10 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER TEN PART III Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return THE EXPLOITATION OF security mispricing in such a way that risk-free profits can be earned is called arbitrage. It involves the simultaneous purchase and sale of equivalent securities in order to profit from discrepancies in their prices. Perhaps the most basic principle of capital market theory is that equilibrium market prices are rational in that they rule out arbitrage opportunities. If actual security prices allow for arbitrage, the result will be strong pressure to restore equilibrium. Therefore, security markets ought to satisfy a “no-arbitrage condition.” In this chapter, we show how such no-arbitrage conditions together with the factor model introduced in Chapter 8 allow us to generalize the security market line of the CAPM to gain richer insight into the risk–return relationship. We begin by showing how the decomposition of risk into market versus firm-specific influences that we introduced in earlier chapters can be extended to deal with the multifaceted nature of systematic risk. Multifactor models of security returns can be used to measure and manage exposure to each of many economywide factors such as business-cycle risk, interest or inflation rate bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 324 risk, energy price risk, and so on. These models also lead us to a multifactor version of the security market line in which risk premiums derive from exposure to multiple risk sources, each with their own risk premium. We show how factor models combined with a no-arbitrage condition lead to a simple relationship between expected return and risk. This approach to the risk–return tradeoff is called arbitrage pricing theory, or APT. In a single-factor market where there are no extra-market risk factors, the APT leads to a mean return–beta equation identical to that of the CAPM. In a multifactor market with one or more extra-market risk factors, the APT delivers a mean-beta equation similar to Merton’s intertemporal extension of the CAPM (his ICAPM). We ask next what factors are likely to be the most important sources of risk. These will be the factors generating substantial hedging demands that brought us to the multifactor CAPM introduced in Chapter 9. Both the APT and the CAPM therefore can lead to multiple-risk versions of the security market line, thereby enriching the insights we can derive about the risk–return relationship. 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 325 10.1 Multifactor Models: An Overview The index model introduced in Chapter 8 gave us a way of decomposing stock variability into market or systematic risk, due largely to macroeconomic events, versus firm-specific or idiosyncratic effects that can be diversified in large portfolios. In the single-index model, the return on a broad market-index portfolio summarized the impact of the macro factor. In Chapter 9 we introduced the possibility that asset-risk premiums may also depend on correlations with extra-market risk factors, such as inflation, or changes in the parameters describing future investment opportunities: interest rates, volatility, market-risk premiums, and betas. For example, returns on an asset whose return increases when inflation increases can be used to hedge uncertainty in the future inflation rate. Its risk premium may fall as a result of investors’ extra demand for this asset. Risk premiums of individual securities should reflect their sensitivities to changes in extra-market risk factors just as their betas on the market index determine their risk premiums in the simple CAPM. When securities can be used to hedge these factors, the resulting hedging demands will make the SML multifactor, with each risk source that can be hedged adding an additional factor to the SML. Risk factors can be represented either by returns on these hedge portfolios (just as the index portfolio represents the market factor), or more directly by changes in the risk factors themselves, for example, changes in interest rates or inflation. Factor Models of Security Returns We begin with a familiar single-factor model like the one introduced in Chapter 8. Uncertainty in asset returns has two sources: a common or macroeconomic factor and firmspecific events. The common factor is constructed to have zero expected value, because we use it to measure new information concerning the macroeconomy, which, by definition, has zero expected value. If we call F the deviation of the common factor from its expected value, bi the sensitivity of firm i to that factor, and ei the firm-specific disturbance, the factor model states that the actual excess return on firm i will equal its initially expected value plus a (zero expected value) random amount attributable to unanticipated economywide events, plus another (zero expected value) random amount attributable to firm-specific events. Formally, the single-factor model of excess returns is described by Equation 10.1: Ri 5 E (Ri ) 1 bi F 1 ei (10.1) where E(Ri ) is the expected excess return on stock i. Notice that if the macro factor has a value of 0 in any particular period (i.e., no macro surprises), the excess return on the security will equal its previously expected value, E(Ri ), plus the effect of firm-specific events only. The nonsystematic components of returns, the eis, are assumed to be uncorrelated across stocks and with the factor F. Example 10.1 Factor Models To make the factor model more concrete, consider an example. Suppose that the macro factor, F, is taken to be news about the state of the business cycle, measured by the unexpected percentage change in gross domestic product (GDP), and that the consensus is that GDP will increase by 4% this year. Suppose also that a stock’s b value is 1.2. