.04 317.38 3333.33 Total Salary + Bonus 2770 566.57 440.54 0.00 282.75 440.88 706.25 3447.67 Total Equity Compensation 2366 895.20 1904.35 0.00 160.50 378.38 918.50 41203.50 Total Annual Compensation 2757 1297.44 1815.91 8.00 416.00 748.00 1457.00 33988.80 Source: Original data are collected from BoardEx database. Notes: 1. The sample consists of all the non-financial companies from FTSE All-Share Index over financial year 20022011. 2. The valuation of salary and bonus is the amount that is actually paid during the period. 3. The total value of equity-based compensation is the sum of value of shares awarded, value of LTIPs awarded and estimated value of options awarded (using Black-Scholes option pricing model). 4. The total annual compensation is the sum of the value of cash compensation (salary plus bonus) and equity-based compensation. Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom Salary 107 108 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU Total Equity Compensation Bonus Salary Figure 2: CEO Compensation in UK Listed Companies Over 20022011 (£000’s). Source: Original data are collected from BoardEx database. Notes: 1. The sample consists of all the non-financial companies from FTSE All-Share Index over financial year 20022011. 2. The valuation of salary and bonus is the amount that is actually paid during the period. 3. The total value of equity-based compensation is the sum of value of shares awarded, value of LTIPs awarded and estimated value of options awarded (using Black-Scholes option pricing model). 4. The total annual compensation is the sum of the value of cash compensation (salary plus bonus) and equity-based compensation. annual compensation of all the company’s executive directors (including the CEO), supported by Figures 2 and 3, demonstrating the historical trend of the mean value of CEO compensation and executive average compensation over the sample period. Panel A of Table 1 illustrates CEO total annual compensation and its components for the whole sample period. On average, a CEO receives £1,939,880 total annual compensation each year, which includes £1,414,610 equity compensation (accounting for 63.81% of the total remuneration), £449,560 salary (accounting for 20.28% of the total compensation), and £361,810 bonus (accounting for 16.32% of the total compensation). Thus, the equity-based compensation (the sum of share options, current share rewards and LTIPs) emerges as the largest component of CEO compensation in UK listed companies. Figure 2 demonstrates the evolution of CEO compensation over the sample period. Firstly, there appears an overall persistent rise in CEO total compensation level with an average of more than twofold growth from £1134,560 in year 2002 to £2,378,900 in year 2011. The total annual compensation increased at an average rate of 12.8% per annum that has gone much beyond Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom Total Equity Compensation Bonus 109 Salary Figure 3: Executive Average Compensation in UK Listed Companies Over 20022011 (£000’s). Source: Original data are collected from BoardEx database. Notes: 1. The sample consists of all the non-financial companies from FTSE All-Share Index over financial year 20022011. 2. The valuation of salary and bonus is the amount that is actually paid during the period. 3. The total value of equity-based compensation is the sum of value of shares awarded, value of LTIPs awarded and estimated value of options awarded (using Black-Scholes option pricing model). 4. The total annual compensation is the sum of the value of cash compensation (salary plus bonus) and equity-based compensation. the annual performance of the FTSE All-Share Index (the Index) during the same period (the 10-year annualised total return of the Index) which is only 4.8%,12 indicating that there is hardly a link between executive pay and firm performance in UK listed companies. Meanwhile, accompanying the strong upward trend, there also appears some volatility in the level of CEO total compensation. Three temporary declines in CEO total compensation appeared in year 2006, 2008 and 2011, coinciding with the Index performance fluctuations which decreased significantly in year 2006, 2008 and 201113 (the biggest drop in year 2008 is in connection with the global financial crisis during 20082009). Moreover, the rise of equity-based compensation contributes the most to the increase of CEO total compensation over the sample period, which makes up 12 FTSE All-Share Index factsheet, as at 30 June, 2011, from FTSE website. The year-on-year performance (total return) of FTSE All-Share was 16.8% in 2006 (dropped from 22.0% in 2005), −29.9% in 2008, −3.5% in 2011 respectively (FTSE All-Share Index factsheet, as at 31 December, 2012, from FTSE website). 13 110 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU more than 60% of CEO total compensation in the sample firms (an average of 59.34% of the total compensation in year 2002 to 62.98% in year 2011). The executive compensation (see Panel B of Table 1 and Figure 3) shows the same patterns with CEO compensation as discussed above (in terms of the pay structure and the historical trend), but the average pay level of executive directors is significantly lower than the CEOs’. Specifically, on average, an executive receives £1,297,440 total annual compensation each year (compared with GBP 1,939,880 of the CEOs), including an average of £331,510 salary (accounting for 22.68% of the total compensation), £240,840 bonus (accounting for 16.48% of the total compensation), and £895,200 equity-based compensation (accounting for 61.24% of the total compensation). Remuneration Reporting DIRECTORS’ REMUNERATION REPORT REGULATIONS 2002 Following a consultation document on directors’ remuneration the UK government announced that further reform on remuneration disclosure would be required, and as a result, the Directors’ Remuneration Report Regulations 2002 (the Regulations14), specifying the content of directors’ remuneration reports, came into force for all UK incorporated quoted companies from 31 December 2002, which are contained in the relevant sections of the Companies Act 2006.15 As stated by the DTI, the purpose of the legislation is to: enhance transparency in setting directors’ pay; improve accountability; and provide for a more effective performance linkage. The Regulations require listed companies to produce a detailed annual directors’ remuneration report, which should include the following information (Ferrarini, Moloney, & Vespro, 2003, p. 17): (i) Remuneration committee. The report must name each director who was a member of the committee; The report also must name any person who provided the committee with advice or service; (ii) Remuneration policy. The report must include a statement of the company’s remuneration policy for the following financial year and for subsequent financial years. The statement must 14 Schedule 8 of the Large and Medium-sized Companies and Groups (Accounts and Reports) Regulations 2008. 15 Sections 420422, 439 Companies Act 2006. Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom include, for each director, detailed summary of any performance conditions chosen to which any entitlement to share options or LTIPs is subject, the reason for using of the performance conditions and the performance assessment methods; other terms and conditions for each director’ s remuneration, and contract duration, notice period and termination payments under such contracts; the report much also contains a performance graph which sets out the total shareholder return of the company; (iii) Detailed audit financial information. This should include for each director during the financial year, emoluments, share options, LTIPs, pensions, sums paid to third parties in respect of directors’ duties. Moreover, the Regulations require listed companies to hold a shareholder vote on that report. It is required that either shareholders should be allowed to vote on the remuneration report at the AGM (annual general meeting), or that special procedures are created to allow shareholders to move a resolution on remuneration at the AGM, which is known as ‘say on pay’ (Keasey & Watson 1991). In sum, the key requirements of the Regulations involve the following two aspects: • First, it sets out the legal requirement prescribing the form and content of the directors’ remuneration report. • Second, it sets out the mandatory requirement that companies must submit their remuneration report to an annual advisory vote at their AGM, separately from votes on any other matters (According to the Regulations, Section 7, the existing directors must ensure the resolution is put to the vote of the AGM. If they fail to do so, each existing director is guilty of an offence and liable to a fine). Taken together, the regulations represent ‘the largest step towards full disclosure to date’ (Roach, 2002) which have greatly improved the transparency on executive remuneration in the United Kingodm by enforcing detailed disclosure of executive remuneration in the UK-listed companies. Moreover, the regulations emphasise the role of shareholders in executive pay setting and encourage shareholders to engage in companies’ pay-setting process by giving them (advisory) voting right on remuneration reports. THE 2012 DIRECTORS’ REMUNERATION REPORTING REFORM Following the publication of a discussion paper on executive remuneration (BIS, 2011) seeking views on how to improve remuneration 111 112 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU policies in the United Kingodm, in June 2012, the UK government announced that further reforms are needed to tackle ‘the failings in the corporate governance framework for executive remuneration’ that have been exposed during the latest global financial crisis. This included (i) Giving shareholders more power through binding votes, so they can hold companies to account; (ii) Boosting transparency so that what people are paid is clear and easily understood; (iii) Working with responsible business and investors to promote good practice and ensure reforms have a lasting impact (BIS, 2012a). These reforms will impact all UK incorporated quoted companies.16 The purpose of these reforms is ‘to help restore the link between pay and performance by giving shareholders the power to hold the companies they own to account. They come in the context of a drive to encourage stronger working relationships between company boards and shareholders’ (Policy paper of BIS January 2013). As such, the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills (BIS) published a consultation paper of the new reporting regulations for director’s remuneration, which will replace rather than add to the current reporting regulations. The new regulations are expected to come into force from October 2013,17 alongside the relevant sections of the Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Bill 2012,18 which will amend the relevant provisions of Companies Act 2006 and set out the shareholder voting requirements. The draft regulations specify that the directors’ remuneration report should be split into two distinct parts in order to ensure greater transparency and facilitate the new shareholder voting regime (BIS, 2012a): (i) A policy report setting out a forward-looking (future) policy on remuneration, including exit payments, and disclosure of material factors taken into account when setting pay policy. This part of the report will be subject to a binding vote and it will only be legally required when there is a shareholder vote (at a minimum this will happen every three years). (ii) An implementation report on how the policy was implemented in the past (reported) financial year. This part of the report will set out how the policy has been implemented in the reporting 16 Quoted companies, as defined by the Companies Act 2006. This means companies registered in the UK and with equity listed on the main market in the UK, in another state in the European Economic Area or on the New York Stock Exchange or NASDAQ. There are around 900 such companies. 17 The regulations will replace Schedule 8 of the Large and Medium-sized Companies and Groups (Accounts and Reports) Regulations 2008. 18 The Bill was introduced to the House of Commons on 23 May 2012, and completed its passage on 24 April 2013. Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom year, including actual payments made to directors set out as a single figure, exit payments made and disclosure of the link between company performance and pay. It will be required on an annual basis and will be subject to an advisory vote. To sum up, the proposed legislation and regulations will require: • A two-part structure to the directors’ remuneration report comprising a forward-looking statement relating to the company’s future pay policy (the Policy Statement) and an implementation report disclosing pay received or earned and termination payments made with respect to the reported financial year (the Implementation Report); • A binding shareholder vote on the Policy Statement, every three years or sooner if there are changes made to it; and a nonbinding annual shareholder vote on the Implementation Report; • The new regime therefore will provide a more robust framework within which companies and shareholders can set, agree and implement pay policy so as to restore a stronger, clearer link between pay and performance in UK companies. Remuneration Challenges PROBLEMS IN UK EXECUTIVE REMUNERATION As we mentioned earlier, the recent financial crisis and the subsequent economic downturn in western economies have once again provoked the debate on director’s compensation especially in terms of the highly controversial executive pay-setting issue. In particular, in the United Kingodm, the concern has focused on the problems that ‘the link between pay and performance has grown weak; and the constant, ratcheting up of executive pay is unsustainable’ (Business Secretary Vince Cable; BIS, 2012a). There has emerged a consensus among business leaders, investors, academics and governance experts that the rising executive pay is not linked to firm performance (BIS, 2012a). It is revealed that the average total remuneration19 of FTSE 100 CEOs had a fourfold increase from an average of £1m to £4.2m (13.6% a year) for the period 19982010. This is faster than the increase in the FTSE 100 index, retail prices or average remuneration levels across all employees for the same period (BIS, 2012b), 19 This figure includes salary, bonus, deferred bonus, other benefits, longterm incentives, share options and pensions. 113 114 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU Executive remuneration in FTSE 250 companies has also risen fast, although at a slower rate, while growth in average CEO salaries in Small Cap and AIM companies has been more modest (Hutton Review, 2010, cited in BIS, 2012b, p. 6). Consistent with the above findings, our statistic data on executive directors’ remuneration in FTSE All-Share companies over years 20022011 also suggest that there is hardly a link between executive pay and firm performance in UK listed companies (see the discussion in section ‘Remuneration Design (Schemes)’). Moreover, there is compelling evidence of a disconnection between pay and performance in UK companies. Researchers have studied the relationship between executive directors’ pay and long-term performance in the United Kingodm, whereas little evidence of the link between pay and performance has been found (refer to the recent evidence of Bell & Reenen, 2011; Gregg et al., 2010; BIS, 2012b). In particular, research also revealed that there is an asymmetric sensitivity of pay to performance. That is, top executive pay appears to go up when performance is good, but there is comparatively less elasticity downwards when performance is average or poor. As a result, average levels of executive pay have ratcheted upwards (Bell & Reenen, 2011, cited in BIS, 2012a). Meanwhile, the increasingly complex pay structure moving towards incentive payments (LTIPs, share options, and bonus) over the last decade (BIS, 2012b) has led to increasing length and complexity of company reports, which make it more difficult for report users to identify the main facts and figures amongst lots of other detailed information in the current Directors’ Remuneration Report. It is clear that regulations for pay reporting have not kept up with developments in market practice (BIS, 2012b). In particular, despite companies already being required to give full disclosure of remuneration under the Directors’ Remuneration Regulations (2002), companies do not give a clear figure for total remuneration for each individual director nor do they seem to provide a clear line of sight between levels and structure of remuneration and directors’ performance in meeting the company’s strategic objectives. It is also highlighted that in some areas the Regulations themselves add to some of this complexity as it can be difficult to understand and that clarification of what is expected could improve compliance in these areas (BIS, 2012b). Feedback to the consultation on company reporting led by BIS also suggests that without access to better and more concise information about pay, particularly on the link to performance, shareholders find it difficult to hold companies to account (BIS, 2012b). Therefore, two problems in UK remuneration practices have been highlighted in recent scrutiny which are the divergence of executive pay from firm performance and decreased transparency Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom caused by increasingly complex remuneration report, indicating ‘the failings in the corporate governance framework for executive remuneration’ (BIS, 2012a). CHALLENGES FOR REMUNERATION POLICY In response to the failure in the governance of directors’ remuneration, in June 2012, the government has announced a comprehensive package of reforms to address these failures, including binding shareholder votes and greater transparency (see detailed discussion in previous section). On 25 April 2013, the Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Bill 2013 received Royal Assent and has become a law which includes new rules relating to quoted companies’ disclosure of directors’ remuneration and shareholder approval of directors’ remuneration reports. It gives effect to the new regime from 1 October 2013. The final regulations remain unchanged from the draft published in June. Once in force, directors’ remuneration reports will be split into two parts: a forward-looking pay policy report, which will be subject to the binding shareholder vote; and a report on how that policy was implemented over the previous year, which will be subject to an advisory vote. The new regulations will apply to UK incorporated quoted companies with financial years commencing on or after that date. However, there are limitations to how effective these legislations will be alone. In particular, shareholders and remuneration committees, as currently constituted, arguably lack the will to curb executive pay. Since most remuneration committee members are current/ former lead executives themselves, they have strong sympathies with the executives whose pay levels they are deciding, and operate on the understanding that if their pay award is generous, they will benefit from decisions made by other committee members, as part of a general upward trend in pay awards. In recent years, the proliferation of international investors and short-term shareholdings on UK equity market (FRC, 2011, 2012a, 2012b) means that it is increasingly unlikely that shareholders are actually in a position to hold the executive to account. Therefore, to instil these changes in companies’ governance culture and behaviour will require the complement of corporate governance codes and guidelines (FRC, 2012a, 2012b). Acknowledgements The authors are grateful for the financial supported provided by the National Social Science Foundation of China (ID: 10ZD&035), the National Natural Science Foundation of China (ID: 71132001) and 115 116 JEAN J. CHEN AND ZHEN ZHU the Programme for Changjiang Scholars and Innovative Research Team in Nankai University (PCSIRT). References Bell, B., & van Reenan, J. (2011). Firm performance and wages: Evidence from across the corporate hierarchy. LSE. Retrieved from http://cep.lse.ac.uk/conference_papers/ 04_11_2011/BellVReenen_FirmPerformanceandWages.pdf BIS. (2011). Executive remuneration. Discussion paper. London: Department for Business Innovation and Skills. BIS. (2012a). Directors’ pay: Consultation on revised remuneration reporting regulations. London: Department for Business Innovation and Skills. BIS. (2012b). Improved transparency of executive remuneration reporting: Impact assessment. London: Department for Business Innovation and Skills. Bruce, A., & Buck, T. (2005). Executive pay and UK corporate governance. In K. Keasey, S. Thompson, & M. Wright (Eds.), Corporate governance: Accountability, enterprise, and international comparisons (pp. 117135). West Sussex: John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Cadbury Report. (1992). Report of the committee on the financial aspects of corporate governance. London: Gee. Committee on Corporate Governance. (1998). Final report [Hampel Report]. London: Gee. Conyon, M., & Murphy, K. (2000). The prince and the pauper? CEO pay in the US and UK. Economic Journal, 110, 640671. Conyon, M. J., Peck, S. I., Read, L. E., & Sadler, G. V. (2000). The structure of executive compensation contracts: UK evidence. Long Range Planning, 33, 478503. DTI. (2001). Modern company law for a competitive economy: Final report. London: DTI. Ferrarini, G., Moloney, N., & Vespro, C. (2003). Executive remuneration in the EU: Comparative law and practice. Working paper, University Genoa and ECGI. FRC. (2011). Developments in corporate governance 2011. London: Financial Report Council. FRC. (2012a). Developments in corporate governance 2012. London: Financial Report Council. FRC. (2012b, Spetember). Feedback statement: Revisions to the UK corporate governance code and guidance on audit committees. London: Financial Report Council. Gregg, P., Jewell, S., & Tonks, I. (2010). Executive pay and performance in the UK. LSE. Retrieved from http://www2.lse.ac.uk/fmg/workingPapers/discussionPapers/ DP657_2010_ExecutivePayandPerformanceintheUK.pdf Higgs, D. (2003). Review of the role and effectiveness of non-executive directors. London: DTI. Hutton Review of Fair Pay in the public sector, Interim Report. (2010, December). Retrieved from http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/hutton_interim_report.pdf Jenson, M. C., Murphy, K. J., & Wruck, E. (2004). Remuneration: Where we’ve been, how we got there, what are the problems, and how to fix them. Working Paper No. 44/2004. Harvard University and The European Corporate Governance Institute. Directors’ Remuneration in the United Kingdom Keasey, K., Short, H., & Wright, M. (2005). The development of corporate government codes in the UK’. In K. Keasey, S. Thompson, & M. Wright (Eds.), Corporate governance: Accountability, enterprise, and international comparisons (pp. 2144). West Sussex: Wiley. Keasey, K., & Watson, R. (1991). Financial distress prediction models: A review of their usefulness. British Journal of Management, 2, 89102. KPMG. (2010). KPMG’s guide to executive remuneration 2010. London: KPMG LLP. Mallin, C. A. (2007). Corporate governance (2nd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Murphy, K. J. (1999). Executive compensation. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labour economics (Vol. 3, pp. 24852563). Amsterdam: NorthHolland. Roach, L. (2002). The director’s remuneration report regulations 2002 and the disclosure of executive remuneration. Working paper, Cardiff University. Smith, R. (2003). Audit committees combined code guidance [Smith Report]. London: Financial Reporting Council. Solomon, J. F. (2010). Corporate governance and accountability (3rd ed.). New York, NY: Wiley. The High Pay Commission. (2011). What are we paying for? Exploring executive pay and performance. Working paper, The High Pay Commission. Retrieved from http:// www.mbsportal.bl.uk/secure/subjareas/accfinecon/highpaycommission/126842whatare wepayingfor11.pdf. Accessed on March 13, 2013. The Walker Report. (2009). A review of corporate governance in UK banks and other financial industry entities. Tricker, B. (2009). Corporate governance: Principles, policies, and practice. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 117 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 8 Directors’ Remuneration in Germany Markus Stiglbauer, Julia Wittek and Sven Thalmann Remuneration Regulation THE GERMAN TWO-TIER SYSTEM In general, there are two common sets of rules when it comes to corporate governance systems: one-tier board systems and two-tier board systems. Whereas the one-tier board system is primarily found in Anglo-Saxon countries, Germany is one among other countries like Finland, Austria or Denmark that are well-known for their twotier system. The main difference between these two systems is that in the one-tier system both executive and non-executive directors form one board, the board of directors, while the two-tier system follows the concept of an organizational separation of management and supervision implemented through the management board (Vorstand) and the supervisory board (Aufsichtsrat). This principle of separation which applies for all stock corporations regardless of their size and workforce is granted by the German Stock Corporation Act (GSCA Aktiengesetz) which prohibits a simultaneous membership on both boards of the same company (§ 105 GSCA). According to § 76 GSCA the management board is in charge of the management of the firm and its representation in and out of court (§ 78 GSCA). The duties of the supervisory board include the appointment and dismissal of board directors (§ 84 GSCA), monitoring the management board as well as approving fundamental business decisions (§ 111 GSCA; Stiglbauer, Fischer, & Velte, 2012). The members of the supervisory board are elected by the shareholders at the general meeting (§ 101 GSCA), as referenced in 119 120 MARKUS STIGLBAUER ET AL. Figure 1: German Two-Tier System. Source: Stiglbauer (2010). Figure 1. In Germany the supervisory board consists of at least three up to a maximum of 21 members depending on the company’s share capital but the board number has to be divisible by three (§ 95 GSCA). Major stock corporations are subject to employee representatives on the supervisory board (co-determination). This means that depending on the size of the company the supervisory board must comprise two thirds of shareholder representatives and one third of employee representatives for companies with more than 500 employees (§ 4 One-third Participation Act) or one half of shareholder and the other half of employee representatives for companies with more than 2,000 employees, respectively (§ 7 Co-Determination Act). For major stock corporations, in the event of a tie vote, the chairman of the supervisory board has a casting vote according to § 29 Co-Determination Act. In order to prepare its deliberations and resolutions or for supervision purposes, the supervisory board is recommended to appoint one or more committees from among its members (§ 107 GSCA). This includes an audit committee of which the main tasks are the supervision of accounting processes, the efficiency of risk management, and internal control systems as well as external audit (§ 107 GSCA). Unlike committees in Anglo-Saxon countries, German committees are very restricted in their authorities and act in a more preparatory way (Ziemons, 2000). The main idea behind that limitation is that decisions should only be made with the consent of the supervisory board and cannot be delegated to single board members (§ 107 GSCA). REMUNERATION REGULATION OF THE MANAGEMENT BOARD AND SUPERVISORY BOARD In general, the remuneration of the management board and the supervisory board is regulated in the GSCA (§§ 87, 113 GSCA). As the GSCA does not define a specific structure of the remuneration of management and supervisory board members in German listed Directors’ Remuneration in Germany companies, the German Government commission introduced the German Code of Corporate Governance (GCCG) in 2002 (Schaller, 2011). The GCCG affects the structure of the remuneration, as German listed companies have to submit a declaration of conformity with the GCCG and have to explain every departure from the Code (Schaller, 2011). The guidelines regarding the remuneration of the management board are to be found in the article 4.2 and for the supervisory board in the article 5.4 of the GCCG. Due to the everrising quest for sustainability and transparency, the German Government has increasingly concerned itself with the remuneration of managers in the past years. Besides the already existing GCCG since 2002, the German Government passed the Management Board Remuneration Disclosure Act (VorstOG Vorstandsvergütungs Offenlegungsgesetz) in 2006. The law forces publicly traded corporations to provide detailed disclosure of both performance and nonperformance-based compensation as well as long-term incentives of each board member in the notes. Originally, the law was introduced to give companies an incentive to establish appropriate, performance-based management compensation due to increased transparency (Stiglbauer et al., 2012). Unfortunately the plan failed to succeed. Due to a lack of binding standardized presentation in the annual reports like, for example, in the UK, companies used this loophole to report management salary figures in such a circumstantial way that it was almost impossible to comprehend or compare (Ribaudo, 2006). Against all expectations, salaries even increased and it was argued that one cannot separately evaluate the performance of individual board members (Müller, 2009). With this and the financial crisis taking its toll in 2008, the Act Regarding the Appropriateness of Management Board’s Remuneration (VorstAG Gesetz zur Angemessenheit der Vorstandsvergütung) came into force on August 5, 2009 (Klöhn, 2012). The basic idea of this law is to link the variable compensation of the management board to the company’s development on the basis of several years’ assessment data. The criteria for the assessment of the management board’s remuneration have been tightened and are more specific than before. Thus, the supervisory board can reduce the remuneration if the company’s business situation deteriorates to such an extent that such remuneration could not be justified (GSCA § 87; Klöhn, 2012). For example, before this regulation, the supervisory board was entitled to reduce the management’s compensation in case of great unfairness for the company. Now, after the introduction of the VorstAG, the supervisory board is expected to cut down management compensation to a reasonable level (Klöhn, 2012). Due to the new regulation the supervisory board is not only given a stricter 121 122 MARKUS STIGLBAUER ET AL. responsibility in judging the appropriateness of the management board’s compensation, it is also held liable for agreeing to unreasonable high management remuneration (GSCA § 116). Remuneration Design (Schemes) REMUNERATION OF THE MANAGEMENT BOARD In exchange for their know-how and managing abilities, the management board has to be granted an appropriate remuneration system which is set by the full supervisory board. As mentioned before, the GSCA is quite general when it comes to board remuneration which is why it is also very useful to look at the German Code of Governance. According to the GCCG, the supervisory board is responsible for the determination of the total compensation of each board member which includes monetary compensation components, retirement benefits, other benefits, especially in the event of termination of employment, fringe benefits, and benefits by third parties, which were promised or granted with regard to the work of the management board (GCCG 4.2.3). Moreover, the supervisory board has to ensure proportionality between the approved compensation and the duties and performance of such member as well as the company situation and that the remuneration does not exceed standard remuneration without any special reasons. Furthermore, the remuneration structure of listed companies should be aimed at a sustainable corporate development (§ 87 para. 1 GSCA; Ringleb, Kremer, Lutter, & Werder, 2014). In order to achieve this § 87 GCSA and the GCCG 4.2.3 also recommend a variable next to a fixed remuneration (Stiglbauer et al., 2012; Velte, Weber, & Stiglbauer, 2013). The GCCG further recommends that the monetary compensation components should comprise fixed and variable components (GCCG 4.2.3). The fixed components are not performance-related and are usually paid monthly (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). The GSCA and the GCCG state that the supervisory board has to make sure that variable components are based on a multi-year assessment which considers both, positive and negative developments (GSCA § 87, GCCG 4.2.3). The variable components are performance-related and comprise variable cash compensation and share-based compensation. The variable cash compensation includes royalties and bonuses and is usually paid annually. The amount of the variable cash compensation depends on the achievement of pre-defined objectives, which may differ significantly between companies (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). For example, the amount of variable cash compensation may Directors’ Remuneration in Germany depend on the revenues or the profit of the company. In addition, companies may also use more than one objective for the determination of the variable cash compensation. In Germany, absolute accounting performance measures such as EBIT (Earnings before Interest and Taxes) are most commonly used (Götz & Friese, 2013). However, relative accounting performance measures such as ROA (Return on Assets) or RONA (Return on Net Assets) and valuebased measures such as EVA (Economic Value Added) are rarely applied. From the perspective of the value-based management, the use of such performance measures is preferable, as they are significantly more meaningful than absolute accounting performance measures (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). In their study on board remuneration of companies listed in the German DAX and MDAX, Götz and Friese (2013) found that on the average 2.6 key figures are used in the practice for the calculation of short-term variable remuneration and 2.2 key figures for the measurement of long-term variable remuneration in DAX companies. Next to personal, individual objectives, the calculation is mainly based on accounting performance measures as well as share-based performance measures. Moreover, the focus on a sustainable corporate development has also become an important issue for companies when it comes to remuneration systems. The average long-term assessment period for variable remuneration is 3.4 years among management boards of companies listed in the DAX and MDAX (Götz & Friese, 2013). The annual general meeting often authorizes the supervisory board to grant the management board shares or options (sharebased compensation). Regarding the design of the share-based compensation, the supervisory board has numerous options. In addition to real shares or real options, the supervisory board can grant the members of the management board virtual shares or virtual options. Furthermore, caps, exercise barriers, or vesting periods can be implemented. In order to avoid extremely high payouts due to an exceptional unforeseen performance of the share price, caps are often installed. Exercise barriers define when the respective management board members may sell a share or exercise an option. For example, the share price or the profit of the company has to rise by 20 percent before a share can be sold or an option can be granted. Within the vesting period, the respective management board members may not sell a share or exercise an option. The Act on the Appropriateness of Management Board Remuneration (VorstAG) calls for a vesting period of at least four years. Götz and Friese (2013) found that 57 out of 80 corporations listed in the DAX and MDAX participated in stock option programs which are implemented in order to create an optimum mix of risk and opportunity awareness among managers. Pension awards are payments by the company that are made after the termination of employment to a former member of the 123 124 MARKUS STIGLBAUER ET AL. management board. For pension awards, the supervisory board should determine the level of provision aimed in each case and consider the resulting annual and long-term expense for the company. In determining the level, the length of time for which the individual has been a member of the management board is another important factor to take into account (GCCG 4.2.3). It is standard practice and also recommended in the German Corporate Governance Code that in the event of premature termination of activity without good cause, management board contracts determine that severance payments made to the resigning board member do not exceed two years’ compensation including fringe benefits (severance payment cap) and compensate no more than the remaining term of the contract (GCCG 4.2.3). If the contract of employment is terminated for a serious cause for which the management board member is responsible, no payments are made to the management board member. The severance payment cap should be calculated on the basis of the total compensation for the past year and if appropriate the expected total compensation for the current year. Payments promised in the event of premature termination of a contract of employment due to a change of control are not to exceed 150 percent of the severance payment cap (GCCG 4.2.3). In addition to the structure of the remuneration, criteria for the appropriateness of the compensation are mentioned in the German Corporate Governance Code. According to which, the criteria are the tasks and performance of an individual management board member, the economic situation, the performance and outlook of the company, and the common level of compensation taking into account the peer companies and the structure of the remuneration in place in other areas of the company (GCCG 4.2.2). Among others, findings of a study by the Institute of Management Accounting at the Philipps-University Marburg and the Institute of Management and Control at the Georg-AugustUniversity Göttingen on the status quo of the remuneration of management boards in the German Prime Standard (DAX, MDAX, TecDAX, and SDAX) are presented (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). In the study, only the monetary compensation components were considered. Pension awards, other awards, especially in the event of termination of employment, fringe benefits, and benefits by third parties which were promised or granted with regard to the work of the management board, were not taken into account. The study showed that the effects of the financial crisis in 2007 as well as the following economic recovery of many companies are clearly reflected in the remuneration of the management board over the years. After a significant drop in 2008 and 2009, from h904 tsd. per capita in 2007 to h761 tsd. per capita in 2009, Directors’ Remuneration in Germany the total compensation rose to h951 tsd. per capita, in 2010, which equals an increase by 25 percent compared to the prior year. Thus, the average management board compensation per capita of all the companies listed in the German Prime Standard reached the pre-crisis level (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). In 2011, it further increased and exceeded the one million mark for the very first time (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). However, the level of compensation varies significantly between indices which can be seen in another study of Götz and Friese from 2013 that only looked at larger corporations and correspondingly higher management salaries listed in indices like the DAX and MDAX. With an average total salary of around h2.9 million a member of the management board of a company listed in the DAX averagely received about three times the amount of a management board member listed in the SDAX or TecDAX and approximately twice as much as a board member in the MDAX with around 1.5 million euros (Götz & Friese, 2013). In the same period the fixed board remuneration for MDAX companies was about 0.6 million euros on average compared to 0.8 million euros for the DAX. It is very interesting to find that the main difference in board remuneration between these two indices is the proportion of variable and share-based components of the total compensation. In short, 70 percent of the total salary of DAX board members and 60 percent of MDAX board members are performance-based. Although their salaries almost rose throughout the years since the economic crisis, the management boards of both DAX and MDAX still do not meet the remuneration levels from the boom year of 2007 (Götz & Friese, 2013), in contrast to the findings from the previous study by Rapp and Wolff (2012). In general, the inconsistencies between the two studies are only due to the inclusion of the board remunerations of companies listed in the TecDax and SDAX (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). In 2012, the range of board remuneration of companies listed in the DAX varied between 6.3 million euros per capita (Volkswagen AG) and 1.4 million euros (Commerzbank AG), and between 4.5 million euros (Axel Springer AG) and 0.5 million euros (GAGFAH S.A.) in the MDAX. When we look at the Prime Standard again, the proportion of fixed remuneration per head increased continuously from 55 percent in 2007 to 63 percent until 2009. Due to the rising importance of variable remuneration components, the proportion of fixed remuneration fell in 2010 and 2011. However, the proportion of fixed remuneration never fell below 50 percent which allows the conclusion that the proportion of fixed remuneration in companies listed in the MDAX, TecDAX, and SDAX (and relatively smaller revenue) are comparatively much higher than in the DAX. The economic recovery of many 125 126 MARKUS STIGLBAUER ET AL. companies after the crisis period of 2008 and 2009 is also reflected in the increase of the proportion of the variable cash compensation in 2010 and 2011. During the crisis in 2008 and 2009 the proportion of fixed remuneration rose, while the variable cash compensation diminished from 36 percent in 2007 to 30 percent in 2009 and regained its level of 36 percent in 2010 and 2011 (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). About half of the companies of the German Prime Standard use share-based compensation. Overall, the share-based compensation still plays a minor role regarding the total compensation which, in many cases, can be explained by the long-term alignment of the variable cash compensation (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). REMUNERATION OF THE SUPERVISORY BOARD According to § 113 GSCA, the remuneration of the supervisory board is determined in the articles of the company or set by the general meeting. The German Corporate Governance Code complements the article of the GSCA and contains guidance for the structure and the appropriateness of the remuneration (Lazar, Metzner, Rapp, & Wolff, 2011). Like the management board, the supervisory board’s remuneration depends on the duties and responsibilities of each member, the membership in committees, and of course the company’s success or business situation (GCCG 5.4.6; GSCA § 124; Ringleb et al., 2014). The general meeting can resolve on an amendment of the articles, for example, to reduce such remuneration, if the supervisory board compensation is determined in the articles. Usually, the remuneration consists of monetary compensation components and fringe as well as retirement benefits, but the latter only applies to full-time chairmen of the supervisory board (Emmerich & Habersack, 2008; Ringleb et al., 2014). Furthermore and again similar to the management board, the chairman of the supervisory board is usually granted a two to four times and the deputy chairman a 1.5 times higher salary than ordinary supervisory board members due to their higher responsibilities and duties (Ringleb et al., 2014). Usually, the remuneration of members of the supervisory board is composed of a fixed component, a function-related component and a variable component depending on the success of the company (Lazar et al., 2011). In case of performance-based pay it has to be made sure that the compensation is oriented towards sustainable corporate development (GCCG 5.4.6). However, there is a clear trend towards fixed remuneration and fringe benefits instead of performance-based pay, as the supervisory board’s monitoring function should be independent from a company’s success (Lazar et al., 2011; Ringleb et al., 2014). Directors’ Remuneration in Germany Remuneration Reporting As previously stated, since the introduction of the VorstOG in 2006, publicly traded corporations have to disclose detailed information on the remuneration of each member of the management and supervisory board, former members of these boards as well as the compensation of members in advisory boards in the notes (§ 285 GCC). Moreover, according to § 289 GCC the management report should provide information on the remuneration system of publicly traded companies. As corporations often disclose their remuneration system and corresponding detailed information in a separate compensation report (as a part of the management report), the German Commercial Code states that the disclosure in the notes can be omitted if the remuneration report fulfills the requirements of § 285 GCC. However, the disclosure can also be circumvented if the annual general meeting passes a resolution for a maximum of five years but only with a majority of at least 75 percent of the represented share capital (GCC § 286). Thus, only the total compensation of the management and supervisory board has to be disclosed, as the already existent transparency rules remain in force. In their study of companies listed in the German Prime Standard from 2005 to 2011, Rapp and Wolff (2012) found that since the regulatory changes in 2006 the proportion of companies that disclose individualized compensation increased from 43 percent to 81 percent until 2011. The highest increase was from 2005 to 2006, where the proportion of companies with individualized disclosures rose by 27 percent to 73 percent. In the following years, the proportion increased steadily (Rapp & Wolff, 2012). As mentioned earlier, a lot of companies, especially big corporations summarize the details of the management board members’ remuneration in a separate compensation report. Next to the remuneration itself, it has become increasingly common to give detailed information on their objectives, long-term and mid-term incentive (LTI and MTI) plans in order to achieve those targets, the term of the LTIs and MTIs, the corresponding performance measurements, the payout, and of course the renewal of such incentive plans. Moreover, many corporations provide a clear calculation table to make the remuneration structure more comprehensible for other stakeholders. As many corporations use different key figures and incentive plans for the calculation of management remuneration, the GCCG recommends that as of 2014 corporations should use remuneration model tables provided by the GCCG in order to increase transparency due to this constantly rising complexity of (variable) board remuneration systems (GCCG 4.2.5; Götz & Friese, 2013). 