+Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 1 The Fundamentals of Managerial Economics McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + 1-2 Managerial Economics Manager Economics A person who directs resources to achieve a stated goal. The science of making decisions in the presence of scare resources. Managerial Economics The study of how to direct scarce resources in the way that most efficiently achieves a managerial goal. + 1-3 Economic vs. Accounting Profits Accounting Profits Total revenue (sales) minus dollar cost of producing goods or services. Reported on the firm’s income statement. Economic Profits Total revenue minus total opportunity cost. + Opportunity Cost Accounting Costs The explicit costs of the resources needed to produce produce goods or services. Reported on the firm’s income statement. Opportunity Cost The cost of the explicit and implicit resources that are foregone when a decision is made. Economic Profits Total revenue minus total opportunity cost. 1-4 + 1-5 Profits as a Signal Profits signal to resource holders where resources are most highly valued by society. Resources will flow into industries that are most highly valued by society. Marginal (Incremental) Analysis 1-6 Control Variable Examples: Output Price Product Quality Advertising R&D Basic Managerial Question: How much of the control variable should be used to maximize net benefits? + 1-7 Net Benefits Net Benefits = Total Benefits - Total Costs Profits = Revenue - Costs 1-8 Marginal Benefit (MB) Change in total benefits arising from a change in the control variable, Q: B MB Q Slope (calculus derivative) of the total benefit curve. 1-9 Marginal Cost (MC) Change in total costs arising from a change in the control variable, Q: C MC Q Slope (calculus derivative) of the total cost curve + Marginal Principle To maximize net benefits, the managerial control variable should be increased up to the point where MB = MC. MB > MC means the last unit of the control variable increased benefits more than it increased costs. MB < MC means the last unit of the control variable increased costs more than it increased benefits. 1-10 + The Geometry of Optimization: Total Benefit and Cost Total Benefits & Total Costs Costs Slope =MB Benefits B Slope = MC C Q* Q 1-11 + The Geometry of Optimization: Net Benefits Net Benefits Maximum net benefits Slope = MNB Q* Q 1-12 +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 2 Market Forces: Demand and Supply McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 2-14 Overview I. Market Demand Curve The Demand Function Determinants of Demand Consumer Surplus II. Market Supply Curve The Supply Function Supply Shifters Producer Surplus III. Market Equilibrium IV. Price Restrictions V. Comparative Statics + 2-15 Market Demand Curve Shows the amount of a good that will be purchased at alternative prices, holding other factors constant. Law of Demand The demand curve is downward sloping. Price D Quantity 2-16 Determinants of Demand Income Normal good Inferior good Prices of Related Goods Prices of substitutes Prices of complements Advertising and consumer tastes Population Consumer expectations + 2-17 The Demand Function A general equation representing the demand curve Qxd = f(Px ,PY , M, H,) Qxd = quantity demand of good X. Px = price of good X. PY = price of a related good Y. Substitute good. Complement good. M = income. Normal good. Inferior good. H = any other variable affecting demand. + 2-18 Inverse Demand Function Price as a function of quantity demanded. Example: Demand Function Qxd = 10 – 2Px Inverse Demand Function: 2Px = 10 – Qxd Px = 5 – 0.5Qxd Change in Quantity Demanded Price A to B: Increase in quantity demanded 10 A B 6 D0 4 7 Quantity 2-19 2-20 Change in Demand Price D0 to D1: Increase in Demand 6 D1 D0 7 13 Quantity 2-21 Consumer Surplus: The value consumers get from a good but do not have to pay for. Consumer surplus will prove particularly useful in marketing and other disciplines emphasizing strategies like value pricing and price discrimination. 2-22 I got a great deal! That company offers a lot of bang for the buck! Dell provides good value. Total value greatly exceeds total amount paid. Consumer large. surplus is 2-23 I got a lousy deal! That car dealer drives a hard bargain! I almost decided not to buy it! They tried to squeeze the very last cent from me! Total amount paid is close to total value. Consumer surplus is low. + Consumer Surplus: The Discrete Case 2-24 Price Consumer Surplus: The value received but not paid for. Consumer surplus = (8-2) + (6-2) + (4-2) = $12. 10 8 6 4 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity Consumer Surplus: + The Continuous Case 2-25 Price $ 10 Consumer Surplus = $24 - $8 = $16 Value of 4 units = $24 8 6 Expenditure on 4 units = $2 x 4 = $8 4 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity 2-26 + Market Supply Curve The supply curve shows the amount of a good that will be produced at alternative prices. Law of Supply The supply curve is upward sloping. Price S0 Quantity 2-27 Supply Shifters Input prices Technology or government regulations Number of firms Entry Exit Substitutes in production Taxes Excise tax Ad valorem tax Producer expectations + 2-28 The Supply Function An equation representing the supply curve: QxS = f(Px ,PR ,W, H,) QxS = quantity supplied of good X. Px = price of good X. PR = price of a production substitute. W = price of inputs (e.g., wages). H = other variable affecting supply. + 2-29 Inverse Supply Function Price as a function of quantity supplied. Example: Supply Function Qxs = 10 + 2Px Inverse Supply Function: 2Px = 10 + Qxs Px = 5 + 0.5Qxs + 2-30 Change in Quantity Supplied Price A to B: Increase in quantity supplied S0 B 20 A 10 5 10 Quantity 2-31 + Change in Supply S0 to S1: Increase in supply Price S0 S1 8 6 5 7 Quantity 2-32 + Producer Surplus The amount producers receive in excess of the amount necessary to induce them to produce the good. Price S0 P* Q* Quantity 2-33 Market Equilibrium The Price (P) that Balances supply and demand QxS = Qxd No shortage or surplus Steady-state 2-34 If price is too low… Price S 7 6 5 D Shortage 12 - 6 = 6 6 12 Quantity 2-35 If price is too high… Surplus 14 - 6 = 8 Price S 9 8 7 D 6 8 14 Quantity + Price Restrictions Price Ceilings The maximum legal price that can be charged. Examples: Gasoline prices in the 1970s. Housing in New York City. Proposed restrictions on ATM fees. Price Floors The minimum legal price that can be charged. Examples: Minimum wage. Agricultural price supports. 2-36 2-37 Impact of a Price Ceiling Price S PF P* P Ceiling D Shortage Qs Q* Qd Quantity + 2-38 Impact of a Price Floor Price Surplus S PF P* D Qd Q* QS Quantity + 2-39 Comparative Static Analysis How do the equilibrium price and quantity change when a determinant of supply and/or demand change? + 2-40 Applications of Demand and Supply Analysis Event: The WSJ reports that the prices of PC components are expected to fall by 5-8 percent over the next six months. Scenario 1: You manage a small firm that manufactures PCs. Scenario 2: You manage a small software company. + Use Comparative Static Analysis to see the Big Picture! Comparative static analysis shows how the equilibrium price and quantity will change when a determinant of supply or demand changes. 