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 325 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 326 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets If GDP increases by only 3%, then the value of F would be 21%, representing a 1% disappointment in actual growth versus expected growth. Given the stock’s beta value, this disappointment would translate into a return on the stock that is 1.2% lower than previously expected. This macro surprise, together with the firm-specific disturbance, ei, determines the total departure of the stock’s return from its originally expected value. CONCEPT CHECK 10.1 Suppose you currently expect the stock in Example 10.1 to earn a 10% rate of return. Then some macroeconomic news suggests that GDP growth will come in at 5% instead of 4%. How will you revise your estimate of the stock’s expected rate of return? The factor model’s decomposition of returns into systematic and firm-specific components is compelling, but confining systematic risk to a single factor is not. Indeed, when we motivated systematic risk as the source of risk premiums in Chapter 9, we noted that extra market sources of risk may arise from a number of sources such as uncertainty about interest rates, inflation, and so on. The market return reflects macro factors as well as the average sensitivity of firms to those factors. It stands to reason that a more explicit representation of systematic risk, allowing for different stocks to exhibit different sensitivities to its various components, would constitute a useful refinement of the single-factor model. It is easy to see that models that allow for several factors—multifactor models—can provide better descriptions of security returns. Apart from their use in building models of equilibrium security pricing, multifactor models are useful in risk management applications. These models give us a simple way to measure investor exposure to various macroeconomic risks and construct portfolios to hedge those risks. Let’s start with a two-factor model. Suppose the two most important macroeconomic sources of risk are uncertainties surrounding the state of the business cycle, news of which we will again measure by unanticipated growth in GDP and changes in interest rates. We will denote by IR any unexpected change in interest rates. The return on any stock will respond both to sources of macro risk and to its own firm-specific influences. We can write a two-factor model describing the excess return on stock i in some time period as follows: Ri 5 E (Ri ) 1 biGDPGDP 1 biIRIR 1 ei (10.2) The two macro factors on the right-hand side of the equation comprise the systematic factors in the economy. As in the single-factor model, both of these macro factors have zero expectation: They represent changes in these variables that have not already been anticipated. The coefficients of each factor in Equation 10.2 measure the sensitivity of share returns to that factor. For this reason the coefficients are sometimes called factor loadings or, equivalently, factor betas. An increase in interest rates is bad news for most firms, so we would expect interest rate betas generally to be negative. As before, ei reflects firmspecific influences. To illustrate the advantages of multifactor models, consider two firms, one a regulated electric-power utility in a mostly residential area, the other an airline. Because residential demand for electricity is not very sensitive to the business cycle, the utility has a low beta bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 326 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 327 on GDP. But the utility’s stock price may have a relatively high sensitivity to interest rates. Because the cash flow generated by the utility is relatively stable, its present value behaves much like that of a bond, varying inversely with interest rates. Conversely, the performance of the airline is very sensitive to economic activity but is less sensitive to interest rates. It will have a high GDP beta and a lower interest rate beta. Suppose that on a particular day, a news item suggests that the economy will expand. GDP is expected to increase, but so are interest rates. Is the “macro news” on this day good or bad? For the utility, this is bad news: Its dominant sensitivity is to rates. But for the airline, which responds more to GDP, this is good news. Clearly a one-factor or single-index model