127 128 MARKUS STIGLBAUER ET AL. Also, the use of uniform remuneration tables would make a positive contribution to the comparability of board remuneration structures between different corporations. Remuneration Challenges The last pages gave an overview of the current remuneration situation in Germany and its development over the last few years. Of course, there are still many challenges that need to be faced and discussed. As mentioned before, the variable remuneration component of the management board is usually performance-related. Since there is no specific determination on what key figure to use for performance measurement or simply which remuneration instruments (cash, real or virtual stocks or options, uncertified securities, etc.), there will always be significant differences in variable board remuneration between companies (Prinz & Schwalbach, 2013). For example, profits heavily depend on German or international financial reporting standards and with no specific, uniform method of determination, the management board is given the opportunity to manipulate the amount of reported profits due to a large scope of assessment possibilities. In order to report higher profits in the short or medium run, the management board can, for example, neglect necessary investments which would eventually cause a serious drop in revenue or lead to significantly higher costs in the mid- or long term (Schömig, 2013). One could argue that this problem has been solved with the implementation of taking LTI and MTI plans into account but this also bears the risk of greater non-transparency. It is very difficult for stakeholders to understand the effective (variable) remuneration of board members over several years due to the persisting individual and highly complex variable remuneration systems. The long-term character of these remuneration instruments causes time-delayed success and final payments that comply neither with the value at the grant date nor with the original success expectations (Götz & Friese, 2013). Moreover, it was found that not a single of the DAX30 corporations retroactively informs about achieving targets of mid- or long-term performance indicators quantitatively or accumulated over the years in their compensation reports and followed by a proper goal achievement analysis (Prinz & Schwalbach, 2013). Especially, the still remaining lack of transparency when it comes to, for example, the consideration of individual and taskrelated criteria of board members other than the chairman, salaries of former board members, selection, measurement, and weighting of non-financial criteria are just a few more crucial points that will Directors’ Remuneration in Germany have to be improved or need special attention in the future (Prinz & Schwalbach, 2013). However, substantial changes are about to come in the next years. In 2013, the German Government planned to pass the Act to Improve the Supervision of Board Remuneration and Amendment of Further Stock Corporation Law Provisions (VorstKoG Gesetz zur Verbesserung der Kontrolle der Vorstandsvergütung und Änderung weiterer aktienrechtlicher Vorschriften) which legitimates the annual general meeting to decide on management board remuneration at the proposal of the supervisory board (§ 120 GSCA “Say on Pay”). The Law did not come into force as the German Federal Council dropped the passing immediately prior to the parliamentary elections (Peters & Hecker, 2013). The Federal Council justified their decision with the resulting imbalance of power between the three company bodies: management board, supervisory board, and general meeting. If the supervisory board was only able to make restricted decisions on management board remuneration, it would fail to have an important leverage for the implementation of their supervisory functions. Due to the strengthening of the general meeting there would also be a shift from employee to equity interests. Furthermore, it could be difficult for the supervisory board to establish a sustainable and long-term remuneration policy when depending on the annual stockholder vote (Deutscher Bundestag, 2013). However, it turns out that the coalition agreement of the new government coalition between the Christian Democratic Party and the Social Democratic Party stipulates the passing of the VorstKoG in order to reinforce the general meeting and thus to indirectly regulate inflated management salaries. The second passage regarding the determination of a maximum ratio between the total remuneration of management board members and the average employee salary of the company has been removed from the coalition agreement (Hoppe, Kersting, & Hofmann, 2013). However, the future will show if this is the right path to go. In their study, Götz and Friese (2013) criticize the limitation of board remuneration to absolute amounts as board remuneration should be set in relation to the revenues they generate. For example, the excessive remuneration of the management board of the Volkswagen AG has often been criticized in the past years. But if the remuneration is put in relation to the EBIT of the business year, with a ratio of 0.50 percent VW is far below the DAX average of 0.80 percent (Götz & Friese, 2013). Thus, it remains questionable if general meetings are really able to properly estimate the value of management boards’ remuneration. When it comes to the remuneration system of supervisory boards, it is interesting to find that opinions differ widely on the market. On the one hand there is a growing tendency toward a solely fixed remuneration on the grounds that members of the 129 130 MARKUS STIGLBAUER ET AL. supervisory board should be paid well in both good times and bad in order to fulfill their monitoring functions independently from the expected amount of compensation. On the other hand, it is argued that unlike external consultants, the supervisory board is also responsible for the long-term strategy of a company and therefore should benefit from long-term and sustained corporate success, too (Fockenbrock, 2013). Moreover, the growing gap between highly (e.g., Volkswagen AG) and poorly paid supervisory board members who claim for a better compensation adapted to their greater responsibilities will require a lot of attention in the next years. Although one could see that much has been done to regulate board remuneration in the past years, there still remain serious issues that need to be dealt with and eventually be solved. It is up to the German Government and the economy to find solutions through binding regulations or voluntary rules (e.g., GCCG) in order to reduce these current problems and minimize prospective challenges. References Deutscher Bundestag (Ed.). (2013). Anrufung des Vermittlungsausschusses zum Gesetz zur Verbesserung der Kontrolle der Vorstandsvergütung und zur Änderung weiterer aktienrechtlicher Vorschriften (VorstKoG), printed matter 17/14790. Emmerich, V., & Habersack, M. (2008). Aktien- und GmbH-Konzernrecht, Vol. 5. München: C.H. Beck. Fockenbrock, D. (2013). Aufsichtsräte steigen auf Fixgehalt um. Handelsblatt, 11/13/ 2013, p. 21. Götz, A., & Friese, N. (2013). Vorstandsvergütung im DAX und MDAX 2012 Fortsetzung der empirischen Analyse nach Einführung des Vorstandsvergütungsangemessenheitsgesetzes. Corporate Finance Biz, 4(6), 374383. Hoppe, T., Kersting, S., & Hofmann, S. (2013). Koalition entschärft Regeln für Gehälter. Handelsblatt, 11/27/2013, p. 11. Klöhn, L. (2012). Die Herabsetzung der Vorstandsvergütung gem. § 87 Abs. 2 AktG in der börsennotierten Aktiengesellschaft. Zeitschrift für Unternehmens und Gesellschaftsrecht, 41(1), 134. Lazar, C., Metzner, Y., Rapp, M. S., & Wolff, M. (2011). Praxis der Aufsichtsratsvergütung in börsennotierten Unternehmen Status Quo und Herausforderungen. HHL Research Paper Series in Corporate Governance, 3. Müller, K.-P. (2009). Ich räume ein, dass wir zu oft geschwiegen haben. Handelsblatt, 11/16/2009, p. 4. Peters, M., & Hecker, A. (2013). BB-Report zu den Änderungen des DCGK im Jahr 2013. Betriebs Berater, 48(15), 28872894. Prinz, E., & Schwalbach, J. (2013). Zehn Anmerkungen zur laufenden Debatte um Managergehälter. Der Aufsichtsrat, 10(78), 111113. Rapp, M. S., & Wolff, M. (2012). Vergütung deutscher Vorstandsorgane 2012. Frankfurt: Verlagsgruppe Handelsblatt. Directors’ Remuneration in Germany Ribaudo, P. (2006). Steigende Spitzengehälter in den Chefetagen. Bezüge im Schnitt um elf Prozent geklettert Aktionärsschützer bemängeln Intransparenz. Die Welt, 10/17/2006, p. 17. Ringleb, H.-M., Kremer, T., Lutter, M., & Werder, A. (2014). Kommentar zum Deutschen Corporate Governance Kodex: Kodex Kommentar, Vol. 5. Munich: C.H. Beck. Schaller, P. D. (2011). Aktienbasierte Incentives im Rahmen der Vorstandsvergütung Eine empirische Analyse der Determinanten und der Implikationen auf die Investitionsentscheidung sowie die Performance deutscher Prime-StandardUnternehmen. Dissertation, Munich 2011. Schömig, P. N. (2013). Corporate Governance, Wertschöpfung Managementvergütung. Corporate Finance Biz, 4(7), 428433. und Stiglbauer, M. (2010). Corporate Governance Berichterstattung und Unternehmenserfolg: Eine empirische Untersuchung für den deutschen Aktienmarkt. Wiesbaden: Gabler Verlag. Stiglbauer, M., Fischer, T. M., & Velte, P. (2012). Financial crisis and corporate governance in the financial sector: Regulatory changes and financial assistance in Germany and Europe. International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, 9(4), 331347. Velte, P., Weber, S., & Stiglbauer, M. (2013). Reform der europäischen Corporate Governance: Praxisfolgen für die externe Abschlussprüfung. Herne: NWB Verlag. Ziemons, H. (2000). Erteilung des Prüfungsauftrages an den Abschlussprüfer einer Aktiengesellschaft durch einen Aufsichtsratsausschuss? Der Betrieb, 53(2), 7781. 131 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 9 Directors’ Remuneration in Italy Marco Artiaco Introduction Remuneration systems are a key element of corporate governance. Their purpose is to acquire the management and cater its choices to align the goals of the members of the board with those of the shareholders using motivational levers. Regarding the capacity of remuneration systems to influence the board of directors, the main reference is the “agency theory,” according to which a subject, the agent (the board) is acting in favor of, or as a representative to a second subject, the principal (the shareholder). This theory shows problems in the relationship between the agent (the board) and the principal (shareholder) in the presence of uncertainty and information asymmetry. In fact, in this case the agent will most likely be motivated to maximize their goals at the expense of the shareholder (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). The studies on this issue have tried to verify whether the system of remuneration may be a tool of alignment between the objectives of the agent and those of the shareholder. The empirical analysis which allows this approach to reach different solutions is done by relating the financial size of the system (amounts and structure), with variables such as ownership, and the separation between ownership and control. On one hand, executive compensation is just a matter of contract, it is only necessary to identify, previously, the optimal compensation model that aligns the objectives of the board with those of the shareholders (Core, Guay & Larcker, 2002; Jensen & Meckling, 1976). On the other hand, the system of remuneration is only partly influenced by the need to align the board’s objectives to those of the partners. This will also depend on other variables, such as 133 134 MARCO ARTIACO the ability of the board to influence the extent of compensation to the executives, making it an annuity of the board of directors (Bertrand & Mullainathan, 2001; Aghion, Philippe, Blanchard, Olivier-Jean, 1994; Yermack, 1997). Remuneration levels grow due to the introduction of incentive systems and weak corporate governance. The Italian context was defined by a large amount of stateowned companies, a Catholic rich-blaming culture, for this reason, executive compensations were significantly lower than in the United States and compensation design schemes were also simpler than American ones. Since the 1990s, Italian remuneration standards have aligned with capitalistic countries’ remuneration levels. In Italy, the exponential growth in directors’ compensation over the last few decades can be explained by different causes: shareholder ownership, corporate governance, and regulatory framework. The Italian economic system was defined by a substantial heterogeneity in companies’ dimensions and a geographical fragmentation (Artiaco, 2013). Italian peculiarities are explained by a clear separation between productive and non-productive areas and a niche-market-oriented production. Moreover, the Italian stock market is characterized by inefficiency and companies’ undercapitalization. The Italian ownership structure is characterized by a separation between ownership and control, in which shareholders such as families, financial institutions, or banks are able to control and manage the business with less than 51% ownership through specific financial instruments such as pyramidal ownership or juridical instruments such as shareholder agreements. In this context, it is more convenient for majority shareholders to get an annual compensation, than to be entitled to receive profits (Barca, 1995). In this context, high remuneration packages have been allotted despite poor managerial performance. This phenomenon can be ascribable to a poor regulation system as well as weak governance. The economic and financial crisis has called into question remuneration and incentive schemes; regulators have started setting rules for listed financial companies with the intention of regulating remuneration and incentive plans. In the following sections, an in-depth analysis of the Italian remuneration system has been developed. It includes key factors and peculiar characteristics of Italian companies. Our aim is to give a synthetic explanation of the Italian regulation system, remuneration design schemes, remuneration reporting, and Italian remuneration guidelines. Remuneration Regulation The Italian response to the crisis has been characterized by tighter regulation and re-regulation of the corporate governance Directors’ Remuneration in Italy remuneration policies rules. Corporate governance rules vary, depending on company peculiarities. Unlisted companies are subject to civil law rules. Listed companies, in contrast, are subject to much more detailed rules. Some companies are subject to peculiar rules due to their core business. Listed financial companies, for example, are subject to a self-disciplinary code for listed companies and the Bank of Italy’s rules for financial companies. The Italian compensation discipline sets out different rules and compensation schemes for: (1) (2) (3) (4) Listed companies Banks and bank holding companies Government-owned unlisted companies Unlisted companies. As described in the following paragraphs, different regulatory levels imply differences between remuneration models. LISTED COMPANIES Italian listed companies may also adopt the Code of Self-Discipline of Listed Companies published by Borsa Italiana1 (the Italian Stock Exchange) in 1999. According to article 2389 of the Italian Civil Code, the board of directors’ compensation must be established by the board meeting. This is clearly a good example of a “say-on-pay” tool. According to article 2389, 3rd comma, of Civil Code the board of directors, upon examination of proposals from the committee for remuneration and having heard the board of auditors, determines the salary compensation and contract terms of the managing director, through the committee for remuneration, to which the specific duty has been assigned, and of other administrators who fulfill particular roles, including the participation on committees instituted by the board of directors. In companies with a supervisory board, the shareholders’ ordinary meeting fixes the remuneration of the members of the supervisory board, if not set out in the articles of association (Civil Code new art. 2364-bis). As stated before, Italian listed companies may also adopt the Self Disciplinary Code for Listed Companies, which integrates the Civil Code provisions. 1 Italian Stock Exchange or Borsa Italiana: Borsa Italiana S.p.A. is the company responsible in Italy for the organization, management, and development of markets for the trading of financial instruments. 135 136 MARCO ARTIACO In accordance with the “comply or explain” principle, rather than setting out binding laws Borsa Italian set out a SelfDisciplinary Code, which listed companies may either comply with, or if they do not comply, explain publicly why they do not. SelfDisciplinary Code Peculiarities will be discussed below in CONSOB legislative decree no. 58 of 24 February 1998 (CONSOB, 1998). CONSOB LEGISLATIVE DECREE No. 58 OF 24 FEBRUARY 1998 Consolidated Law on Finance pursuant to Articles 8 and 21 of Law no. 52 of 6 February 1996. (see art. 123-ter) Text updated with amendments introduced by Italian Legislative Decree no. 69 of 21.6.2013, converted with amendments from Law no. 98 of 9.8.2013 and by Law no. 97 of 6.8.2013. Consob Legislative Decree n. 58/1998 sets out rules on remuneration disclosure for Listed Companies Article123-ter Report on remuneration 1. At least twenty-one days prior to the date of the shareholders’ meeting established by article 2364, paragraph two, or the shareholders’ meeting established by article 2364-bis second paragraph of the Italian Civil Code, companies with listed shares shall make a report on remuneration available to the public at the company registered offices, on its internet website or in any of the other ways established by Consob regulation. 2. The report on remuneration shall be laid out in the two sections established by paragraphs 3 and 4 and is approved by the Board of Directors. In companies adopting the dualism system, the report is approved by the supervisory board, upon proposal, limited to the section established by paragraph 4, letter b), of the management board. 3. The first section of the report on remuneration explains: a) the company’s policy on the remuneration of the members of the administrative bodies, general managers and executive with strategic responsibilities with reference to at least the following year; b) the procedures used to adopt and implement this policy. 4. The second section, which is intended for the members of the administrative and auditing bodies, general managers and, in aggregate form, without prejudice to the provisions of the regulation issued in accordance with paragraph 8, for executives with strategic responsibilities: a) provides a suitable representation of each of the items comprising remuneration, including treatment provided for in the event of cessation of office or termination of employment, highlighting the coherence with the company’s policy in terms of remuneration approved the previous year; Directors’ Remuneration in Italy 5. 6. 7. 8. b) analytically illustrates the fees paid during the financial year of reference, for any title and in any form by the company and by subsidiaries or associates, noting any components of said fees that refer to activities performed in years prior to that of reference, in addition to highlighting the fees to be paid in one or more subsequent years in exchange for the work performed in the year of reference, potentially specifying an estimated value for components that cannot objectively be quantified in the year of reference. Fee plans established by article 114-bis are attached to the report, or the report specifies the section of the company’s website where these documents can be viewed. Without prejudice to the provisions of articles 2389 and 2409terdecies, first paragraph, letter a) of the Italian Civil Code and article 114-bis, the shareholders’ meeting called in accordance with article 2364, paragraph two or article 2364-bis, paragraph two, of the Italian Civil Code, resolves in favour or against the section of the report on remuneration established by paragraph 3. The resolution is not binding. The outcome of voting is made available to the public in accordance with article 125-quater, paragraph 2. By regulation, adopted having first consulted with the Bank of Italy and Isvap as concerns the parties respectively supervised and considering sector Community regulations, Consob indicates the information to be included in the section of the remuneration report established by paragraph 3, including all information aiming to highlight the coherence of the remuneration policy with the pursuit of the company’s long-term interests and with the risk management policy, in accordance with the provisions of paragraph 3 of Recommendation 2004/913/EC and paragraph 5 of Recommendation 2006/385/EC. By regulation adopted in accordance with paragraph 7, Consob also indicates the information to be included in the section of the remuneration report envisaged by paragraph 4. Consob may: a) identify the managers with strategic responsibilities for which information is supplied in nominative form; b) differentiate the level of information detail according to company dimension. Source: Legislative decree. (CONSOB). No. 58 of 24 February 1998. (It.) The comply-or-explain principle is a central element of EU corporate governance: listed companies should state in the report and accounts whether they comply with the Code and give reasons for any areas of non-compliance. The same as to the remuneration. 137 138 MARCO ARTIACO Article 6 Remuneration of directors Principles 6.P.1. The remuneration of directors and key management personnel shall be established in a sufficient amount to attract, retain and motivate people with the professional skills necessary to successfully manage the issuer. 6.P.2. The remuneration of executive directors and key management personnel shall be defined in such a way as to align their interests with pursuing the priority objective of the creation of value for the shareholders in a medium-long term timeframe. With regard to directors with managerial powers or performing, also de-facto, functions related to business management, as well as with regard to key management personnel, a significant part of the remuneration shall be linked to achieving specific performance objectives, possibly including non-economic objectives, identified in advance and determined consistently with the guidelines contained in the policy described in principle 6.P.4. The remuneration of non-executive directors shall be proportionate to the commitment required from each of them, also taking into account their possible participation in one or more committees. 6.P.3. The Board of Directors shall establish among its members a remuneration committee, made up of independent directors. Alternatively, the committee may be made up of non-executive directors, the majority of which to be independent; in this case, the chairman of the committee is selected among the independent directors. At least one committee member shall have an adequate knowledge and experience in finance or remuneration policies, to be assessed by the Board of Directors at the time of his/her appointment. 6.P.4. The Board of Directors shall, upon proposal of the remuneration committee, establish a policy for the remuneration of directors and key management personnel. Source: Legislative decree. (CONSOB). No. 58 of 24 February 1998. (It.) Remuneration policy establishes guidelines and directions according to which remunerations shall be determined by the board of directors, with reference to the remuneration of inside directors and other directors covering particular offices, and by the managing directors with reference to the key management personnel. Directors’ Remuneration in Italy In expressing the opinion pursuant to article 2389, paragraph 3, of the Italian Civil Code, statutory auditors shall also verify the consistency of the proposals with the policy on remuneration. The complexity of the remuneration issue requires that related board decisions must be supported by some preliminary activities and proposals of the remuneration committee. In carrying out its tasks, the remuneration committee shall ensure appropriate links with all relevant functional and operational departments of the issuer. It is also appropriate that the chairman of the board of statutory auditors or another statutory auditor designated by the board chairman participates in the works of the committee; the remaining statutory auditors are allowed to attend. In performing its duties, remuneration committee should use external consultants with an expertise in compensation policies. Such consultants must not simultaneously provide the human resources department, directors, or key management personnel, with significant services which might compromise their independence. The remuneration committee shall report to the shareholders on the exercise of its functions; for this purpose the chairman or another committee member should be present at the annual shareholders’ meeting. BANK AND BANKING HOLDINGS In the financial services sector, corporate governance should take account of stakeholders’ interests (e.g. depositors, savers, life insurance policy holders, etc.), as well as the stability of the financial system, due to the systemic nature of many players. The aim of the following paragraph is to describe the main legislative responses of the Italian regulators to the financial crisis with reference to financial intermediaries: (1) On March 30, 2011, the Bank of Italy published a set of supervisory provisions concerning banks’ remuneration and incentive policies and practices (known as “New Regulations”) with the purpose of implementing the European Directive 2010/76/ EC of 24 November 2010 (“Capital Requirements Directive III” or “CRD III Directive”). CRD III Directive, together with the guidelines approved by the Committee of European Banking Supervisors (“CEBS”), are construed in the context of the measures applied to face up to the financial crisis that struck global markets over the last few years. In line with European regulation standards, the New Regulations lay down the fundamental principles whereby credit institutions are required to ensure that their remuneration policies and practices are consistent with their organizational structure and 139 140 MARCO ARTIACO promote sound and effective risk management. In particular, the New Regulations strengthen the following principles: (a) transparency and disclosure of information on remuneration policies and practices: relevant information is required to be distributed, analyzed and further checked by the competent corporate bodies; (b) structure of variable remuneration: variable remuneration (especially with regard to selected categories of employees) has a full set of provisions well separated from those applicable to the fixed remuneration; (c) risk alignment: in this respect, the employees’ remuneration, to a given extent, may be paid out in shares (or other financial instruments); furthermore, deferred payments are also provided, as well as ex post correction mechanisms. The New Regulations shall apply to banks and banking groups (“Banks”) subjected to the authority of the Bank of Italy including, without limitation, foreign branches of Italian banks and Italian branches of foreign banks. Many of the provisions set forth in the New Regulations shall be applicable in accordance with the principle of proportionality: in this respect, among other issues, the New Regulations shall apply in full to major banks only (i.e., those having certain prerequisites, such as total assets equal to, or greater than, Euro 40 billion, etc.), while some of the relevant provisions shall not apply to minor banks and financial intermediaries. The New Regulations aim at causing banks to adopt adequate remuneration and incentive measures which may help improve competitiveness and good governance, in accordance with long-term strategies and sound and effective risk management, particularly with regard to share-based incentives. (2) The Supervisory Circular of March 2, 2012 (Comunicazione del 2 marzo 2012 Bilanci 2011: distribuzione di utili e corresponsione di remunerazioni, “2012 Bullettin, March 2012, n.3, Shareholder dividends and compensations) stresses the need for full implementation of the Bank of Italy provisions of March 30, 2011, so as to ensure inter alia, the sustainability of the variable component of remuneration in relation to the financial situation and the achievement or maintenance of an adequate capital base in an unfavorable cyclical phase. (3) March 13, 2013 Supervisory Circular on 2012 accounts: valuation of credit assets, remuneration policy, distribution of dividends. (4) The Bank of Italy therefore expects the banking system as a whole to reduce variable remuneration significantly, in line with the criteria laid down in the March 2011 provisions and Directors’ Remuneration in Italy the indications of the Supervisory Circular of March 2, 2012. For the banks that have incentive plans based on a one-year performance accrual period that made a loss in 2012 or had a negative risk-adjusted operating margin, the correct application of the March 2011 provisions: (a) prevents awarding or paying bonuses based on the 2012 results to board members, the general manager, or other “key personnel” whose variable remuneration depends exclusively or prevalently on objectives referring to the bank as a whole; (b) must entail, for the rest of the staff, at least a significant reduction in bonuses even in the event of attainment of individual performance objectives and those of the relevant business unit. (5) Legislative Decree no. 58 of February 24, 1998 Consolidated Law on Finance pursuant to Articles 8 and 21 of Law no. 52 of February 6, 1996 (see art. 123- ter). Text updated with amendments introduced by Italian Legislative Decree no. 69 of 21.6.2013, converted with amendments from Law no. 98 of 9.8.2013 and by Law no. 97 of 6.8.2013 (see Box 1). (6) ISVAP Regulation No. 39, June 9, 2011 (ISVAP Regulation), in force since June 23, 2011, sets out rules on remuneration policies of insurance companies with the objective of ensuring the adoption of remuneration systems in line with the international principles on remuneration policies in the financial sector, including Commission Recommendations 2009/384/EC and 2009/385/EC, April 30, 2009. GOVERNMENT-OWNED UNLISTED COMPANIES In accordance with the DPR 05/10/2010 n. 195 the Italian Regulator set a maximum remuneration and compensation limit for government-owned unlisted company employees. State employees’ compensation cannot exceed the maximum compensation perceived by the president of the High Court of Appeal (Corte di Cassazione). Corporate governance is becoming a key issue. In Italy, corporate governance rule implementation has been making great strides, however it will take some time to evaluate their application in real life in the coming years. The emerging regulatory framework is extremely heterogeneous for several reasons. First, for many years there was hesitancy in regulating this matter as the market was considered the appropriate tool to ensure the proper functioning of the remuneration system. Some firms’ peculiarities tend to reduce the consequences of potential limitations on remuneration level and this is even truer in an international and competitive directors’ labor market. 141 142 MARCO ARTIACO When certain types of expertise are not industry-specific, national or regulatory limits on the level of remuneration may create distortions in the labor market. These limitations may reduce control effectiveness on remuneration schemes, and encourage both firms and directors to adopt innovative remuneration schemes with the intention of circumventing these quantitative constraints (OECD, 2011). Secondly, by its own nature, remuneration is a complex matter. For this reason, rules are mostly set by regulators or through self-regulation authorities rather than by legislative bodies. For this reason, some countries chose to determine an accurate discipline on this subject, some others decided to leave room for a self-disciplinary approach to remuneration matters. Therefore, different countries have different approaches in regulating the matter. UNLISTED COMPANIES In Italy, the majority of small and medium enterprises are not listed or quoted on tradable equity markets. The overwhelming majority of SMEs or start-up companies remain under the ownership and control of the founder or founding family. Such unlisted companies lie at the heart of the Italian economy. For unlisted companies, in accordance with Article 2389 Civil Code “The shareholders’ ordinary meeting fixes the remuneration of the members of the board of directors.” This prevision aims to overcome the agency problem in unlisted companies. In general, regulators’ and legislators’ ability to influence remuneration schemes in a substantial way is rather limited. Nevertheless, lawmakers have enacted specific measures to control directors’ remuneration level. Regulators have become more and more focused on the determination of specific measures that are supposed to implement the capacity of the structure of corporate governance to produce proper remuneration and incentive systems. Remuneration Design Schemes In Italy, remuneration schemes are a function of shareholder ownership and corporate governance, as well as the above-mentioned regulatory framework. The structure and operation of the board of directors is a determinant of the remuneration system; more recent studies have attempted to identify the relationship between pay and the characteristics of the board. This is done by using empirical models that relate the size of the compensation system (amounts and structure) with variables, such as the characteristics and functioning of the Directors’ Remuneration in Italy board of directors (e.g. number of meetings, number of outside directors, number of inside directors). Decisive elements are the size of the board of directors and the effort spent (Boyd, 1996). Others have investigated, through empirical analysis, the correlation that exists between pay, professional characteristics of the members of the board of directors, and business variables (Bryan, Hwang, Klein, & Lilien, 2000). The remuneration scheme is based on different components: some are linked to directors’ responsibilities, others aim to promote good managerial practices. In Italy, the most common remuneration scheme is based on the following elements: a base salary, a nonequity-linked variable part (annual bonus), an equity-linked variable part (sometimes stock option plans are offered to management as part of their compensation at the withdrawal from office), and an extraordinary part. This compensation scheme is consistent with the “Worldwide Total Remuneration Report” (Tower Perrins, 1997). As shown in the text, a directors’ remuneration scheme is linked to their roles and responsibilities. The board of directors is composed of different members with different roles, duties, and responsibilities. Just to be clear, we can divide board members into outside directors (professionals or deputy) and inside directors (managers). Outside directors are expected to monitor and challenge the performance of inside directors, whereas inside directors participate in the day-to-day management of the firm. The directors’ role among the board brings peculiar duties and responsibilities, which must be taken into account in the remuneration scheme design process (Lorsch & MacIver, 1989; Mizruchi, 1983; Zahra & Pearce, 1989). The board of directors is made up of many directors and acts collectively with managerial, control and strategic functions. According to the “agency theory” (Fama & Jensen, 1983) management may wish to grow the company in ways that maximize their personal power and wealth. In a stewardship perspective, management's and shareholders’ interests match. For this reason, a controlling and monitoring activity is not considered to be extremely useful. Controlling and management functions can be synthetized in the board composition. Among Italian companies, there can be both strong CEOs and strong boards depending on the board characteristics: strong CEOs influence the board’s decisions, whereas strong boards control and monitor management behavior. Some authors have identified a relationship between the level of remuneration of the entire board of directors and that of the CEO. The underlying assumption in this case, is that as the compensation of the CEO increases, so will the propensity of the other members to ask for higher returns. The same study also notes that there is an indirect correlation between the level of commitment required by the 143 144 MARCO ARTIACO CEO, and the board for control. In fact, in the presence of more complex businesses, there is a larger increase in the compensation of the CEO, and for the board of directors (Brick, Palmon, & Wald, 2002). In order to understand remuneration structure as well as compensation levels in Italy, some examples are provided in the following paragraphs. The average compensation of Italian listed companies’ directors between 2007 and 2010 is shown in Table 1. The fixed compensation package design is an essential part of the remuneration design process. In fact, most of the other remuneration elements depend on the fixed remuneration part. Target bonuses and option grants, for example, are usually estimated as a percentage of the fixed remuneration part. Pension benefits and termination benefits are tied to the remuneration level. Having said that, every increase in fixed compensation amount brings positive effects on other compensation elements One of the main issues arising in recent years is the dichotomy between inside and outside directors, which determines a compensation difference. The figures in Table 1 show that remunerations schemes are based on a fixed part, which remunerates the chairman's legal representative role (in contrast to the CEO's managerial role). This evidence suggests that base salary is predominantly responsibility-related. Chairpersons deserve legal representation whereas CEOs deserve managerial responsibility. Usually, inside directors (i.e. chairman, managing director, CEO) have a full-time commitment in the firm and they are involved in its day-to-day management. Outside directors are not fully involved in the firm but they are expected to monitor executive directors’ work. Outside directors make their contribution in board meetings. Outside directors may also be independent directors. However, inside directors’ remuneration is significantly different from that of outside directors. This separation is far too high in terms of the importance of the director’s role, and it shows that, in Italy, remuneration schemes tend to favor inside directors with a Table 1: The Average Compensation of Italian Listed Companies’ Directors between 2007 and 2010. Fixed Remuneration Component (h/1000) 2007 2008 2009 2010 Chairman 505 524 503 538 Vice-chairman 224 250 245 228 CEO 423 407 417 435 Outside directors 51.4 Source: SpencerStuart (2010), “Italia Board Index.” 56.4 61.9 61.9 Directors’ Remuneration in Italy 145 managerial role, instead of rewarding outside directors with a supervisory role. Another interesting fact about remuneration schemes in Italy is the amount of the remuneration that is a fixed part over the total remuneration package (see Table 2). A positive trend in base salarytotal compensation ratio can be highlighted with the only exception of vice-presidents. Nonetheless, CEO base salarytotal compensation ratio is well below 50%. CEOs are supposed to be led by positive economic results. This is the reason why variable remuneration is higher than fixed salary. Figures show that inside directors assigned with a managerial role are provided with a variable-based compensation, whereas outside directors are provided with a fixed-based compensation. Inside and outside directors’ base salaries are closely related to their competencies, responsibilities, and their commitment to their role as board members. In consideration of outside directors’ role and functions, their fixed-based compensation should be linked to their independence from the company’s fortune. Figures show that a “pay for performance” culture has caught on. This evidence is consistent with the Anglo-Saxon model described by Yensen and Murphy. All these elements cannot be determined in abstract terms, because they are linked to corporate characteristics and environment. However, in the remuneration design process, some elements are in common among firms. The great majority of Italian listed companies’ directors are awarded with a variable compensation. According to the 2012 (Assonime, 2013) Survey, 178 Italian companies adopted incentive remuneration systems. A total of 61% of these firms (equal to 146 firms) opted for short-term variable compensation (annual bonus). Short-term remuneration schemes are based on an ex ante determination of achievable management goals (e.g. revenues, profits, EBITDA, etc.), and on an ex post evaluation of achieved targets. Short-term incentive plans are based on planning and controlling Table 2: The Amount of the Remuneration Fixed Part over Total Remuneration Package. Base Salary/Total Compensation Ratio 2007 2008 2009 2010 Chairman 59% 55% 61% 64% Vice-president 43% 46% 46% 41% CEO 31% 34% 36% 39% Outside directors 86% 89% 90% 91% Source: SpencerStuart, 2010; “Italia Board Index.” 