2-41 + 2-42 Scenario 1: Implications for a Small PC Maker Step 1: Look for the “Big Picture.” Step 2: Organize an action plan (worry about details). Big Picture: Impact of decline in component prices on PC market Price of PCs 2-43 S S* P0 P* D Q0 Q* Quantity of PC’s + Big Picture Analysis: PC Market Equilibrium price of PCs will fall, and equilibrium quantity of computers sold will increase. Use this to organize an action plan contracts/suppliers? inventories? human resources? marketing? do I need quantitative estimates? 2-44 + Scenario 2: Software Maker More complicated chain of reasoning to arrive at the “Big Picture.” Step 1: Use analysis like that in Scenario 1 to deduce that lower component prices will lead to a lower equilibrium price for computers. a greater number of computers sold. Step 2: How will these changes affect the “Big Picture” in the software market? 2-45 Big Picture: Impact of lower PC prices on the software market 2-46 Price of Software S P1 P0 D* D Q0 Q1 Quantity of Software + 2-47 Big Picture Analysis: Software Market Software prices are likely to rise, and more software will be sold. Use this to organize an action plan. +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 3 Quantitative Demand Analysis McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + Overview I. The Elasticity Concept Own Price Elasticity Elasticity and Total Revenue Cross-Price Elasticity Income Elasticity II. Linear Demand Functions 3-49 + 3-50 The Elasticity Concept How responsive is variable “G” to a change in variable “S” EG , S % G % S If EG,S > 0, then S and G are directly related. If EG,S < 0, then S and G are inversely related. If EG,S = 0, then S and G are unrelated. + 3-51 The Elasticity Concept Using Calculus An alternative way to measure the elasticity of a function G = f(S) is EG , S dG S dS G If EG,S > 0, then S and G are directly related. If EG,S < 0, then S and G are inversely related. If EG,S = 0, then S and G are unrelated. + 3-52 Own Price Elasticity of Demand EQ X , PX % Q X % PX d Negative according to the “law of demand.” Elastic: EQ X , PX 1 Inelastic: EQ X , PX 1 Unitary: EQ X , PX 1 + 3-53 Perfectly Elastic & Inelastic Demand Price Price D D Quantity Perfectly Elastic ( EQX ,PX ) Quantity Perfectly Inelastic ( EQX , PX 0) 3-54 + Own-Price Elasticity and Total Revenue Elastic Inelastic Increase (a decrease) in price leads to a decrease (an increase) in total revenue. Increase (a decrease) in price leads to an increase (a decrease) in total revenue. Unitary Total revenue is maximized at the point where demand is unitary elastic. + 3-55 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 Q + 3-56 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR 80 800 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q + 3-57 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR 80 1200 60 800 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q + 3-58 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR 80 1200 60 40 800 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q + 3-59 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR 80 1200 60 40 800 20 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q + 3-60 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR Elastic 80 1200 60 40 800 20 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 Elastic 30 40 50 Q + 3-61 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR Elastic 80 1200 60 Inelastic 40 800 20 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 Elastic 20 30 40 Inelastic 50 Q + 3-62 Elasticity, Total Revenue and Linear Demand P 100 TR Unit elastic Elastic Unit elastic 80 1200 60 Inelastic 40 800 20 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 Elastic 20 30 40 Inelastic 50 Q + 3-63 Demand, Marginal Revenue (MR) and Elasticity For a linear inverse demand function, MR(Q) = a + 2bQ, where b < 0. P 100 Elastic Unit elastic 80 60 Inelastic 40 20 0 10 20 40 MR 50 Q When MR > 0, demand is elastic; MR = 0, demand is unit elastic; MR < 0, demand is inelastic. Factors Affecting + Own Price Elasticity Available Substitutes 3-64 The more substitutes available for the good, the more elastic the demand. Time Demand tends to be more inelastic in the short term than in the long term. Time allows consumers to seek out available substitutes. Expenditure Share Goods that comprise a small share of consumer’s budgets tend to be more inelastic than goods for which consumers spend a large portion of their incomes. + 3-65 Cross Price Elasticity of Demand EQX , PY %QX %PY d If EQX,PY > 0, then X and Y are substitutes. If EQX,PY < 0, then X and Y are complements. + 3-66 Income Elasticity EQX , M %QX %M d If EQX,M > 0, then X is a normal good. If EQX,M < 0, then X is a inferior good. + 3-67 Uses of Elasticities Pricing. Managing cash flows. Impact of changes in competitors’ prices. Impact of economic booms and recessions. Impact of advertising campaigns. And lots more! + 3-68 Example 1: Pricing and Cash Flows According to an FTC Report by Michael Ward, AT&T’s own price elasticity of demand for long distance services is -8.64. AT&T needs to boost revenues in order to meet it’s marketing goals. To accomplish this goal, should AT&T raise or lower it’s price? + 3-69 Answer: Lower price! Since demand is elastic, a reduction in price will increase quantity demanded by a greater percentage than the price decline, resulting in more revenues for AT&T. + Example 2: Quantifying the Change If AT&T lowered price by 3 percent, what would happen to the volume of long distance telephone calls routed through AT&T? 3-70 + Answer 3-71 • Calls would increase by 25.92 percent! EQX , PX %QX 8.64 %PX d %QX 8.64 3% d 3% 8.64 %QX d %QX 25.92% d + Example 3: Impact of a change in a competitor’s price According to an FTC Report by Michael Ward, AT&T’s cross price elasticity of demand for long distance services is 9.06. If competitors reduced their prices by 4 percent, what would happen to the demand for AT&T services? 3-72 + Answer 3-73 • AT&T’s demand would fall by 36.24 percent! EQX , PY %QX 9.06 %PY %QX 9.06 4% d 4% 9.06 %QX d %QX 36.24% d d + Interpreting Demand Functions Mathematical representations of demand curves. Example: QX 10 2 PX 3PY 2M d Law of demand holds (coefficient of PX is negative). X and Y are substitutes (coefficient of PY is positive). X is an inferior good (coefficient of M is negative). 3-74 +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + Overview I. Consumer Behavior Indifference Curve Analysis Consumer Preference Ordering II. Constraints The Budget Constraint Changes in Income Changes in Prices III. Consumer Equilibrium IV. Indifference Curve Analysis & Demand Curves Individual Demand Market Demand 4-76 + Consumer Behavior Consumer Opportunities Consumer Preferences The possible goods and services consumer can afford to consume. The goods and services consumers actually consume. Given the choice between 2 bundles of goods a consumer either Prefers bundle A to bundle B: A B. Prefers bundle B to bundle A: A B. Is indifferent between the two: A B. 4-77 Indifference Curve Analysis Indifference Curve A curve that defines the combinations of 2 or more goods that give a consumer the same level of satisfaction. 