cannot capture such differential responses to varying sources of macroeconomic uncertainty. Example 10.2 Risk Assessment Using Multifactor Models Suppose we estimate the two-factor model in Equation 10.2 for Northeast Airlines and find the following result: R 5 .133 1 1.2(GDP) 2 .3(IR) 1 e This tells us that, based on currently available information, the expected excess rate of return for Northeast is 13.3%, but that for every percentage point increase in GDP beyond current expectations, the return on Northeast shares increases on average by 1.2%, while for every unanticipated percentage point that interest rates increases, Northeast’s shares fall on average by .3%. Factor betas can provide a framework for a hedging strategy. The idea for an investor who wishes to hedge a source of risk is to establish an opposite factor exposure to offset that particular source of risk. Often, futures contracts can be used to hedge particular factor exposures. We explore this application in Chapter 22. As it stands, however, the multifactor model is no more than a description of the factors that affect security returns. There is no “theory” in the equation. The obvious question left unanswered by a factor model like Equation 10.2 is where E(R ) comes from, in other words, what determines a security’s expected excess rate of return. This is where we need a theoretical model of equilibrium security returns. We therefore now turn to arbitrage pricing theory to help determine the expected value, E(R), in Equations 10.1 and 10.2. 10.2 Arbitrage Pricing Theory Stephen Ross developed the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) in 1976.1 Like the CAPM, the APT predicts a security market line linking expected returns to risk, but the path it takes to the SML is quite different. Ross’s APT relies on three key propositions: (1) security returns can be described by a factor model; (2) there are sufficient securities to diversify away idiosyncratic risk; and (3) well-functioning security markets do not allow for the persistence of arbitrage opportunities. We begin with a simple version of Ross’s model, which assumes that only one systematic factor affects security returns. 1 Stephen A. Ross, “Return, Risk and Arbitrage,” in I. Friend and J. Bicksler, eds., Risk and Return in Finance (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, 1976). bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 327 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 328 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Arbitrage, Risk Arbitrage, and Equilibrium An arbitrage opportunity arises when an investor can earn riskless profits without making a net investment. A trivial example of an arbitrage opportunity would arise if shares of a stock sold for different prices on two different exchanges. For example, suppose IBM sold for $195 on the NYSE but only $193 on NASDAQ. Then you could buy the shares on NASDAQ and simultaneously sell them on the NYSE, clearing a riskless profit of $2 per share without tying up any of your own capital. The Law of One Price states that if two assets are equivalent in all economically relevant respects, then they should have the same market price. The Law of One Price is enforced by arbitrageurs: If they observe a violation of the law, they will engage in arbitrage activity—simultaneously buying the asset where it is cheap and selling where it is expensive. In the process, they will bid up the price where it is low and force it down where it is high until the arbitrage opportunity is eliminated. The idea that market prices will move to rule out arbitrage opportunities is perhaps the most fundamental concept in capital market theory. Violation of this restriction would indicate the grossest form of market irrationality. The critical property of a risk-free arbitrage portfolio is that any investor, regardless of risk aversion or wealth, will want to take an infinite position in it. Because those large positions will quickly force prices up or down until the opportunity vanishes, security prices should satisfy a “no-arbitrage condition,” that is, a condition that rules out the existence of arbitrage opportunities. There is an important difference between arbitrage and risk–return dominance arguments in support of equilibrium price relationships. A dominance argument holds that when an equilibrium price relationship is violated, many investors will make limited portfolio changes, depending on their degree of risk aversion. Aggregation of these limited portfolio changes is required to create a large volume of buying and selling, which in turn restores equilibrium prices. By contrast, when arbitrage opportunities exist, each investor wants to take as large a position as possible; hence it will not take many investors to bring about the price pressures necessary to restore equilibrium. Therefore, implications for prices derived from no-arbitrage arguments are stronger than implications derived from a risk–return dominance argument. The CAPM is an example of a dominance argument, implying that all investors hold mean-variance efficient portfolios. If a