146 MARCO ARTIACO tools, namely the annual budget (Airoldi & Zattoni, 2001). The variable compensation part is closely related to the board performance. In the presence of an incentive plan system, managing directors who achieve company targets, get a variable compensation such as the annual bonus. The variable compensation part is a performance-based award: no bonus will be paid unless a certain performance target is reached. A target bonus is paid when a standard target is achieved. Some companies are characterized by a peculiar compensation scheme: directors who are eligible to be rewarded with an annual compensation plan are effectively rewarded with the annual bonus only if they achieve some specified personal targets. Incentive systems linked to short-term objectives have been recently subjected to harsh criticism, as they are believed to be the reason for risky choices (OECD, 2009). The most recent policy regulations have been calling upon boards to award directors with a long-period oriented variable compensation (long-term incentive plans). In 2012, 120 out of 240 Italian listed companies (50% overall) chose to adopt incentive systems linked to 35-year goals. This percentage increases if we only analyze Italian financial firms. This fact is due to recent regulation. One interesting fact about remuneration schemes in Italy is the widespread use of stock option plans. At the end of the 1990s in Italy, stock option plans were not as common as in the USA, the UK, or France (Murphy, 1998). At present in Italy, stock options packages are still uncommon compensation tools mainly due to poor financial market performances and a disadvantageous tax treatment. Stock option packages usually constitute a variable compensation tool. Stock options are a performance incentive tool, which aligns management and shareholders’ interests. Stock options packages give directors the right to buy or subscribe for company’s shares. Stock options are technically American call options, which give the holder the right to buy shares at a fixed price during a defined time period. At the end of 2010, only 58 Italian (listed and unlisted) companies chose to adopt stock option incentive plans. Among these, 42 listed companies adopted stock option incentive plans for their 93 directors (SpencerStuart, 2010). In Italy, stock option plans are losing their appeal mainly because of their tax regime and the stock market trend. Remuneration Reporting Some studies (Rappaport, 2005; The Walker Report, 2009) support the need to align the compensation of top management administrators while putting into perspective any long-term trends, and by Directors’ Remuneration in Italy 147 always taking into account the interests of company, and that of the shareholders. Others (Kirkpatrick, 2009) support linking compensation and risk. With reference of this fact, some interesting elements emerge from an analysis of the two major listed Italian companies, namely Telecom Italia and Enel. An in-depth analysis of their 2012 remuneration reports highlights that they all have adopted a similar compensation and incentive structure. The following examples are extremely relevant; Telecom Italia and Enel are both big companies, subject to listed company regulations, with advanced corporate governance. The Telecom Italia 2012 remuneration system is described in Box 1. Box 1: Telecom Italia 2012 Remuneration Scheme. Telecom Italia 2012 Remuneration Scheme Outside directors remuneration • EUR 110,000 per year for every outside director; • EUR 45,000 per year for every internal control member and/or corporate governance committee member; • EUR 20,000 per year for every remuneration committee member; • EUR 20,000 per year for every director who is appointed to the supervisory board; • EUR 90,000 for the vice-president, who is responsible for the internal control system functioning. Board of directors’ Chairman Remuneration Fixed Compensation • EUR 110,000 per year for the director role; • EUR 1,400,000 per year for the chairman role; • EUR 35,000 per year as executive committee member. Variable Compensation • Variable compensation linked to annual performance goals. The target value is equal to the fixed compensation plus a variable percentage, from 50% to 150%, of the fixed compensation linked to assigned targets achievement; (continued) 148 MARCO ARTIACO • One-off participation in the 2011 long-term incentive plan, equal to a EUR 2,100,000 cash bonus (150% of the fixed compensation) plus 2,253,702 ordinary Telecom shares (150% of the fixed compensation expressed in shares); • Benefits as similarly recognized for the company’s management; • Net annual payment to the supplementary pension fund equal to 10% of the fixed salary and equal to 10% of the annual premium expected, for results to the target level. CEO Remuneration • Fixed annual remuneration equal to EUR 1,000,000 as a gross annual salary for the employment relationship; • Waiver of the fixed compensation for the position of director and member of the executive committee; • Variable remuneration for the chief executive officer related to annual performance objectives, with target value equal to the fixed amount and range of variation from 50% to 150%, depending on the level of achievement of objectives; • One-off participation in the 2011 long-term incentive plan, represented by a cash bonus of EUR 1,500,000 (150% of the fixed annual remuneration) and 1,609,787 ordinary shares (150% of the fixed annual remuneration expressed in shares; Benefits as similarly recognized for the company’s management. Source: Remuneration report, Telecom 2013. As described above, Telecom’s remuneration system is based on a fixed compensation component as well as a variable compensation component (incentive system). Compensation and incentive amounts vary according to the role and duties of the single director. Telecom’s board of directors is composed of 17 members of whom 12 are outside directors. Outside directors are rewarded with fixed compensation only. Directors’ fixed compensation varies between a minimum of EUR 110,000 and a maximum of EUR 200,000 per year as a function of participation in one or more committees. The chairman is rewarded with both a fixed and a variable compensation. Chairman’s fixed compensation amounts to EUR 1,918,000 cash (consisting of EUR 110,000 for his/her director role, EUR 1,400,000 for his/her chairman function, EUR 408,000 in perks and other compensation). A variable fee of EUR 1,050,000 Directors’ Remuneration in Italy made up of both annual awards resulting from incentive systems and long-term incentive schemes must also be added. The chief executive officer is rewarded with both a fixed and a variable compensation. CEO fixed compensation is equal to EUR 1,005,000 in cash. A variable compensation of EUR 317,000, made up of both annual awards resulting from incentive systems and long-term incentive schemes, must be added. The relationship between Telecom inside directors’ variable remuneration and total remuneration is significantly lower than the average of Italian listed companies. In particular, in 2012 the ratio between Italian listed companies CEOs’ variable compensation and total compensation was equal to 43%, whereas, the Telecom CEO variable compensation over total compensation ratio was equal to 24%. The same applies to Telecom vice-president, with a variable compensation/fixed compensation ratio equal to 17%, well below the national average. Inside directors’ remuneration is ultimately, in line with that of similar size companies, EUR 8,416,000. The level of inside directors’ remuneration has been decreasing in recent years; however, it includes long-term incentive plans, thanks to outside directors’ commitment to safeguarding stakeholders’ interests. This phenomenon is consistent with literature (Boyd, 1996), which attributes to the board characteristics the ability to control the board remuneration. However, it was not free of charge, in fact, shareholders’ cost of management is equal to EUR 6,411,000 while cost of control is equal to EUR 2,050,000. Enel’s remuneration system is designed as described in Box 2. It is based on a fixed compensation component and a variable compensation component (incentive system). The total compensation amount and potential incentives vary according to the directors’ roles and duties. Enel’s board of directors is composed of nine members of whom seven are outside directors (Remuneration Report Enel, 2013). Outside directors are rewarded with fixed compensation only. Directors’ fixed annual compensation varies between a minimum of EUR 85,000 and a maximum of EUR 150,000 as a function of their participation in one or more committees. The Enel chairman receives both a fixed and variable compensation. The chairman's fixed compensation is equal to EUR 750,000 in cash. The chairman’s variable compensation is equal to EUR 600,000, made up of annual awards resulting from incentive systems and long-term incentive schemes. The chairman is finally rewarded with a EUR 37,000 payment as a compensation for his/her participation in the corporate governance committee. 149 150 MARCO ARTIACO Box 2: 2013 Enel Remuneration System. 2013 Enel Remuneration System Outside Directors Remuneration: • EUR 85,000 annual gross base salary; • An additional compensation for committee members: ○ EUR 30,000 annual gross compensation for the committee chairman; ○ ○ ○ EUR 20,000 annual gross compensation for committee members; EUR 1000 attendance fee (per session) for committee members and committee chairman; The maximum amount received by each committee member may not exceed the total amount of EU 70,000 per year. Chairman Compensation: • EUR 750,000 annual gross base salary. In addition, the chairman is entitled to the compensation for his/her participation in any of the committees; • The variable remuneration amounts to a maximum of 80% of the fixed annual compensation. The variable compensation is conditional upon the achievement of annual performance objectives. With specific reference to the year 2013, the company chose to reduce it by 30%; • Other fees: ○ ○ ○ ○ Insurance policy (to cover risks such as death or permanent disability); Protection measures in case of judicial or administrative proceedings; Insurance policy equal to one-twelfth of the total emoluments, fixed and variable part, for each year of the effective term of office; Extraordinary awards linked to strategically important operations. CEO DG Compensation: ○ EUR 1,423,357 annual gross salary divided into EUR 720,000 annual gross base salary for CEO role and EUR 703,357 gross base salary for DG function; Directors’ Remuneration in Italy 151 • Variable compensation: ○ Short-term compensation part amounts to a maximum of 150% of the fixed annual remuneration. It is linked to the achievement of annual performance objectives. With specific reference to the year 2013, the short-term compensation was reduced by 30% for the CEO managerial role; ○ Mediumlong-term variable compensation, linked to participation in incentive plans, subject to specific goals achievement. • Other compensation: ○ A severance package pay equal to 2 years of the fixed component (for every single function); ○ A non-compete payment; any violation of the non-compete agreement involves damages compensation. the refund is set at an amount equal to twice the equivalent value of the noncompetition agreement; ○ An insurance policy (to cover risks such as death or permanent disability); Protection measures in case of judicial or administrative proceedings; ○ ○ ○ ○ An insurance policy that provides one-twelfth of the total emoluments, fixed and variable part, for each year of the effective term of office; A contributory pension; An extra payment at the end of the mandate in case of particular relevant strategic achievements. Source: 2013 Enel Remuneration Report. The Enel CEO, who is at the same time appointed with DG function, is rewarded with a fixed and variable compensation. Enel CEO compensation amounts to EUR 1,423,000 in cash. The CEO variable compensation is equal to EUR 2,594,000 made up of both annual awards resulting from incentive systems and long-term incentive schemes. The ratio between Enel CEO variable compensation and total compensation turns out to be higher than the national average of listed companies. In particular, in 2012 the ratio between Italian listed companies CEOs’ variable compensation and total compensation was equal to 43%, whereas the Enel CEO variable compensation accounted for 65% of total compensation. 152 MARCO ARTIACO This indicator is in line with the national average if you look at the years 20072010. Enel directors’ remuneration is in line with those of similar-size companies. The choice of valuable incentive systems is based on the will of diversifying management remuneration, even in the presence of positive results and stable earnings. Thus constituted, the Enel board cost is equal to EUR 6,406,000. The shareholders’ cost of management is hence equal to EUR 5,405,000, while control cost is equal to EUR 1,002,000. Conclusions Remuneration policies of Italian regulated firms seem to be oriented to finding solutions in order to acquire and retain top managers. Remuneration level and structure are set with the intent to assign remunerations in line with the Italian market salary, rather than designing a behavioral-oriented incentive system. However, the Italian corporate governance system still seems weak. Some of the tools that have been proposed by Italian regulators, in order to improve effectiveness of remuneration systems are: (1) An extension of remuneration disclosure measures: to avoid opportunistic behavior it is necessary for the company to have a more transparent approach when determining remuneration systems. Since 2010, Italian listed companies and banks have been obliged to provide an annual remuneration report concerning directors’ compensations. In this sense, the approach of “say on pay,” which is what the latest regulations point towards, seems to be on the right track to solving the issue at hand. (2) A new paradigm in the incentive system for banks and banking holdings: remuneration structure will be divided into a fixed and a variable part, provided that variable compensation is linked to long-term objectives (35 years). (3) Independent directors’ control over remunerations: the board control function, which is expressed through independent directors, is essential to ensure the effective operation of the remuneration system. Independent directors have the responsibility to perform some basic functions including the alignment of the remuneration of bank and listed companies’ inside directors to long-term shareholders’ interests, the design of incentive systems, the control function and the production of information, which is essential for the protection of shareholders and stakeholders (OECD, 2004). (4) A better understanding of the underlying relationship between risk and remuneration: certain components of the Directors’ Remuneration in Italy compensation system are influenced by risk management systems that guarantee an analytical approach through ad hoc decision-making models. This solution aligns the objectives of the board of directors, to those of the shareholders. In fact, we believe that the structure of the remuneration system comes down to a contractual issue for banks, as noted by Core, Guay, and Larcker (2002) and Jensen and Meckling (1976) for which it is only necessary to identify, beforehand, the optimal compensation model that aligns the objectives of the board to those of the shareholders. Corporate governance is one of the tools that can be used to stem directors’ power and to address the effectiveness of systems of remuneration. The solutions selected by authorities in order to regulate financial firms such as transparency, remuneration system structure, incentive mechanism control, and risk management should be extended to all companies in which remuneration is a critical issue due to the magnitude of the amounts, the existence of possible conflict of interest situations with other stakeholders involved, and the generation of potential systemic risks linked to the intrinsic nature of the business (for example, state-owned firms or firms which operate in a concession regime). Compensation issues have been addressed by financial regulations as a source of potential systemic risks. The current macroeconomic situation has been highlighting that compensation issue cannot be limited solely to financial firms. A correct remuneration system is at heart of the firm’s ability to engage different stakeholders in the production and redistributive process and more generally, to develop the firm’s social cohesion. Remuneration issues affect every single firm, but they are more relevant in those cases in which a plurality of interests is involved. If one accepts stakeholder interest protection as objective evidence of the need for remuneration controls, companies, which would be subject to compensation controls, would be extremely numerous. For example, those firms that operate under public concessions (such as transportation companies, freeway-managing firms, public interest providing firms, arms-producing companies, etc.) or operating as suppliers of Italian public administration would fall into this category. We must move from a regulatory approach towards remuneration, linked to financial-firm models and paradigms, to an objective approach on remuneration issues. Corporate governance measures on remunerations should be related to their effective remuneration amount. Firms should be free to assign higher remuneration if they are able to assure adequate control mechanisms and if the remuneration exceeds high-threshold remuneration (relevant remuneration). 153 154 MARCO ARTIACO If those limits are overshooting, remuneration schemes can become a key factor in company functioning. Firms’ governance basically depends on the quality vision and motivation of leading figures. References Aghion, P., & Blanchard, O.-J., (1994). On the speed of transition in central Europe. In S. Fischer & J. J. Rotemberg (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1994, Volume 9 (pp. 283–319). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Airoldi, G., & Zattoni, A. (2001). Piani di stock option. Progettare La Retribuzione Del Top Management. EGEA. Artiaco, M. (2013). Remunerazione degli amministratori e corporate governance: Nuovi paradigmi dopo la crisi finanziaria. Milano: FrancoAngeli s.r.l. Assonime. (2013). La corporate governance in Italia: Autodisciplina e remunerazioni (anno 2013). Milano, Italy. Barca, F. (1995). On Corporate Governance in Italy: Issues, Facts and Agenda. Paper presented at the OECD conference “The Influence of Corporate Governance and Financing Structures on Economic Performance”. Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2001). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 901–932. Boyd, B. K. (1996). Determinants of US outside director compensation. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 4, 202–211. Brick, I. E., Palmon, O., & Wald, J. K. (2002). CEO compensation, director compensation, and firm performance: Evidence of cronyism. Department of Finance and Economics, Rutgers Business School. Bryan, S., Hwang, L., Klein, L., & Lilien, S. (2000). Compensation of outside directors: An empirical analysis of economic determinants. Working paper, Wake Forest University, Winston-Salem NC. Core, J. E., Guay, W. R., & Larcker, D. F. (2002). Executive equity compensation and incentives: A survey. Working Paper, Wharton School. Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 301–325. Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360. Kirkpatrick, G. (2009). The corporate governance lessons from the financial crisis. OECD, 1220. Legislative decree. (CONSOB). No. 58 of 24 February 1998. (It.). Lorsch, J. W. (1989). Pawns or potentates: The reality of America’s corporate boards. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School. Lorsch, J. W., & MacIver, E. (1989). Pawns or potentates: The reality of America’s corporate boards. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Mizruchi, M. S. (1983). Who controls whom? An examination of the relation between management and board of directors in large American corporations. Academy of Management Review, 8, 426–435. Murphy, K. J. (1998). Executive compensation. Handbook of Labor Economics (Vol. 3). Amsterdam: North Holland. Directors’ Remuneration in Italy OECD. (2004). Principles of corporate governance. Paris. OECD. (2009). The Corporate Governance lessons from the financial crisis. OECD. (2011). Board Practices: Incentives and Governing Risks. Rappaport, A. (2005). The economics of short-term performance obsession. Financial Analysts Journal, 61(3), 65–79. SpencerStuart. (2010). Osservatorio sui consigli di amministrazione delle società quotate Italiane. Italia Board Index. The Walker Report. (2009). A review of corporate governance in UK banks and other financial industry entities. Tower Perrin’s. (1997). Worldwide Total Remuneration report, in Murphy, K. J., (1998) Executive Compensation. Yermack, D. (1997). Good timing: CEO stock option awards and company news announcements. Journal of Finance, 52, 449–476. Zahra, S. A., & Pearce, J. (1989). Boards of directors and corporate financial performance: A review and integrative model. Journal of Management, 15, 291–334. 155 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 10 Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Montserrat Manzaneque, Elena Merino and Regino Banegas Remuneration Regulation In Spain, as in other international contexts, speculation that accompanied the stock market bubble and economic growth favored the proliferation of excessive compensation to senior officers and directors of companies. These remunerations have remained despite the obvious decline in business economic performance. This situation has resulted in the proliferation of a legal focus on control and transparency as measures to ensure remuneration commensurate with performance and responsibility, especially aimed at listed companies and financial institutions. The following sections summarize some of the most important laws or recommendations relating to directors’ remuneration in Spain, with particular emphasis on those that are currently in place (from 2013) for listed companies and financial institutions. REGULATION FOR LISTED COMPANIES The law and recommendations applicable to listed companies, summarized in Figure 1, shall now be addressed. Ley de Sociedades de Capital or Companies Act (Royal Decree, 2010) Spanish legislation establishes the principle of gratuitousness in relation to directors, unless the bylaws provide otherwise, as set out in 157 158 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Mandatory Ley de Sociedades de Capital Or Companies Act (Royal Decree, 2010) Voluntary Sustainable Economy Act (Law 2/2011) Unified Good Governance Code of Listed Companies (CNMV, 2013) (Article 217) Specification of remuneration systems in the company bylaws (Articles 218 and 219) Special requirements for remuneration systems in form of profit sharing or remuneration through shares (Article 260) Directors remuneration disclosure in notes of the annual accounts (Article 61 3rd) 1. Disclosure of directors’ compensation through the “Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors” 2. Requires putting a vote of the General Shareholders” Meeting in the annual report as a separate point on the agenda. (Recommendation 8) Reserve the right of the Board of Directors to approve the remuneration policy and the directors’ remuneration (Recommendations 33 – 36) Remuneration policy orientation criteria Figure 1: Laws or Recommendations Relating to the Directors’ Remuneration in Spain. Source: Own Research. Article 217 of Ley de Sociedades de Capital or Companies Act1 (from now on LSC). This article specifies that the bylaws should include a reference to the “remuneration systems” used to compensate the directors. Therefore, the company cannot compensate directors with systems that do not appear in the bylaws. This has encouraged the development of company bylaws in this regard. Also, the LSC imposed a number of limitations, conditions, and constraints related to compensation in the form of profit sharing (Article 218), which will be detailed later. On the question of the ratification or approval of the compensation system by the competent corporate body as a control mechanism, the Spanish law is not concrete. At greater depth, it is important to make reference to the voluntary recommendations of codes of good governance, something that will be discussed later. Only in relation to the remuneration consisting of the delivery of shares, options or linked to the value of these shares, does the LSC (Article 219) specify the need of approval of the General Shareholders’ Meeting. The agreement will express, as applicable, 1 Royal Legislative Decree 1/2010, of July 2, approving the revised text of the Corporations Act. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain the number of shares to be granted, the exercise price of the stock options, the value of the shares taken as reference, and the duration of this remuneration system. With regard to remuneration disclosure, the LSC (Article 260) includes the contents of the previous Royal Legislative Decree 1564/ 19892 (Article 200), establishing that the companies have to include a breakdown of “salaries, allowances and payments of any kind” granted to directors and obligations for pensions or life insurance, advances, loans, and guarantees granted in their favor, as part of the notes to the annual accounts. However, it is noteworthy that this law refers to global information grouped by type of remuneration and, therefore the information on remuneration received by each member of the Board of Directors is left out of this requirement, an area which we refer to later, the importance of which has been highlighted in all national and international forums on this topic. Codes of Good Governance As in other countries, Spain has followed the European and international line on the issue of directors’ remuneration, which is to establish recommendations through codes of good governance. The content of these codes can be followed or not by companies. The first code of corporate governance in Spain, the Olivencia Report (1998) recommended that the policy for the remuneration of directors, whose proposal, evaluation, and review should be attributed to the Remuneration Committee, which conforms with the criteria of moderation, is related to the performance of the company and that the company provides detailed and individualized information regarding this (Recommendation 15). Later, in relation to the Board remuneration, the Aldama Report (2003) included the following recommendations (Section 6. Remuneration of the Board and senior management, Chapter IV. The company organs): (a) the remuneration in shares, stock options, or options referenced to the share price should be limited to executives or internal directors; (b) the individual remuneration of directors with itemized breakdown should be listed in the notes of the annual accounts; and (c) the clauses about “golden parachutes” of the directors should have the formal approval of the Board of Directors. Afterwards, the Unified Good Governance Code of Listed Companies (CNMV, 2006) (from now on CUBG) incorporated the majority of content of the European recommendations regarding directors’ remuneration (2004/913/EC, 2005/162/EC, 2009/385/ 2 Royal Decree 1564/1989, of December 22, approving the revised text of the Spanish Companies Act. 159 160 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. EC3) and of the previous codes developed in Spain (Aldama Report, 2003; Olivencia Report, 1998). Particularly, in regard to directors’ remuneration, we can highlight the recommendations 35, 40, and 41 of CUBG (CNMV, 2006). Recommendation 35 starts from the conviction that complete transparency regarding directors’ remuneration, including total payments to executive directors, is a way to mitigate the risk of immoderate compensation. This transparency should extend to all remuneration components and concepts, including director severance packages. Given the complexity of deferred payment schemes (insurance or pensions), these will be best understood if they are translated for comparative purposes into an estimated amount or annual equivalent cost. The Code recommends that the board approve a detailed remuneration policy, as envisaged in Recommendation 40, which should be written up and submitted at the General Shareholders’ Meeting. Finally, Recommendation 41 proposes that the individual directors’ remuneration should be listed in the notes of the annual accounts. Another important recommendation in this respect is number 8, which states that the Board of Directors’ right to approve the remuneration policy and the directors’ remuneration should be reserved. The CUBG (CNMV, 2006) also incorporates a number of recommendations concerning the criteria to take into account when setting the remuneration policy (Recommendations 3639) to which reference is made in Section “Remuneration Design (Schemes)” of this chapter. In June 2013, an amendment of Unified Code was published (CNMV, 2013), suppressing the recommendations incorporated into the new rules published and which are discussed in this document. These regulatory changes have meant Recommendations 35, 40, and 41 do not appear in the next text that has been incorporated into CUBG (CNMV, 2013), since they have ceased to be recommendations to become requirements. However, Recommendation 8, and in absence of reference in the Spanish legislation as to the body which should make the approval of the remuneration of directors and senior officers, remains as such in the new text of the CUBG (CNMV, 2013). Also, the recommendations about the remuneration policy orientation criteria are maintained, although due to the rearrangement of the contents they become Recommendations 3336 (previously 3639). 3 Commission Recommendation of December 14, 2004, fostering an appropriate regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies (2004/ 913/EC), Commission Recommendation of February 15, 2005, on the role of non-executive or supervisory directors of listed companies and on the committees of the (supervisory) board (2005/162/EC), and Commission Recommendation of April 30, 2009, complementing Recommendation 2004/913/EC and 2005/162/EC as regards the regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies (2009/385/EC). Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Sustainable Economy Act (Law 2/2011) Previous experience on the poor compliance of the recommendations of the codes of good governance, especially Recommendations 40 and 414 regarding directors’ remuneration of CUBG (CNMV, 2006), and in applying the principles of good corporate governance arising from international agreements and organizations, the Sustainable Economy Act (Law 2/2011) gave legal cover to the transparency. Article 27 requires increasing transparency in relation to remuneration policy and directors’ remuneration of those that are listed companies. In addition, the Article 61 3rd requires, starting from 2011, on the one hand, that the board should submit a report on the directors’ remuneration policy to the advisory vote of the General Shareholders’ Meeting, as a separate point on the agenda. With the submission of this proposed remuneration report to the advisory approval of the General Shareholders’ Meeting, the system called “say-on-pay” has been incorporated into Spanish law, through which voting occurs, binding or advisory, of the individual remuneration of directors. Spain joins other European countries like United Kingdom and Sweden, which already include this measure. However, there are other countries like Netherlands and Norway that have gone one step further towards a binding vote. After all, what’s the point of the vote if it is merely advisory? Davis (2007) explains that “the advisory vote is the yellow card. A large shareholder vote against a pay report is the yellow card warning to the company board.” Therefore, it is expected that the failure to have the vote of the shareholders is a warning regarding the actions taken on remuneration by the Board of Directors. In other words, the advisory vote allows the shareholders’ Meeting to take a stance which, without affecting the validity of the company’s remuneration commitments, may equate to a vote of confidence or no confidence in the directors’ stewardship. On the other hand, all listed Spanish companies, regardless of the sector, should disclose their directors’ compensation individually through the “Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors.” The content of this report has recently been defined by Circular 4/2013.5 4 According to report by CNMV, available at www.cnmv.es, only 28.2% of the listed companies comply with every point of Recommendation 40 in year 2007 (the Board should submit a report on directors’ remuneration policy to the advisory vote of the General Meeting as a separate item on the agenda, etc.), 21.3%, 21.2%, and 27.3% in years 2008, 2009, and 2010, respectively. For its part, 30.5% of the listed companies comply with the disclosure of individual remuneration in year 2007, 30.5%, 28.2%, and 31.8% in years 2008, 2009, and 2010, respectively. 5 Circular 4/2013, of June 12, of the National Securities Market, which sets the annual report models remuneration of directors of listed companies and members the board of directors and the supervisory board of the savings banks that issue securities admitted to trading on official stock markets. 161 162 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. The content of this report is detailed in Section “Remuneration Reporting” of this chapter. Securities Market Act (Article 61 Encore) The Aldama Report (2003), which has been referred to previously, and especially the Commission for its development, decided to complement the voluntary recommendations with a legislative intervention, forcing companies to report on the degree of compliance with the recommendations. This was reflected in the Article 116 of the Ley del Mercado de Valores or Securities Market Act, introduced by Law 26/20036 (at present, Article 61 encore of the Securities Market Act as amended by the Sustainable Economy Law). This article establishes the obligation for listed companies to make public an annual corporate governance report (Corporate Governance Annual Report). In this report, the listed companies shall detail the recommendations of CUBG being followed and the reasons why the rest are not being followed (the well-known principle of comply or explain). Consequently, this report contains information on the degree of compliance with the recommendations related to the directors’ remuneration, to which we eluded earlier (Recommendation 8 and Recommendations 3336, CUBG 2013). Also, the Corporate Governance Annual Report contained information, among others, about the remuneration of Board members and related operations of the company and its shareholders and its directors and executives (Circular 4/2007, CNMV). However, the regulatory changes that occurred as a result of the enactment of the Sustainable Economy Law have removed the references to the information on directors’ remuneration from the Corporate Governance Report,7 due to this information being included in the 6 Law 26/2003, of July 17, on Transparency and information instruments of listed companies. 7 Following the approval of the amendment of the Unified Code of Good Governance (CNMV, 2013), the Order ECC/461/2013 of March 20 includes the content of the new model and Circular 5/2013 defines the official model. Order ECC/461/2013 of March 20, which will determine the content and structure of the annual corporate governance report, the annual report on remuneration, and other means of information of listed companies, boxes savings, and other entities that issue securities admitted to trading on official stock markets. Circular 5/2013, of June 12, of the National Securities Market, which provides models of annual corporate governance reports of listed companies of the savings banks and other institutions that issue securities admitted to trading on official stock markets. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors. The content of this report is developed later. Other Regulations of Listed Companies (Semiannual Financial Information and Significant Event) The Royal Decree 1362/20078 regulates the presentation by listed companies of the semiannual financial information. Circular 1/ 20089 establishes models to submit such information. Among the information to be collected, we highlight certain data on the remuneration of directors and senior officers (see Section “Remuneration Reporting”). Article 47 of Royal Decree 1362/2007 also establishes the obligation to notify the CNMV as a significant event, the compensation systems of directors of companies listed on an official secondary market in Spain or another European Union market, involving the delivery of shares in the company in exercising their duties, rights, or share options or any system whose settlement is linked to the evolution of the price of such shares. This communication may be made directly by the director or senior officer in question or by society. Communications should be made both at the time of the establishment of the system (in the same way that contact should be made if there is any change) and the time of settlement of the same. For the communication of such information, as relevant information, the CNMV proposes a model in Annex VIII of the Circular 2/2007,10 mandatory. REGULATION FOR FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS Financial institutions have received special treatment by the importance in the economy of any country. This is why we have thought it proper to refer to the recommendations and regulations applicable 8 Royal Decree 1362/2007, of October 19, by which develops the Law 24/ 1988, of July 28, on the Securities Market (Law 1988), in relation to the transparency requirements in relation to information about issuers whose securities are admitted to trading on a secondary market or on another regulated market in the European Union. 9 Circular 1/2008, of January 30, the National Commission on the Securities Market, on periodic reporting issuers with securities admitted to trading on regulated markets on yearly financial reports, interim management statements, and the quarterly financial reports. 10 Circular 2/2007, of December 19, of the National Securities Market, by adopting models of notification of significant shareholdings of directors and managers, operations of the issuer of shares and other models. 163 164 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Voluntary Mandatory International and European organisms European Union Principles for Sound Compensation Practices (FSF, 2009) Recommendation of 30 April 2009 (2009/384/EU) Spanish legislation Law 2/2011 of Sustainable Economy Royal Decree 711/2011 High-level principles of Remuneration Policies (CEBS, 2009) Application Standards of the Sound Compensation Practices (FSB, 2009) Green Paper on Corporate Governance in financial istitutions and remuneration policies (2010) Circular 4/2011, 30 November, Bank of Spain Royal Decree-Law 2/2012, 3 February, consolidation of financial sector Figure 2: Laws or Recommendations Relating to Directors’ Remuneration in Spain in Financial Institutions. Source: Own Research. to such institutions in Spain (see Figure 2), but, without going into the analysis, as this would exceed the scope of this work. European and International Recommendations The absence of good remuneration practices in some financial institutions has been one of the factors that contributed to the financial crisis that began in the summer of 2007. Besides this, the importance of financial institutions in the economy of a country has recently led some international forums, such as the G-20 and the Financial Stability Forum (FSF) (now replaced by the Financial Stability Board, 2009a and 2009b), senior European bodies, such as the European Commission (2010), and international regulatory bodies, such as the Committee Basel, and the Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS), to pay great attention to compensation practices of financial institutions. Spanish legislation on directors’ remuneration of financial institutions is closely linked to these European and international pronouncements on the matter. So they have affected the Spanish context in a double sense. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain On one hand, in Spain, the Bank of Spain recommends that the financial institutions adopt and implement different documents published by the above organisms, among others: • Principles for Sound Compensation Practices published by the FSF11 (April 2009); • High-level Principles of Remuneration Policies published by the CEBS12 (April 2009); • Application Standards of the Sound Compensation Practices published by FSF13 (September 2009). On the other hand, as a member country, it must take into account the recommendations and documents proposed by the European Union. On the issue of remuneration, the European Union published the Commission Recommendation of April 30, 2009, on remuneration policies in the financial services (2009/384/CE), which was later followed by the Green Paper on Corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies (2010). Sustainable Economy Act (Law 2/2011) and Royal Decree 771/2011 The adoption in Spain of the Law 2/2011, of March 4, of Sustainable Economy and Royal Decree 771/201114 involved the adaptation of Directive 2010/76/EU.15 The birth of this policy has its origin in consensus by supervisors and regulatory bodies, including the G-20 and the CEBS, that the inappropriate remuneration structures of some financial institutions have been a contributory factor of the failure of individual financial institutions and systemic problems in Member States and globally. Law 2/2011, amending Law 13/1985, authorizes the Bank of Spain to require credit institutions adopting governance standards including remuneration policies and practices consistent with sound risk management and effectiveness. 11 Available at http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_0904b. pdf 12 Available at http://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/16094/Highlevel+principles+for+ remuneration +policies.pdf 13 Available at http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_0909 25c.pdf 14 Royal Decree 771/2011, of June 3, by amending Royal Decree 216/2008, of February 15, on the capital of financial institutions and Royal Decree 2606/1996 of December 20, on deposit guarantee funds of credit institutions. 15 Directive 2010/76/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of November 24, 2010, amending Directives 2006/48/EC and 2006/49/EC as regards capital requirements for the trading book and for re-securitisations, and the supervisory review of remuneration policies. 165 166 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. For its part, the Royal Decree 771/2011 adds a new chapter to the Royal Decree 216/2008,16 in relation to remuneration policies of banks. Other Regulation for Financial Institutions Circular 4/201117 amending Circular 3/2008,18 to incorporate the criteria established by the Committee on Banking Supervision (Basel III), especially in relation to the transparency that should prevail in the remuneration policy delivered to entities’ managers and employees whose decisions affect the risk policy of the entity. In addition, the Royal Decree-Law 2/201219 contains the rules applicable to the remuneration of directors and executives of credit institutions having needed or will need financial support from the Fund for Orderly Bank Restructuring. Remuneration Design (Schemes) THE REMUNERATION POLICY FOR DIRECTORS IN SPAIN. A QUESTION LINKED TO THE BOARD STRUCTURE As already mentioned, the document in which the remuneration systems of the company are contained is the bylaws. However, and following the recommendations of CUBG, the development of this remuneration policy corresponds to the Nomination and Remuneration Committee (sometimes given another name). Specifically, this text attributed to the Nomination and Remuneration Committee the following functions (Recommendation 52, CUBG 2013): a) Propose to the Board: i. The remuneration policy for directors and senior officers; ii. The individual remuneration of executive directors and other terms of their contracts; iii. The basic conditions of the contracts of senior officers; b) Oversee compliance with the remuneration policy set by the company. 16 Royal Decree 216/2008, of February 15, on the capital of financial institutions. 17 Circular 4/2011, of November 30, the Bank of Spain, by amending Circular 3/2008, of May 22, on the calculation and control of minimum capital. 18 Circular 3/2008, of May 22, on the calculation and control of minimum capital. 19 Royal Decree-Law 2/2012, of February 3, consolidation of financial sector. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Thereby, the Board of Directors will have the documents necessary to perform one of the functions assigned to it under Recommendation 8 of the same text (CUBG 2013), which has already been referred to, in order to approve this compensation policy. Once approved, the Board of Directors or the Nomination and Remuneration Committee prepares a report on the remuneration policy, which will be voted upon, only in an advisory sense, at the General Shareholders’ Meeting as a separate item on the agenda, according to Article 61 3rd of the Sustainable Economy Act (Law 2/ 2011). The content of this report is discussed in Section “Remuneration Reporting” of this chapter. Also, the supervisory role of the Nomination and Remuneration Committee on compliance with the remuneration policy (Recommendation 52.b) is also noteworthy. To guarantee the compliance of this function, the CUBG recommends that this Commission be composed exclusively of external directors20 and have a minimum of three members, notwithstanding that if members of the Committee so approve, the executive directors or senior officers can attend the different sessions. In addition, the President must be independent (Recommendation 39, CUBG 2013). After describing the decision-making process concerning the remuneration policy based on the recommendations of the CUBG 2013 and the Economic Sustainability Act and before delving into the compensation systems that revolve around the directors, it should be noted that Spain has a corporate governance system of companies characterized by a single Board of Directors (Unitary Board System), in which different types of directors cohabit with different functions and responsibilities (see Figure 3). According to the CUBG (CNMV, 2006), the Board of Directors for listed companies is composed of internal (inside) or executive and external (outside) or non-executive directors. In the second case, there are two categories: (a) independent, those who are in a position to perform their duties without being influenced by any connection within the company, its shareholders or its management; and (b) proprietary, those who own equity state above or equal to the legally determined threshold for a significant holding, or otherwise appointed due to their status as shareholders or those who represent shareholders. 