4-78 Good Y III. II. I. Marginal Rate of Substitution The rate at which a consumer is willing to substitute one good for another and maintain the same satisfaction level. Good X + 4-79 Consumer Preference Ordering Properties Completeness More is Better Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution Transitivity 4-80 Complete Preferences Completeness Property Consumer is capable of expressing preferences (or indifference) between all possible bundles. (“I don’t know” is NOT an option!) If the only bundles available to a consumer are A, B, and C, then the consumer is indifferent between A and C (they are on the same indifference curve). will prefer B to A. will prefer B to C. Good Y III. II. I. A B C Good X 4-81 More Is Better! More Is Better Property Bundles that have at least as much of every good and more of some good are preferred to other bundles. Bundle B is preferred to A since B contains at least as much of good Y and strictly more of good X. Bundle B is also preferred to C since B contains at least as much of good X and strictly more of good Y. More generally, all bundles on ICIII are preferred to bundles on ICII or ICI. And all bundles on ICII are preferred to ICI. Good Y III. II. I. 100 A B C 33.33 1 3 Good X 4-82 Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution Marginal Rate of Substitution The amount of good Y the consumer is willing to give up to maintain the same satisfaction level decreases as more of good X is acquired. The rate at which a consumer is willing to substitute one good for another and maintain the same satisfaction level. To go from consumption bundle A to B the consumer must give up 50 units of Y to get one additional unit of X. To go from consumption bundle B to C the consumer must give up 16.67 units of Y to get one additional unit of X. To go from consumption bundle C to D the consumer must give up only 8.33 units of Y to get one additional unit of X. Good Y III. II. I. A 100 B 50 C 33.33 25 1 2 3 D 4 Good X 4-83 Consistent Bundle Orderings Transitivity Property For the three bundles A, B, and C, the transitivity property implies that if C B and B A, then C A. Good Y Transitive preferences along with the more-is-better property 100 imply that 75 indifference curves will not 50 intersect. the consumer will not get caught in a perpetual cycle of indecision. III. II. I. A C B 1 2 5 7 Good X 4-84 The Budget Constraint Opportunity Set The set of consumption bundles that are affordable. PxX Y + PyY M. Budget Line M/PY Budget Line Y = M/PY – (PX/PY)X The bundles of goods that exhaust a consumers income. PxX + PyY = M. Market The Opportunity Set Rate of Substitution The slope of the budget line -Px / Py M/PX X 4-85 Changes in the Budget Line Y Changes in Income Increases lead to a parallel, outward shift in the budget line (M1 > M0). Decreases lead to a parallel, downward shift (M2 < M0). Changes in Price A decreases in the price of good X rotates the budget line counter-clockwise (PX0 > PX1). An increases rotates the budget line clockwise (not shown). M1/PY M0/PY M2/PY Y M0/PY M2/PX M0/PX M1/PX X New Budget Line for a price decrease. M0/PX0 M0/PX1 X 4-86 Consumer Equilibrium The equilibrium consumption bundle is the affordable bundle that yields the highest level of satisfaction. Consumer equilibrium occurs at a point where MRS = PX / PY. Equivalently, the slope of the indifference curve equals the budget line. Y M/PY Consumer Equilibrium III. II. I. M/PX X + 4-87 Price Changes and Consumer Equilibrium Substitute Goods An increase (decrease) in the price of good X leads to an increase (decrease) in the consumption of good Y. Examples: Coke and Pepsi. Verizon Wireless or AT&T. Complementary Goods An increase (decrease) in the price of good X leads to a decrease (increase) in the consumption of good Y. Examples: DVD and DVD players. Computer CPUs and monitors. + 4-88 Complementary Goods When the price of Pretzels (Y) good X falls and the consumption of Y rises, then X and Y M/PY 1 are complementary goods. (PX1 > PX2) B Y2 II A Y1 I 0 X1 M/PX1 X2 M/PX2 Beer (X) + Income Changes and Consumer Equilibrium Normal Goods Good X is a normal good if an increase (decrease) in income leads to an increase (decrease) in its consumption. Inferior Goods Good X is an inferior good if an increase (decrease) in income leads to a decrease (increase) in its consumption. 4-89 + 4-90 Normal Goods An increase in income increases the consumption of normal goods. Y M1/Y (M0 < M1). B Y1 M0/Y II A Y0 I 0 X0 M0/X X1 M1/X X + 4-91 Decomposing the Income and Substitution Effects Initially, bundle A is consumed. A decrease in the price of good X expands the consumer’s opportunity set. Y C The substitution effect (SE) causes the consumer to move from bundle A to B. A II A higher “real income” allows the consumer to achieve a higher indifference curve. The movement from bundle B to C represents the income effect (IE). The new equilibrium is achieved at point C. B I 0 IE SE X + 4-92 A Classic Marketing Application Other goods (Y) A buy-one, get-one free pizza deal. A C E D II I 0 0.5 1 2 B F Pizza (X) 4-93 Individual Demand Curve Y An individual’s demand curve is derived from each new equilibrium point found on the indifference curve as the price of good X is varied. II I X $ P0 D P1 X0 X1 X 4-94 Market Demand The market demand curve is the horizontal summation of individual demand curves. It indicates the total quantity all consumers would purchase at each price point. $ Individual Demand Curves $ Market Demand Curve 50 40 D1 1 2 D2 Q 1 2 3 DM Q + 4-95 Conclusion Indifference curve properties reveal information about consumers’ preferences between bundles of goods. Completeness. More is better. Diminishing marginal rate of substitution. Transitivity. Indifference curves along with price changes determine individuals’ demand curves. Market demand is the horizontal summation of individuals’ demands. +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 5 The Production Process and Costs McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + 5-97 Overview I. Production Analysis Total Product, Marginal Product, Average Product Isoquants Isocosts Cost Minimization II. Cost Analysis Total Cost, Variable Cost, Fixed Costs Cubic Cost Function Cost Relations + 5-98 Production Analysis Production Q = F(K,L) Function Q is quantity of output produced. K is capital input. L is labor input. F is a functional form relating the inputs to output. The maximum amount of output that can be produced with K units of capital and L units of labor. Short-Run Fixed vs. Long-Run Decisions vs. Variable Inputs 5-99 Production Function Algebraic Forms Linear production function: inputs are perfect substitutes. Q F K , L aK bL Leontief production function: inputs are used in fixed proportions. Q F K , L min bK , cL Cobb-Douglas production function: inputs have a degree of substitutability. Q F K , L K L a b + Productivity Measures: Total Product Total Product (TP): maximum output produced with given amounts of inputs. Example: Cobb-Douglas Production Function: Q = F(K,L) = K.5 L.5 K is fixed at 16 units. Short run Cobb-Douglass production function: Q = (16).5 L.5 = 4 L.5 Total Product when 100 units of labor are used? Q = 4 (100).5 = 4(10) = 40 units 5100 + Productivity Measures: Average Product of an Input Average Product of an Input: measure of output produced per unit of input. Average Product of Labor: APL = Q/L. Measures the output of an “average” worker. Example: Q = F(K,L) = K.5 L.5 If the inputs are K = 16 and L = 16, then the average product of labor is APL = [(16) 0.5(16)0.5]/16 = 1. Average Product of Capital: APK = Q/K. Measures the output of an “average” unit of capital. Example: Q = F(K,L) = K.5 L.5 If the inputs are K = 16 and L = 16, then the average product of capital is APK = [(16)0.5(16)0.5]/16 = 1. 