security is mispriced, then investors will tilt their portfolios toward the underpriced and away from the overpriced securities. Pressure on equilibrium prices results from many investors shifting their portfolios, each by a relatively small dollar amount. The assumption that a large number of investors are mean-variance optimizers is critical. In contrast, the implication of a no-arbitrage condition is that a few investors who identify an arbitrage opportunity will mobilize large dollar amounts and quickly restore equilibrium. Practitioners often use the terms arbitrage and arbitrageurs more loosely than our strict definition. Arbitrageur often refers to a professional searching for mispriced securities in specific areas such as merger-target stocks, rather than to one who seeks strict (risk-free) arbitrage opportunities. Such activity is sometimes called risk arbitrage to distinguish it from pure arbitrage. To leap ahead, in Part Four we will discuss “derivative” securities such as futures and options, whose market values are determined by prices of other securities. For example, the value of a call option on a stock is determined by the price of the stock. For such securities, strict arbitrage is a practical possibility, and the condition of no-arbitrage leads to exact pricing. In the case of stocks and other “primitive” securities whose values are not determined strictly by another bundle of assets, no-arbitrage conditions must be obtained by appealing to diversification arguments. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 328 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 329 Well-Diversified Portfolios Consider the risk of a portfolio of stocks in a single-factor market. We first show that if a portfolio is well diversified, its firm-specific or nonfactor risk becomes negligible, so that only factor (or systematic) risk remains. The excess return on an n-stock portfolio with weights wi, Swi 5 1, is RP 5 E (RP) 1 bP F 1 eP where (10.3) bP 5 g w i b i ; E ( RP) 5 g wi E (Ri ) are the weighted averages of the bi and risk premiums of the n securities. The portfolio nonsystematic component (which is uncorrelated with F ) is eP 5 Swi ei , which similarly is a weighted average of the ei of the n securities. We can divide the variance of this portfolio into systematic and nonsystematic sources: s 2P 5 b 2P s 2F 1 s2 (eP ) where s2F is the variance of the factor F and s2(eP) is the nonsystematic risk of the portfolio, which is given by s2 (eP ) 5 Variance ( g wi ei ) 5 g w2i s2 (ei ) Note that in deriving the nonsystematic variance of the portfolio, we depend on the fact that the firm-specific eis are uncorrelated and hence that the variance of the “portfolio” of nonsystematic eis is the weighted sum of the individual nonsystematic variances with the square of the investment proportions as weights. If the portfolio were equally weighted, wi 5 1/n, then the nonsystematic variance would be 2 2 1 1 1 s (ei ) s2(eP) 5 Variance ( g wiei ) 5 a a n b s2(ei ) 5 n a n 5 n s2 (ei ) where the last term is the average value of nonsystematic variance across securities. In words, the nonsystematic variance of the portfolio equals the average nonsystematic variance divided by n. Therefore, when n is large, nonsystematic variance approaches zero. This is the effect of diversification. This property is true of portfolios other than the equally weighted one. Any portfolio for which each wi becomes consistently smaller as n gets large (more precisely, for which each w2i approaches zero as n increases) will satisfy the condition that the portfolio nonsystematic risk will approach zero. This property motivates us to define a well-diversified portfolio as one with each weight, wi , small enough that for practical purposes the nonsystematic variance, s2(eP), is negligible. CONCEPT CHECK 10.2 a. A portfolio is invested in a very large number of shares (n is large). However, one-half of the portfolio is invested in stock 1, and the rest of the portfolio is equally divided among the other n 2 1 shares. Is this portfolio well diversified? b. Another portfolio also is invested in the same n shares, where n is very large. Instead of equally weighting with portfolio weights of 1/n in each stock, the weights in half the securities are 1.5/n while the weights in the other shares are .5/n. Is this portfolio well diversified? bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 329 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 330 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Because the expected value of eP for any well-diversified portfolio is zero, and its variance also is effectively zero, we can conclude that any realized value of eP will be virtually zero. Rewriting Equation 10.1, we conclude that, for a well-diversified portfolio, for all practical purposes RP 5 E (RP ) 1 bP F The solid line in Figure 10.1, panel A plots the excess return of a well-diversified portfolio A with E (RA) 5 10% and bA 5 1 for various realizations of the systematic factor. The expected return of portfolio A is 10%; this is where the solid line crosses the vertical axis. At this