20 Although it was included in the proposed amendment to the Unified Code of Corporate Governance, ultimately not included in the final version, the recommendation for incorporating on the Remuneration Committee a remuneration expert, as picked up in the Commission Recommendation of April 30, 2009 (paragraph 7). 167 168 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Executive directors Non-Executive directors CEO Executive directors Independent directors Proprietary directors Figure 3: Typical Board Structure in Spain. Source: Merino, Manzaneque, and Banegas (2012, p. 395). The remuneration structure for directors is linked to this structure. In general terms, there are two kinds of remunerations according to the functions exercised by the directors, the time devoted to exercise their functions and expected results of their work: • The remuneration for performance of core duties stemming from Board membership usually linked to dedication, expertise, and responsibility. • The remuneration to directors for performance within the company of functions other than those attached to the position of director. • The remuneration to executive directors for performance of their executive function usually linked to competitiveness and alignment of shareholders-managers interests. • The remuneration to other kind of directors, to perform other functions distinct to the duties of oversight and decision-making exercised jointly on the Board of Directors or on the company’s committees, like advice or representation (such as by a president, e.g., who is not an executive who performs representation or advice functions for which they are paid). Also, the functions of the external directors deserve special attention with respect to their compensation, as this could compromise their independence. Hence, according to the CUBG 2013 the companies should note several recommendations in this regard: Recommendation 33. Remuneration comprising the delivery of shares in the company or other companies in the group, share options or other share-based instruments, payments linked to the company’s performance or membership of pension schemes should be confined to executive directors. The delivery of shares is excluded from this limitation when directors are obliged to retain them until the end of their tenure. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Recommendation 34. External directors’ remuneration should sufficiently compensate them for the dedication, abilities and responsibilities that the post entails, but should not be so high as to compromise their independence. Finally, should be noted that there are no limits in the Spanish legal system regarding the amount to be received by directors as compensation for the performance of their duties, except in cases where compensation is based on participation in social benefits (see Section “Remuneration Systems’ Elements in Spanish Companies”). Nevertheless, it is worth mentioning a particular case is limited to the financial sector. Specifically, Article 5 of Royal Decree-Law 2/2012 establishes certain limitations on remuneration to entities that receive support from the Fund for Orderly Bank Restructuring. Despite this lack of legislation, the concern to avoid excessive remuneration is evident in the reflections that CUBG 2013 page 22 and 23 makes in this respect, advising them to avoid setting as an objective achieving the average pay of other comparable companies. Adopting these decisions could lead to an unwarranted upward trend in pay or “ratchet effect” by the mere desire to approach the average of companies whose remunerations are below this. REMUNERATION SYSTEMS’ ELEMENTS IN SPANISH COMPANIES In recent years, the remuneration packages for directors and senior officers used by Spanish listed companies have spent less on sophisticated systems based on fixed remuneration and allowances in keeping with more complex formulas that try to link compensation with the company’s strategic objectives, align the interests of managers with those of shareholders and retain qualified professionals, through the constitution of compensation systems that are comparable and competitive with other companies within the same sector. In this sense, there are many remuneration systems or formulas ranging from fixed remuneration in cash to more complex systems such as the deferred compensation linked to the medium- and longterm objectives and materialized as shares to receive in the future. So, the remuneration structure for directors, according to Spanish practice, may include one or more of the concepts summarized in Table 1. These compensation systems and the rules applicable to them in the Spanish context will be described in detail next. Fixed Remuneration a. Salary It includes only the amounts paid to directors for their participation on the Board of Directors or for services performed in 169 170 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Table 1: Systems of Remuneration to Directors. Remuneration System Fixed remuneration Description Salary (Cash or in Shares) Fixed fee for their work on management or committees of the Board of Directors. Complements Fixed special allowances related to the responsibility, travel expenses or attendance fees (fixed amount independent on the number of meetings), and so on. Benefits and perquisites Other standard benefits, such as free use of company car, free telephone or other additional perquisites. Also, some benefits like salary advances, loans, insurance premiums, guarantees, and so on. Annual variable remuneration Multi-annual variable remuneration (Compensation systems tied to share price or in shares) Compensation in the form of profit sharing Amounts of money calculated as a percentage of profit of the company. Attendance fees Allowances related to travel expenses (the amount depending on the number of meetings). Stock options Remuneration that provides the beneficiaries the right (but not the obligation) to buy company shares for a fixed price (strike price) during a specified period (exercise period) after the vesting period. Performance shares Commitment to deliver a number of shares within a period determined under the condition of meeting certain financial targets character or linked to the shareholder returns. Stock appreciation rights Rights that give the possibility to receive an amount in cash or in shares. The amount is calculated as the difference between the market price of the shares on a certain date and the initial reference price multiplied by the number of rights granted. Deferred stock bonus Commitment to deliver a number of shares of the company equal to the annual variable remuneration of senior officers and directors. Restricted shares Delivery of shares that the beneficiary cannot sell in the market during a period of time. Sometimes, the company also sets other conditions such as compliance with certain goals or no dividend payments. Phantom shares Right to receive similar units to shares usually provides entitlement to dividends, the value of which is equivalent to one share. To the end of the term of the plan, the directors are to be entitled to payment of the shares revaluation. Pension plans The perception of this type of remuneration is conditional upon retirement or termination of senior executive in company. Rights of compensation for cases of termination Amounts as compensation in certain cases of termination of their relationship with the company. Source: Own research. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain their role as senior officers or directors. This pay remains constant and is independent of the activity level of directors and their potential impact of management on the results of the company. The remuneration granted to the directors in terms of shares is also considered in the same light. Sometimes, the companies can force directors to invest the compensation received, in whole or in part, into shares and hold it for a period of time, in other words, a remuneration policy of mandatory reinvestment in shares. b. Complements It includes concepts like Special Responsibility Allowance, extra compensation for geographical mobility, and attendance fees for meetings of the Board of Directors and its delegated committees when the remuneration is independent of the number of meetings which are attended by directors. Benefits and Perquisites Remuneration is granted, usually to senior officers or directors, through the performance of their executive duties in consideration of the services they provide to the company and which include among others, the use of vehicles, health insurance, life insurance, telephone charges, and so on. In relation to these systems of remuneration, neither the regulations nor the CUBG (CNMV, 2013) manifest itself in this regard. Variable Annual Remuneration (Bonus) It includes the amounts of money received in the form of profit sharing or any other formula that links these perceptions to the achievement of specific measurable objectives (company’s net sales or other financial management indicators). Regarding this remuneration system, the CUBG (Recommendation 36, CNMV, 2013) recommends including safeguards to ensure they reflect the professional performance of the beneficiaries and not simply the general progress of the markets or the company’s sector, atypical or exceptional transactions or circumstances of this kind. Also, the CUBG (Recommendation 33, CNMV, 2013) recommends that external directors are excluded from this system (variable component linked to the company’s net profit or other financial management indicators, e.g., operating profit or EBITDA, or the value of its market value at a given point in time). The aim is to avoid the conflict of interest that could arise when directors have to evaluate accounting practices or to take earnings-related decisions when their salary depends on it. However, the CUBG (CNMV, 2013) recognizes the contribution of these systems in 171 172 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. aligning the interests of directors with those of shareholders, hence it considers appropriate its use when compensating the executive directors. a. Compensation in the form of profit sharing21 Because of the risk attributable to this system, by focusing on short-term profits (manipulation of fictitious profits and dividends according to the schedule of retributions, overvaluation of the annual accounts with the appearance of fictitious profits, and so on), it is subject to a concrete legal regime. Specifically, Spanish law requires that such compensation be collected in keeping with the bylaws of corporation (Article 218 LSC), mentioning the percentage or the amount destined for that purpose. Moreover, the law imposes limits, conditions and constraints on this compensation system, which in some cases differs, depending on the type of business associations (see Table 2). It should also be pointed out that the CUBG (Recommendation 35, CNMV, 2013) recommends that for the determination of this remuneration any qualifications stated in the external auditor’s report which might prejudice the profits should also be taken into account so that the compensation is not based on fictitious profits. a. Attendance fees It is a kind of remuneration that tries to cover the expenses incurred by directors for attending board meetings and its delegated committees when they are dependent on the number of meetings attended by them. The aim of this type of compensation is to encourage the active participation of directors. Multi-Annual Variable Remuneration (Compensation Systems Tied to Share Price or in Shares) This is a remuneration to be received by the Board, either in cash or in shares of the company. When the amount is in cash, this will be determined with reference to the market value or share appreciation of the company over a period of time. There are a lot of remuneration elements in which this system can be realized, as is described in Table 1. 21 Although this system may consist of profit sharing or any formula linked to other financial indicators, we only are focused on profit sharing because other systems are rarely used in Spanish practice. Table 2: Limits, Conditions, and Constraints Related to Compensation in the Form of Profit Sharing. Maximum Limit (Article 218, LSC) Limited Liability Company Constraints for its Recognition (Articles 273 and 274, LSC) The value of equity is not less than the share capital (before or after benefits distribution). The available reserves must be at least equal to the amount of research and development expenses appearing on the balance sheet. If there is goodwill, restricted reserves should be set aside to the tune of the same amount. A percentage of the profits representing at least 5% of the initial amount should be destined towards covering this cost. 10% of net profit for each year must be transferred to the legal reserve until the total amount of this reserve reaches at least 20% of the share capital. The mandatory reserve and the reserve established by the bylaws have been covered. A minimum dividend of 4% to the shareholders or the maximum percentage established by the bylaws has been paid to the shareholders. Source: Own research. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Joint Stock Companies 10% of the disposable profit Conditions to Consider Prior to Delivery (Article 218, LSC) 173 174 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Regarding the specific rules applicable to them, and as mentioned previously, the LSC (Article 219) manifests that remuneration consisting of the delivery of shares, stock options, or linked to the value of these shares, should be expressly specified in bylaws and be approved by the General Shareholders’ Meeting. The agreement will express, as applicable, the number of shares to be granted, the exercise price of the stock options, the value of the shares taken as reference and the duration of this remuneration system. For its part, the CUBG (CNMV, 2013) recommends (Recommendation 33) that this type of system be confined to executive directors, for the reasons that have been discussed previously. In addition, the CUBG (CNMV, 2013) expressly refers to share-based variable incentives, proposing payments based on the improvement in the share price to the cost of capital for shareholders or that of peer organizations instead of on the absolute change in the price. The objective of this assertion is to avoid disproportionate earnings for market reasons. Pension Plans As discussed, in this remuneration system concepts are included that are related to retirement or termination of the directors when they have reached a certain age. Under Spanish law, the commitments of the company for these items are usually materialized in two alternatives: (a) defined contribution systems, in which the company agrees to pay a specified amount periodically for the director; or (b) defined benefit systems when the company agrees to guarantee a certain income to the director. These systems are governed by Spanish law by Royal Decree 304/2004, of February 20.22 This regulation aims to develop the revised text of the Law Regulating Plans and Pension Funds, approved by Royal Legislative Decree 1/2002, of November 29.23 Rights of Compensation for Cases of Termination Sometimes, the contracts of executive directors include certain indemnification clauses for termination of their jobs (called “golden parachutes”), which is a common practice in Spain since the employment or commercial relationship they have with the company is not covered by the Statute of Workers. 22 Royal Decree 304/2004, of February 20, which approves the plans and pension funds Regulations. 23 Royal Legislative Decree 1/2002, of November 29, approving the revised text of the Law Regulating Plans and Pension Funds. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Table 3: 175 Average Remuneration per Director (20042011). 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Type of Remuneration (Data in thousands of Euros) Fixed remuneration 82.4 84.4 71.4 102.2 104.7 102.9 104.7 111.9 Variable remuneration 41.6 43.8 53.0 69.0 65.1 68.5 63.2 75.1 Attendance fees 21.3 25.4 19.0 26.0 27.5 28.3 27.8 28.3 Others 50.4 65.6 68.5 82.7 71.1 89.7 64.5 64.9 195.7 219.2 211.9 279.9 268.4 289.4 260.2 280.2 Total Type of Directors (Data in thousands of Euros) Executive director Proprietary director Independent director 578 654 872 918 999 1,115 1,022 1,128 82 83 86 101 102 96 93 99 65 80 85 105 104 110 115 117 Other outsiders 119 212 208 135 162 140 116 143 Number of business 182 176 173 173 164 156 153 149 Average of directors per Board 9.7 9.6 9.9 10.1 10.4 10.4 10.4 10.5 Source: Compiled from data of Corporate Governance Report of the issuers of securities admitted to trading on the official secondary market (CNMV).24 PRACTICE REGARDING REMUNERATION SYSTEMS IN SPAIN (20042011) Regarding the level of compensation, the data collected from the Corporate Governance Report of the issuers of securities admitted to trading on official secondary markets reveal an average remuneration per director of h280.2k for 2011 which represents an increase of 43.2% from 2004 and 7.7% compared to 2010 (see Table 3). The component that has grown more has been the variable remuneration in response to the demands of national and international organizations. Regarding the type of director the most significant increase has occurred for executives who have seen their remuneration increased by almost 100% from 2004. Regarding the remuneration structure, the Spanish compensation system to directors is characterized by fixed salary, although, the variable remuneration linked to the company performance has grown in the last years, to stand at 26.8% of the remuneration structure (see Figure 4). 24 Available at http://www.cnmv.es/portal/Publicaciones/PublicacionesGN. aspx?id=21 176 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Type of Remuneration Fixed remuneration (%) Year 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 41.9 38.5 33.7 36.5 39.0 35.5 40.2 39.9 Variable remuneration (%) 21.1 20.0 25.0 24.6 24.3 23.7 24.3 26.8 Attendance fees (%) 10.8 11.6 9.0 9.3 10.3 9.8 10.6 10.1 Others (%) 26.2 29.9 32.3 29.5 26.5 31.0 24.9 23.2 Fixed remuneration Attendance fees Variable remuneration Others Figure 4: Aggregate Remuneration for Board of Directors Percentage Distribution by Type of Remuneration (20042011). Source: Compiled from data of Corporate Governance Report of the issuers of securities admitted to trading on the official secondary market (CNMV). Remuneration Reporting One issue to which different codes have paid special attention over the years is the transparency of the remuneration of directors which, despite already being regulated (section 200 LSA, current art. 260 LSC), has always been highly opaque, due to individual information not being provided by companies, without which there has never been a homogeneous and comparable model to adhere to for the submission of information. Until 2011, the format in which companies collated information regarding the remuneration policy was voluntary and there was no official model, reasons why the Spanish companies would offer information on the remuneration of directors and senior officers without following homogeneous criteria. However, in general terms, the content has been consistent with recommendations 35 and 41 of CUBG (CNMV, 2006) which stipulated concrete information regarding: Recommendation 35. The company’s remuneration policy, as approved by its Board of Directors, should specify at least the following points: Directors’ Remuneration in Spain a) The amount of the fixed components, itemized where necessary, of board and board committee attendance fees, with an estimate of the fixed annual payment they give rise to; b) Variable components, in particular: i. The type of directors they apply to, with an explanation of the relative weight of variable to fixed remuneration items. ii. Performance evaluation criteria used to calculate entitlement to the award of share options or any performance-related remuneration; iii. The main parameters and grounds for any system of annual bonuses or other, noncash benefits; and iv. An estimate of the sum total of variable payments arising from the remuneration policy proposed, as a function of degree of compliance with pre-set targets or benchmarks. c) The main characteristics of pension systems (for example, supplementary pensions, life insurance and similar arrangements), with an estimate of their amount or annual equivalent cost. d) The conditions to apply to the contracts of executive directors exercising senior functions. Among them: i. Duration; ii. Notice periods; and iii. Any other clauses covering hiring bonuses, as well as indemnities or “golden parachutes” in the event of early termination of the contractual relation between company and executive director. Recommendation 41. The notes to the annual accounts should list individual directors’ remuneration in the year, including: a) A breakdown of the compensation obtained by each company director, to include where appropriate: i. Participation and attendance fees and other fixed director payments; ii. Additional compensation for acting as chairman or member of a board committee; iii. Any payments made under profit-sharing or bonus schemes, and the reason for their accrual; iv. Contributions on the director’s behalf to defined contribution pension plans, or any increase in the director’s vested rights in the case of contributions to defined benefit schemes; v. Any severance packages agreed or paid; vi. Any compensation they receive as directors of the other companies in the group; vii. The remuneration executive directors receive in respect of their senior management posts; 177 178 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. viii. Any kind of compensation other than those listed above, of whatever nature and provenance within the group, especially when it may be accounted a related-party transaction or when its omission would detract from a true and fair view of the total remuneration received by the director. b) An individual breakdown of deliveries to directors of shares, share options or other share-based instruments, itemized by: a. Number of shares or options awarded in the year, and the terms set for their execution; b. Number of options exercised in the year, specifying the number of shares involved and the exercise price; c. Number of options outstanding at the annual close, specifying their price, date and other exercise conditions; d. Any change in the year in the exercise terms of previously awarded options. c) Information on the relation in the year between the remuneration obtained by executive directors and the company’s profit, or some other measure of enterprise results. In addition, the different Spanish codes of good governance (Aldama Report, 2003; Olivencia Report, 1998), which have already been mentioned, have insisted on the disclosure of the individual remuneration granted to members of the Board of Directors. However, and inter alia, it has been a habit that has extended little in practice. For their part, the Corporate Governance Annual Report, and as previously mentioned, following the request of the aforementioned Securities Market Act (Article 61 encore) and the development of the Circular 4/2007 (CNMV), contained aggregate information on the directors’ remuneration by type of remuneration concept and type of director. As such, the lack of information on individual remuneration and the need to seek comparable and homogeneous models of information are the main reasons that have guided the last Spanish regulatory reform regarding this issue. Currently, in relation to the disclosure of directors’ remuneration, the last Spanish legislative reform, the Sustainable Economy Act (Law 2/ 2011), has led to the modification of the contents of the Annual Corporate Governance Report and the emergence of a new information model called the Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors. That is why the legal requirement for listed companies to report on remuneration has ensured that the majority of information on this topic, previously collected in the Annual Corporate Governance Report, is now collected in the aforementioned Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors. In fact, in the new model of the Annual Corporate Governance Report (Circular 5/2013) only has to include information on the Directors’ Remuneration in Spain 179 overall remuneration of the Board (section C.1.15) and total remuneration for members of senior officers who are not executive directors (section C.1.16). Meanwhile, the Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors includes information on past, present, and future remuneration policies granted to directors, expressing the individual remuneration given to each of the members of the Board of Directors (see Table 4). Table 4: Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors. Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors (A) Remuneration policy of the company for the financial year, with full explanation of the following: A.1. The remuneration policy; A.2. The process for determining the remuneration policy; A.3. The fixed component of remuneration; A.4. The variable components of the remuneration systems; A.5. Systems of long-term savings of the compensation; A.6. Indemnities agreed or paid to directors; A.7. The conditions of the contracts of executive directors; A.8. The supplementary payments; A.9. Advances, loans, and guarantees; A.10. Remuneration in kind; A.11. The compensation earned by the director under payments made by the listed company to a third party in which the director serves; A.12. Other remuneration; A.13. The actions taken to reduce risk. (B) Remuneration policy planned for future years, indicating the following: B.1. General Forecast remuneration policy; B.2. Decision-making process for setting the remuneration policy; B.3. Created incentives to reduce risk; (C) Overall summary of how the remuneration policy applied during the year ended (D) Details of the individual remuneration of each of the directors, stating: D.1. Individual remuneration of each of the directors (including remuneration for the exercise of executive functions) accrued during the year, indicating the following: The remuneration earned by the company, showing separately cash remuneration, reward systems based on actions, systems of long-term savings and other benefits. The remuneration earned by company directors for their membership on the Boards in other companies of the group, showing separately cash remuneration, systems of share-based payment systems, long-term savings and other benefits. Summary of the total remuneration. 180 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Table 4: (Continued ) Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors D.2. Report on the relationship between the remuneration received by the directors and the profits or performance of the entity, explaining, where appropriate, how variations in the company performance have influenced the change in the remuneration of directors. D.3. Report the results of the advisory vote of the general meeting in the annual report on salaries last year, indicating the number of negative votes if issued. (E) Other information of interest which cannot be included in any of the preceding paragraphs. Source: Compiled from data of Corporate Governance Report of the issuers of securities admitted to trading on the official secondary market (CNMV). As part of the semiannual financial information, listed companies must collect the following information about the remuneration of directors and senior officers (Circular 1/2008): • Amount accrued in both the issuing corporation by the group companies. • Remuneration information broken down into the following: fixed remuneration, variable remuneration, allowances, bylaw, transactions in shares and/or other financial instruments, other remuneration, and other benefits (advances, loans, contributions made during the period and funding obligations and pension plans, life insurance premiums paid during the period and guarantees provided to them). Remuneration Challenges The latest measures taken in Spain on the issue of remuneration of senior officers and directors (preparing the annual report and submitting it to advisory vote of the General Shareholders’ Meeting) are looking to get more control over compensation policies and increase information transparency thereof. The principle aim is that of curbing the excesses in compensation produced in recent years, irrespective of the global economic crisis in which we have been immersed. As these measures begin to be implemented this year, it remains to be seen in the years to come as to whether these measures manage to reach the “deterrent effect” desired and remuneration is moderated. The Spanish government is currently considering taking other measures as well, such as: (a) limits on compensation to variable remunerations and allowances; and (b) the possibility that the vote Directors’ Remuneration in Spain of the General Shareholders’ Meeting regarding the Annual Report on Remuneration of Directors to be binding. Regarding the first aspect, a new Commercial Code is being developed, which has devoted a chapter to the corporate governance of listed companies. One of the points of this future standard, which is already drafted and pending approval, is that it limits variable remuneration to be distributed among the members of the Board of Directors to a maximum of 1% of the profit before tax. However, as a sign of just how controversial this measure is, within the Commission for the preparation of this legislation, the first attempts have already emerged at discussion between those who prefer a procedure with all of the law and those who bow down to maintaining the self-based guidelines for listed companies. Moreover, in June 2013, the Spanish government set a goal to “put the national standards at the highest level of performance against the criteria and principles of Good Governance,” which constituted a Committee of Experts on Corporate Governance. To achieve this objective, the Commission should study the current situation in Spain and propose measures to improve areas, especially those explicitly laid out, in evaluating the role of the General Shareholders’ Meeting in controlling remuneration policy bodies’ management and senior officers of the company, and the possibility of developing a code of good governance for unlisted companies. After the report by the Committee of Experts, the National Securities Market is responsible for making the necessary changes in the Unified Code of Good Governance. Regarding the weight of the vote of the General Shareholders’ Meeting, it is currently under discussion as to the possibility of making it consultative or binding. The authors welcome the proposal to limit variable remuneration of Board members, however, it could also be interesting to limit fixed remuneration and allowances, if we take into account that this is a very important part of the remuneration granted to the directors. In the same vein, it could also be interesting if the vote on the remuneration policies failed to achieve the desired effect of moderating the remuneration, to plan for the possibility that such a vote was binding in the face to the approval of remuneration policies. References Aldama Report. (2003). Report by the special commission to foster transparency and security in the markets and in listed companies. Madrid: CNMV. Circular 1/2008. (2008, January 30). The National Commission on the Securities Market, on periodic reporting issuers with securities admitted to trading on regulated markets on yearly financial reports, interim management statements and, if, the quarterly financial reports. 181 182 MONTSERRAT MANZANEQUE ET AL. Circular 2/2007. (2007, December 19). The National Securities Market, by adopting models notification of significant shareholdings of directors and managers, operations of the issuer of shares and other models. Circular 3/2008. (2008, May 22). On the calculation and control of minimum capital. Circular 4/2007. (2007, December 27). The National Securities Market, by amending the model of corporate governance report of listed companies. Circular 4/2011. (2011, November 30). The Bank of Spain, by amending Circular 3/ 2008, of May 22, on the calculation and control of minimum capital. Circular 4/2013. (2013, June 12). The National Securities Market, which sets the annual report models remuneration of directors of listed companies and members the board of directors and the supervisory board of the savings banks that issue securities admitted to trading on official stock markets. Circular 5/2013. (2013, June 12). The National Securities Market, which provides models annual corporate governance report of listed companies of the savings banks and other institutions that issue securities admitted to trading on official stock markets. Comisión Nacional del Mercado de Valores (Spanish Securities Markets Commission or CNMV). (2006). Unified good governance code. May. Madrid: Author. Comisión Nacional del Mercado de Valores (Spanish Securities Markets Commission or CNMV). (2013). Unified good governance code. June. Madrid: Author. Commission Recommendation. (2004). Commission Recommendation of 14 December 2004 fostering an appropriate regime for the remuneration of directors of listed companies (2004/913/EC). Commission Recommendation. (2005). Commission Recommendation of 15 February 2005 on the role of non-executive or supervisory directors of listed companies and on the committees of the supervisory board (2005/162/EC). Commission Recommendation. (2009). Commission Recommendation of 30 April 2009 on remuneration policies in the financial services (2009/384/CE). Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS). (2009). High-level principles of remuneration policies. Retrieved from http://www.eba.europa.eu/documents/10180/ 16094/High-level+principles+for+remuneration+policies.pdf Davis, S. (2007). Does “Say on Pay” work? Lessons on making CEO compensation accountable. Yale Millstein Center Policy Briefing. European Commission. (2010). Green paper on corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies. European Parliament and Council. (2010). Directive 2010/76/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 24 November 2010 amending Directives 2006/48/ EC and 2006/49/EC as regards capital requirements for the trading book and for re-securitisations, and the supervisory review of remuneration policies. Financial Stability Board. (2009a). Application standards of the sound compensation practices published by the FSF. Retrieved from http://www.financialstabilityboard. org/publications/r_090925c.pdf. Accessed on September. Financial Stability Board. (2009b). FSF principles for sound compensation practices. Retrieved from http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_0904b.pdf. Accessed on April. Law. (1985). Law 13/1985 of 25 May on investment ratios, own funds and information obligations of financial intermediaries. Law. (1988). Law 24/1988, of 28 July, on the Securities Market. Directors’ Remuneration in Spain Law. (2003). Law 26/2003, of 17 July, on Transparency and information instruments of listed companies. Law. (2011). Law 2/2011, of 4 March, Sustainable Economy. Merino, E., Manzaneque, M., & Banegas, R. (2012). Control of directors’ compensation in Spanish companies: Corporate governance and firm performance. In A. Davila, M. J. Epstein, & J. F. Manzoni (Eds.), Performance measurement and management control: Global issues. Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Olivencia Report. (1998). Código de Buen Gobierno (Informe Olivencia). Madrid: CNMV. Order ECC. (2013). Order ECC/461/2013 of 20 March, which will determine the content and structure of the annual corporate governance report, the annual report on remuneration and other means of information of listed companies, boxes savings and other entities that issue securities admitted to trading on official stock markets. Royal Decree. (1989). Royal Decree 1564/1989, of 22 December, approving the revised text of the Spanish Companies Act. Royal Decree. (2002). Royal Legislative Decree 1/2002, of 29 November, approving the revised text of the Law Regulating Plans and Pension Funds. Royal Decree. (2004). Royal Decree 304/2004, of 20 February, which approves the plans and pension funds Regulations. Royal Decree. (2007). Royal Decree 1362/2007, of 19 October, by which develops the Law 24/1988, of 28 July, on the Securities Market, in relation to the transparency requirements in relation to information about issuers whose securities are admitted to trading on a secondary market or on another regulated market in the European Union. Royal Decree. (2008). Royal Decree 216/2008, of 15 February, on the capital of financial institutions. Royal Decree. (2010). Royal Legislative Decree 1/2010, of 2 July, approving the revised text of the Corporations Act. Royal Decree. (2011). Royal Decree 771/2011, of 3 June, by amending Royal Decree 216/2008, of 15 February, on the capital of financial institutions and Royal Decree 2606/1996 of 20 December on deposit guarantee funds of credit institutions. Royal Decree. (2012). Royal Decree-Law 2/2012, of 3 February, consolidation of financial sector. 183 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 11 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia Hussein Ahmed Tura Introduction The Ethiopian Commercial Code1 (hereinafter the Commercial Code) is a basic legislation governing various types of business organizations including partnerships, joint ventures, private limited companies, and share companies. Given that this legislation has not been updated since its adoption in 1960, it lacks provisions on many aspects of company governance particularly on directors’ remuneration. In addition to inadequacy of provisions pertinent to share companies, there is no single stipulation regarding directors’ remuneration of private limited companies. With respect to share companies, the law does not delineate any difference between executive and non-executive directors’ remuneration. Furthermore, it does not seem to entitle directors to receive remuneration as of right. The Commercial Code states that directors may receive remuneration only where the general meeting of shareholders decides to that effect or where companies incorporate terms on directors’ remuneration into their articles of association. Besides, the law does not require companies to establish a remuneration committee. Moreover, there is lack of legal provision or clear practice on the link between directors’ remuneration and performance of companies. Regarding the quantum of directors’ remuneration, the National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE) recently adopted a directive limiting the annual directors’ remuneration in the commercial banks not to exceed 50,000 Birr 1 See Commercial Code of Ethiopia (1960). 185 186 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA and monthly allowance 2,000 Birr, respectively. Despite the significance of regulating directors’ remuneration in banking industry owing to its overall importance to the country’s economy, this insignificant lump sum may adversely affect the independence of directors, retention of talented experts, and very disproportionate to the counter of legal responsibilities put upon the directors. This chapter explores the Ethiopian company law with respect to directors’ remuneration. With a view to showing the profile of the Ethiopian companies, it begins with a brief discussion on the features of companies and the growing tendency toward separation of ownership and control in share companies. The main discussion focuses on directors’ remuneration in Ethiopian share companies with special reference to the remuneration regulation, remuneration design (scheme), remuneration reporting, and remuneration challenges. Profile of Ethiopian Companies The majority of Ethiopian companies are family-based or closely owned and small in size of their operation.2 Most of them are private limited companies, which are considered to be “the best form for a company with only few owners.”3 For instance, among the 125 companies formed from 1991 to 1993, only 6 were share companies while 119 were private limited companies.4 By the same token, among 2,098 companies formed from 2008 to 2009, only 38 were share companies while 2,060 were private limited companies.5 Few years ago, only wealthy people used to set-up well capitalized share companies with five or more members who are often kith or kin of the founders.6 The case of entrepreneurs and professional managers launching companies with huge capital base and with nominal contribution from their own pockets was rare. Establishing companies by raising capital through public equities has been in the boom in the country, especially since mid-2008.7 2 Most of the smallest Ethiopian businesses are not organized as companies but as sole proprietorships, which are also required to register with the state. Those businesses have little or no reason to be companies; for instance, limited liability has little meaning for small-scale businesses especially when business is done on personal basis and court lawsuits are virtually unknown or impracticable. 3 See USAID (2007, p. 19). 4 See Girma (1994, p. 217). 5 See Tura, (2011a, p. 46). 6 See Addis Fortune Magazine (2011). 7 http://www.hg.org/article.asp?id=19590 (Last visited on July 9, 2013). Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia Although there are few share companies ordinarily incorporated under the existing Commercial Code and are unconnected to State Owned Enterprises, endowments and Midrock Groups, the majority of Ethiopia’s largest companies are owned or controlled by state bodies or political parties.8 Structurally, the endowment companies appear to have some similarity with nominee and proxy companies that were used to be found in some European institutions.9 Such companies account for larger part of the economy than privately owned companies, which can add a political tone in doing business.10 State-owned companies are not organized under the company law and thus not subject to its rules and protective provisions. The regulation on boards of public enterprises is to be found in Proclamations No. 25/1992 and No. 277/2002. The boards of public enterprises, excluding those in financial sector, are supervised by the Privatization and Public Enterprises Supervising Agency (PPESA). On the other hand, public financial enterprises are supervised by the Public Financial Enterprise Agency. PPESA is responsible for the appointment and replacement of board members of all public enterprises under its jurisdiction including the chairman. The Public Enterprises Proclamation No. 25/1992 requires state-owned enterprises to keep books of accounts following Generally Accepted Accounting Principles. The annual audits of the enterprises are carried out by the Office of Auditor General.11 The Emerging Separation of Ownership and Control in the Ethiopian Share Companies There has been unprecedented growth in the number of companies formed and under the process of formation through initial public offering of shares (IPOs) presently in Ethiopia.12 While this has helped the companies to mobilize huge capital from the public, it has also brought about the dispersion of corporate ownership 8 See Negash (2008, p. 10). Ibid. 10 USAID (2007, p. 20). 11 PSD (2009, p. 16). 12 For instance, six banks were newly formed in the country, while other 16 commercial banks are operating in the market. See http://capitalethiopia. com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=14181:three-hund red-million-birr-for-new-bank&catid=12:local-news&Itemid=4 (Last visited on September 23, 2013). 9 187 188 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA Table 1: Ownership Patterns in Some of the Non-Financial and Financial Companies. Name of Companies Combined Holdings of Highest 10 Holders in % Average Holding in % Combined Holdings of Directors in % No. of Shareholders Awash Int. Bank SC NA 0.037 NA 2,834 Birhan Int. Bank SC NA 0.01 NA 6,000 Bunna Bank SC NA 0.008 NA 11,200 Cheha Business SC 5.64 0.564 3.954 177 Crstal Tannery SC 6.667 0.083 2.583 360 Ehil Beranda Ehil Negadewoch SC 9.0 0.909 6.363 110 Papirus School SC 3.89 0.359 7.5 Sky Bus SC 1.138 0.020 0.399 2,793 YesheraTera Birhan Limat SC 6.57 0.657 5.921 152 Zemen Bank SC 9.37 0.034 1.659 2,878 110 Source: The Trade Registry at the FDRE Ministry of Trade, 2013. among several thousands of shareholders in each of these companies.13 Although separation of ownership and control usually comes into effect with the existence of thousands of shareholders in a given company, this may not be true in case where the distribution of shares is relatively even (Table 1). As can be gathered from Table 1, there is a movement, particularly in the financial share companies and recently in other sectors, from a closely held company towards more and broad-based share ownership. Even though what is truly triggering the dispersion of ownership is not clear, two factors are believed to constitute the causes for this phenomenon. The first one is related to the rise of inflation which might have made saving less attractive for the public,14 driving investment towards the widely available publicly offered shares. However, a comprehensive study of shareholder 13 Petros (2010, p. 14). In Habesha Cement SC, for instance more than 40% of the shareholders have 5,000 ETB (5 shares) each which is the minimum allowed holding, whereas 90% of the shareholders in Buna Bank (i.e., 10,350 out of 11,500) own less than 100,000 shares each. See Reporter (Amharic Version) of October 11 Edition. Likewise, in Brehan Bank S.C., the size of shareholders owning less than 100,000 is 95% percent (i.e., 5,708 out of 6,000 shareholders) see, Addis Fortune Magazine, edition of October 4, 2010. 