5101 + Productivity Measures: Marginal Product of an Input Marginal Product on an Input: change in total output attributable to the last unit of an input. Marginal Product of Labor: MPL = Q/L Measures the output produced by the last worker. Slope of the short-run production function (with respect to labor). Marginal Product of Capital: MPK = Q/K Measures the output produced by the last unit of capital. When capital is allowed to vary in the short run, MPK is the slope of the production function (with respect to capital). 5102 Increasing, Diminishing and Negative Marginal Returns Q Increasin DiminishingNegative g Marginal Marginal Marginal Returns Returns Returns Q=F(K,L) MP AP L 5103 + Guiding the Production Process Producing on the production function Aligning incentives to induce maximum worker effort. Employing the right level of inputs When labor or capital vary in the short run, to maximize profit a manager will hire labor until the value of marginal product of labor equals the wage: VMPL = w, where VMPL = P x MPL. capital until the value of marginal product of capital equals the rental rate: VMPK = r, where VMPK = P x MPK . 5104 5105 Isoquant Illustrates the long-run combinations of inputs (K, L) that yield the producer the same level of output. The shape of an isoquant reflects the ease with which a producer can substitute among inputs while maintaining the same level of output. 5106 Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution (MRTS) The rate at which two inputs are substituted while maintaining the same output level. MRTS KL MPL MPK 5107 Linear Isoquants Capital and labor are perfect substitutes Q = aK + bL MRTSKL = b/a Linear isoquants imply that inputs are substituted at a constant rate, independent of the input levels employed. K Increasing Output Q1 Q2 Q3 L 5108 Leontief Isoquants Capital and labor are perfect K complements. Capital and labor are used in fixed-proportions. Q = min {bK, cL} Since capital and labor are consumed in fixed proportions there is no input substitution along isoquants (hence, no MRTSKL). Q3 Q2 Q1 Increasing Output L 5109 Cobb-Douglas Isoquants Inputs are not perfectly substitutable. Diminishing marginal rate of technical substitution. K Q3 Q2 Q1 Increasing Output As less of one input is used in the production process, increasingly more of the other input must be employed to produce the same output level. Q = KaLb MRTSKL = MPL/MPK L 5110 Isocost The combinations of inputs that K produce a given level of output at the same cost: C1/r wL + rK = C C0/r Rearranging, New Isocost Line associated with higher costs (C0 < C1). C C 0 C0/w C11/w K= (1/r)C - (w/r)L K For given input prices, isocosts farther from the origin are C/r associated with higher costs. Changes in input prices change the slope of the isocost line. L New Isocost Line for a decrease in the wage (price of labor: w0 > w1). C/w1 C/w0 L 5-111 + Cost Minimization Marginal product per dollar spent should be equal for all inputs: But, this is just MPL MPK MPL w w r MPK r MRTS KL w r + 5112 Cost Minimization K Slope of Isocost = Slope of Isoquant Point of Cost Minimizatio n Q L 5113 + Optimal Input Substitution A firm initially produces Q0 by employing the combination of inputs represented by point A at a cost of C0. Suppose w0 falls to w1. The isocost curve rotates counterclockwise; which represents the same cost level prior to the wage change. To produce the same level of output, Q0, the firm will produce on a lower isocost line (C1) at a point B. The slope of the new isocost line represents the lower wage relative to the rental rate of capital. K K0 K1 A B Q0 0 L0 L1 C0/w0 C1/w1 C0/w1L 5114 Cost Analysis Types of Costs Short-Run Fixed costs (FC) Sunk costs Short-run variable costs (VC) Short-run total costs (TC) Long-Run All costs are variable No fixed costs Total and Variable Costs C(Q): Minimum total cost $ of producing alternative levels of output: C(Q) = VC + FC VC( Q) C(Q) = VC(Q) + FC VC(Q): Costs that vary with output. FC: Costs that do not vary with output. 5115 F C 0 Q 5116 Fixed and Sunk Costs FC: Costs that do not change $ as output changes. Sunk Cost: A cost that is forever lost after it has been paid. Decision makers should ignore sunk costs to maximize profit or minimize losses C(Q) = VC + FC VC( Q) F C Q 5117 Some Definitions Average Total Cost ATC = AVC + AFC ATC = C(Q)/Q $ MC ATC AVC Average Variable Cost AVC = VC(Q)/Q MR Average Fixed Cost AFC = FC/Q Marginal Cost MC = C/Q AF C Q 5118 Fixed Cost Q0(ATC-AVC) $ = Q0 AFC = Q0(FC/ Q0) MC ATC AVC = FC ATC AFC Fixed Cost AVC Q0 Q 5119 Variable Cost $ Q0AVC = Q0[VC(Q0)/ Q0] = VC(Q0) MC ATC AVC AVC Variable Cost Minimum of AVC Q0 Q 5120 Total Cost Q0ATC $ = Q0[C(Q0)/ Q0] = C(Q0) MC ATC AVC ATC Minimum of ATC Total Cost Q0 Q + Cubic Cost Function C(Q) = f + a Q + b Q2 + cQ3 Marginal Cost? Memorize: MC(Q) = a + 2bQ + 3cQ2 Calculus: dC/dQ = a + 2bQ + 3cQ2 5121 + An Example Total Cost: C(Q) = 10 + Q + Q2 Variable cost function: VC(Q) = Q + Q2 Variable cost of producing 2 units: VC(2) = 2 + (2)2 = 6 Fixed costs: FC = 10 Marginal cost function: MC(Q) = 1 + 2Q Marginal cost of producing 2 units: MC(2) = 1 + 2(2) = 5 5122 5123 Long-Run Average Costs $ LRAC Economies of Scale Diseconomies of Scale Q* Q + Economies of Scope C(Q1, 0) + C(0, Q2) > C(Q1, Q2). It is cheaper to produce the two outputs jointly instead of separately. Example: It is cheaper for Time-Warner to produce Internet connections and Instant Messaging services jointly than separately. 5124 + 5125 Cost Complementarity The marginal cost of producing good 1 declines as more of good two is produced: MC Q1,Q2) /Q 1 Example: Cow hides and steaks. 2 < 0. + Conclusion To maximize profits (minimize costs) managers must use inputs such that the value of marginal of each input reflects price the firm must pay to employ the input. The optimal mix of inputs is achieved when the MRTSKL = (w/r). Cost functions are the foundation for helping to determine profit-maximizing behavior in future chapters. 5126 +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8 Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + Overview I. Perfect Competition Characteristics and profit outlook. Effect of new entrants. II. Monopolies Sources of monopoly power. Maximizing monopoly profits. Pros and cons. III. Monopolistic Competition Profit maximization. Long run equilibrium. 8128 8129 Perfect Competition Environment Many buyers and sellers. Homogeneous (identical) product. Perfect information on both sides of market. No transaction costs. Free entry and exit. 8130 Key Implications Firms are “price takers” (P = MR). In the short-run, firms may earn profits or losses. Entry and exit forces long-run profits to zero. + Unrealistic? Why Learn? 