point the systematic factor is zero, implying no macro surprises. If the macro factor is positive, the portfolio’s return exceeds its expected value; if it is negative, the portfolio’s return falls short of its mean. The excess return on the portfolio is therefore E (RA ) 1 bA F 5 10% 1 1.0 3 F Compare panel A in Figure 10.1 with panel B, which is a similar graph for a single stock (S) with bs 5 1. The undiversified stock is subject to nonsystematic risk, which is seen in a scatter of points around the line. The well-diversified portfolio’s return, in contrast, is determined completely by the systematic factor. In a single-factor world, all pairs of well-diversified portfolios are perfectly correlated: Their risk is fully determined by the same systematic factor. Consider a second welldiversified portfolio, Portfolio Q, with RQ 5 E(RQ) 1 bQF. We can compute the standard deviations of P and Q, as well as the covariance and correlation between them: sP 5 bP sF; sQ 5 bQ sF Cov ( RP , RQ ) 5 Cov (bP F, bQ F ) 5 bP bQ s2F r PQ 5 Cov (RP, RQ ) 51 sP sQ Excess Return (%) Excess Return (%) A S 10 10 F 0 A F 0 B Figure 10.1 Excess returns as a function of the systematic factor. Panel A, Well-diversified portfolio A. Panel B, Single stock (S). bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 330 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 331 Perfect correlation means that in a plot of expected return versus standard deviation (such as Figure 7.5), any two well-diversified portfolios lie on a straight line. We will see later that this common line is the CML. Diversification and Residual Risk in Practice What is the effect of diversification on portfolio residual SD in practice, where portfolio size is not unlimited? In reality, we may find (annualized) residual SDs as high as 50% for large stocks and even 100% for small stocks. To illustrate the impact of diversification, we examine portfolios of two configurations. One portfolio is equally weighted; this achieves the highest benefits of diversification with equal-SD stocks. For comparison, we form the other portfolio using far-from-equal weights. We select stocks in groups of four, with relative weights in each group of 70%, 15%, 10%, and 5%. The highest weight is 14 times greater than the lowest, which will severely reduce potential benefits of diversification. However, extended diversification in which we add to the portfolio more and more groups of four stocks with the same relative weights will overcome this problem because the highest portfolio weight still falls with additional diversification. In an equally weighted 1,000-stock portfolio, each weight is 0.1%; in the unequally weighted portfolio, with 1,000/4 5 250 groups of four stocks, the highest and lowest weights are 70%/250 5 0.28% and 5%/250 5 0.02%, respectively. What is a large portfolio? Many widely held ETFs each include hundreds of stocks, and some funds such as the Wilshire 5000 hold thousands. These portfolios are accessible to the public since the annual expense ratios of investment companies that offer such funds are of the order of only 10 basis points. Thus a portfolio of 1,000 stocks is not unheard of, but a portfolio of 10,000 stocks is. Table 10.1 shows portfolio residual SD as a function of the number of stocks. Equally weighted, 1,000-stock portfolios achieve small but not negligible standard deviations of 1.58% when residual risk is 50% and 3.16% when residual risk is 100%. The SDs for the unbalanced portfolios are about double these values. For 10,000-stock portfolios, the SDs are negligible, verifying that diversification can eliminate risk even in very unbalanced portfolios, at least in principle, if the investment universe is large enough. Residual SD of Each Stock 5 50% Residual SD of Each Stock 5 100% N N SD(eP) Equal weights: wi 5 1/N 4 25.00 4 60 6.45 60 200 3.54 200 1,000 1.58 1,000 10,000 0.50 10,000 Sets of four relative weights: w1 5 0.65, w2 5 0.2, w3 5 0.1, w4 5 0.05 4 36.23 4 60 9.35 60 200 5.12 200 1,000 2.29 1,000 10,000 0.72 10,000 SD(eP) 50.00 12.91 7.07 3.16 1.00 72.46 18.71 10.25 4.58 1.45 Table 10.1 Residual variance with even and uneven portfolio weights bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 331 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 332 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Executing Arbitrage Imagine a single-factor market where the well-diversified portfolio, M, represents the market factor, F, of Equation 10.1. The excess return on any security is given by Ri 5 ai 1 bi RM 1 ei , and that of a well-diversified (therefore zero residual) portfolio, P, is RP 5 aP 1 bP RM (10.4) E (RP) 5 aP 1 bP E (RM) (10.5) Now suppose that security analysis reveals that portfolio P has a positive alpha.2 We also estimate the risk premium of the index portfolio, M, from macro analysis. Since neither M nor portfolio P have residual risk, the only risk to the returns of the two portfolios is systematic, derived from their betas on the common factor (the beta of the index is 1.0). Therefore, you can eliminate the risk of P altogether: Construct a zero-beta portfolio, called