14 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia profiles needs to be conducted along with the analyses of the volume of savings in banks in the context of formation of share companies through IPOs in Ethiopia.15 The second reason seems to be the design of company promoters who put a minimum and maximum amount of shareholding.16 This in turn must have been propelled by the emergence of professional and eager managers who are confident enough to collect capital from the wider public and make profit.17 Despite lack of clear policy regarding non-financial companies, the government policy in relation to the financial share companies engaged in banking business seems to be supporting dispersed share ownership. In this regard, Article 11(1) of the Banking Business Proclamation No. 592/2008 prohibits any person other than the FDRE Government from holding more than 5% of the shares in a bank. Moreover, while Article 2(11) defines a shareholder who owns 2% or more of the shares as an influential shareholder, the Proclamation refers to fitness criteria to be met by such a person under Article 4(1). The Proclamation also states that a share transfer that will make a person an influential shareholder shall be approved by the NBE under Article 10(1). To implement these provisions, the NBE has issued directives entitled “Time Limit for Reduction and/or Relinquishing Shareholdings Directive No. SBB/47/2010” that specifies the time limit for reduction of excess shares. It provides that “within 36 months from the effective date of this directive (i.e., 16th day of August 2010), a person who holds shares in a bank, either on his own or jointly with his spouse or with a person who is below the age of 18 years and related to him by consanguinity to the first degree, in excess of 5% of total subscribed capital of the bank shall reduce such holding to 5% or less and/or is influential shareholder in a bank, must relinquish his shareholdings in another bank.”18 A person who fails to comply with the provisions of this directive shall be penalized in accordance with Article 58(7) of Proclamation No. 592/2008. Such a person shall be punished with a fine up to 10,000 Birr and with an imprisonment up to three years.19 Thus, the cumulative reading of these provisions shows that the government’s policy in relation to financial share companies is toward diffused ownership. Nevertheless, there is no clear policy regarding non-financial 15 According to Access Capital research, in the year 2009, more than a billion Birr share sale was launched by six companies. Access Capital SC 2009. See http://www.africaneconomicoutlook.org/fileadmin/uploads/aeo/ 2014/PDF/CN_Long_EN/Ethiopie_EN.pdf. It is not clear whether or not bank deposits dropped by an equivalent amount. 16 See Addis Fortune Magazine (2011). 17 Ibid. 18 See Directives No. SBB/47/2010, Article 3(1) and (2). 19 See Banking Business Proclamation (2008). 189 190 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA share companies as the Commercial Code does not contain a provision dealing with this issue. Even if the policy towards diffused ownership in the financial institutions might be related to the fear of minority shareholder exploitations, this should not be taken as a conclusion that companies with small investors are not important to Ethiopia. “If the country needs to create a middle income segment of its population, and if it wants to have big companies that can pool capital from the broader public and compete on global level in post-WTO accession, encouraging the public to invest in share companies is an indispensable policy.”20 Concentrated companies are vital for the country’s economic development as they add assets to its overall GDP and create job opportunities to the citizens. Thus, it can be argued that concentrated ownership should not be prohibited for the mere fear of minority shareholders exploitation by block holders. The government should encourage such types of share companies since formation of companies in such manner enables them to pull huge amount of capital from the general public by way of public subscription as may be deemed necessary.21 In general, the emergence of newer companies with dispersed shareholders who have no control over the company is changing the company environment in Ethiopia. In such cases, control over the company is left in the hands of a few managers who in turn may be controlled by block holders. This demonstrates that the law should be reformed in a way that ensures shareholders protection and boosts the confidence of investors on share companies. In other words, appropriate laws and institutions that can tackle problems of corporate governance emerging under the new situation of separation between ownership and control in the country are highly necessary. Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopian Share Companies REMUNERATION REGULATION The Commercial Code recognizes directors’ remuneration under Article 353. It provides that “directors may receive a fixed annual remuneration, the amount of which shall be determined by a general meeting and charged against general expenses.”22 It also stipulates 20 See Tura (2011a, p. 80). Ibid. 22 See Commercial Code of Ethiopia (1960). Article 353 (1). 21 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia that “the articles of association may provide that the directors may receive a specified share in the net profits of a financial year.”23 Thus, directors’ remuneration can be decided through two procedures. First, the general shareholders meeting may decide that a fixed annual remuneration should be paid to the members of a board of directors. Second, companies may specify in their articles of associations that certain percent (e.g., 510%) of their net profits in a financial year shall be paid to directors. Moreover, the Commercial Code states that “the fixed remuneration and share in the profits to be allocated to the board of directors shall be allocated in one sum; and that the board shall arrange the distribution among its members in such proportion as it deems fit.”24 However, the amount of a share in the net profits may not exceed 10%. This share is calculated after deduction of: (a) amounts allocated to reserve funds provided by law or the articles of association; (b) the statutory dividend, where provided in the articles of association or where not provided, a sum representing 5% of the paid up value of shares which have not been redeemed; (c) amounts allocated to reserve funds established by resolution of a general meeting; and (d) amounts carried forward.25 In fixing share in profits, amounts distributed or capitalized and charged in a previous balance sheet shall be considered.26 It should be noted that “the director’s share in the net profits shall not be paid where no dividend has been distributed to the shareholders.”27 This provision is a precondition for enforcement of specified share in the net profits of a financial year under sub-article 2 of article 353. This means, directors’ remuneration may not be paid where companies make profits but where a decision is reached by directors that no dividend will be distributed to each shareholder. One may wonder why directors could be denied remuneration after succeeding in making profits. The main reason behind this stipulation might be aimed at precluding directors from reserving some portion of the profit for their own remuneration while at the same time unwilling to distribute dividend to the shareholders. Besides, directors may decide to re-invest the annual profit instead of distributing it to the shareholders as their remuneration percentage will increase in the next year. Thus, directors may choose to re-invest the annual profits of a company even for several years as this normally increases their share based on the level of the growth. Thus, the 23 Ibid. Article 353(2). Ibid. Article 353(3). 25 Ibid. Article 353(4). 26 Ibid. Article 353(5). 27 Ibid. Article 353(6). 24 191 192 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA directors will be obliged to distribute dividend to shareholders in order to receive their remuneration out of annual net profit as per article 353(2) of the Commercial Code. Moreover, the Ministry of Commerce and Industry, taking into account the special benefits which have been provided to directors having the status of founders and having regard to the position of the company and to the salaries and benefits of its employees, may, on the position of shareholders representing not less than 10% of the capital, order the reduction of the remuneration of the directors where it considers it to be excessive.28 REMUNERATION DESIGN (SCHEME) The Commercial Code recognizes three types of remuneration schemes. These are fixed annual remuneration,29 share in annual net profits,30 and mixed remuneration scheme.31 Fixed Annual Remuneration, which must be decided by the general shareholders’ assembly, does not depend on the making of profits by a company. As it is charged against general expenses, directors can be paid without waiting for annual profits of a company. Such type of remuneration may be determined by a general shareholders’ meeting (GSM) at the beginning of a financial year. Here one may wonder as to why the law entitles directors to receive remuneration even in the absence of profit. One possible reason is that it is difficult to conclude that there was no work done by directors in a budget year though the company fails to make profit. Companies might fail to make profits due to various reasons. For instance, companies might not make profits during the phase of their establishment though directors made their best efforts to that effect. Thus, if remuneration is not paid in such period because of absence of profit, no one may be willing to serve in board of directors. Similarly, companies might not make annual profits even after long operation in the market where they undertake further constructions and new investments. Adopting share in profit-based remuneration alone can affect a company by encouraging short termism at the expense of the long-term benefits. If the directors’ remuneration is exclusively based on the share in annual profit, directors may take 28 Ibid. Article 353(7). Ibid. Article 353(1): Directors may receive a fixed annual remuneration, the amount of which shall be determined by a general meeting and charged against general expenses. 30 Ibid. Article 353(2): “The articles of association may provide that the directors may receive a specified share in the net profits of a financial year.” 31 Ibid. Article 353(3): The fixed remuneration and share in the profits to be allocated to the board of directors shall be allocated in one sum. 29 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia every risk to make profit, which in turn undermines the long-term goals of the company and the interest of shareholders. Thus, being an appropriate incentive mechanism, fixed yearly remuneration is vital to strike a balance between conflicting interests of a company and its stakeholders. Share in Annual Net Profits is the second scheme of directors’ remuneration recognized under Article 353(2) of the Commercial Code, which substantially differs from that of the fixed annual remuneration. The articles of association of a company may stipulate that directors may receive specified share in the net profits of a financial year, the amount of which may vary from year to year on the basis of the overall amount of net profit made by the company. For instance, 5% of ten million and 10% of two million result in differing amount. This share is calculated after deduction of amounts allocated to reserve funds provided by law or the articles of association; the statutory dividend, where provided in the articles of association or where not provided, is a sum representing 5% of the paid up value of shares which have not been redeemed; amounts allocated to reserve funds established by resolution of a general meeting; and amounts carried forward as per Article 353(4) of the Commercial Code. Mixed Remuneration Design is the third option stipulated under Article 353(3) of the Commercial Code, where a company may entitle its directors to receive mixture of fixed yearly remuneration and share in profits in a single financial year. For example, the GSM may decide that directors receive five million Birr (fixed annual remuneration); and the articles of association of the same company may provide that directors are entitled to 3% of the net profits of a financial year. The amount of remuneration may vary depending on the size of the company and its annual net profits. Adopting a mixed directors’ remuneration design can be beneficial to both directors and the company. In one hand, the fixed annual remuneration design helps directors to be more prudent and hard working toward the implementation of the long-term strategies and objectives of the company. On the other hand, if the remuneration is solely a fixed yearly allowance, directors may be demotivated to make profits in a short period of time since they may entirely focus on long-term goals. Moreover, they may lose diligence to work toward profit making as they are guaranteed to be remunerated irrespective of the annual net income of the company. Thus, fixed yearly remuneration alone cannot be appropriate incentive. In a similar vein, designing directors’ remuneration on the basis of share in annual net profits alone may also have its own downsides. For instance, it may motivate directors to take excessive risks to make annual profit in order to be remunerated, which in turn can undermine the overall longterm strategies of a company. The mixed remuneration design, 193 194 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA therefore, can be used as an appropriate incentive mechanism that can motivate directors to work towards the long-term wellbeing of a company without being discouraged from striving to make annual profits. It should be noted here that the Commercial Code does not prohibit the share companies from paying monthly allowance. In addition, it does not cover other compensation schemes such as bonuses, stock options, pension, and benefits (car, healthcare, etc.). By adopting Directives No. SBB/49/2011, the NBE, the supervisory body of the financial institutions in the country, has set the maximum annual directors’ remuneration of a commercial bank not to exceed 50,000 Birr for each director since January 15, 2011. Moreover, the Directives impose a limit on the monthly allowance given to bank’s board members for transport, telephone, and other related costs. Accordingly, “monthly allowance pay to a bank director shall not exceed 2,000 (Two Thousand) Birr.” The Directives further stress that “no bank can pay any compensation for the board directors, other than these two payments.” REMUNERATION REPORTING The Commercial Code requires statements to be provided concerning directors’ remuneration. It stipulates that “the balance sheet submitted to the annual general meeting shall show the total amount of remuneration, allowances, annuities, retirement benefits and benefits in kind given to the directors.”32 Pursuant to this provision, all share companies are duty bound to disclose details on directors’ remuneration. As a mandatory legal provision on remuneration reporting, it may play a significant role in ensuring transparency in boardroom. It is particularly relevant to control excessive selfrewarding activities by executive or non-executive directors. In addition, the Commercial Code specifies that “loans or guarantees to directors shall also be shown.”33 Disclosure of details on directors’ loans or guarantees is required to control conflict of interests between the company and its directors. It is also important to avoid indirect self-rewarding of directors who assume fiduciary duties on behalf of shareholders. However, except financial institutions which are currently under strict regulation of the NBE, share companies are not answerable for failing to observe this mandatory provision of law as most companies do not report their remuneration regularly as per legal requirement. 32 33 Ibid. Article 361(1). Ibid. Article 361(2). Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia REMUNERATION CHALLENGES Although the Commercial Code lays down guidelines regarding directors’ remuneration, there are certain challenges surrounding its enforcement. For instance, the Commercial Code does not oblige share companies to pay directors remuneration unless it is decided by the Shareholders’ General Meeting or it is otherwise incorporated into the articles of association of a company. It is also not clear as to whether the law entitles other employees to participate on annual share in profits although there is a clue to this end. Besides the lack of definition of the term “director” in the Commercial Code, the law does not distinguish between a remuneration of executive and non-executive directors’ remuneration. There are also controversies surrounding the quantum of directors’ remuneration in commercial banks. The following few sections devote to a critical analysis of the challenges surrounding directors’ remuneration in Ethiopia. Directors’ Remuneration: Right or Privilege? The first controversy surrounding directors’ remuneration in Ethiopia emanates from the term “may” in Article 353(1) of the Commercial Code. This may give rise to a question as to whether directors of share companies are entitled to remuneration as of “right” or whether it constitutes a mere “privilege” that is paid or denied by the sole decision of companies’ shareholders. It may be argued that since the term “may” is a permissive auxiliary and the law requires the amount of remuneration to be fixed by the general meeting of shareholders, directors have no right to claim its payment as of right. This tends to limit directors’ right to enforce payment of remuneration where there is no clear contractual relationship between a company and its directors. In fact, directors’ remuneration may be incorporated into a company’s articles of association that would be a contractual basis for its enforcement. Otherwise, it would be difficult for directors to enforce their right to remuneration in courts of law where it is not expressly stipulated in the articles of association or decided by shareholders general meeting. This has also been a practical challenge. For instance, directors of Wogagen Bank, one of profit-making private banks in Ethiopia, worked for four years without receiving any fixed yearly remuneration or share in annual net profits since it was neither decided by general shareholders meeting nor incorporated into the company’s articles of association. One of the former members of the board of directors of this bank disclosed that “we were failed to sue the company for payment of directors’ remuneration in the belief that there is no legal or contractual basis for our claim.” He also added that this bank started to pay them after it was decided by the general meeting of shareholders. Moreover, he does not think that directors’ remuneration is right unless there is a clear contract on the matter. 195 196 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA On the other hand, it can be argued that directors should be entitled to remuneration irrespective of a decision of shareholders or its inclusion into a company’s articles of associations. This is because the same legislation (the Commercial Code) contains provisions imposing heavy liabilities on members of board of directors individually and collectively. For instance, Article 364 of the Commercial Code prescribes the following liability of directors to the company. 1. Directors shall be responsible for exercising the duties imposed on them by law, the memorandum or articles of association and resolutions of meetings, with the care due from an agent. 2. Directors shall be jointly and severally liable to the company for damage caused by failure to carry out their duties. 3. Directors who are jointly and severally liable shall have a general duty to act with due care in relation to the general management. 4. Directors shall be jointly and severally liable when they fail to take all steps within their power to prevent or to mitigate acts prejudicial to the company which are within their knowledge. 5. Directors shall be responsible for showing that they have exercised due care and diligence. 6. A director shall not be liable where he is not at fau1t and has caused a minute dissenting from the action which has been taken by the board to be entered forthwith in the directors’ minute book and sent to the auditors. In the same token, Article 366 of the Commercial Code stipulates for directors liability to creditors as follows: 1. Directors shall be liable to the company’s creditors where they fail to preserve intact the company’s assets. 2. Proceedings may be instituted by the creditors against the directors where the company’s assets are insufficient to meet its liabilities. 3. A resolution of the general meeting not to institute proceedings against the directors shall not affect the creditor’s rights. 4. Creditors may not apply to set aside a resolution to compromise except on the grounds available to them under civil law. Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia Furthermore, Banking Business Proclamation No. 592/2008 under Article 58 (6) provides that members of board of bank directors shall be punished with a fine from Birr 50,000 to Birr 100,000 and with a rigorous imprisonment from 10 to 15 years when any of them: a) obstructs the proper performance by an auditor of his duties in accordance with the provisions of this Proclamation or inspection of a bank by an inspector duly authorized by the National Bank; or b) with intent to deceive, makes any false or misleading statement or entry or omits any statement or entry that should be made in any book, account, report or statement of a bank; c) knows or ought to know the insolvency of the bank and receives or authorizes or permits the acceptance of a deposit. Therefore, it is paradoxical for the law to allow companies to deny payment of directors’ remuneration particularly where they have already made annual net profits while imposing the above heavy liabilities on directors. Therefore, there should be a right to remuneration corresponding to duties imposed on directors emanating from a mandatory provision of law. In addition, the role of effective directors’ remuneration as a tool of good corporate governance in share companies should not be underestimated. It can play a significant role in aligning the interest of shareholders with those of directors who are expected to undertake wider powers given to them by the law, the memorandum or articles of associations and resolutions passed at meetings of shareholders.34 Besides, an appropriate remuneration design is an incentive that may enhance the diligence and commitment of directors to carry out their overall duties in the interests of shareholders honestly. The main problem of corporate governance is the agency cost where the power of control and ownership separates and solely falls in the hands of few managers or controlling block holders. The institution of board of directors is created to safeguard the interests of dispersed shareholders against opportunism of those who control the company. Although the Commercial Code stipulates for directors’ remuneration under Article 353 as an incentive mechanism, it should be adequate and legally enforceable. The Commercial Code also allows directors to become shareholders in a company35 and obliges them to deposit as security with the company such number of their registered shares in the company as is fixed in the memorandum of association which shall not be handed back until the owners have ceased to be directors and have fully discharged their liabilities, if any to the company.36 Accordingly, the Commercial Code tries to mitigate agency costs in a share company by providing an incentive and controlling mechanisms. 34 Ibid. Article 363. Ibid. Article 347(1). 36 Ibid. Article 349(1) and (2). 35 197 198 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA Moreover, it should be noted that directors normally superintend the management on behalf of the shareholders of a company with dispersed share ownership. They also formulate general and specific policies and strategies of a company as well as decide on credit transactions, involving millions of money in case of financial companies provided that they will be responsible if things go wrong. Furthermore, the function of directorship by its nature involves costs that need to be compensated for the time and effort sacrificed for the benefit of a company. Therefore, there is no reason why directors would assume the responsibilities in profit-making companies without remuneration, and there is no justification for the law to deny a right to remuneration while it imposes burdensome liabilities on board members. Thus, Article 353 of the Commercial Code should be made a mandatory provision that obliges share companies to pay director’s remuneration where the articles of association remain silent. Remuneration of Executive and Non-Executive Directors: No Distinction? “Director” may be defined as “a person having control over the direction, conduct, management or superintendence of the affairs of the company.”37 Although the Commercial Code does not define the term “director,” it is defined under Article 2(6) of the Banking Business Proclamation No. 592/2008 as “any member of the board of directors of a bank, by whatever title he may be referred to.” The important factor to determine whether a person is a director is to refer to the nature of the office and its duties and it does not matter by what title she/he is referred to. In other words, if she/he is the member of the board and performs the functions of a directorship, she/he would be considered as a director in the eyes of the law. Article 347(1) of the Commercial Code stipulates that “[O]nly members of a company may manage the company.” A company may have managing or whole time directors who are in charge of the day-to-day conduct of the affairs of a company; and that they are together with other team members collectively known as “management” of the company.38 A company may also have part time non-executive directors who have nothing to do with the day-to-day management of the company. They may attend board meetings and meetings of committees of the board in which they are members.39 The Commercial Code also stipulates that “a company shall have not less than three and more than twelve directors who shall form a board of directors.”40 However, Article 353 of the 37 See Fernando (2006, p. 189). Ibid. 39 See Fama and Jensen (1983). 40 See Commercial Code of Ethiopia (1960), Article 347(2). 38 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia Commercial Code does not make a distinction between remuneration that should be paid for the executive directors and nonexecutive directors. This may create confusion on whether it is justifiable to remunerate both executive and non-executive directors likely. Should Body Corporate Directors Be Remunerated? The Commercial Code stipulates that “[B]odies corporate may be directors, but the chairman of the board of directors shall be a person.”41 Nonetheless, it is not clear as to whether a body corporate, which does not have a physical existence and is always represented by a physical person, should be entitled to directors’ remuneration because of mere fact of its membership in a certain board. Particularly, since remuneration is paid to directors for their tangible contribution to a company they govern, a body corporate (juridical person) is not in a position to undertake directors’ duties/functions; and that it is always represented by a physical person, which gives rise to agency relationship. A basic question worth consideration here is whether it is reasonable to remunerate a legal person (body corporate), which is represented by a physical person while a physical person (representative) claims payment of remuneration to his own use. In other words, are representatives of a body corporate or a legal person who participate in another profit-making company to carry out board of directors’ functions legally obliged to transfer directors’ remuneration that they received for their participation in a board of directors of another company? Assume that Nib International Bank (NIB) is a member of board of directors of Awash International Bank (AIB). As NIB (legal person) is not in position to undertake functions of directorship like participating in committee meeting, preparing business plan and controlling the management, it was represented by Mr. X (a physical person). Assume also that AIB paid annual remuneration amounting 500,000 (Five Hundred Thousand) Birr to each of its eight members of its board of directors. Who do you think is legally entitled to receive this remuneration, NIB or Mr. X? In this regard, there has been a case between Tumsa Endowment for Oromia Development (Plaintiff) versus Mr. Abdishu Hussein (defendant), which was brought before the Federal High 41 Ibid. Article 347 (4). 199 200 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA Court of Ethiopia. In this case, the defendant was the former general manager of the plaintiff for almost ten years. He was also specifically empowered to represent the plaintiff in all companies where it owns shares and to participate on meetings, to vote and safeguard the interests of the plaintiff. Accordingly, the defendant participated in the board of directors of Wogagen Bank SC (one of the privately owned banks in Ethiopia) for eight consecutive years by representing the Plaintiff. During this period, he received about 2.5 million Birr in the form of directors’ remuneration from the Wogagen Bank SC and used it for his own gain. This remuneration was decided in accordance with Article 353(1) of the Commercial Code by the 11th Annual GSM of Wogagen Bank SC. As can be read from the Minutes of this meeting, the main reason for deciding for payment of the directors’ remuneration was to compensate directors who sacrificed their time, knowledge, and efforts to maintain the interests of shareholders and the Bank. It is further mentioned that annual share in net profits (5%) was meant to be an incentive to instill diligence and commitment in board members for their future endeavors. Moreover, the decision passed by the GSM took into consideration the legal responsibilities and burdensome duties assumed by directors as a justification to pay directors’ remuneration. The new management of the plaintiff brought a legal proceeding against the defendant in 2012 alleging that the defendant was not legally entitled to receive remuneration for his personal gain; and that since he was the former general manager of the plaintiff, he acted as a mere representative while participating in the board of the Bank on behalf of the plaintiff, which was the actual and legal director; and that he illegally misappropriated the remuneration paid to the actual board member (the body corporate) and pleaded to the court to order the transfer of the total amount of money received in the form of directors’ remuneration with its legal interest (9%) to the Plaintiff. On the other hand, the defendant argued that although he participated in the board of the Bank which paid him remuneration while he was the representative of the present plaintiff, he is legally entitled to receive directors’ remuneration; and that he committed no fault in appropriating the sum of money he received in the form of directors’ remuneration for his personal gain which he received because of his personal efforts and contributions he personally made to the Bank with other members of the board, but not on behalf of the plaintiff. He further claimed that the purpose of remuneration is compensating individual board members than artificial person that has only an imaginary existence, and that the plaintiff could not make any tangible contribution to the operation and growth of the bank although it was a board member. He stated that he protected the interest of the plaintiff, which received a chunk amount of dividend because Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia of his participation in the board of the Bank on its behalf. However he contended that it would be illogical to pay remuneration to the plaintiff since remuneration is an incentive given to the board members for their personal commitments and diligence. He also adduced the decision passed by the general meeting of shareholders of the Bank that appreciates directors’ previous performance in controlling the management, formulating and implementing viable business goals, objectives and strategies as a result of which the Bank became more profitable. The decision also clearly indicates that directors sacrificed their time, knowledge, and honestly undertook their fiduciary duties which resulted in the overall growth of the Bank and enabled each shareholder to receive substantial amount of dividend and that it is fair to reward each director for their wonderful contribution so that they will continue to work diligently and honestly in the future. The defendant also argued that the former board of the plaintiff tacitly approved the remuneration he received and utilized for his personal use as he was not asked to transfer it to the asset of the plaintiff. He also alleged that it is a customary practice in the Ethiopian share companies where individual representatives of body corporate receive directors’ remuneration for their own gain despite the fact they represent their employer companies and participate in a board of another share company. The Federal High Court decided in favor of the plaintiff by citing Articles 2209 and 2210 of the Civil Code of Ethiopia. However, this decision was reversed by the Federal Supreme Court appellate division which found that directors’ remuneration was paid to the defendant for his personal contribution to the Wogagen Bank SC; that the scope of the power of agency entrusted upon the defendant by the plaintiff does not prohibit receiving directors’ remuneration (Article 2181 of Civil Code); that the defendant participated in the board of directors of the bank after personally fulfilling the requirements set by the NBE; that he personally assumed the legal responsibilities in accordance with the new Banking Business Proclamation and NBE directives; that as directors’ remuneration is an incentive or reward or compensation for persons who can work and produce tangible outcome, it would be unjust to deny payment of remuneration to the defendant; and that directors’ remuneration is an allowance meant for compensating costs incurred by directors while performing their functions.42 42 This case is still pending at the Federal Supreme Court Cassation Division, which will render final and binding decision. Source: Federal Supreme Court Cassation Division (2014). 201 202 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA The implication of a power of agency entrusted upon a physical person to participate in a board of directors of a share company could be relevant where disagreement arises between the body corporate director (principal) and the physical person (agent) as to who is legally entitled to receive remuneration. The existence of contract of agency should not be confused with entitlement to remuneration because of the following reasons. First, directors are not as of right entitled to remuneration because of their being elected as members in certain board of a share company including commercial banks as per Article 353(1) of the Commercial Code of Ethiopia. The payment of directors’ remuneration is based on the exclusive decision of GSM on the basis of directors’ actual works, contributions, and overall company performance. In other words, Article 353(1) of the Commercial Code is not a mandatory provision regarding the payment of remuneration unless it is decided by a general meeting of shareholders. On the other hand, the main purpose of directors’ remuneration is to compensate individuals who actually work and contribute their time, expertise, and effort toward the development of a business organization. It may also serve to attract talented and experienced professionals to increase the overall business performance of a company. Besides, remuneration is an incentive or reward for the performance of directors. Accordingly, there is no reason why body corporate director would be entitled to remuneration unless the content and purpose of specific agency as per Article 2181 of the Civil Code clearly show that the agent is empowered to receive remuneration on behalf of the principal. Otherwise, there would be no basis, contractual or legal, to effect payment to a body corporate director, given that a sole fact of membership does not give rise to a right to remuneration. Therefore, the existence of power of agency in which a physical person is appointed to participate in certain board, without specific agency to receive remuneration, should not be construed as precluding a physical person (agent) from receiving remuneration for his own benefits as long as the payment is effected based on the performance of the company paying it. It is obvious that a body corporate, because of its very nature, cannot undertake actual work that may produce tangible result for which remuneration could be paid. Thus, after all, why should a legal person be rewarded at the expense of a physical person who sacrifices his time, effort, and knowledge? Moreover, the scope and purpose of agency should be taken into account. For a body corporate to be entitled to directors’ remuneration, there must be an express and specific agency on this particular point. Second, the directors of commercial banks should not be taken as mere representatives of a body corporate. Banking Business Proclamation and Directives of the NBE set preconditions regarding Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia professional qualifications, ethical conducts, and heavy civil and criminal liabilities (see Proclamation No. 592/2008, Article 58; NBE Directives SBB/54/2012). Election of a person to participate in a certain board of directors does not give rise to automatic assumption of position of a director unless the National Bank approves him personally. Therefore, a person who served as a director in certain board of private bank should be legally entitled to remuneration, not only because he works but also he assumes the responsibility of directorship with risks of civil and criminal liabilities. Hence, there is no justification for the law to deny a right to remuneration while imposing burdensome liabilities on a person who works in a board of directors’ of certain private bank. Amount of Bank Directors’ Remuneration Becomes Controversial There is also controversy regarding the amount of directors’ remuneration, especially, in relation to the financial companies in Ethiopia. According to Article 353(4) of the Commercial Code, the amount of directors’ remuneration ranges from 5% to 10% of the annual net profit of a company subject to deductions provided under sub-articles of the same provision [Article 353(4)(ad)]. The NBE has found such payments in banks as being huge amount of money as they remunerate their board members with generous pay packages.43 For example, in 2010 alone, private banks declared a net profit of 1.4 billion Birr after paying 575.4 million Birr in profit tax and the directors of 11 private banks received a total of 37.3 million Birr in allowances and profit sharing in the 2009/2010 fiscal year.44 Among them, Awash International Bank held the leading position by spending 9.3 million Birr on its directors, followed by Nib International Bank which awarded its members of board of directors 7.5 million Birr.45 According to the survey conducted by the NBE, the highest paid director pocketed one million Birr per annum, whereas the lowest paid was 102,000.00 Birr.46 The NBE further observed that competition among shareholders to secure a seat on the board was prevalent due to this generous remuneration scheme for directors in the private banks.47 In order to regulate this problem, the NBE issued Directives No. SBB/49/ 2011 on January 6, 2011, in accordance with Article 14(4)(e) of the Banking Business Proclamation No. 592/2008 which authorizes it to issue directives on the maximum remuneration of a director of a 43 See Addis Fortune Magazine (2011). Ibid. 45 Ibid. 46 See Capital Magazine (2011). 47 See Tura (2011b, p. 70). 44 203 204 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA bank, to address disputes and create industry peace and good corporate governance among financial institutions.48 The directives limit the remuneration of individual private bank directors to 50,000.00 Birr in one operating year, and a monthly allowance of 2,000.00 Birr. Banks are also prohibited from paying directors any benefits, in cash or in kind, in addition to the set annual amount. The failure to implement the directives could earn a non-complying bank a penalty of 10,000 Birr and make it liable for criminal and civil suits.49 The Directives have indeed entailed debate among different persons including members of boards of directors of private banks and officials of the NBE. The Directives have been criticized for a number of reasons. First, it is contended that the fixed pay scheme proposed by the Directives does not take into account the size of the banks, the experience and responsibility of each director, or the complexity of the operations they are engaged in.50 Second, the Directive is believed to have removed the right of shareholders to reward those they trust to sit in the boardroom and make decisions on their behalf.51 According to this view, although banks in particular and financial institutions in general are highly important for the overall economy of the country thereby deserving regulation to avoid scandals, it should equally be taken into account that private banks are profit-oriented institutions and individuals involved in their governance also deserve incentives which are proportionate to their contribution.52 Third, it is argued that “the new pay package is too draconian and would push talented individuals out of the governance of the banking sector.”53 A banker in the top management of a private bank who requested anonymity admits “the importance of regulating banks in the current situation” but underlines that “while the directives is a move towards the right direction, the new remuneration scheme, set at a maximum of fifty thousand Birr for the board of directors has been set too low.” This was also shared by eight members of board of directors of private banks who wished their name to be withheld. They argued that “the amount of remuneration set does not take into consideration the workload, which involves meetings and committee work, as well as the risk involved in being a director.” They also argued that “the content of the directives in relation to the amount of directors’ remuneration would 48 Directives No. SBB/49/2011, Preamble. Proclamation No. 592/2008, Article 58. 50 Hussein, Directives No. SBB/49/2011, Preamble. 51 Ibid. 52 Ibid. 53 See Addis Fortune Magazine (2011). 49 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia discourage many people as it is mainly those with many years of experience in the banking sector that are sought after.” Some of them stated that they would not want to take the workload for the next term of election and risk of a 15-year imprisonment if things go wrong. In the fourth place, the low remuneration might also open the door for corruption in the banking industry as the board of directors is the top governing body that decides on key financial and credit issues. On the other hand, the Government argues that the Directives will have positive contribution towards the creation of industry peace and good corporate governance in the commercial banks in the country.54 It is asserted that “sound corporate governance is vital for the health of individual banks and the banking sector as a whole” while “excessive remuneration recently being paid by banks to directors have become a threat to the health of the banking system.”55 It is also suggested that “[t]he amount paid to directors before issuance of the directives was excessive and was creating a corporate governance crisis and conflicts among shareholders to obtain seats on the boards of directors.”56 It has also been maintained that “the NBE, as the regulator of financial institutions, is responsible for setting guidelines on the remuneration of board of directors in light of good corporate governance practices in the best interest of all stakeholders.”57 Furthermore, it is hoped that the Directives can promote long-term profits and interests of companies by discouraging high risk taking for the short-term gains. Given the economic significance of banks, the directors’ remuneration must be in line with the interest of all stakeholders. That is why the Proclamation No. 591/2008 authorizes the NBE “to foster a healthy financial system and to undertake such other related activities as are conducive to rapid economic development of Ethiopia.”58 Furthermore, the Banking Business Proclamation empowers the NBE to issue directives on the maximum remuneration of directors.59 54 Directives No. SBB/49/2011, Preamble. See NBE. 56 The NBE asserted that it has received many requests from shareholders and those who did not get seats on a bank’s board to intervene, before the issuance of the Directives. Interview with Mr. Solomon Desta, Director of Bank Supervision for NBE, April 26, 2011. 