8131 Many small businesses are “price-takers,” and decision rules for such firms are similar to those of perfectly competitive firms. It is a useful benchmark. Explains why governments oppose monopolies. Illuminates the “danger” to managers of competitive environments. Importance of product differentiation. Sustainable advantage. Managing a Perfectly Competitive Firm (or Price-Taking Business) 8132 8133 Setting Price $ $ S Pe Df D QM Market Firm Qf 8134 Profit-Maximizing Output Decision MR = MC. Since, MR = P, Set P = MC to maximize profits. Graphically: Representative Firm’s Output Decision Profit = (Pe - ATC) Qf* MC $ ATC AVC Pe = Df = MR Pe ATC Qf* Qf 8135 A Numerical Example + Given P=$10 C(Q) = 5 + Q2 Optimal Price? P=$10 Optimal Output? MR = P = $10 and MC = 2Q 10 = 2Q Q = 5 units Maximum Profits? PQ - C(Q) = (10)(5) - (5 + 25) = $20 8136 8137 + Should this Firm Sustain Short Run Losses or Shut Down? Profit = (Pe - ATC) Qf* < 0 ATC MC $ AVC ATC Pe Loss Pe = Df = MR Qf* Qf + Shutdown Decision Rule A profit-maximizing firm should continue to operate (sustain short-run losses) if its operating loss is less than its fixed costs. Operating results in a smaller loss than ceasing operations. Decision rule: A firm should shutdown when P < min AVC. Continue operating as long as P ≥ min AVC. 8138 + Firm’s Short-Run Supply Curve: MC Above Min AVC ATC MC $ AVC P min AVC Qf* Qf 8139 + Short-Run Market Supply Curve 8140 The market supply curve is the summation of each individual firm’s supply at each price. P Firm 1 Market Firm 2 P P S1 S2 SM 15 5 10 18 Q 20 25 Q 30 43Q + Long Run Adjustments? If firms are price takers but there are barriers to entry, profits will persist. If the industry is perfectly competitive, firms are not only price takers but there is free entry. Other “greedy capitalists” enter the market. 8141 + 8142 Effect of Entry on Price? $ $ S Entry S* Pe Pe* Df Df* D QM Market Firm Qf Effect of Entry on the Firm’s Output and Profits? MC $ AC Pe Df Pe* Df* QL Qf* Q 8143 + 8144 Summary of Logic Short run profits leads to entry. Entry increases market supply, drives down the market price, increases the market quantity. Demand for individual firm’s product shifts down. Firm reduces output to maximize profit. Long run profits are zero. + Features of Long Run Competitive Equilibrium P = MC Socially efficient output. P = minimum AC Efficient plant size. Zero profits Firms are earning just enough to offset their opportunity cost. 8145 8146 Monopoly Environment Single firm serves the “relevant market.” Most monopolies are “local” monopolies. The demand for the firm’s product is the market demand curve. Firm has control over price. But the price charged affects the quantity demanded of the monopolist’s product. + 8147 “Natural” Sources of Monopoly Power Economies of scale Economies of scope Cost complementarities 8148 “Created” Sources of Monopoly Power Patents and other legal barriers (like licenses) Tying contracts Exclusive contracts Collusion Contract... I. II. III. 8149 Managing a Monopoly Market power permits you to price above MC Is the sky the limit? No. How much you sell depends on the price you set! 8150 A Monopolist’s Marginal Revenue P 100 TR Unit elastic Elastic Unit elastic 1200 60 Inelastic 40 800 20 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 30 40 MR Elastic Inelastic 50 Q Monopoly Profit Maximization Produce where MR = MC. Charge the price on the demand curve that corresponds to that quantity. MC $ ATC Profit PM ATC D QM MR Q 8151 + Alternative Profit Computation Total Revenue - Total Cost P Q Total Cost P Q Total Cost Q Q Total Cost P Q Q Q P ATC P ATC Q 8152 8153 Useful Formulae What’s the MR if a firm faces a linear demand curve for its product? P a bQ MR a 2bQ, where b 0. 1 E Alternatively, MR P E A Numerical Example + Given estimates of P = 10 - Q C(Q) = 6 + 2Q Optimal output? MR = 10 - 2Q MC = 2 10 - 2Q = 2 Q = 4 units Optimal price? P = 10 - (4) = $6 Maximum profits? PQ - C(Q) = (6)(4) - (6 + 8) = $10 8154 8155 Long Run Adjustments? None, unless the source of monopoly power is eliminated. 8156 Why Government Dislikes Monopoly? P > MC Too little output, at too high a price. Deadweight monopoly. loss of 8157 + Deadweight Loss of Monopoly $ MC Deadweight Loss of Monopoly ATC PM D MC QM MR Q + Arguments for Monopoly The beneficial effects of economies of scale, economies of scope, and cost complementarities on price and output may outweigh the negative effects of market power. Encourages innovation. 8158 8159 Monopolistic Competition: Environment and Implications Numerous buyers and sellers Differentiated products Implication: Since products are differentiated, each firm faces a downward sloping demand curve. Consumers view differentiated products as close substitutes: there exists some willingness to substitute. Free entry and exit Implication: Firms will earn zero profits in the long run. Managing a Monopolistically Competitive Firm Like a monopoly, monopolistically competitive firms have market power that permits pricing above marginal cost. level of sales depends on the price it sets. But … The presence of other brands in the market makes the demand for your brand more elastic than if you were a monopolist. Free entry and exit impacts profitability. Therefore, monopolistically competitive firms have limited market power. 8160 8161 Marginal Revenue Like a Monopolist P 100 TR Unit elastic Elastic Unit elastic 1200 60 Inelastic 40 800 20 0 10 20 30 40 50 Q 0 10 20 30 40 MR Elastic Inelastic 50 Q + Monopolistic Competition: Profit Maximization Maximize profits like a monopolist Produce output where MR = MC. Charge the price on the demand curve that corresponds to that quantity. 8162 Short-Run Monopolistic Competition MC $ ATC Profit PM ATC D QM MR Quantity of Brand X 8163 + Long Run Adjustments? If the industry is truly monopolistically competitive, there is free entry. In this case other “greedy capitalists” enter, and their new brands steal market share. This reduces the demand for your product until profits are ultimately zero. 8164 + Long-Run Monopolistic Competition Long Run Equilibrium (P = AC, so zero profits) $ MC AC P* P1 Entry MR Q1 Q* MR1 D D1 Quantity of Brand X 8165 8166 Monopolistic Competition The Good (To Consumers) Product Variety The Bad (To Society) P > MC Excess capacity Unexploited economies of scale The Ugly (To Managers) P = ATC > minimum of average costs. Zero Profits (in the long run)! + Maximizing Profits: A Synthesizing Example C(Q) = 125 + 4Q2 Determine the profit-maximizing output and price, and discuss its implications, if 8167 You are a price taker and other firms charge $40 per unit; You are a monopolist and the inverse demand for your product is P = 100 - Q; You are a monopolistically competitive firm and the inverse demand for your brand is P = 100 – Q. + Marginal Cost C(Q) = 125 + 4Q2, So MC = 8Q. This is independent of market structure. 