57 Ibid. 58 Proclamation No. 591/2008, Article 4: To achieve these purposes, the NBE is further empowered to license and supervise banks, insurance companies, and other financial institutions; and to create favorable conditions for the expansion of banking, insurance, and other financial services for the achievement of these objectives in accordance with relevant laws. 59 Ibid. Article 14(4)(e). 55 205 206 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA Moreover, directors’ remuneration in Ethiopia should be in line with international best practices. “Instead of setting monetary figures on the directors’ pay, the regulator should have required banks to set up a remuneration committee independent of the board to prepare a remuneration policy.”60 This is supported by the experience of countries with good practices in the corporate governance of financial institutions. For instance, the G20 summit held at Pittsburgh on September 2425, 2009, underlined the “pressing need for remuneration and governance principles in financial institutions” which should be “based on a globally consistent framework aimed at ‘aligning compensation’ with long-term value creation, not excessive risk taking.”61 Moreover, it has been stressed that “a board remuneration committee should be an integral part of an institution’s governance structure and should be competent, independent and be able to demonstrate that compensation decisions are aligned with the institutions’ financial stability and future performance.”62 Therefore, the NBE should have considered the internationally accepted practices while setting the amount of remuneration. Lack of Legal Requirement for Remuneration Committee Another legal gap in relation to regulation of directors’ remuneration is the silence of the law on remuneration committee. The Commercial Code and other relevant laws do not provide for establishment of a remuneration committee in share companies in Ethiopia. The practice is also unsatisfactory as companies rarely establish remuneration committee in their board. The importance of this committee is underlined in a number of countries. For instance, various corporate governance codes and principles contain provisions calling for establishment of remuneration committee. In this regard, the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance provides that “Boards may consider establishing remuneration committee with a minimum number or be composed entirely of non-executive members.”63 London Stock Exchange (LSE) Combined Code also stipulates that “remuneration committees should be made up exclusively of non-executive directors who make recommendations on the company’s framework of executive remuneration and who must operate independently from managerial interference and from any 60 See Addis Fortune Magazine (2011). See Deringer (2009). 62 Ibid., p. 5. 63 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD Principle of Corporate Governance (1999, revised 2004), Principle VI.E.1 and Annotation to OECD Principle VI.E.1. See http://www.oecd.org/corporate/ principles-corporate-governance.htm. 61 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia intrusive business relationship; they should be granted full authority to seek counsel from both inside and outside sources.”64 It stresses that “[t]hey should establish a formal and transparent procedure for developing policy on executive remuneration and for fixing the remuneration packages of individual directors.” Similarly, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision stated that “A Compensation Committee should be set up for providing oversight of remuneration of senior management and other key personnel and ensuring that compensation is consistent with the bank’s culture, objectives, strategy and control environment.”65 In the same token, Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) lays down non-mandatory recommendations on remuneration committees as follows. The board should set up a remuneration committee to determine on their behalf and on behalf of the shareholders with agreed terms of reference, the company’s policy on specific remuneration packages for executive directors, including pension rights and any compensation payment. The remuneration committee should comprise of at least three directors, all of whom should be non-executive directors, the chairman of the committee being an independent director. The Chairman of the remuneration committee should be present at the AGM to answer the shareholder queries.66 Although none of the relevant laws of Ethiopia requires the establishment of remuneration committee in financial as well as non-financial companies, valuable lessons could be drawn from international best practices for the future legal improvement in this regard. Participation of Employees Other than Directors on Annual Share in Profits Commercial Code lacks a provision entitling employees or workers other than directors to annual remuneration. However, the background document on Article 353 of the Ethiopian Commercial Code states the following: 64 London Stock Exchange Combined Code on Corporate Governance (2003). 65 Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Principles for Enhancing Corporate Governance, Bank for International Settlements’ Communications CH-4002 Basel, Switzerland, October 2010, principle 3, section 53. 66 SEBI (2000). 207 208 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA Remuneration of directors must be limited if one wishes to avoid inequitable payments. This article contains severe provisions … It finishes with an important provision for the protection of minorities, in which appears, following the example of German law, the desire to maintain a certain proportion between the remuneration of directors and that of the company’s other personnel(employees, workers). It follows that the tremendous problem of the participation of the personnel in the profits of the enterprise can be attached to this provision and the whole problem can be discussed at the same time unless one thinks that under present circumstances the discussion would be premature.67 As can be understood from this commentary, Article 353 of the Commercial Code was introduced following the example of German law with a view to maintaining certain proportion between the remuneration of directors and that of the company’s other personnel (employees, workers). Germany, with its system of codetermination granting employees a formal role in corporate governance, is often cited as the prime example of the “stakeholder model.”68 Nonetheless except the above explanatory note on Article 353 of the Commercial Code, there is no other clue under the Commercial Code as to whether workers or employees other than directors are entitled to share in annual profits in the Ethiopian companies. On the other hand, Article 353(4)(b) is not clear because of lack of definition of “statutory dividend”69 and as to whose interest it was reserved. When we read this provision in light of the above commentary on Article 353, “statutory dividend” seems meant to 67 See Winship (1974, p. 16). See Salacuse (2002, p. 54). 69 Article 353(4)(b) of the Commercial Code provides that the amount of share in the net profits may not exceed 10% and that this share should be calculated after deduction of “… the statutory dividend, where provided in the articles of association, or where not provided, a sum representing 5% of the paid up value of shares which have not been redeemed.” However, it is not clear why the law requires the deduction of this amount before payment of directors’ remuneration. It is also difficult to identify a beneficiary of the “statutory dividend” or a sum representing 5% of the paid up value of shares which have not been redeemed to be deducted from the annual net profit. A clue in the Commercial Code that would be of help to relate the term “statutory dividend” in Article 353(4)(b) to terms envisaged in Articles 337 and 457 as “statutory interest” or “fixed” or “interim interest.” This is discernible from the provisions of Article 337(2) that runs “these shares do not confer any right to that part of the dividend representing the statutory interest.” It may, therefore, be argued that the term “statutory dividend” in Article 353(4)(b) is the same with “statutory interest,” “fixed interest,” or “interim interest.” 68 Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia maintain the interest of employees since other sub-provisions of Article 353 of the Commercial Code are clear enough and do not give any implication regarding participation of other employees on share in annual profits of a company. In contrast, some members of board of directors and executive officers of share companies in Ethiopia believe that “employees do not have any legitimate right to participate in profit-sharing scheme of companies particularly on the annual net profits and may receive only certain amount of bonuses on the sole will of board of directors.”70 Due to its vagueness, Article 353(4)(b) of the Commercial Code remains inapplicable. The draft version of the revised Commercial Code also maintains this provision without any modification to it. The objectives of companies differ in civil law and common law legal systems. In Germany and other European civil law countries, the main objective of a company is to maximize the interest of stakeholders including employees, suppliers, depositors, and the community at large unlike the shareholder model of corporate governance followed in the common law countries such as the US and the UK, which primarily targets the protection of interests of the shareholders of publicly held companies.71 The difference on the experiences of countries basically stems from their cultural backgrounds, philosophical underpinnings of doing business, and the concept of profit sharing that could be extended to role of employees of a company.72 In Germany, the interests of the employees can be represented in an organization by variety of ways, including through trade unions, codetermination (employee participation on board of directors), profit sharing, equity sharing, and team production solution.73 The concept of profit sharing with employees in order to protect their interests in an organization became much more widely used in Europe in the 1990s.74 The majority of profit-sharing schemes are broad-based. That is, all or more employees were included in the scheme of profit sharing rather than just executives only.75 Profit sharing motivates the individual worker to put in his/her best as his/her efforts are directly related to the profits of the organization, in which one gets a share.76 The objective of such profit sharing is to encourage employees’ involvement in the company and improve 70 See Hussein, Directives No. SBB/49/2011, Preamble. See Salacuse (2002, p. 23). 72 Ibid. 73 Ibid. 74 Ibid. 75 Ibid. 76 Ibid. 71 209 210 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA their motivation and distribution of wealth among all the factors of production.77 We have seen that the background document on Article 353 of the Commercial Code tends to recognize other employees’ right to participate in the profit sharing of a share company in Ethiopia, although it is not clear as to whether Article 353(4)(b) is reserved to achieve this purpose. Involving employees in annual profit sharing is in line with the notion of corporate social responsibility. The above commentary should be taken as a benchmark for share companies in Ethiopia to rethink of rewarding not only directors but also other employees as doing so will benefit them more. Conclusion The Commercial Code of Ethiopia provides for the directors’ remuneration.78 There are three schemes of annual directors’ remuneration recognized under the Commercial Code including annual fixed remuneration, share in annual net profits, and mixed remuneration. Companies also pay monthly allowances and other cash and in kind benefits. Directors’ remuneration can be decided by GSM or specified in a company’s articles of association. However, the law lacks important provisions and clarity regarding the directors’ remuneration which makes its application controversial and complicated. For instance, the law does not expressly oblige companies to pay directors’ remuneration unless it is provided in the articles of association or decided by shareholders’ meeting. Nevertheless, there is no justification for the law to deny a right to remuneration while it imposes burdensome liabilities on a person who works in a board of directors. Besides, the Commercial Code does not specify any difference between remuneration of executive and non-executive directors. In this regard, lack of definition of the term “director” in the law may complicate the issue as to whether a body corporate is entitled to directors’ remuneration where an agent participates in another company’s board of directors without specific purpose of receiving remuneration on its behalf. Particularly, a person who serves as a director in certain board of private bank in Ethiopia should be legally entitled to remuneration, not only because she/he personally contributes for the growth of the company but also because she/he assumes the responsibility of directorship with risks of civil and criminal liabilities. 77 78 Ibid. See Commercial Code of Ethiopia (1960), Article 353. Directors’ Remuneration in Ethiopia The NBE fixed the maximum amount of directors’ remuneration not to exceed 50,000 Birr per year in companies engaged in banking business. This directive neglects factors such as the workload, which involves meetings and committee work, and the risk involved in being a director. On the other hand, excessive remuneration systems can hurt a company’s long-term strategy by encouraging undue focus on short-term gains. For instance, executive incentive schemes that encouraged excessive risk taking are part of a wider problem that contributed to the global financial and economic crisis in 2008.79 There is thus the need to strike the appropriate balance between the pitfalls of exaggerated payment packages versus inadequate thresholds of remuneration to directors.80 The directors’ remuneration should be incentive-oriented based on company and individual best director performance and meanwhile be designed so as to align directors’ interests with those of shareholders subject to the precaution against excessive payments.81 The remuneration packages for executive directors should be determined by the remuneration committee which should follow clearly laid down and transparent procedures.82 Criteria such as performance and the company’s position among its competitors in the same or similar industry can indeed be considered in the determination of all incentive schemes.83 Furthermore, the remuneration packages of all directors should be disclosed in the annual report. The disclosures regarding all elements of remuneration package of all the directors, that is, salary, benefits, bonuses, stock options, pension, etc., should be made to the shareholders. Besides, shareholders should have the final say in approving remuneration of the full-time as well as the non-executive directors. The remuneration packages of senior employees holding key executive posts should be approved by the board and full details thereof should be disclosed to the shareholders. References Addis Fortune Magazine. (2011, April 28). Addis Ababa. Banking Business Proclamation. (2008). Article 58(7), Proclamation No. 592, Fed. Neg.Gaz. 14th year, No. 57. Capital Magazine. (2011, February 29). Addis Ababa. 79 See CIMA (2010, p. 2). See Hussein, Directives No. SBB/49/2011, Preamble, p. 76. 81 Ibid. 82 Ibid. 83 Ibid. 80 211 212 HUSSEIN AHMED TURA CIMA (the Chartered Institute of Management Accountants). (May 2010). Executive remuneration schemes and their alignment with business sustainability. Discussion paper, p. 2. Commercial Code of Ethiopia. (1960). Proclamation No. 166/1960, Book II, Articles 210 to 554, Neg.Gaz. Extraordinary Issue No. 3. Deringer, F. B. (2009, October). LLP, remuneration and corporate governance in financial institutions. Retrieved from www.freshfields.com. Accessed on April 26, 2012. Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 301325. Federal Supreme Court Cassation Division. (2014). Retrieved from http://www.fsc. gov.et Fernando, A. C. (2006). Corporate governance: Principles, policies, and practices (p. 189). New Delhi: Pearson Education. Girma, A. (1994). Problems and prospects for the emergence of a stock market in Ethiopia. In G. Yoseph & A. H. B. Kello (Eds.), The Ethiopian Economy: Problems and Prospects of Private Sector Development. Proceedings of the third annual conference on the Ethiopian economy, Addis Ababa (p. 217). London Stock Exchange Combined Code on Corporate Governance. (2003, July). Retrieved from http://www.frc.org.uk/documents/pagemanager/frc/Web%20Optimi sed%20Combined%20Code%203rd%20proof.pdf. Accessed on May 11, 2015. NBE. The Preamble of “Limits on Board Remuneration and Number of Employees Who Sit on Bank Board Directives No. SBB/49/2011”. Negash, M. (2008). Rethinking corporate governance in Ethiopia (p. 10). Johannesburg: University of the Witwatersrand. Petros, F. (2010, March). Emerging separation of ownership and control in Ethiopian share companies: Legal and policy implications. Mizan Law Review, 4(1), 14. Private Sector Development [PSD]. (2009, June). Hub, draft project document for development of corporate governance in Ethiopia, p. 16. Salacuse, W. J. (2002, December). Corporate governance in the UNECE region, The Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Turfts University, Medford, MA. Paper commissioned for the Economic Survey of Europe, 2003 No. 1 by the secretariat of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe, UN/ECE, Geneva, p. 54. Securities and Exchange Board of India [SEBI]. (2000, March). Report of the Kumar Mangalam Birla Committee on Corporate Governance, Final Report: India, Section 6.2. Retrieved from http://www.sebi.gov.in/commreport/corpgov.html. Accessed on May 11, 2015. Tura, H. A. (2011a). Corporate governance in Ethiopia: What should the future look like? LL.M Thesis, Addis Ababa University School of Law, p. 80. Tura, H. A. (2011b, June). Overview of corporate governance in Ethiopia: The role, composition and remuneration of directors in share companies. Mizan Law Review, 6(1), 70. USAID. (2007, January). Ethiopian Commercial Law and Institutional Reform and Trade Diagnostic, p. 19. Winship, P. (1974). Background documents of the Ethiopian commercial code of 1960 (p. 16). Addis Ababa: Faculty of Law, Haile Sellassie I University. CHAPTER Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements: From European Legislation to German Implementation$ 12 Oliver Kruse, Christoph Schmidhammer and Erich Keller Introduction This chapter analyses the implementation of remuneration policies in German banking institutions starting from European legislation standards. The regulations are examined with respect to appropriate prerequisites of incentive-compatible remuneration systems. The risk-taking behavior of the financial sector was an important driver of the financial crisis of 20072009.1 Consequently, supervisors and banking authorities were required to develop effective rules for sustainable financial stability. For managers, excessive $ The chapter reflects the personal opinions of the authors and not necessarily the views of Deutsche Bundesbank. 1 A survey of the institute of International Finance in 2009 shows that 98% of the institutions were convinced and that inappropriate remuneration practise strongly contributed to the financial crisis. The following weakness was mentioned: asymmetric alignment of remuneration systems, transparency, strategy, and risk taking. See International Monetary Fund [IMF] (April, 2008), chapter 2, and Financial Stability Board (FSB, 2013). 213 214 OLIVER KRUSE ET AL. risk taking could be an incentive when profits and losses are rewarded asymmetrically. This means that managers expect high compensation payments related to short-term profits while losses do not necessary lead to negative rewards. From a scientific perspective, the moral hazard problem is induced by the behavior of managers and investors. Both profit from unlimited upside returns, while downside risk is limited due to government intervention. This is the case when institutions are regarded to be systemic relevant or “too big to fail.”2 The problem of moral hazard could be solved by implementing systems that are able to control management activities. Implementing and operating systems would cause agency costs. A number of papers have analyzed the impact of moral hazard, for example, Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W. H (1976). Authors investigate the general nature of “agency costs generated by the existence of debt and outside equity.”3 In the case of the financial crises where losses are socialized and tax payers had “to pay the bill,” a significant reduction of social welfare is the consequence. In the case of systemic relevant institutions, excessive protection payments could destabilize economies and increase the risk of government illiquidity. To avoid this scenario, clear rules of banking supervisors help to insure the safety of the financial system. Although this causes agency costs, the implementation of rules can be expected to be significantly cheaper than costs induced by the retrieval of an insolvent major institution. Consequently, banking supervisors started to develop and implement prudential rules on an international level. For example, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) defines Compensation Principles and Standards Assessment Methodology in 2010 (BIS, 2010), which can be regarded as recommendation for banking systems worldwide. The European Parliament and Council has adopted remuneration policies (EU Directive, 2013), namely Directive 2013/36/EU on access to the activity of credit institutions and the prudential supervision of credit institutions and investment firms, amending directive 2002/87/EC and repealing Directives 2006/48/EC and 2006/49/EC (CRD IV). European standards are subsequently implemented into German legislation via legal acts, denominated as Regulation on the Supervisory Requirements for Remuneration Systems in Institutions (“Verordnung über die aufsichtsrechtlichen Anforderungen an Vergütungssysteme von Instituten InstitutsVergV”). After illustrating the prerequisites of an incentive-compatible remuneration system, this chapter provides an overview about the regulative framework of the EU. In the next section, we describe the 2 3 Bebchuk and Spamann (2010). Jensen and Meckling (1976). Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements characteristics of the German remuneration regulation in comparison to the EU framework. Finally, the chapter discusses the incentive-compatibility of the European and German remuneration systems and concludes with future challenges. Prerequisites of an Incentive-Compatible Remuneration System Since many years remuneration systems are well accepted in human resource management. Popular examples in literature analyzing remuneration systems for banks are, for example, Erdmann (1991), Rinker (1997), or Kruse (2001). The three authors state that important functions of an effective implementation and operation of remuneration systems are that: They should increase the motivation which leads to a better performance. Variable elements of remuneration significantly support this function, especially when the performance of an individual and the business performance are adequately rewarded. In cases where an individual’s performance strongly influences the business performance of the whole unit or bank, exceptional high bonuses are paid, see, for example, in investment banking activities or in distribution functions. They should promote operational and strategic business objectives. For this function the time-horizon is important. If shorttime bonuses are paid solely, operational objectives will be promoted. Short-time bonuses can contradict strategic objectives of institutions, if high risk taking is incentivized. They should increase employee attractiveness. Institutions are willing to pay high bonuses in order to attract high performers.4 Because functions can be contradicting, it is challenging to design remuneration systems which adequately fulfill the main features, for example, an increase in motivation and strategic objectives.5 Erdmann (1991), Rinker (1997), or Kruse (2001) show that diverging functions can only be achieved, if the following prerequisites are fulfilled. Transparency: Motivation theories and their evaluation illustrate that variable remuneration increases motivation, if employees 4 5 Herring et al. (2014). Rosenstiehl (1975), Staehle (1999). 215 216 OLIVER KRUSE ET AL. clearly understand performance-related bonus systems. Vice versa is true for systems that are not transparent.6 Flexibility: Remuneration systems should allow for flexibility in order to adjust for changing internal and external conditions. Compensation Impact: Motivation theories indicate that the amount of variable payments has to be perceived as significant. Otherwise variable components do not contribute to increase motivation. Efficiency: Remuneration systems are regarded to be efficient, if the cost-value ratio is low. In other words, the costs for remuneration and handling should be in due proportion to its benefits. Justice: This prerequisite includes three elements. First, remuneration has to cover knowledge and skills. Second, the level of performance should be adequately rewarded and finally, remuneration should be in line with market conditions. Similar market conditions for all participants are designated as level playing field. Individual and Team Practicability: Remuneration systems should consider the performance of an individual and if appropriate, the performance of a team. This prerequisite contributes to the perception of justice. Figure 1 shows that functions and prerequisites are directly and indirectly connected. Kruse (2001) highlights that the prerequisites Transparency, Flexibility, Compensation Impact, Efficiency, Justice, and Individual and Team Practicability significantly contribute to the acceptance of a remuneration system. Only when bonus systems are accepted, a successful implementation and sustainable operation can be achieved. Regulative Remuneration Standards of the EU Article 75 of the Directive 2013/36/EU provides an overview of remuneration policies in the EU. The role of national authorities, for example, national banks like the German Federal Financial Supervisory Authority (BaFin), as well as the role of the European Banking Authority (EBA), and the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) is described. While national authorities are required to collect information which are disclosed by banking institutions (and provide EBA with information), EBA has to issue guidelines which support banks to implement the guidelines set out in Articles 9295 of the Directive. The focus of information collection 6 Porter and Lawler (1968). Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements 217 Functions Increasing performance motivation Promoting operational and strategic business objectives Enhancing employer attractiveness Acceptance Individual and team practicability Transparency Flexibility Compensation impact Efficiency Justice Prerequisites Figure 1: Functions and Prerequisites of Remuneration Systems.7 Source: Kruse (2001). and reporting is on natural persons who earn more than 1 million Euros per year.8 Article 92 of the Directive highlights that remuneration rules which have to be applied on the group, parent company, and (offshore) subsidiary level. Remuneration policies should include a broad range of staff reaching from senior management, risk takers, staff engaged in control functions, and any staff who has material impact on the risk profile of an institution. The risk profile of an institution can be characterized according to size, international structure as well as nature, scope, and complexity of activities.9 This characterization is of special interest for the German banking system which is heterogeneous in size and complexity of its institutions. Based on data provided by Deutsche Bundesbank (2013),10 the heterogeneity can be shown by relating the number of institutions and 7 Kruse (2001). Directive 2013/36/EU, Article 75. 9 Directive 2013/36/EU, Article 92. 10 Bankenstatistik, March 2013, of Deutsche Bundesbank (2013). 8 218 OLIVER KRUSE ET AL. the corresponding balance sheet total. The German banking system includes 1,867 independent banks where, for example, 1,104 cooperative institutions (59% of the number of German institutions) comprise approximately 11% of the balance sheet total, while 4 large banks comprise more than 31%.11 The German remuneration regulation accounts for that fact, which is described in Section “The Implementation of Remuneration Regulations in Germany.” The Directive 2013/36/EU enumerates remuneration characteristics which have to be implemented on a national level. Important requirements are that12: • remuneration policy is consistent with effective risk management and does not encourage excessive risk taking; • remuneration policy is in line with the long-term business strategy; • management is responsible for implementing a review process of the remuneration policy; staff involved in control functions are independent from business units they oversee; • a remuneration committee has to be implemented in institutions, which directly oversees senior officers; the implementation of a committee is primarily addressed at significant institutions with respect to size, scope, and complexity; organizational details are described in Article 95 of the Directive 2013/36/EU. Article 92 makes a clear distinction between fixed and variable remuneration criteria. While fixed wages reward professional and organizational experience, variable remuneration should reflect a sustainable and risk-adjusted performance. Details of variable remuneration elements are described in Article 95 of the Directive 2013/ 36/EU. One central element is a long-term oriented compensation of performance-based components. The time span of the variable remuneration should be spread over the business-cycle of an institution’s business risk. Furthermore, variable compensation should not exceed fixed components. An exception is the remuneration of shareholders or owners of institutions who could earn up to 200% of the fixed income.13 At least 50% of the variable remuneration shall consist of shares, equivalent ownership interests, or instruments that could be converted to Common Equity Tier 1.14 11 Statistical data is based on December 2012. Directive 2013/36/EU, Article 92. 13 Directive 2013/36/EU, Article 95; the opportunity 200% variable remuneration obliges the decision of member states. 14 Directive 2013/36/EU, Article 95. 12 Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements In order to establish sustainable long-term oriented risk management strategies, a minimum of 40% of variable allowances have to be deferred over a period of 35 years. In the case of high volume payments, at least 60% have to be deferred.15 The EBA has illustrated a multiyear example of fixed and variable upfront and deferred payments (EBA, 2012). For institutions that benefit from government intervention, Article 93 of the Directive 2013/36/EU imposes additional rules restricting variable remuneration policies. The Implementation of Remuneration Regulations in Germany In Germany, European remuneration standards are implemented via Regulation on the Supervisory Requirements for Remuneration Systems in Institutions (Verordnung über die aufsichtsrechtlichen Anforderungen an Vergütungssysteme von Instituten InstitutsVergV). As required by European law, German regulation fully covers the content defined in Directive 2013/36/EU. One noticeable difference appears in the structure. The German regulation is divided in general requirements and special requirements of major institutions.16 The division accounts for the heterogeneity of the German banking system, including a low number of major banks and a high portion of small- and medium-sized banks like savings banks, cooperative banks, or credit and special institutions. In § 17 of the German regulation major institutions are classified with respect to the size of the balance sheet amount, exceeding 15 billion Euros.17 Besides the size of an institution, the risk structure can also determine major banks. For example, if an institution exceeds 15 billion Euros and the risk structure is regarded to be low, an institution can be classified not to be major. Vice versa is true for banks which are below the level of 15 billion Euros, however, comprising a high risk structure. Each institution has to consider general remuneration rules like the relation between fixed and variable payments, the alignment of variable payments, and an institution’s strategy or organizational policy principles. Major institutions are required to fulfill more detailed regulatory standards. For all banks, variable remuneration has to be aligned with the success of an institution. Major banks are 15 Directive 2013/36/EU, Article 95. Translated paragraphs of the German remuneration standards rely on Wagner and Schulte (2014). 17 Three years average. 16 219 220 OLIVER KRUSE ET AL. additionally required to consider an individual’s qualitative as well as quantitative profit contributions. Further examples of requirements are the analysis of individual risk contribution profiles, the deference of variable payments, and the implementation of remuneration officials. Altogether, absolute implementation costs which are necessary to establish adequate remuneration systems are expected to be significantly higher for major banks.18 However, basic remuneration rules have to be fulfilled independently of the bank size. Although the German regulation accounts for the heterogeneity of its banking system, relative costs (related to the balance sheet total) could be significantly higher for smaller banks. Incentive-Compatibility of the European and German Regulation of Remuneration Systems In Table 1, we analyze whether the prerequisites of an incentivecompatible remuneration system are fulfilled for the European regulation as well as the German implementation by applying the features described in section “Prerequisites of an IncentiveCompatible Remuneration System.” Altogether, a high portion of prerequisites that are necessary for a successful and motivating working environment are fulfilled. Some arguments are open or limited, for example, justice between EU members and non-EU members or the compensation impact with respect to variable elements. Regarding the acceptance of managers or staff, new regulations might be unpopular although a high portion of prerequisites are fulfilled due to limited variable remuneration opportunities or implementation and operation costs. However, a high level of acceptance can be expected in society. Conclusion and Perspectives Implementing and operating remuneration standards causes agency costs leading to a reduction of social welfare. Compared to potential costs induced by government interventions, for example, in the case of an insolvency of a major institution, agency costs can be expected to be significantly lower. This argument is possibly the strongest 18 Regulation on the Supervisory Requirements for Remuneration Systems in Institutions (2013). Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements 221 Table 1: Analysis of the Prerequisites of an Incentive-Compatible Remuneration System of the EU Regulation and German Implementation. Requirements European Remuneration Regulation German Implementation Transparency Fulfilled: remuneration policy has to be published; significant banks have to deliver more detailed information Fulfilled: remuneration policy has to be published; major banks (e.g., > 15 billion Euros) have to deliver more detailed information Flexibility Limited: clear framework with national options Limited: clear framework by using national options, e.g., definition of major banks/exceptions for collective employees Compensation Impact Limited: the variable elements shall Limited: the variable elements shall not exceed 100% of fixed not exceed 100%/200% (national components (but national options) option if the institution is owned by shareholders or members) Efficiency Open: high costs for implementing and operating the system; labor costs could be reduced due to restricted variable payments Open: high costs for implementing and operating the system; labor costs could be reduced due to restricted variable payments Justice Fulfilled (inside EU): Fulfilled (inside EU and inside Germany): fixed remuneration should reflect fixed remuneration should reflect professional experience and professional experience and organizational responsibility; organizational responsibility; performance-related, variable remuneration (level playing field limited performance-related, variable remuneration (level inside EU); restrictions of playing field inside EU); variable payments are identical; restrictions of variable payments market orientation (level playing are identical; field inside EU) market orientation (level playing Open: EU jurisdictions versus nonfield inside EU) EU jurisdictions Open: Germany versus non-EU jurisdictions Individual and Fulfilled: variable remuneration Fulfilled: variable remuneration Team Practicability should be the result of individual should be the result of individual and the business unit assessment and the business unit assessment Acceptance Fulfilled: society Fulfilled: society Open: employees/management Open: employees/management supporting the acceptance of remuneration regulations in the society. However, the perspective of managers or staff could strongly differ from the perspective of the society. Only in the case of a perfect international level playing field, the prerequisite “justice” would be fulfilled contributing to the acceptance of remuneration 222 OLIVER KRUSE ET AL. regulation. Because of international diverging standards which contradicts level playing field, the acceptance of managers or staff can be expected to be low. Other arguments possibly reducing acceptance of managers or staff are relative implementation and operation costs (divided by bank size) which can be expected to strongly diverge with respect to bank size. Acceptance can be regarded to be highly important for a successful implementation of remuneration standards. Current survey experiences of the BaFin illustrate, that some institutions try to undermine regulatory requirements, for example, not fully defining risk takers or implementing asymmetric variable remuneration components (avoiding maluses).19 Michael Barnier (EU Commissioner) for example states that some institutions are investing big efforts avoiding regulatory remuneration standards.20 Altogether remuneration standards are an important step in the direction of a sustainable financial stability. However, achieving high levels of acceptance which significantly would contribute to the stability of the law will be a huge challenge in the near future. References Bebchuk, L. A., & Spamann, H. (2010). Regulating bankers´ pay. Georgetown Law Journal, 98, 247287. Börsenzeitung. (2014). Börsenzeitung, March 5, 2014. Botterweck, B., Jaeger, M., Steinbrecher, I., & Vergütungssysteme (2014). Prüfungskampagne: Qualitätsmängel bei allen Instituten. BaFin Journal, February, 89. Deutsche Bundesbank. (2013). Deutsche Bundesbank, Bankenstatistik, März 2013. Erdmann, U. (1991). Die Entlohnung von Führungskräften in Kreditinstituten. Frankfurt am Main, 1991. FSB. (2013). Financial Stability Board: Principles for an Effective Risk Appetite Framework. Consultative Document, 2013. Herring, F., Low, H.-P., William, A., & Slulte, W. (2014). Remuneration System, The implementation of national and European Rules in Banks and Investment Fund Companies. Frankfurt. IMF. (2008). International Monetary Fund: Global Financial Stability Report, Containing Systemic Risks and Restoring Financial Soundness, April 2008. Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial behavior, Agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 4, 305360. Kruse, O. (2001). Variable Vergütungssysteme in Banken eine Akzeptanzstrategie zur Gestaltung und Implementierung, 2001. 19 20 Botterweck, Jaeger, Steinbrecher, and Vergütungssysteme (2014). Börsenzeitung, March, 5, 2014 (author unknown). Reviewing Institution’s Remuneration Requirements Porter, L. W., & Lawler III, E. E. (1968). Managerial attitudes and performance. Homewood, IL: Irwin. Rinker, A. (1997). Anreizsysteme in kreditinstituten, Gestaltungsprinzipien und steuerungsimpulse aus controllingsicht. Frankfurt am Main: Knapp. Rosenstiehl, L. V. (1975). Die motivationale Grundlagen des Verhaltens in Organisationen, Leistung und Zufriedenheit. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. Staehle, W. H. (1999). Management, Eine verhaltenswissenschaftliche Perspektive. München: Vahlen. Wagner, O., & Schulte, M. (2014). Vergütungssysteme – die Umsetzung der nationalen und europäischen. Regelungen in Banken und Fondsgesellschaften. Verband der Auslandsbanken. 223 This page intentionally left blank CHAPTER 13 The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration Roberta Provasi and Patrizia Riva Introduction During the last 10 years the European Commission has outlined a framework for community action to improve company laws and corporate governance practices in the European Union, to enhance, as a consequence, the real economy, promoting efficiency and competitiveness of European companies worldwide as well as strengthening the shareholders’ rights and third parties protection. This review process, which started in 2003 with the “Action Plan for the Company Law Modernization and Corporate Governance Enhancing” has accelerated in recent years. It was the result of the global economic and financial crisis and of the careful consideration on the factors which contributed to its occurrence which followed. With regard to the problem of determining the remuneration of companies’ directors, the European Community has agreed with the approach pointing out that the problem originates mainly on conflicts of “principalagent.” These arise both: (a) within public companies with widespread shareholders, between executive directors (agent) and shareholders as a whole (principal); and (b) within companies controlled by a limited number of shareholders, between controlling shareholders (agent) and other shareholders (principals). 225 226 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA The Commission noticed that in recent years, on one hand there has been an increasing relevance of the variable part of directors’ remuneration (i.e., linked to performance and responsibilities), but on the other hand there has been an orientation to short-term remuneration policies with a detriment of the results obtained in the long term. For these reasons, since 2004, the Commission has repeatedly tried to address the matter with three recommendations (Commission Recommendation 2004/913/EC, 2005/162/EC, and 2009/385/EC) which addressed the following topics: (a) transparency regarding remuneration policies in general and remuneration of individual executive and non-executive directors in particular; (b) shareholder votes on remuneration reports; (c) embedding an independent remuneration committee and the provision of appropriate incentives to stimulate results and value creation in the long term. Nevertheless, in 2010 and already earlier in 2007, in Commission reports SEC (2007) 1022 and (2010) 285, the Commission had been able to see that certain Member States did not adequately address the issues related to remuneration. For this reason in 2010 with the “Green Paper on corporate governance of financial institutions” consultation, the Commission returned to the theme by asking and obtaining clear indication about the need to refine directors’ incentive structure, so as to encourage long-term results, sustainable for companies. Most observers, however, were opposed to the introduction of regulatory measures concerning the remuneration structure in listed companies, while others had favored the introduction of European rules to give greater transparency to the remuneration policies and to give shareholders a right to vote on these issues. As a result of this long debate, the Green Paper of the European Union in 2011 focused on two of the issues mentioned, namely: (a) making compulsory for companies the disclosures on remuneration policies adopted and on compensation attributed to executive and non-executive directors; (b) requiring the shareholders to vote on the remuneration policy. In 2012 a further consultation on the future of European company law was undertaken. The results of all these consultations led the Commission to publish, on December 12, 2012, the document “Action Plan: European company law and corporate governance a modern legal framework for more engaged shareholders and sustainable companies,” by The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration which the European Commission wanted to expose the future lines of action to be pursued both in the area of corporate governance of listed companies and in corporate law. The main lines of action set out in the above action plan were: (a) to strengthen transparency; (b) to involve shareholders, in particular to encourage members to an active participation in corporate governance through enhanced monitoring by shareholders on remuneration policies and on transactions with related parties. The European Commission recognized in particular the dangers of inadequate remuneration policies (too focused on short-term goals and not justified by the results achieved) and incentive structures in favor of directors that could lead to unjustified transfers of value in favor of the executive directors, with potential damage to the company, shareholders, and other stakeholders. For this reason, the European Commission expressed the view that policies on remuneration must be able to create long-term value, provide welfare for corporations and should therefore be based on a real connection between remuneration and achievements. In addition, a more efficient supervision by shareholders on remuneration policies adopted by the listed companies should be required as it could be part of the solution to the problem. Therefore, the need to strengthen the transparency of remuneration policies and individual remuneration accorded to managers (principle of “say on pay”), as well as to recognize to shareholders a right to vote (to be established if binding on the directors or if purely consultative) regarding the remuneration policy adopted by the company as described in the remuneration report, which sets out the way in which this policy has been implemented in the previous year, emerged. With this initiative, the Commission also intended to remedy the problem of inconsistency between the disciplines of individual Member States relating to the right to vote on remuneration policy and/or the remuneration report, also in order to ensure the comparability of the information disclosed to the market by the companies in the different EU states. On April 9, 2014, the European Commission published the Proposal for a Directive amending Directive 2007/36/EC as regards the encouragement of long-term shareholder and Directive 2013/34/ EU regarding certain report elements on corporate governance. The primary goal of the proposed revision of the Directive was to contribute to the long-term sustainability of the EU companies, creating favorable conditions for shareholders and to improve the crossborder voting rights by increasing the efficiency of the equity investment chain in order to contribute to the growth, jobs creation and 227 228 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA competitiveness in the EU. In particular, regarding the remuneration of directors, since in the current framework several weaknesses were found, the proposal aims to strengthen the correlation between directors’ remuneration and results, by strengthening shareholders’ monitoring. The document did not regulate the remuneration level, which is left to the decision of the companies and their shareholders. Articles 9bis and 9ter required listed companies to disclose detailed and easily accessible information regarding the remuneration policy and individual remuneration of directors and Article 9ter authorizes the Commission to prescribe a standard of presentation of some of this information by an implementing act. As stated in the proposal, all the benefits of the directors in any form must be considered in the remuneration policy and included in the report. These rules give to shareholders the right to approve the remuneration policy and to vote on the report on remuneration. Therefore, the report favors the exercise of shareholders’ rights and ensures the liability of directors. Literature Review Directors’ remuneration has been considered one of the central issues in the debate on the stability of financial markets as it concerns not only large financial institutions but all the companies which have recognized corporate governance relevance (Baur, 2008; Bebchuck & Fried, 2004; Bender, 2004; Fernandez, 2003; Ferrarini, Moloney, & Vespro, 2003). The different approaches developed in literature share some basic principles: 1. The principle of fair and reasonable remuneration. Compensation must be adequate to attract and retain top executives, but at the same time it needs to be defined in order to safeguard the interests of shareholders and stakeholders. Interests of managers may not be consistent with those of the company. Managers can pursue their own interests to the detriment of others, committing the company in highly risky projects. This may be to raise their own power and possibly the value of their options in the short term. 2. The principle of transparency as an essential tool to monitor and neutralize the bad tendencies of compensation designers who often try to make the amount of part of the remuneration not clearly intelligible (the so-called camouflage mechanism). In listed companies the two principles are particularly relevant for executives (directors and managers) for which the remuneration The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration system is variable and linked to the performance (especially with stock option plans) (Santosuosso, 2010). Best practices and regulatory codes in the different systems have provided rules to ensure greater transparency and increasingly precise mechanisms (such as annual remuneration reports). In addition, some rules have been introduced to better define and align the interests of managers with those of shareholders and stakeholders enriching and qualifying the bargaining process (internal and external to the company) to get free and balanced negotiations and a higher rate of agreements aligned to market conditions (“arm’s length” bargaining). Most effective incentive plans have the characteristic that a significant part of the remuneration is related to the overall corporate performance (in terms of profitability for the shareholderbondholder) with a focus on the medium and long term. Short-term goals involve the risk of management myopia which drive to maximize current results reducing or even postponing policies (especially investment) that contribute to the going concern and success of the company over time (Core, Guay, & Larcker, 2003). The basic requirement is to provide shareholders and independent directors, as well as non-executive directors, with greater powers. This is possible by: (i) introducing rules to enhance the independence of the board increasing the number of independent directors and appointing a nomination committee and a remuneration committee, composed of non-executive and independent directors with powers of recommendations, proposals, and advice; (ii) requiring independent consultants to work out critical details of remuneration agreements; and (iii) asking for a shareholders’ meeting vote on executive relevant remuneration plans (Bhagat & Black, 1999). In many jurisdictions all these aspects are directly regulated by the law so that the economic rule is elevated to a legal provision. French Law (L.225-42-1, co.2, of the Code de Commerce) prohibits remuneration, for listed companies, not related to performance. German law (87-1 AktG) requires that the supervisory board sets the total remuneration of the management board at an “appropriate” level, based also on performance and that the criteria for determining the fairness are linked to the tasks of each member of the board and benchmark considerations valuing the choices made by similar companies (Baums, 2001); it is not allowed to exceed the established extent except for specific reasons. In Italy negotiation takes place primarily between directors and shareholders: as a general rule remuneration is defined when directors are appointed or by a shareholders’ meeting (art. 2389, paragraph 1, Civil Code). 229 230 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA Despite the existence of regulatory frameworks, distorting the effects of executive top management behavior persist and operations performed happen to affect the value and the stock prices of the company or its subsidiaries or parent. The literature is unanimous in considering this as being due to: (a) the mismatch between the executive directors’ interests and those of the stakeholders; (b) the provision of plans acknowledging compensation disproportionately in favor of managers; and (c) the low efficiency of both the agreement mechanisms and the execution monitoring (Melis, Carta, & Gaia, 2008). In models based on performance (equity-based pay models) the selection of the performance indicator is complex and executive directors may cooperate to structure the remuneration components to their advantage, suggesting they are in the condition to manipulate indicators (Cheffins, 2003). Similarly, in models based on simple options (share-option-based pay) managers influencing the structuring step can achieve greater benefits without any link to the company performance (Chance, Kumar, & Todd, 2000). Limits are also related to the governance “dysfunction.” The board of directors even with the presence of independent directors is sometimes almost inactive and in awe of the executive directors. The reasons can be extremely varied, economic or not, from solidarity dynamics (collegiality, teamwork, desire to avoid conflict, sometimes friendship and loyalty) to real conflicts of interest, related to the influence that executives may have on the appointment of directors and on the renewal of their assignment (Brick, Palmon, & Wald, 2006). Many studies have aimed at identifying reforms to better link compensation to performance and especially to try to strengthen the negotiating power of the shareholders to the power of the directors in order to balance the interests of different stakeholders involved. In particular, the American doctrine suggested (Ferrarini, 2005): • to use share prices as the main performance index, neutralizing market effects and sector influence and not recognizing special bonuses or privileges for non-measurable effects of special operations (such as company acquisitions); • to reduce the so-called “windfalls” in equity-based plans, considering and neutralizing results obtained by chance and which cannot be considered as due to managers’ good performance; • to keep all incentive mechanisms implemented by the company to create value, but modifying the payment timing (separating the assignment step from the payment step and distributing the second over a longer period of time), and avoiding all sort of “soft landing” mechanisms in case of management failures (the so-called golden parachutes); The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration • to ensure accountability and transparency, fairly reporting any remuneration component (including deferred wages, retirement fund and consulting, stock option plans) in order to avoid any possible remuneration camouflage. European Approach to the Regulation of Directors’ Remuneration Although the phenomenon in Europe has not reached the proportions observed in the United States, due to the different structure of share ownership of the European companies, in recent decades there has been an increasing use of different remuneration forms to motivate directors (Becht, Bolton, & Roell, 2002). The issue was therefore subsequently been taken into consideration as part of the “action plan” drawn up by the European Commission in order to define the priorities of the harmonization process of European company law (see The Communication from the Commission “Modernizing company Law and corporate governance in the European Union. A plan to move forward,” May 21, 2003, Com (284) 2003 final) (COM, 2004). In particular, in this plan, the Commission expressed the intention to start a process of homogenization of the various national legal provisions concerning the remuneration of listed company directors in regulated European markets. The Commission decided to opt in the first phase for the issuance of a recommendation, which is an act devoid of mandatory value for Member States but indicating the legislative policy goals that the Commission intends to promote and possibly pursue with ad hoc legislative measures, where possible by a spontaneous adaptation by member countries. The measure provided by the “action plan” was concretely translated into two separate recommendations: (a) the first Recommendation, approved on December 14, 2004 (Recommendation 2004/913/EC, published in the Official Journal of the European Union of December 29, 2004. 153), which specifically regulated the remuneration of listed company directors in regulated European markets; (b) the second Recommendation, adopted on February 15, 2005 (Recommendation 2005/162/EC, published in the Official Journal of the European Union of February 25, 2005), which regulated the role that “independent directors” should play in the corporate governance of listed companies. 231 232 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA RECOMMENDATION 2004/913/EC The Community Recommendation 913/2004 is based on some statements already included in the previous 2003 document. It gives a range of proposals to strengthen shareholders’ rights and modernize the boards of directors. It provides for an initiative aimed at encouraging an appropriate regulatory regime for directors’ remuneration in the Member States. It makes it clear that new regulation is necessary to avoid conflicts of interest and hence to implement appropriate governance controls, based on adequate information rights. Form, structure, and level of directors’ remuneration are matters falling within the competence of companies and their shareholders, but it is also one of the key areas where executive directors may have a conflict of interest. It is important that listed companies display appropriate transparency in dealing with investors, so as to enable them to express their views. In brief, the EC Recommendation is exclusively referred to the directors’ remuneration of listed companies in regulated European markets. It invites the States to introduce by June 30, 2006: (1) a combined set of disclosure obligations intended to increase transparency for market and for shareholders especially with regard to the directors’ remuneration, possibly extending such measures to other components of the administration not part of the board, such as the general manager; (2) a specific commitment with regard to the remuneration through equity incentives. More specifically, according to the first set of provisions, listed companies in regulated markets should draw up and publish (also on the website) on an annual basis a remuneration statement to be included in the annual report or separately, in which should expose the directors’ remuneration policy that the company intends to follow in the next year and in subsequent years. The structure and consistency of the different remuneration components of individual directors (fixed fees, variable compensation in the form of bonuses, or non-cash remuneration and even amounts paid by the company to administrators for other activities different from the one covered by the contract) should be disclosed. The information should be given also related to assignments carried out within the group to which the company belongs. The Recommendation then invites Member States to adopt specific legislative provisions to establish that, as already experienced in regulated US markets, share-based remuneration may be adopted only after the shareholders’ annual general meetings vote. The Commission suggests that the shareholders’ approval should be imposed for each additional director’s long-term incentives. The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration The document is structured into four sections and the main guidelines are the following: Sections I Section Scope and definition II Section Remuneration policy III Section Remuneration of individual directors IV Section Share-based remuneration Guidelines Transparency and accountability generate investor confidence Harmonized regulation contributes to eliminate unequal treatment Shareholders need a clear vision of the remuneration policy Remuneration policy should be part of the agenda of the annual general meeting giving shareholders an effective chance to express their views and an opportunity to debate Remuneration policy will be better controlled if voted on by the shareholders; the vote could be advisory Disclosure of individual directors’ remuneration is important to appreciate in the light of the overall performance of the company Variable remuneration schemes (in shares, share options, or any other right to acquire shares) should be subject to the prior approval of the general meeting The following paragraphs summarize the main contents of each section and profile the ways guidelines are expected to be implemented by companies at the three different levels of disclosure: the general, the individual, and the specific situation of share-based remuneration. REMUNERATION POLICY Disclosure is required. Companies have to draw up a special report of the remuneration policy named a remuneration statement. It may be included in the annual report or in the notes to the annual accounts of the company and posted on the website. It must focus on policies for the following years and policies implemented in the previous year with particular emphasis on changes that have occurred. The report must contain some main information: 1. Relative importance of the variable and non-variable components of the remuneration. 233 234 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA 2. Performance criteria on which variable components of the remuneration are based. 3. Linkage between remuneration and performance. 4. Main parameters and rationale for annual bonus scheme and non-cash benefits. 5. Main characteristics of supplementary pensions or early retirement schemes. 6. Main terms of the contracts of executive directors, especially with regard to duration, applicable notice periods, and provisions for termination payments. 7. Information on the preparatory and decision-making process used for determining the formulation of remuneration policies, such as the composition of the Remuneration Committee, the role of external consultants whose services have been used in determination of the remuneration policy, and the role of the shareholders’ annual general meeting. The EC Recommendation points out the relevance of shareholders’ vote on directors’ remuneration: the topic must be on the agenda of the shareholders’ annual general meeting. The vote may be mandatory or advisory and member state may provide minimum quorum (at least 25% of those present or represented). REMUNERATION OF INDIVIDUAL DIRECTORS The individual remuneration and other benefits should be the disclosed in the annual accounts or in the notes to the annual accounts or in the remuneration report. The main information which should be presented is: • total amount of salary paid or due in the year; • remuneration and advantages received from any undertaking belonging to the same group; • remuneration paid in the form of profit sharing or bonus and the reasons for such compensation; • additional remuneration for special services outside the scope of usual functions of a director; • compensation paid to or receivable in connection with the activity termination during that financial year; • total estimated value of non-cash benefits; • the number of share options offered or shares granted by the company during the relevant financial year and their conditions of application; • the number of share options exercised during the relevant financial year and the price or the value in the share incentive scheme at the end of the financial year; The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration • the number of options unexercised and the main conditions for the exercise of the rights; • any change in the terms and conditions of existing share options occurring during the financial year; • any change in the benefits accrue mechanism and retirement fund contributions. SHARE-BASED REMUNERATION All share-based remuneration mechanisms must be approved during the shareholders’ annual general meeting. The approval relates to: • grant of the share-based schemes, including share options, to directors; • determination of their maximum number and main conditions of the granting; • terms within which options can be exercised; • conditions for any change in the exercise price options; • any other incentive mechanism for which directors are eligible. The annual general meeting should set the deadline within which the body responsible for directors’ remuneration may award these types of compensation to individual directors. It is also required in the assembly approval in the case of a discounted option arrangement under which any rights are granted to subscribe to shares at a price lower than the market value of the share on the date when the price was determined or is lower than the average of market values over a number of days preceding it. Before the general assembly meeting shareholders must be adequately forewarned about the contents of the stock option plan and incentive. The costs of these operations must be disclosed. Similar information must be available on the company’s web. RECOMMENDATION 2005/162/EC A second Recommendation was approved on February 15, 2005 and, even though it concerns the role of non-executive or supervisory directors in the corporate governance of listed companies, it is also closely related to the remuneration topic. It gives relevant suggestions about the organizational process that listed companies should follow to determine directors’ remunerations. The presence of independent representatives on the board, capable of challenging the decisions of management, is widely considered as a means of protecting the interests of shareholders and other stakeholders. In companies with a dispersed ownership, the primary concern is how to make managers accountable to weak 235 236 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA shareholders. In companies with controlling shareholders, the focus is more on how to make sure that the company will be run in a way that sufficiently takes into account the interests of minority shareholders. Ensuring adequate protection for third parties is relevant in both cases. Whatever the formal board structure of a company, the management function should therefore be subject to an effective and sufficiently independent supervisory function. Independence should be understood as the absence of any material conflict of interest. The supervisory role of non-executive or supervisory directors is commonly perceived as crucial in three areas, where the potential for conflict of interest of management is particularly high, especially when such matters are not a direct responsibility for shareholders: nomination of directors, remuneration of directors, and audit. It is therefore appropriate to foster the role of non-executive or supervisory directors in these areas and to encourage the creation within the (supervisory) board of committees responsible respectively for nomination, remuneration, and audit. Member States are invited to introduce legislation that would require the establishment of the three committees within the board of directors (or the supervisory board in the dual system). As a general rule, therefore, the nomination, remuneration, and audit committees should make recommendations aimed at preparing the decisions to be taken by the board. The primary purpose of the committees should be to increase the efficiency of the board by making sure that decisions are based on due consideration, and to help organize its work with a view to ensuring that the decisions it takes are free of material conflicts of interest. The creation of the committees is not intended, in principle, to remove the matters considered from the purview of the board itself, which remains fully responsible for the decisions taken in its field of competence. With regard to the remuneration committee, the Commission suggests (in the guidelines provided in Annex I) that it should be composed exclusively of non-executive directors who are not involved in the daily management of the company and that at least a majority of its members should be independent. Independence characteristics are highlighted in the same recommendation and guidelines contained in Annex II. The Committee makes proposals, for the approval of the board, on the remuneration policy for executive or managing directors. Such a policy should address all forms of compensation, including in particular the fixed remuneration, performance-related remuneration schemes, pension arrangements, and termination payments. Proposals related to performance-related remuneration schemes should be accompanied with recommendations on the related objectives and evaluation criteria, with a view to properly aligning the pay of executive or managing directors with the long-term interests of the shareholders and the objectives set by The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration the board for the company. The committee should make proposals to the board on the individual remuneration to be attributed to executive or managing directors, ensuring that they are consistent with the remuneration policy adopted by the company and the evaluation of the performance of the directors concerned. In doing so, the committee should be properly informed as to the total compensation obtained by the directors from other companies affiliated to the group. It is also asked to make proposals to the board on suitable forms of contract for executive or managing directors and to assist it in overseeing the process whereby the company complies with existing provisions regarding disclosure of remunerationrelated items (in particular the remuneration policy applied and the individual remuneration attributed to directors). Special attention has to be given to the structure of remuneration for senior management monitoring both the level and the structure. And finally with respect to stock options and other share-based incentives which may be granted to directors, managers, or other employees, the committee should debate the general policies, review information provided in the annual report and to the shareholders meeting and make proposals concerning special choices about granting options. The Recommendation specifies that the remuneration committee should be able to avail itself of consultants, with a view to obtaining the necessary information on market standards for remuneration systems. The committee selects the consultants, appoints them, and should receive appropriate funding from the company to this effect. Additional EU Interventions In March 2009 the Commission with the Communication for the Spring European Council, Driving European recovery provided strategic guidelines to regulate and promote the best practices in implementing the two previous Recommendations (2004/913/EC and 2005/162/EC) and announced what would have been the further steps to be taken. Among these, special attention was given to the remuneration of financial sector directors which resulted in London G20 commitments. The Commission presented its plan to restore and maintain a stable and reliable financial system. In particular, the Communication announced that a new Recommendation on remuneration in the financial services sector would be presented in order to improve risk management in financial firms and align pay incentives with sustainable performance. The 30th April 2009 the “EU Commission Recommendation on remuneration policies in the financial services sector” was delivered. It integrates the previous recommendations and contains some clarification agreed to give greater consistency to the principles set out 237 238 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA with regard to remuneration policies orienting the containment of financial risk and was therefore addressed to the categories that carry out activities with major impacts on business risk. The document clearly sets out that excessive risk-taking in the financial services industry, and in particular in banks and investment firms, has contributed to the failure of financial undertakings and to systemic problems in Member States and globally. These problems have spread to the rest of the economy and led to high costs for society. Whilst not the main cause of the financial crisis that unfolded in 2007 and 2008, there is a widespread consensus that inappropriate remuneration practices in the financial services industry also induced excessive risk-taking and thus contributed to significant losses of major financial undertakings. Remuneration practices in a large part of the financial services industry have been running counter to effective and sound risk management. These practices tended to reward short-term profit and gave staff incentives to pursue unduly risky activities which provided higher income in the short term while exposing financial undertakings to higher potential losses in the longer term. Creating appropriate incentives within the remuneration system itself should reduce the burden on risk management and increase the likelihood that these systems become effective. Therefore, there is a need to establish principles on sound remuneration policies. Again, in the same period (April, 2009), the Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS) published a set of “Highlevel Principles for Remuneration Policies (Rem. HLP)”; the principles were intended to assist in remedying unsound remuneration policies. Whilst institutions’ remuneration policies were not the direct cause of this crisis, their drawbacks, nonetheless, contributed to its gravity and scale. It was generally recognized that excessive remuneration in the financial sector fueled a risk appetite that was disproportionate to the loss-absorption capacity of institutions and of the financial sector as a whole. On July 13, 2009 the European Commission published a revision proposal of Directive 2006/48/EC and 2006/49/EC on capital requirements for credit institutions and investment firms (the Capital Requirements Directive, or “CRD”). The presentation of the proposal had been announced in the April 30, 2009 Communication, to complement the Commission’s recommendations on remuneration policies in the financial services industry and on the directors’ remuneration of listed companies. With the proposal adoption the Commission set the goal of: (a) make it mandatory for banks and investment firms to adopt remuneration policies that should be measured as a function of proper risk management of the financial institution and be effectively aligned with the long-term interests of the entities; The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration (b) consider remuneration policies and their relationship with risk management subject to the supervision of the Authorities and provide the necessary tools to monitor and punish those who adopt remuneration policies that encourage excessive risk-taking. In particular, the Recommendation of April 30, 2009 completes the previous legislation and strengthens the remuneration policies with regard to the following aspects: (a) Principles and scope of application The proposal applies to banks and investment firms authorized under Directive 2004/39/EC 8, having their legal head office or central administration in a Member State. As stipulated in the Recommendation for Financial Institutions, the principles on remuneration policy should be applied both by the parent company at the group level, both on individual companies within the group, including those established in offshore financial centers; moreover, Member States should ensure that branches of financial companies resident in a third country and operating in one Member State are subject to similar principles to those applicable to financial companies residing in the EU. (b) Structure and remuneration The remuneration should be structured in order to ensure an appropriate balance between fixed and variable parts. The fixed part must represent a sufficiently high proportion of total remuneration, such as to pursue a flexible policy on incentives and, where appropriate, not to pay any bonuses. Recommendation for Financial Institutions provides: ○ the variable component should not exceed a fixed preconceived maximum amount; ○ it should enable firms to withhold bonuses in case of circumstances of economic deterioration; ○ the adoption of negotiating forecasts that enable companies to ask their employees to refund, in whole or in part, the bonus paid on the basis of data subsequently proved “manifestly errors.” In case of a significant bonus amount, payment of the prominent part of the same should be deferred for an appropriate period of time and be subject to the achievement of further performance targets in the medium to long term. According to the Recommendation for Financial Institutions, the bonus amount to be deferred should be given in relation to the total bonus amount in turn, compared to the total remuneration of the beneficiary. The Recommendation for Financial Institutions also specifies that the payment of the deferred bonus part should: consider the risks associated with the 239 240 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA achievement of results in which the bonus is tied and could be liquidated in the form of shares, options, or other financial instruments. (c) Parameters used for bonus calculation The remuneration related to the achievement of performance targets should be calculated on the basis of results combination obtained from the single unit concerned, the bank, or investment firm as a whole. In identifying the parameters to be used to assess individual performance, the Recommendation for Financial Institutions and the Principles suggest using, in addition to financial criteria, also non-financial and/or qualitative, such as the level of compliance with the rules and internal procedures, criteria; this is the level of customer satisfaction. The current and future risks, the cost of capital used and liquidity related to the results achievement (and to the actual payment of bonuses) should also be considered in bonus calculation. These results should be evaluated over a period of years in order to ensure that the assessment process is based on the longterm results of the company. For this purpose, the Proposal, as far as the Recommendation for Financial Institutions, suggests an evaluation period of between 3 and 5 years. (d) Golden parachute The amounts allocated in case of early dissolution of an employment contract, the so-called golden parachute, must reward goals achieved by employees during the employment period and not be seen as “reward for failure.” (e) Decision-making and governance The remuneration policy must be drawn up and approved by the board of directors (supervisory), which is responsible for the application of its principles. Recommendation for Financial Institutions suggests that, in the determination of the remuneration policy, the control authorities, the human resources department, and external experts should be involved. In this sense, companies should make sure that the boards of directors’ members, the remuneration committee’ and staff participating in the remuneration policy draft, have the “necessary skills” and are independent from the business units to which they are called upon to pronounce. The implementation of the remuneration policy should be subject (at least annually) to a central and independent internal review. As specified in the Recommendation for Financial Institutions, the staff involved in the monitoring process should be independent from the controls operating units and should be adequately paid (independently from the results achieved from the company subject to control). The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration (f) Transparency requirements and disclosures profile The general principles of the remuneration policy should be formalized and accessible to all staff to which they apply. Staff should be informed in advance about the criteria that will be used to determine their remuneration. The evaluation process should be well documented and made available. Staff must also receive information regarding: a. the decision-making process used for determining the remuneration policy, including, where appropriate, information on the composition and remuneration committee mandate, the external consultants and the role played by all parties involved; b. the relationship between remuneration and performance; c. the methods used for the results evaluation and the risk adjustment; d. the criteria for performance evaluation on the basis of which shares allocation, options or remuneration variable components are determined; e. the main parameters and the reasons related to the granting of any other bonus. (g) Impact on the supervisory authorities powers Remuneration policies are under the monitoring of the supervisory authorities under the CRD. In order to ensure converging political control, CEBS should ensure on an ongoing basis the guideline arrangements, including on remuneration. To the supervisory authorities, also in the remuneration matters, should be granted the power to adopt: restrictive measures, both qualitative (e.g., may require banks and investment firms to reduce the risk inherent to their activities, products marketed by them, as well as in remuneration systems) and quantitative (e.g., they could oblige some parties to hold more of their own funds to cover these risks); and/or financial and non-financial sanctions. The European Parliament subsequently gave its opinion on remuneration of listed companies and remuneration policies in the financial services with the resolution of July 7, 2010. It is related to the Commission Recommendation premise of April 30, 2009 and with other provisions and proposals of International organization. The resolution, structured in 45 sections, highlights the importance of the following issues: (a) an effective remuneration governance that considers the opportunity of establishing a remuneration committee for financial institutions and listed companies, which should be independent, defines the remuneration policies, responds to shareholders and 241 242 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA supervisors, and works closely with the company risk committee for the evaluation of the incentives provided by the remuneration system; (b) an effective conformity between remuneration and prudent risk because remuneration must be in proportion to the size, organization, and complexity of the company as well as appropriate to all risk categories and the risks timeline; (c) a correct balance between fixed and variable remuneration, it is proposed that the variable remuneration is paid only if it is sustainable according to the financial situation, which is deferred over a period considered appropriate (reasonable) and that it should also be paid by other non-cash instruments; (d) an effective prudential supervision and involvement of the other parties involved, it is necessary that companies disclose clear, comprehensive and timely information about the remuneration policies adopted. The European Commission has undertaken an important path for the modernization of company law and enhancing corporate governance thanks to the publication of the Green Paper on corporate governance in financial institutions and remuneration policies adopted in June 2010. In this first Paper the Commission had already announced plans to launch a wider reflection on the corporate governance of all listed companies. After only a year, the Commission on April 5, 2011 published a second Green Paper on the EU framework for corporate governance through which a consultation was launched aimed at identifying ways to improve and modernize the system of corporate governance of European listed companies. It was followed by a consultation process, which ended on July 22, 2011. The results were “summarized” in a Feedback Statement dated November 15, 2011. Within the Green Paper, the European Commission has fundamentally identified three main subjects on which to start the consultation: (a) the board; (b) the shareholders; (c) the comply or explain basis. In particular, with reference to the remuneration policy the most participants to the consultation were in favor of the proposal to introduce an obligation to disclose information about the remuneration paid by the company to its managers, in order to balance the different national rules and, in this way, make it comparable to information provided by the companies of different Member States. Many of the above considerations are subsequently integrated in Directive 2010/76/EC of November 24, 2010 amending Directives 2006/48/EC and 2006/49/EC. In particular, this Directive accentuated that the inadequate remuneration structures of some financial institutions contributed to the bankruptcy of certain financial institutions and caused systemic problems in the United States The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration and globally. To oppose the potentially disadvantageous effects of designed remuneration structures remuneration policies that are consistent with the effective risk management should be introduced. A further consultation on the future of European company law was undertaken and brought on December 12, 2012 to the publication of the new “Action Plan: European company law and corporate governance a modern legal framework to make shareholders more engaged and sustainable companies.” The action plan identifies three main lines of action: (a) Increasing transparency with regard to listed companies and institutional investors. For this purpose, the Commission proposes the adoption of compulsory measures to: ○ strengthen the commitment of information on the policies adopted, to ensure diversity within the board and on the evaluation of non-financial risks through the Accounting Directives; ○ allow shareholder identification by the company at the European level; ○ introduce disciplinary reporting obligations about voting policies and activism of institutional investors, and the voting report. (b) Enhancing the active role of shareholders. For this purpose, the Commission proposes to amend shareholders’ rights to: ○ strengthen the control of the shareholders on the directors’ remuneration, providing the obligation of an assembly vote on remuneration policy and on the report that explains how the policy was implemented and the remuneration of individual directors; ○ strengthen the oversight of transactions with related parties; ○ introduce rules on the transparency of the advisors’ activity and conflicts of interest. (c) Supporting the growth and competitiveness of listed and unlisted companies. The Commission aims to take the necessary measures to promote the freedom of the company and to create a legal framework for the creation of cross-border transactions. On June 26, 2013, the Parliament and the Council issued the Directive 2013/36/EU amending the previous Directive 2002/ 49/2002 and withdrawing Directives 2006/48/EC and 2006/ 49/EC. Directive 2013/36/EU (CRD IV) gives large space to the remuneration policies of credit institutions and supervision over them. The Directive goal is to encourage remuneration policies that are consistent with effective risk management. In 243 244 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA conclusion it is advisable that institutions specify clearly the remuneration policies that they are aligned with, the risk propensity, risk values, and long-term interests of the institution. In determining the remuneration policy it should be considered as the fixed and the variable components represented by monetary components when they are non-monetary. To avoid excessive risk-taking a maximum ratio between fixed and total variable remuneration should be set. The provisions on remuneration should be reviewed periodically to ensure prudential containment of financial stability and so as not to threaten the shareholders’ rights. In 2014 the Commission adopted further measures to improve the corporate governance of listed companies; in particular, on April 9, 2014 the proposal for the revision of the Directive 2007/36/EC on the shareholders’ rights was published. With reference to the remuneration policies, for the first time at a European level, it introduced the voting rights of shareholders on remuneration. The proposals commit companies to publish transparent information, which is comparable and comprehensive, on their remuneration policies and implementing procedures. According to the European approach, no constraint in relation to the maximum amount of wages is expected, but each company is required to submit its remuneration policy to the binding vote of shareholders, which should, however, set a ceiling on the directors’ remuneration. The company is also expected to disclose the wages and working conditions of its employees, giving attention to the ratio of employees’ salariesdirectors’ remuneration and discussing the long-term sustainability of the company remuneration policies in the context of the general company strategy. Evidence on the Actual Compliance of the Italian Remuneration Reports to the CG Code In Italy, the procedure for the implementation of European Directives on listed companies directors’ remuneration began on December 22, 2010 with the approval by the Council of Ministers of the Legislative Decree 259/2010. It implemented the recommendations of the European Community 2004/913 and 2009/385 and has been enforced since 2012. In particular, the decree introduced art. 123ter TUIF which provides the publication on the company The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration website of the report on remuneration policies and on the compensation at least 21 days before the shareholders’ meeting. In 2011 the Corporate Governance Committee was established (hereinafter also the “Committee”), as result of an agreement between the promoters of the Corporate Governance Code (Borsa Italiana, Abi, Ania, Assogestioni, Assonime, and Confindustria). The aim of the Committee was to ensure a continuous and structured process for both the implementation and the monitoring of the best practices adopted by Italian listed companies (Riva and Provasi, 2015). Among the other issues, the Committee controls the implementation of art.6 of the Corporate Governance Code which deals with the remuneration issue, providing some recommendations, such as, for example, the definition of a variable component of the remuneration of executive directors (principle 6.P.2), the provision of a cap to the variable component of remuneration packages (criterion 6.C.1, let. b), as well as the recommendation concerning indemnities eventually set out by the issuer in case of early termination or non-renewal of directors (criterion 6.C.1, let. f). The Remuneration Report should provide at least information required by Consob in the Scheme no. 7-bis, Annex 3A of the Issuer Regulation which provides a scheme about the information to be provided in the Remuneration Report. That scheme requires information to be provided, on an individual basis, in case of companies of “non -small” size, as defined by Consob Regulation no. 17221/2010, also for key management personnel in case their “total compensation (as a result of monetary remuneration and that one based on financial instruments, including also those received by subsidiaries and affiliated) exceeds the highest total compensation” paid to “members of the administrative or control corporate bodies or general managers.” This happens rarely and it is generally related to “exit situations,” when a subject hierarchically subordinate receives exceptionally a total remuneration which is higher than that paid to the top management of the company. The Remuneration Report is an extensive report, which provides a lot of information, both ex ante, on the policy adopted by the company, and ex-post, on the effectively paid remuneration. In December 2014, Assonime published the results of its annual survey about the compliance with the Italian corporate governance code (Italian Corporate Governance Committee, 2014). The 2014 analysis covers 230 Italian companies, listed on the Italian Stock Exchange on December 31, 2013, whose Reports were available as of July 15, 2014: the survey covers substantially the whole stock list (Assonime, 2015). It includes two monographic parts. The first one analyzes as in the previous year the remuneration of directors and statutory auditors, while the second focuses on the application of the complyor-explain principle. The part dealing with remuneration of directors and statutory auditors is based on information drawn from the 245 246 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA Remuneration Reports, which are made up of two sections: a first section, subject to a non-binding vote of the Annual General Meeting (AGM), describes the company remuneration policy as well as the procedures used for the adoption and the implementation of this policy. The second section provides information on the remuneration actually paid to directors, statutory auditors, and general managers (as well as, on an aggregated basis, the remuneration of the key management personnel), distinguishing between remunerations paid by the company and those paid by subsidiaries or affiliated companies. With specific reference to the “Remuneration Reports,” even though there are still areas for improvement, information made available is substantial and significant. The first section of the Report provides information on the remuneration policy and the governance procedures. The policy may have a different level of detail and specification depending on the company and on the specific topic. In particular, not all companies have expressed a precise orientation with respect to each point provided in the regulatory scheme. A number of companies either communicate not to have made specific provisions relating to a specific point or state that the board “may” decide on a case-by-case basis. 