8168 Price Taker + MR = P = $40. Set MR = MC. 40 = 8Q. Q = 5 units. Cost of producing 5 units. C(Q) = 125 + 4Q2 = 125 + 100 = $225. Revenues: PQ = (40)(5) = $200. Maximum profits of -$25. Implications: Expect exit in the long-run. 8169 Monopoly/Monopolistic Competition + MR = 100 - 2Q (since P = 100 - Q). Set MR = MC, or 100 - 2Q = 8Q. Optimal output: Q = 10. Optimal price: P = 100 - (10) = $90. Maximal profits: PQ - C(Q) = (90)(10) -(125 + 4(100)) = $375. Implications Monopolist will not face entry (unless patent or other entry barriers are eliminated). Monopolistically competitive firm should expect other firms to clone, so profits will decline over time. 8170 Conclusion + 8171 Firms operating in a perfectly competitive market take the market price as given. Produce output where P = MC. Firms may earn profits or losses in the short run. … but, in the long run, entry or exit forces profits to zero. A monopoly firm, in contrast, can earn persistent profits provided that source of monopoly power is not eliminated. A monopolistically competitive firm can earn profits in the short run, but entry by competing brands will erode these profits over time. +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9 Basic Oligopoly Models McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + Overview I. Conditions for Oligopoly? II. Role of Strategic Interdependence III. Profit Maximization in Four Oligopoly Settings Sweezy (Kinked-Demand) Model Cournot Model Stackelberg Model Bertrand Model 9173 + 9174 Oligopoly Environment Relatively few firms, usually Duopoly - two firms Triopoly - three firms less than 10. The products firms offer can be either differentiated or homogeneous. Firms’ decisions impact one another. Many different strategic variables are modeled: No single oligopoly model. 9175 Role of Strategic Interaction Your actions affect the profits of your rivals. Your rivals’ actions affect your profits. How will rivals respond to your actions? 9176 + An Example You and another firm sell differentiated products. How does the quantity demanded for your product change when you change your price? 9177 + P D2 (Rival matches your price change) PH P0 PL D1 (Rival holds its price constant) QH1 QH2 Q0 QL2 QL1 Q 9178 + P D2 (Rival matches your price change) Demand if Rivals Match Price Reductions but not Price Increases P0 D1 D Q0 (Rival holds its price constant) Q + 9179 Key Insight The effect of a price reduction on the quantity demanded of your product depends upon whether your rivals respond by cutting their prices too! The effect of a price increase on the quantity demanded of your product depends upon whether your rivals respond by raising their prices too! Strategic interdependence: You aren’t in complete control of your own destiny! + Sweezy (Kinked-Demand) Model Environment Few firms in the market serving many consumers. Firms produce differentiated products. Barriers to entry. Each firm believes rivals will match (or follow) price reductions, but won’t match (or follow) price increases. Key feature of Sweezy Model Price-Rigidity. 9180 + Sweezy Demand and Marginal Revenue P D2 (Rival matches your price change) DS: Sweezy Demand P0 D1 (Rival holds its price constant) MR1 MR2 MRS: Sweezy MR Q0 Q 9181 + Sweezy Profit-Maximizing Decision P D2 (Rival matches your price change) MC1 MC2 MC3 P0 D1 (Rival holds price constant) MRS Q0 DS: Sweezy Demand Q 9182 9183 + Sweezy Oligopoly Summary Firms believe rivals match price cuts, but not price increases. Firms operating in a Sweezy oligopoly maximize profit by producing where MRS = MC. The kinked-shaped marginal revenue curve implies that there exists a range over which changes in MC will not impact the profit-maximizing level of output. Therefore, the firm may have no incentive to change price provided that marginal cost remains in a given range. + Cournot Model Environment A few firms produce goods that are either perfect substitutes (homogeneous) or imperfect substitutes (differentiated). Firms’ control variable is output in contrast to price. Each firm believes their rivals will hold output constant if it changes its own output (The output of rivals is viewed as given or “fixed”). Barriers to entry exist. 9184 9185 Inverse Demand in a Cournot Duopoly Market demand in a homogeneous-product Cournot duopoly is P a bQ1 Q2 Thus, each firm’s marginal revenue depends on the output produced by the other firm. More formally, MR a bQ 2bQ 1 2 1 MR2 a bQ1 2bQ2 + Best-Response Function Since a firm’s marginal revenue in a homogeneous Cournot oligopoly depends on both its output and its rivals, each firm needs a way to “respond” to rival’s output decisions. Firm 1’s best-response (or reaction) function is a schedule summarizing the amount of Q1 firm 1 should produce in order to maximize its profits for each quantity of Q2 produced by firm 2. Since the products are substitutes, an increase in firm 2’s output leads to a decrease in the profitmaximizing amount of firm 1’s product. 9186 9187 Best-Response Function for a Cournot Duopoly To find a firm’s best-response function, equate its marginal revenue to marginal cost and solve for its output as a function of its rival’s output. Firm MC) Firm MC) 1’s best-response function is (c1 is firm 1’s Q1 r1 Q2 a c1 1 Q2 2b 2 2’s best-response function is (c2 is firm 2’s a c2 1 Q2 r2 Q1 Q1 2b 2 + Graph of Firm 1’s Best-Response Function 9188 Q2 (a-c1)/b Q1 = r1(Q2) = (a-c1)/2b - 0.5Q2 Q2 r1 (Firm 1’s Reaction Function) Q1 Q1M Q1 + Cournot Equilibrium Situation where each firm produces the output that maximizes its profits, given the the output of rival firms. No firm can gain by unilaterally changing its own output to improve its profit. A point where the two firm’s best-response functions intersect. 9189 9190 + Graph of Cournot Equilibrium Q2 (a-c1)/b r1 Cournot Equilibrium M Q2 Q2* r2 Q1* Q1M (a-c2)/b Q1 + Summary of Cournot Equilibrium The output Q1* maximizes firm 1’s profits, given that firm 2 produces Q2*. The output Q2* maximizes firm 2’s profits, given that firm 1 produces Q1*. Neither firm has an incentive to change its output, given the output of the rival. Beliefs are consistent: In equilibrium, each firm “thinks” rivals will stick to their current output – and they do! 9191 + Stackelberg Model Environment Few firms serving many consumers. Firms produce differentiated or homogeneous products. Barriers Firm to entry. one is the leader. The leader commits to an output before all other firms. Remaining firms are followers. They choose their outputs so as to maximize profits, given the leader’s output. 9192 9193 The Algebra of the Stackelberg Model Since the follower reacts to the leader’s output, the follower’s output is determined by its reaction function a c2 Q2 r2 Q1 0.5Q1 2b The Stackelberg leader uses this reaction function to determine its profit maximizing output level, which simplifies a c2 2c1 to Q1 2b + Stackelberg Summary Stackelberg model illustrates how commitment can enhance profits in strategic environments. Leader produces more than the Cournot equilibrium output. Larger market share, higher profits. First-mover advantage. Follower produces less than the Cournot equilibrium output. Smaller market share, lower profits. 9194 + 9195 Bertrand Model Environment Few firms that sell to many consumers. Firms produce identical products at constant marginal cost. Each firm independently sets its price in order to maximize profits (price is each firms’ control variable). Barriers to entry exist. Consumers enjoy Perfect information. Zero transaction costs. + Bertrand Equilibrium Firms set P1 = P2 = MC! Why? Suppose MC < P1 < P2. Firm 1 earns (P1 - MC) on each unit sold, while firm 2 earns nothing. Firm 2 has an incentive to slightly undercut firm 1’s price to capture the entire market. Firm 1 then has an incentive to undercut firm 2’s price. This undercutting continues... Equilibrium: Each firm charges P1 = P2 = MC. 9196 + Conclusion Different oligopoly scenarios give rise to different optimal strategies and different outcomes. Your optimal price and output depends on … Beliefs about the reactions of rivals. Your choice variable (P or Q) and the nature of the product market (differentiated or homogeneous products). Your ability to credibly commit prior to your rivals. 