1. Using benchmarks The Scheme 7-bis of the Annex 3A to the Issuers Regulation (the so-called Consob Scheme) requires issuers to provide, in the first section of their Remuneration Reports, whether the remuneration policy has been defined also with reference to the policies of other issuers and, if so, how this benchmark has been selected. A total of 177 companies disclosed this information (i.e., 77% of the aggregate). Among those providing this kind of information, 68 companies (i.e., 30% of the aggregate) also provide information with respect to the criteria used to identify the benchmark companies (peers): companies considered as basis for comparison when fixing Remunerations. Peer identification is instead quite uncommon: the name of the benchmark has been disclosed by only 13 companies (six in 2013), that is, 6% of the aggregate. 2. Consistency with the remuneration policy The Consob Scheme requires issuers to provide, in the second section of their Remuneration Reports, an adequate representation of each item of the remuneration table, underlining the consistency with the policy of reference. The Remuneration Reports were analyzed looking for explicit information about the consistency of remunerations paid in 2013 and the policy “of reference,” which is, usually, the remuneration policy The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration approved by the Annual General Meeting (AGM) of the same year. The AGM vote is, as already mentioned, an advisory vote: the exceptions are companies in the financial sector, where the AGM should “approve” the remuneration policy. Information on this point has been provided by a small number of issuers: 74 companies, that is, 32% of the aggregate (markedly increased from 21% in 2013). 3. Policy changes The Consob Scheme requires issuers to provide, in the first section of their Remuneration Reports, the objectives pursued with the adopted remuneration policy, its principles and eventual changes to the policy compared to the previous year. In 38 cases (i.e., 17% of the aggregate, decreasing from 22% in 2013) Reports explicitly disclose that the remuneration policy has been changed with respect to the previous year. The reduction is stronger among larger companies (from 34% to 19% of the aggregate among FTSE Mib) and, in particular, in the financial sector (from 44% to 17% of the aggregate). 4. Fixed and variable remuneration The Code recommends that a significant part of the remuneration of managing directors and key management personnel is linked to the achievement of specific performance objectives, including non-economical objectives, set out in advance and consistent with the remuneration policy’s guidelines. The existence of a variable remuneration linked to business results is disclosed by 175 companies (i.e., 76% of cases: the figure is slightly increased from 2013, when the percentage was 74%). The frequency of such disclosure increases according to the company’s size (94% in FTSE Mib, 88% in Mid Cap, 71% in Small Cap). The existence of a relevant number of companies (mediumsmall) where no director receives a variable remuneration may be surprising. 5. Parameters The Code makes various recommendations regarding the structure of the variable component. Inter alia, it is provided that: (a) the fixed component and the variable component should be properly balanced; (b) a ceiling should be set for the variable component; (c) performance goals should be predetermined, measurable and linked to the creation of value for shareholders over the mediumlong run; (d) the payment of a significant portion of the variable remuneration should be deferred for an appropriate period of time; and (e) compensations provided for early termination should not exceed a 247 248 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA specified amount or a specified number of years of remuneration. A description of the predetermined performance parameters, to which the variable remuneration is linked, is almost always provided. This is true in 167 cases (95% of the companies having a variable component for directors; 92% in 2013). Parameter choices may be different; the reference to accounting indicators (EBITDA, EBIT, Profit, EVA, etc.) largely prevails: it can be found in 93% of cases. Much less common (42% of cases) is the reference to “business” targets. The presence of remuneration components related to shares’ market value (stock-based compensation plans, usually options or allocation of shares, the latter often linked to the achievement of business results; more rarely phantom plans based on algorithms related to this value) is reported by 38% of companies; it is more frequent among larger companies (65% of FTSE Mib companies disclosing the presence of variable components). The adoption of stock-based compensation plans for directors is markedly decreased (46% in 2013, 50% in 2012). In 126 cases (72% of the companies having a variable component) an indication of the relative weight of fixed and variable component is provided. Such information is more frequent in the financial sector (85% of cases); less frequently, but still in a pretty high percentage (70% of cases) in other industries. It is basically impossible to report aggregate statistics on the relative weight of the two components because this information is generally provided in a nonhomogeneous form, depending on the different structures of incentive plans. In 89% of cases companies communicate as having set a cap on the variable remuneration. 6. Short- and mediumlong-term oriented variable components The presence of incentive components clearly separated in the remuneration is very widespread: variable remunerations are generally linked to short-term (management-by-objectives plans or MBO) or mediumlong-term performance targets (long-term incentive plans or LTIP). The CG Code recommends that the variable remuneration should be defined in such a way as to pursue the creation of value for shareholders in the mediumlong term, without any specific indication concerning the timing of the performance targets. A short-term-oriented variable remuneration has been observed in 156 cases (i.e., 89% of companies disclosing the presence of a variable remuneration; 82% in 2013). On the other hand, 131 companies disclosed the adoption of a long-term-based variable remuneration (i.e., 75% of the total, substantially increasing from 67% in 2013). Such a variable component is more frequent in the The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration financial sector (80% of cases) and, above all, among larger companies: 94% of companies among FTSE Mib disclosed the presence of a long-term-based variable remuneration (the percentage drops to 80% among Mid Cap and to 65% for Small Cap). 7. Indemnities in case of resignation or dismissal The existence of a cap for indemnities to directors in case of resignation or unfair dismissal is explicitly reported in the Remuneration Report in 57 cases, that is, 25% of the aggregate, as recommended by the Code. It does not mean necessarily that each of these companies has already adopted an agreement on this point: in many cases, in fact, they have a policy which is going to be applied in the future, if and when specific agreements with directors and key managers will be signed. The frequency of such a cap is much more frequent among FTSE Mib companies (47% of cases). Eventual caps are defined according to different parameters and, consequently, data are not easy to analyze on an aggregate basis. The most common situation is the settlement of the cap at 2 years of remuneration. However, we can also find companies where the cap is lower (for instance, 0.3 or 1 year of remuneration) or higher (for instance, 2.5 or 3 years of remuneration), up to a maximum of 6 years of remuneration. Companies are generally (even if sometimes not explicitly) referring to the global remuneration, including its variable component. On the other hand, some companies make explicit reference only to the fixed remuneration, eventually linked to the RAL of the recipient. In some other cases, they disclose the payment of a fixed remuneration, of a more complex remuneration package, that includes a fixed component plus a component linked to the variable remuneration already received, or a “termination treatment” (trattamento di fine mandato, TFM) linked to the length of the mandate or the time prior to the natural termination of the mandate. Some companies underlined that the policy should be understood as the “main rule and would not apply in exceptional circumstances.” Other companies declare that the BoD “can” decide to provide these indemnities; others state that the payment of an indemnity is “generally not intended” (except from law prescriptions for directors that are also managers of the company). In such cases, the cap in obviously intended as 0. 8. Remuneration actually paid Data on the level and structure of individual directors’ remuneration were collected from section II of the Remuneration Report. As in the past, these data have been matched with 249 250 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA information drawn from Corporate Governance Reports, in order to extract information about some relevant issues. The Scheme attached to the Issuers Regulation involves the preparation of very complex tables and often to the duplication of information already provided in other parts of the Report. The average directors’ remuneration amounts to 229,000 h. This varies greatly according to the size of the company (it is 403,000 h in the FTSE Mib, approximately 2.8 times more than the average remuneration in the Small Cap, amounting to 142,000 h). Variations over time are generally not significant. Reports provide the number of directors who are beneficiaries of stock-based plans and of the fair value of such plans, measured using the conventional criterion of the “operating cost” borne by the issuer for the accrual year, pursuant to international financial reporting standards. A very small number of directors (71 directors, that is, 3% of the sample) receive equity compensation “expensed” in whole or in part, during the fiscal year of reference. The number of beneficiaries is almost stable over time (76 directors in 2013, that is, 3.1% of the aggregate). These amounts are quite considerable (amounting to an average of 515,000 h, that is, more than two times the global cash remuneration). The frequency and amount of equity compensations vary according to the size of the company. Cross-checking data of remunerations with those concerning meeting attendance, we investigated the remuneration of the directors who did not take part in any meetings during 2013. The goal was not to identify unjustified fees (commitment for meetings, as mentioned earlier, does not measure the actual commitment required to members of corporate bodies) but to stimulate a reflection on the most appropriate parameters for the commensuration of fees. It is thus observed that among the 15 (eight in 2013, 23 in 2012) directors that attended no meeting (10 of which were due to appointments near to the end of the year), one did not receive any compensation. Another 13 directors have received a low remuneration (less than/equal to 10,000 h), possibly calculated in proportion to their time in office. 9. Remuneration and directors’ role The fees are significantly different depending on the role. The remuneration rank sees at the top MDs, who receive an average remuneration of 846,000 h, followed by executive chairmen, who receive about 25% less than MDs (645,000 h). The other executive directors receive a remuneration which is approximately a little less than 60% of MDs’ remuneration (499,000 h). There are then non-executive chairmen (302,000 h) and The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration deputy-chairmen (257,000 h). Even the following steps are quite sharp: non-executive members of executive committees receive on average 83,000 h. Other non-executive (76,000 h) and independent directors (54,000 h) stand at the bottom of the list. Both the amount of the remuneration and the structure of cash remuneration vary according to directors’ roles: the remuneration of a MD is made on average for the 55% of a fixed component, while bonuses account for 24% and remunerations from subsidiaries for 11% (other items account for smaller amounts). The remuneration of executive chairmen is composed of higher fixed components (68%), much lower bonuses (5%) and fees from subsidiaries generally comparable to those of the MD (11%). The remuneration structure of other executive directors is quite the same, even though they receive a lower fixed component (39%) and definitely higher compensations from subsidiaries (31%). Non-executive chairmen receive almost only fixed compensation (84% of the aggregate). Non-executive directors rarely receive bonuses and other incentives; when this happens, small amounts are involved. Non-executive directors (not independent), however, receive significant compensation from subsidiaries (23,000 h): the weight of this component (31% of the aggregate) is basically the same as for “other executives.” The remuneration of independent directors varies according to company size: among FTSE Mib companies the remuneration slightly exceeds 100,000 h; in Mid Cap companies it is halved (51,000 h) and in Small Caps remuneration decreases by 40% (30,000 h). This trend reflects probably not only the different kinds of problems affecting firms that belong to different index sections, but also a different depth in the application of the Code recommendations that require a specific commitment of independent directors. Global average remuneration of independent directors is stable over time. Independent directors basically perceive additional compensation only for their participation to committees and, however, for limited amounts (16,000 h, that is, 29% of the aggregate). They never perceive equity compensation. It may be interesting to analyze together data concerning both directors’ age and compensation, distinguishing them by role. MDs and “other executives” are the youngest category (average age of 56 years). Followed by “other non-executives” and “other independents” (average ages of, respectively, 56.5 and 59 years). Directors belonging to other categories are generally older (62 years for deputy chairmen, 68 for non-executive chairmen, up to 71 for executive chairmen). 251 252 ROBERTA PROVASI AND PATRIZIA RIVA The survey by Assonime gives more analytical details but what is relevant here is the generally positive conclusion that the Report expresses about the situation observed. The document points out, indeed, that the drafting of specific Remuneration Reports increased significantly the amount of information available to investors. The disclosure level is often a best practice one: there are not many countries where similar information is available on an individual basis (i.e., for each member of the administrative and control corporate bodies). This is especially true for the so-called ex post information (about the remuneration actually paid). References Assonime. (2015). Corporate Governance in Italy: Compliance, remunerations and quality of the comply-or-explain. Retrieved from http://www.assonime.it/ AssonimeWeb2. Accessed in February. Baums, T. (2001). Bericht der Regierungskommission Corporate Governance. Köln, p. 104, 236. Baur, D. G. (2008). Decoupling from the owners and society? An empirical analysis of executing compensation in Germany. Retrieved from http://ssrn.com/abstract= 1140139 Bebchuck, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2004). Pay without performance, the unfulfilled promise of executive compensation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Becht, M., Bolton, P., & Roell, A. (2002). Corporate governance and control. ECGI Finance Working Paper No. 02. Bender, R. (2004). The determination of directors’ remuneration in UK listed companies. London: Centre for Business Performance, ICAEW. Bhagat, S., & Black, B. (1999). The uncertain relationship between board composition and firm performance. Retrieved from SSRN, p. 4 ss. Brick, I. E., Palmon, O., & Wald, J. (2006). CEO compensation, director compensation, and firm performance: Evidence of cronyism? Journal of Corporate Finance, 12, 403. CEBS. (2009). High-level principles for remuneration policies. Retrieved from http:// www.c-bs.org/getdoc/34beb2e0-bdff-4b8e-979a-5115a482a7ba/High-level-principlesfor-remuneration-policies.aspx Chance, D., Kumar, R., & Todd, R. (2000). The “repricing” of executive stock options. Journal of Financial Economics, 57(129), 153. Cheffins, B. R. (2003). Will executive pay globalise along American lines? Corporate Governance, Volume 11. COM. (2004). Comunicazione della commissione “modernizzare il diritto delle società e rafforzare il governo societario nell’Unione Europea. Un piano per progredire” del 21 maggio 2003 [COM (284) 2003 def.], Riv. soc., 568. Core, J. E., Guay, W. R., & Larcker, D. F. (2003). Executive equity compensation and incentives: A survey. Economic Policy Review, 9(2003), 27. Fernandez, A. J. (2003). La retribución de los consejeros, in E. Bueno (dir.), El gobierno de la empresa. En busca de la trasparencia e la confianza. Madrid, 2005, 207. The European Approach to Regulation of Director’s Remuneration Ferrarini, G. (2005). Grandi paghe, piccoli risultati: “rendite” dei managers e possibili rimedi (a proposito di un libro recente). Riv. soc., p. 879. Ferrarini, G., Moloney, N., & Vespro, C. (2003). Executive remuneration in the EU: Comparative law and practice. ECGI, Law Working Paper No. 09/2003, June. Retrieved from http://www.borsaitaliana.it/comitato-corporate-governance/homepage/ homepage.en.htm. Italian Corporate Governance Committee. (2014). Annual report 2014 — 2nd report on the compliance with the Italian corporate governance code. Retrieved from http:// www.borsaitaliana.it/comitato-corporate-governance/homepage/homepage.en.htm. Accessed in December 11. Melis, A., Carta, S., & Gaia, S. (2008). Shareholder rights and director remuneration in blockholder-dominated firms: Why do Italian firms use stock options? Riva, P., & Provasi, R. (2015). Assessment of going concern for the Italian listed companies: An empirical study. Review of Business & Finance Studies, 01/2015, 6(1), 2734. Santosuosso, D. U. (2010). Conflitti di interessi nella remunerazione degli amministratori. “L’attività gestoria nelle società di capitali. Profili di diritto societario italiano e spagnolo a confronto,” A cura di: A. Sarcina — J.A. García Cruces, Cacucci, Bari. 253 This page intentionally left blank Index ABI Principles of Remuneration (2011), 96n3 Accounting regulation, 6768 Act to Improve Supervision of Board Remuneration and Amendment of Further Stock Corporation Law Provisions, 129 Adverse selection, 1314 Advisory vote, 113 Agency conflicts, 1516 Agency costs, 23 Agency theory, 5, 11, 31, 133, 143 adverse selection, 1314 collective action problem, 12 company’s shareholders, 13 different agency conflicts, 1516 key elements, 11 and managerial compensation, 23 base salary, 26 bonus, 26 opportunism, 23 principal-agent model, 23 say on pay votes, 25 short-termism, 25 stock options, 2729 strengthening shareholders’ voting rights, 24 moral hazard, 1415 AGM. See Annual general meeting (AGM) AIB. See Awash International Bank (AIB) “Alternative Mechanism”, 5 Annual bonus plan, 103104 Annual Corporate Governance Report, 178179 Annual directors’ remuneration report, 110111 Annual general meeting (AGM), 111, 246, 247 Annual remuneration report, 97 Antitrust law, 4 “Apply or explain” approach, 98 Appropriateness of Management Board’s Remuneration Act, 121, 123 Audit committee compensation, 87 Awash International Bank (AIB), 199 [B]odies corporate, 199 BaFin. See German Federal Financial Supervisory Authority (BaFin) Bank and banking holdings in Italy, 139141 Bank directors’ remuneration, 203 Directives, 204 economic significance, 205 in Ethiopia, 206 NBE, 203 Banking Business Proclamation No. 592/2008, 197 Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 207, 214 Base salary, 26, 103 BCBS. See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) 255 256 INDEX Big bath accounting, 38 Big BathCap earnings manipulation, 37, 38 Binding vote, 112 BIS. See Department for Business, Innovation and Skills (BIS) Black-Scholes formula (1973), 105 Blue Ribbon Commission, 74, 80 Board independence from CEO, 8384 Board overlaps, 84 Body corporate directors, 199 Civil Code, 202 Commercial Code, 200 defendant, 201 Federal High Court, 201 National Bank, 203 NIB, 199 Bogey, 37 Bonus, 26 awards, 65 “Bonus-Malus” system, 37 Borsa Italiana, 135n1 Boundary systems, 18 Bounded rationality, 10 Cadbury Report, 95 Capital Requirements Directive (CRD), 238 Capital Requirements Directive III (CRD III Directive). See Third Capital Requirement Directive (CRD3) CD&A. See Compensation Discussion and Analysis (CD&A) CEBS. See Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS) CEO compensation system, 59, 60 balance of power, 62 literature on, 6062 plans, 61 See also Executive compensation CG Code, Italian remuneration reports to, 244 Corporate Governance Committee, 245 eventual caps, 249 parameters, 247248 remuneration and directors’ role, 250251 remuneration policy, 246247 “Remuneration Reports”, 246 short-and mediumlong-term oriented variable components, 248249 survey by Assonime, 252 Circular 4/2011, 166 Classical contracts, 8 Classical firm, 5 Coase Theorem, 8 Code of Self-Discipline of Listed Companies, 135136 Codes of Good Governance, 159160 Collective action problem, 12 Collective production, 1618 Combined Code on Corporate Governance (1998), 9899 Commercial Code, 185, 190191, 192, 196, 198199 Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS), 139, 164, 165, 238 CEBS Guidelines, 96n1 Community Recommendation 913/ 2004, 232 Companies Act. See Ley de Sociedades de Capital (LSC) Company law, 4 Compensation committees, 77, 8283 consultants, 83 equity, 7980 equity-based, 28, 31 See also Executive compensation Compensation Discussion and Analysis (CD&A), 76 Complete contract, 9 Index “Comply or explain” approach, 100n7, 136, 137 Conference Board survey, 80 Consob Legislative Decree No. 58 of 24 February (1998), 136138 Consob Scheme, 246247 Contract, 10 Corporate governance, 3, 7, 5051 changes in, 51 elements of financial institutions, 4850 proposals, 4 rules, 135 See also Financial governance Corporate Governance Annual Report, 162, 178 Corporate social performance, 90 Corporate social responsibility (CSR), 15, 36, 39 CRD3. See Third Capital Requirement Directive (CRD3) CSR. See Corporate social responsibility (CSR) Current intrinsic motivator, 3031 DAB plans. See Deferred annual bonus plans (DAB plans) DAX, 123, 125 Decisive elements, 143 Defendant, 89 Deferred annual bonus plans (DAB plans), 104 Department for Business, Innovation and Skills (BIS), 112, 114 Detailed audit financial information, 111 Determinants of director remuneration, 8185 and board independence from CEO, 8384 board overlaps, 84 257 characteristics of firms adopting outside director stockoption plans, 8182 compensation committees, 8283 consultants, 83 Diagnostic control systems, 1718 Director, 198 Director compensation guidelines, 75 Directors’ remuneration agency theory and managerial compensation, 23 base salary, 26 bonus, 26 opportunism, 23 principal-agent model, 23 say on pay votes, 25 short-termism, 25 stock options, 2729 strengthening shareholders’ voting rights, 24 board’s role in, 67 current intrinsic motivator, 3031 design, 6566 employee motivation, 29 in Ethiopia Commercial Code, 185 emerging separation of ownership and control, 187190 Ethiopian companies profile, 186187 non-financial and financial companies, 188 in Ethiopian share companies, 190 challenges, 195207 design, 192194 regulation, 190192 reporting, 194 factors, 6667 in Germany challenges, 128130 design, 122126 258 INDEX regulation, 119122 reporting, 127128 in Italy, 133134 design schemes, 142146 regulation, 134142 reporting, 146152 and motivation, 21 executive contracts, 21 high-powered incentive contracts, 22 shareholders, 22 participation of employees, 207210 policy, 6465 in Spain, 157 annual report on remuneration of directors, 179180 board structure in, 168 recommendations to directors remuneration in, 158 regulation for financial institutions, 163166 remuneration challenges, 180181 remuneration design, 169176 remuneration regulation, 157163 remuneration reporting, 176180 takeover threats, 3031 in United Kingdom challenges, 113115 design, 103110 regulation, 95103 reporting, 110113 in United States, 73 Blue Ribbon Commission, 74 challenges, 9192 corporate social performance, 90 design, 7881 determinants, 8185 dividend paying, 89 empirical evidence on, 81 financial reporting, 8788 market reaction to adding equity to director remuneration plans, 8586 regulation and reporting, 758 shareholder lawsuits, 8990 well-balanced packages, 31 Directors’ Remuneration Report Regulations (2002), 95, 110111 Directors’ Remuneration Reporting Reform (2012), 111113 Discounting, 5253, 55 functions, 53 Dismissal of executives, 21 Dividend paying, 89 Dodd-Frank Act, 75, 76 Dodd-Frank Financial Reform bill, 25 Earnings before interest and tax (EBIT), 26, 123 Earnings management, 87 EBA. See European Banking Authority (EBA) EBIT. See Earnings before interest and tax (EBIT) Economic contract, 10 Economic Value Added (EVA), 123 Employee motivation, 29 Enel CEO, 151 Enel Remuneration System (2013), 149152 Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Bill (2013), 115 Epitomes of transformative CSR, 36n1 Equity-based compensation, 28, 31 Equity-based pay models, 230 Equity compensation, 7980 ESMA. See European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) ESOs. See Executive share options (ESOs); Share option plans (ESOs) Index Ethiopian Commercial Code. See Commercial Code European and German regulation of remuneration system incentive-compatibility, 220 incentive-compatible remuneration system, 221 European and international recommendations, 164165 European approach to director’s remuneration regulation Action Plan, 226227 action plan, 231 EU interventions, 237244 European Commission, 225, 227 Italian Remuneration reports to CG Code, 244 Corporate Governance Committee, 245 eventual caps, 249 parameters, 247248 remuneration and directors’ role, 250251 remuneration policy, 246247 “Remuneration Reports”, 246 short-and mediumlong-term oriented variable components, 248249 survey by Assonime, 252 literature review, 228231 Recommendation 2004/913/EC, 232233 Recommendation 2005/162/EC, 235237 remuneration of individual directors, 234235 policy, 233234 share-based remuneration, 235 See also Directors’ remuneration European Banking Authority (EBA), 216 European Commission, 225, 227 European Community, 225 European legislation to German implementation, 213 259 European Parliament and Council, 214 implementation of remuneration regulations in Germany, 219220 incentive-compatibility of European and German regulation of remuneration system, 220 incentive-compatible remuneration system, 221 prerequisites of incentivecompatible remuneration system, 215216 regulative remuneration standards of EU, 216219 European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA), 216 European Union interventions, 237 “Action Plan”, 243 Directive 2007/36/EC, 244 European Parliament, 241242 golden parachute, 240 Recommendation, 239 Recommendation for Financial Institutions, 239240 Rem. HLP, 238 EVA. See Economic Value Added (EVA) Executive and non-executive directors, 198199 Executive compensation, 133134 and motivation, 3637 plans, 3738 redefining performance evaluation in age of sustainability, 38 CSR, 39 hypotheses, 40 Puma innovative accounting system for sustainability, 40 in 21st century, 3536 See also CEO compensation system 260 INDEX Executive contracts, 21 Executive directors’ benefits provision, 65 Executive remuneration in FTSE 250 companies, 114 Executive share options (ESOs), 97 Exercise barriers, 123 Explicit incentives, 21 Exponential discounting, 5354 Extrinsic motivation, 23, 29 Federal Supreme Court Cassation Division, 201n42 FEDEX days, 37 Financial companies, 47 crisis and effects on remuneration governance in financial institutions, 4850 European initiatives for enhanced governance and remuneration, 5051 financial governance, 47 remuneration, 5155 See also Industrial companies Financial governance, 47 See also Corporate governance Financial institutions, 48 corporate governance elements of, 4850 crisis and effects on remuneration governance in, 48 pre-and post-crisis remuneration governance, 50 stakeholder groups, 49 Financial reporting, 8788 Financial Reporting Council (FRC), 9899 May 2010 consultation document, 100101 September 2012 consultation document, 101 Financial scandals, 39 Financial Service Authority (FSA), 96n1 Financial Stability Board (FSB), 213n1 Financial Stability Forum (FSF), 164 Firm size, 66 Fixed annual remuneration, 192 Fixed compensation package design, 144145 Fixed remuneration, 169, 171 Fraudulent financial reporting, 87 FRC. See Financial Reporting Council (FRC) Free riding, 12 French Law, 229 FSA. See Financial Service Authority (FSA) FSB. See Financial Stability Board (FSB) FSF. See Financial Stability Forum (FSF) FTSE All-Share Index factsheet, 109110 Full value shares, 79 GCCG. See German Code of Corporate Governance (GCCG) General shareholders meeting (GSM), 192 German Code of Corporate Governance (GCCG), 121, 122, 124, 126127 German Commercial Code, 127 German Corporate Governance Code. See German Code of Corporate Governance (GCCG) German Federal Financial Supervisory Authority (BaFin), 216 German Government passed the Management Board Remuneration Disclosure Act. See Vorstandsvergütungs— Offenlegungs-gesetz (VorstOG) Index German law, 229 German Stock Corporation Act (GSCA), 119120, 122, 126 Germany German Prime Standard, 126, 127 German two-tier system, 119120 implementation of remuneration regulations in, 219220 Gesetz zur Angemessenheit der Vorstandsvergütung (VorstAG), 121, 123 Gesetz zur Verbesserung der Kontrolle der Vorstandsvergütung und Änderung weiterer aktienrechtlicher Vorschriften (VorstKoG), 129 Golden parachutes, 174175 Government-owned unlisted companies, 141142 Greenbury Report (1995), 95, 9697 GSCA. See German Stock Corporation Act (GSCA) GSM. See General shareholders meeting (GSM) Hampel Report (1998), 98 Higgs Report, 99 High-level Principles for Remuneration Policies (Rem. HLP), 238 Hostile takeovers, 30 Hyperbolic discounting, 54 IFRS. See International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) IMF. See International Monetary Fund (IMF) Implementation report, 112 Implicit incentives, 21 261 Incentive-compatible remuneration system prerequisites, 215216 Incentive pay, 2122 Incomplete remuneration contracts, 9 bounded rationality, 10 complete contract, 9 nexus of contracts, 1011 See also Directors’ remuneration Independent director compensation, 87 Independent non-executive directors (INEDs), 97 Individual bonus decisions, 65 Individual directors remuneration of, 234235 Industrial companies, 59 accounting regulation, 6768 CEO compensation system, 59, 60 directors’ remuneration board’s role in, 67 design, 6566 factors, 6667 policy, 6465 research design, 62 results, 6264 See also Financial companies INEDs. See Independent nonexecutive directors (INEDs) Initial public offering of shares (IPOs), 187 Interactive control systems, 18 International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS), 67, 68 International Monetary Fund (IMF), 213n1 Intrinsic motivation, 23 IPOs. See Initial public offering of shares (IPOs) ISVAP Regulation, 141 Italian compensation discipline, 135 Italian economic system, 134 Italian listed companies, 135139 262 INDEX Law 2/2011, 165166 Ley de Sociedades de Capital (LSC), 158 Royal Legislative Decree 1564/ 1989, 159 Spanish legislation, 157158 Listing Rules (2004), 96n2, 98 London Stock Exchange (LSE), 98n4, 206 Long-term compensation, 66 Long-term incentive plans (LTIPs), 97, 105, 114, 127, 128, 248 CEO compensation in UK listed companies, 108, 109 executive average compensation in UK listed companies, 109 executive compensation, 110 executive directors’ remuneration, 106108 FTSE All-Share Index factsheet, 109110 percentage of using LTIPs in FTSE 100 companies, 106 share grants, 105 Long-term performance measurement, 65 LSC. See Ley de Sociedades de Capital (LSC) LSE. See London Stock Exchange (LSE) LTIPs. See Long-term incentive plans (LTIPs) pension awards, 123124 pre-defined objectives, 122123 range of board remuneration of companies, 125126 share-based compensation, 123, 126 Management-by-objectives plans (MBO), 248 Market dichotomy, 89 Market for corporate control, 30 MBO. See Management-byobjectives plans (MBO) MDAX, 123, 125 Mediumlong-term oriented variable remuneration, 248249 Meeting fees, 79 Microeconomics, 6 Mid-term incentive plan (MTI plan), 127, 128 Ministry of Commerce and Industry, 192 Mixed remuneration design, 193194 Monetary compensation components, 124 Moral hazard, 1415 Motivation, 23 theories, 215216 MTI plan. See Mid-term incentive plan (MTI plan) Multi-annual variable remuneration, 172 limits, conditions, and constraints, 173 LSC, 174 Multitasking, 27 Management, 1618 compensation plans, 37 Management board remuneration, 122 financial crisis effects, 124125 GCCG, 122, 124 monetary compensation components, 124 NACD. See National Association of Corporate Directors (NACD) NASDAQ, 112n16 National Association of Corporate Directors (NACD), 74 National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE), 185 Italian ownership structure, 134 Italian Stock Exchange. See Borsa Italiana Italian unlisted companies, 142 Index NBE. See National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE) Neo-classical contracts, 8, 9 Neo-classical economics, 4 Net present value (NPV), 52 New Regulations, 139140 New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), 59, 62, 63, 64, 112n16 Nexus of contracts, 1011 Nib International Bank (NIB), 199 NPV. See Net present value (NPV) NYSE. See New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) Opportunism, 23 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 206n63 Ownership, 67, 105 “Pay for performance” culture, 145 Pay-performance link, 3738 Pay-performance sensitivity, 28 Pension awards, 123124 plans, 174 rights, 103n9 Performance evaluation in age of sustainability, 38 CSR, 39 hypotheses, 40 Puma innovative accounting system for, 40 Performance measures, 65 Performance share grants, 105 Phantom stock, 37 Policy report, 112 Post-crisis remuneration governance, 50 PPESA. See Privatization and Public Enterprises Supervising Agency (PPESA) Pre-crisis remuneration governance, 50 Principal-agent model, 23 263 theory models, 5 Privatization and Public Enterprises Supervising Agency (PPESA), 187 Production costs, 6 Proportionality principle, 140 Puma innovative accounting system for sustainability, 40 Quasi-hyperbolic discounting, 54, 55 Quoted companies, 112n16 Recommendation 2004/913/EC, 232233 Recommendation 2005/162/EC, 235 individual remuneration, 237 remuneration committee, 236 Regulation for financial institutions in Spain, 163, 164 Circular 4/2011, 166 European and international recommendations, 164165 Royal Decree 771/2011, 165166 Sustainable Economy Act, 165166 Regulative remuneration standards of EU, 216 Directive 2013/36/EU, 218 functions and prerequisites of remuneration systems, 217 long-term oriented risk management strategies, 219 remuneration policies, 217 Relational contracts, 8, 9 Rem. HLP. See High-level Principles for Remuneration Policies (Rem. HLP) Remuneration, 3, 7, 51, 229 alternative discounting functions, 53 264 INDEX of directors, 138 discounting, 5253 evaluation, 55 exponential discounting, 5354 hyperbolic discounting, 54 policy, 110111, 233234 challenges for, 115 practices, 51 quasi-hyperbolic discounting, 54, 55 structuring variable bonuses over time, 52 systems, 133, 216 Remuneration challenges in Ethiopia, 195 bank directors remuneration, 203206 body corporate directors, 199203 executive and non-executive directors, 198199 lack of legal requirement for Remuneration Committee, 206207 privileges, 195198 in Germany, 128130 in Spain, 180181 in United Kingdom challenges for remuneration policy, 115 problems in UK executive remuneration, 113115 in United States, 9192 Remuneration committee, 110 lack of legal requirement for, 206207 Remuneration design, 103 in Ethiopian share companies, 192194 in Germany management board remuneration, 122126 supervisory board remuneration, 126 in Italy, 142146 in Spain average remuneration per director, 175 practice, 175176 profit sharing, 173 remuneration policy for directors, 166169 remuneration systems elements in, 169175 systems of remuneration to directors, 170 in United Kingdom annual bonus plan, 103104 base salary, 103 ESOs, 104105 LTIPs, 105110 in United States, 78 Conference Board survey, 80 equity compensation, 7980 meeting fees, 79 perquisites, 80, 81 survey of firms, 78 Remuneration Disclosure Requirements (2010), 96n1 Remuneration regulation, 9596 in Ethiopian share companies, 190192 in Germany German two-tier system, 119120 management board and supervisory board, 120122 in Italy, 134135 bank and banking holdings, 139141 government-owned unlisted companies, 141142 Italian compensation discipline, 135 listed companies, 135139 unlisted companies, 142 in Spain, 157 Codes of Good Governance, 159160 for companies, 157 Index LSC, 157159 regulations, 163 Securities Market Act, 162163 Sustainable Economy Act, 161162 in United Kingdom, 9899 Combined Code on Corporate Governance (1998) Greenbury Report (1995), 9697 UK Corporate Governance Code (2010 Code), 99101 UK Corporate Governance Code (2012 Code), 101103 in United States, 75 CD&A, 76 compensation committees, 77 NYSE and NASDAQ, 75 SEC, 756 Remuneration reporting in Ethiopian share companies, 194 in Germany, 127128 in Italy, 146147 2013 Enel Remuneration System, 149152 Telecom Italia 2012 Remuneration Scheme, 147149 in Spain, 176180 in United Kingdom, 111113 2012 Directors’ Remuneration Reporting Reform Directors’ Remuneration Report Regulations (2002), 110111 in United States, 75 CD&A, 76 NYSE and NASDAQ, 75 SEC, 756 Responses to shirking, 17 Return on Assets (ROA), 123 Return on Net Assets (RONA), 123 265 Royal Assent, 115 Royal Decree 1362/2007, 163 Royal Decree 771/2011, 165166 Samuelson’s model, 53 Sarbanes-Oxley Act (2002), 77 “Say on pay” remuneration, 111 system, 161 tool, 135 votes, 25 SDAX, 124125 SEBI. See Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI) SEC. See Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) § 4 One-third Participation Act, 120 § 29 Co-Determination Act, 120 § 107 GSCA, 120 Securities and Exchange Board of India (SEBI), 207 Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), 25, 75 Securities Market Act, 162163 Sensitivity of pay, 21 Share-based compensation, 123, 126 Share-based remuneration, 235 Share-option-based pay, 230 Share option plans (ESOs), 104105 Shareholder(s), 22 lawsuits, 8990 shareholder-manager agency relationship, 14 vote, 111 Shirking, 16, 17 Short-term remuneration schemes, 145 Short-term-oriented variable remuneration, 248249 Short-termism, 25 Smith Report, 99 “Soft landing” mechanisms, 230 Stakeholder(s), 1516, 205 266 INDEX impact of director remuneration, 9091 groups, 49 model, 16, 208 Stakeholders’ Interests, 49 theory, 40 Standardization, 105 Statutory dividend, 208209 Stewardship Code (2010), 99n6 Stock market’s reaction, 8586 Stock options, 27, 7980 equity-based compensation and pay-performance sensitivity, 28 multitasking, 27 packages, 146 senior management pay at public companies, 29 Stock-appreciation rights, 79 Strengthening shareholders’ voting rights, 24 Strike price, 80 Structuring variable bonuses over time, 52 Supervisory board remuneration, 126 Sustainable Economy Act, 161162, 165166 Takeover threats, 3031 Target-based bonuses, 26, 27 TecDAX, 124125 Telecom Italia 2012 Remuneration Scheme, 147149 TFM. See Trattamento di fine mandato (TFM) Theory of firm, 46 Coase Theorem, 8 production costs, 6 situations in market transactions, 7 Theory of property rights, 7 Theory of team production, 17 Theory of transaction costs, 8 Third Capital Requirement Directive (CRD3), 96n1, 139 Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX), 59, 62, 63, 64 Transaction-cost economics, 6 Trattamento di fine mandato (TFM), 249 TSX. See Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX) 2008 Code, 99n6 2010 Code. See UK Corporate Governance Code (2010 Code) UK Corporate Governance Code (2010 Code), 99101 UK Corporate Governance Code (2012), 101103 UK executive remuneration, problems in, 113115 Variable annual remuneration, 171172 VorstAG. See Gesetz zur Angemessenheit der Vorstandsvergütung (VorstAG) Vorstandsvergütungs— Offenlegungs-gesetz (VorstOG), 121 VorstKoG. See Gesetz zur Verbesserung der Kontrolle der Vorstandsvergütung und Änderung weiterer aktienrechtlicher Vorschriften (VorstKoG) Walker Review (2009), 100n7 Well-balanced packages, 31 “Windfalls” in equity-based plans, 230 Worldwide Total Remuneration Report, 143 Year-on-year performance, 109n13 Zero transaction costs, 30