9197 + Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 10 Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. + Game Environments Players’ planned decisions are called strategies. Payoffs to players are the profits or losses resulting from strategies. Order of play is important: Simultaneous-move game: each player makes decisions with knowledge of other players’ decisions. Sequential-move game: one player observes its rival’s move prior to selecting a strategy. Frequency of rival interaction One-shot game: game is played once. Repeated game: game is played more than once; either a finite or infinite number of interactions. 10199 + Simultaneous-Move, One-Shot Games: Normal Form Game A Normal Form Game consists of: Set of players i ∈ {1, 2, … n} where n is a finite number. Each players strategy set or feasible actions consist of a finite number of strategies. Player 1’s strategies are S1 = {a, b, c, …}. Player 2’s strategies are S2 = {A, B, C, …}. Payoffs. Player 1’s payoff: π1(a,B) = 11. Player 2’s payoff: π2(b,C) = 12. 10200 10-201 + Real World Examples of Collusion Garbage Collection Industry OPEC NASDAQ Airlines + 10-202 Pricing to Prevent Entry: An Application of Game Theory Two firms: an incumbent and potential entrant. Potential entrant’s strategies: Enter. Stay Out. Incumbent’s strategies: {if enter, play hard}. {if enter, play soft}. {if stay out, play hard}. {if stay out, play soft}. Move Sequence: Entrant moves first. Incumbent observes entrant’s action and selects an action. + The Pricing to Prevent Entry Game in Extensive Form -1, 1 Hard Incumbent Enter Soft 5, 5 Entrant Out 0, 10 10-203 10-204 + Identify Nash and Subgame Perfect Equilibria -1, 1 Hard Incumbent Enter Soft 5, 5 Entrant Out 0, 10 10-205 + Two Nash Equilibria -1, 1 Hard Incumbent Enter Soft 5, 5 Entrant Out 0, 10 Nash Equilibria Strategies {player 1; player 2}: {enter; If enter, play soft} {stay out; If enter, play hard} + One Subgame Perfect Equilibrium -1, 1 Hard Incumbent Enter Soft 5, 5 Entrant Out 0, 10 Subgame Perfect Equilibrium Strategy: {enter; If enter, play soft} 10-206 + 10-207 Insights Establishing a reputation for being unkind to entrants can enhance long-term profits. It is costly to do so in the short-term, so much so that it isn’t optimal to do so in a one-shot game. +Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power McGraw-Hill/Irwin Michael R. Baye, Managerial Economics and Business Strategy Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 11209 + Overview I. Basic Pricing Strategies Monopoly & Monopolistic Competition Cournot Oligopoly II. Extracting Consumer Surplus Price Discrimination Two-Part Pricing Block Pricing Commodity Bundling III. Pricing for Special Cost and Demand Structures Peak-Load Pricing Cross Subsidies Transfer Pricing IV. Pricing in Markets with Intense Price Competition Price Matching Brand Loyalty Randomized Pricing + Standard Pricing and Profits for Firms with Market Power Price Profits from standard pricing = $8 10 8 6 4 MC 2 P = 10 - 2Q 1 2 3 4 5 MR = 10 - 4Q Quantity 11210 + 11211 An Algebraic Example P = 10 - 2Q C(Q) = 2Q If the firm must charge a single price to all consumers, the profit-maximizing price is obtained by setting MR = MC. 10 - 4Q = 2, so Q* = 2. P* = 10 - 2(2) = 6. Profits = (6)(2) - 2(2) = $8. A Simple Markup Rule + Suppose the elasticity of demand for the firm’s product is EF. Since MR = P[1 + EF]/ EF. Setting MR = MC and simplifying yields this simple pricing formula: P = [EF/(1+ EF)] MC. The optimal price is a simple markup over relevant costs! More elastic the demand, lower markup. Less elastic the demand, higher markup. 11212 An Example + Elasticity of demand for Kodak film is -2. P = [EF/(1+ EF)] MC P = [-2/(1 - 2)] MC P = 2 MC Price is twice marginal cost. Fifty percent of Kodak’s price is margin above manufacturing costs. 11213 + Markup Rule for Cournot Oligopoly Homogeneous N product Cournot oligopoly. = total number of firms in the industry. Market elasticity of demand EM . Elasticity of individual firm’s demand is given by EF = N x EM. Since P = [EF/(1+ EF)] MC, Then, P The = [NEM/(1+ NEM)] MC. greater the number of firms, the lower the profit-maximizing markup factor. 11214 An Example + Homogeneous firms. MC product Cournot industry, 3 = $10. Elasticity of market demand = - ½. Determine EF 11215 the profit-maximizing price? = N EM = 3 (-1/2) = -1.5. P = [EF/(1+ EF)] MC. P = [-1.5/(1- 1.5] $10. P = 3 $10 = $30. + Extracting Consumer Surplus: Moving From Single Price Markets Most models examined to this point involve a “single” equilibrium price. In reality, there are many different prices being charged in the market. Price discrimination is the practice of charging different prices to consumer for the same good to achieve higher prices. The three basic forms of price discrimination are: First-degree (or perfect) price discrimination. Second-degree price discrimination. Third-degree price discrimiation. 11216 + First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimination Practice of charging each consumer the maximum amount he or she will pay for each incremental unit. Permits a firm to extract all surplus from consumers. 11217 11218 Perfect Price Discrimination + Price Profits*: .5(4-0)(10 - 2) = $16 10 8 6 4 Total Cost* = $8 2 MC D 1 * Assuming no fixed costs 2 3 4 5 Quantity + Caveats: In practice, transactions costs and information constraints make this difficult to implement perfectly (but car dealers and some professionals come close). Price discrimination won’t work if consumers can resell the good. 11219 11220 Second-Degree Price Discrimination The practice of posting a discrete schedule of declining prices for different quantities. Eliminates the information constraint present in first-degree price discrimination. Price MC $10 $8 $5 Example: Electric utilities D 2 4 Quantity + Third-Degree Price Discrimination The practice of charging different groups of consumers different prices for the same product. Group must have observable characteristics for third-degree price discrimination to work. Examples include student discounts, senior citizen’s discounts, regional & international pricing. 11221 + Implementing Third-Degree Price Discrimination Suppose the total demand for a product is comprised of two groups with different elasticities, E1 < E2. Notice that group 1 is more price sensitive than group 2. Profit-maximizing P1 prices? = [E1/(1+ E1)] MC P2 = [E2/(1+ E2)] MC 11222 An Example + Suppose the elasticity of demand for Kodak film in the US is EU = -1.5, and the elasticity of demand in Japan is EJ = -2.5. Marginal PU $9 cost of manufacturing film is $3. = [EU/(1+ EU)] MC = [-1.5/(1 - 1.5)] $3 = = [EJ/(1+ EJ)] MC = [-2.5/(1 - 2.5)] $3 = $5 PJ Kodak’s optimal third-degree pricing strategy is to charge a higher price in the US, where demand is less elastic. 11223 + 11224 Two-Part Pricing When it isn’t feasible to charge different prices for different units sold, but demand information is known, two-part pricing may permit you to extract all surplus from consumers. Two-part pricing consists of a fixed fee and a per unit charge. Example: Athletic club memberships. 11225 How Two-Part Pricing Works 1. Set price at marginal cost. Price 2. Compute consumer surplus. 10 3. Charge a fixed-fee equal to consumer surplus. 8 6 Per Unit Charge Fixed Fee = Profits* = $16 4 MC 2 D * Assuming no fixed costs 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity + Block Pricing The practice of packaging multiple units of an identical product together and selling them as one package. Examples Paper. Six-packs of soda. Different sized of cans of green beans. 11226 + An Algebraic Example Typical consumer’s demand is P = 10 - 2Q C(Q) = 2Q Optimal number of units in a package? Optimal package price? 11227 11228 + Optimal Quantity To Package: 4 Units Price 10 8 6 4 MC = AC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity 11229 + Optimal Price for the Package: $24 Price Consumer’s valuation of 4 units = .5(8)(4) + (2)(4) = $24 Therefore, set P = $24! 10 8 6 4 MC = AC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity 11230 + Costs and Profits with Block Pricing Price 10 Profits* = [.5(8)(4) + (2)(4)] – (2)(4) = $16 8 6 Costs = (2)(4) = $8 4 2 D 1 * Assuming no fixed costs 2 3 4 5 MC = AC Quantity + Commodity Bundling The practice of bundling two or more products together and charging one price for the bundle. Examples Vacation packages. Computers and software. Film and developing. 11231 + An Example that Illustrates Kodak’s Moment Total market size for film and developing is 4 million consumers. Four types of consumers 25% will use only Kodak film (F). 25% will use only Kodak developing (D). 25% will use only Kodak film and use only Kodak developing (FD). 25% have no preference (N). Zero costs (for simplicity). Maximum price each type of consumer will pay is as follows: 11232 + Reservation Prices for Kodak Film and Developing by Type of Consumer Type F FD D N Film Developing $8 $3 $8 $4 $4 $6 $3 $2 11233 + Optimal Film Price? Type F FD D N Film Developing $8 $3 $8 $4 $4 $6 $3 $2 Optimal Price is $8; only types F and FD buy resulting in profits of $8 x 2 million = $16 Million. At a price of $4, only types F, FD, and D will buy (profits of $12 Million). At a price of $3, all will types will buy (profits of $12 Million). 11234 + Optimal Price for Developing? Type F FD D N 11235 Film Developing $8 $3 $8 $4 $4 $6 $3 $2 At a price of $6, only “D” type buys (profits of $6 Million). At a price of $4, only “D” and “FD” types buy (profits of $8 Million). At a price of $2, all types buy (profits of $8 Million). Optimal Price is $3, to earn profits of $3 x 3 million = $9 Million. + Total Profits by Pricing Each Item Separately? Type F FD D N Film Developing $8 $3 $8 $4 $4 $6 $3 $2 Total Profit = Film Profits + Development Profits = $16 Million + $9 Million = $25 Million Surprisingly, the firm can earn even greater profits by bundling! 11236 + Pricing a “Bundle” of Film and Developing 11237 + Consumer Valuations of a Bundle Type F FD D N Film $8 $8 $4 $3 Developing Value of Bundle $3 $11 $4 $12 $6 $10 $2 $5 11238 + What’s the Optimal Price for a Bundle? Type F FD D N Film $8 $8 $4 $3 Developing Value of Bundle $3 $11 $4 $12 $6 $10 $2 $5 Optimal Bundle Price = $10 (for profits of $30 million) 11239 11240 Peak-Load Pricing When demand during peak times is higher than the capacity of the firm, the firm should engage in peak-load pricing. Charge a higher price (PH) during peak times (DH). Charge a lower price (PL) during off-peak times (DL). Price MC PH DH PL MRH MRL QL DL QH Quantity + Cross-Subsidies Prices charged for one product are subsidized by the sale of another product. May be profitable when there are significant demand complementarities effects. Examples Browser and server software. Drinks and meals at restaurants. 11241 + Double Marginalization Consider a large firm with two divisions: the upstream division is the sole provider of a key input. the downstream division uses the input produced by the upstream division to produce the final output. Incentives to maximize divisional profits leads the upstream manager to produce where MRU = MCU. Implication: PU > MCU. Similarly, when the downstream division has market power and has an incentive to maximize divisional profits, the manager will produce where MRD = MCD. Implication: PD > MCD. Thus, both divisions mark price up over marginal cost resulting in in a phenomenon called double marginalization. Result: less than optimal overall profits for the firm. 11242 + 11243 Transfer Pricing To overcome double marginalization, the internal price at which an upstream division sells inputs to a downstream division should be set in order to maximize the overall firm profits. To achieve this goal, the upstream division produces such that its marginal cost, MCu, equals the net marginal revenue to the downstream division (NMRd): NMRd = MRd - MCd = MCu + Upstream Division’s Problem Demand C(Q) for the final product P = 10 - 2Q. = 2Q. Suppose the upstream manager sets MR = MC to maximize profits. 10 P* - 4Q = 2, so Q* = 2. = 10 - 2(2) = $6, so upstream manager charges the downstream division $6 per unit. 11244 + 11245 Downstream Division’s Problem Demand for the final product P = 10 - 2Q. Downstream division’s marginal cost is the $6 charged by the upstream division. Downstream profits. 10 P* division sets MR = MC to maximize - 4Q = 6, so Q* = 1. = 10 - 2(1) = $8, so downstream division charges $8 per unit. + Analysis This pricing strategy by the upstream division results in less than optimal profits! The upstream division needs the price to be $6 and the quantity sold to be 2 units in order to maximize profits. Unfortunately, The downstream division sets price at $8, which is too high; only 1 unit is sold at that price. Downstream division profits are $8 1 – 6(1) = $2. upstream division’s profits are $6 1 - 2(1) = $4 instead of the monopoly profits of $6 2 - 2(2) = $8. The Overall firm profit is $4 + $2 = $6. 11246 11247 + Upstream Division’s “Monopoly Profits” Price Profit = $8 10 8 6 4 2 MC = AC P = 10 - 2Q 1 2 3 4 MR = 10 - 4Q 5 Quantity 11248 + Upstream’s Profits when Downstream Marks Price Up to Price $8 Downstream Price Profit = $4 10 8 6 4 2 MC = AC P = 10 - 2Q 1 2 3 4 MR = 10 - 4Q 5 Quantity 11249 Solutions for the Overall Firm? Provide upstream manager with an incentive to set the optimal transfer price of $2 (upstream division’s marginal cost). Overall profit with optimal transfer price: $6 2 $2 2 $8 + Pricing in Markets with Intense Price Competition Price Matching Advertising a price and a promise to match any lower price offered by a competitor. No firm has an incentive to lower their prices. Each firm charges the monopoly price and shares the market. Induce brand loyalty Some consumers will remain “loyal” to a firm; even in the face of price cuts. Advertising campaigns and “frequent-user” style programs can help firms induce loyal among consumers. Randomized 11250 Pricing A strategy of constantly changing prices. Decreases consumers’ incentive to shop around as they cannot learn from experience which firm charges the lowest price. Reduces the ability of rival firms to undercut a firm’s prices. Conclusion + First degree price discrimination, block pricing, and two part pricing permit a firm to extract all consumer surplus. Commodity bundling, second-degree and third degree price discrimination permit a firm to extract some (but not all) consumer surplus. Simple markup rules are the easiest to implement, but leave consumers with the most surplus and may result in double-marginalization. Different strategies require different information. 11251