Z, from P and M by appropriately selecting weights wP and wM 5 1 2 wP on each portfolio: bZ 5 wPbP 1 (1 2 wP)bM 5 0 bM 5 1 wP 5 (10.6) 2bP 1 ; w 5 1 2 wP 5 1 2 bP M 1 2 bP Therefore, portfolio Z is riskless, and its alpha is aZ 5 wP aP 1 (1 2 wP) aM 5 wP aP (10.7) The risk premium on Z must be zero because the risk of Z is zero. If its risk premium were not zero, you could earn arbitrage profits. Here is how: Since the beta of Z is zero, Equation 10.5 implies that its risk premium is just its alpha. Using Equation 10.7, its alpha is wP aP, so E (RZ ) 5 wP aP 5 1 a 1 2 bP P (10.8) You now form a zero-net-investment arbitrage portfolio: If bP , 1 and the risk premium of Z is positive (implying that Z returns more than the risk-free rate), borrow and invest the proceeds in Z. For every borrowed dollar invested in Z, you get a net return (i.e., net of 1 paying the interest on your loan) of aP. This is a money machine, which you would 1 2 bP work as hard as you can.3 Similarly if bP . 1, Equation 10.8 tells us that the risk premium is negative; therefore, sell Z short and invest the proceeds at the risk-free rate. Once again, a money machine has been created. Neither situation can persist, as the large volume of trades from arbitrageurs pursuing these strategies will push prices until the arbitrage opportunity disappears (i.e., until the risk premium of portfolio Z equals zero). 2 If the portfolio alpha is negative, we can still pursue the following strategy. We would simply switch to a short position in P, which would have a positive alpha of the same absolute value as P’s, and a beta that is the negative of P’s. 3 The function in Equation 10.8 becomes unstable at bP 5 1. For values of bP near 1, it becomes infinitely large with the sign of aP. This isn’t an economic absurdity, since in that case, the sizes of your long position in P and short position in M will be almost identical, and the arbitrage profit you earn per dollar invested will be nearly infinite. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 332 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 333 The No-Arbitrage Equation of the APT We’ve seen that arbitrage activity will quickly pin the risk premium of any zero-beta welldiversified portfolio to zero.4 Setting the expression in Equation 10.8 to zero implies that the alpha of any well-diversified portfolio must also be zero. From Equation 10.5, this means that for any well-diversified P, E (RP) 5 bP E (RM) (10.9) In other words, the risk premium (expected excess return) on portfolio P is the product of its beta and the market-index risk premium. Equation 10.9 thus establishes that the SML of the CAPM applies to well-diversified portfolios simply by virtue of the “no-arbitrage” requirement of the APT. Another demonstration that the APT results in the same SML as the CAPM is more graphical in nature. First we show why all well-diversified portfolios with the same beta must have the same expected return. Figure 10.2 plots the returns on two such portfolios, A and B, both with betas of 1, but with differing expected returns: E (rA) 5 10% and E (rB) 5 8%. Could portfolios A and B coexist with the return pattern depicted? Clearly not: No matter what the systematic factor turns out to be, portfolio A outperforms portfolio B, leading to an arbitrage opportunity. If you sell short $1 million of B and buy $1 million of A, a zero-net-investment strategy, you would have a riskless payoff of $20,000, as follows: (.10 1 1.0 3 F ) 3 $1 million 2(.08 1 1.0 3 F ) 3 $1 million .02 3 $1 million 5 $20,000 from long position in A from short position in B net proceeds Your profit is risk-free because the factor risk cancels out across the long and short positions. Moreover, the strategy requires zero-net-investment. You should pursue it on an Return (%) A B 10 8 0 F (Realization of Macro Factor) Figure 10.2 Returns as a function of the systematic factor: an arbitrage opportunity 4 As an exercise, show that when aP , 0 you reverse the position of P in Z, and the arbitrage portfolio will still earn a riskless excess return. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 333 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 334 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Expected Return (%) A 10 rf = 4 Risk Premium D 7 6 C F .5 1 β (With Respect to Macro Factor) Figure 10.3 An arbitrage opportunity infinitely large scale until the return discrepancy between the two portfolios disappears. Well-diversified portfolios with equal betas must have equal expected returns in market equilibrium, or arbitrage opportunities exist. What about portfolios with different betas? Their risk premiums must be proportional to beta. To see why, consider Figure 10.3. Suppose that the risk-free rate is 4% and that a well-diversified portfolio, C, with a beta of .5, has an expected return of 6%. Portfolio C plots below the line from the risk-free asset to portfolio A. Consider, therefore, a new portfolio, D, composed of half of portfolio A and half of the risk-free asset. Portfolio D’s beta will be (.5 3 0 1 .5 3 1.0) 5 .5, and its expected return will be (.5 3 4 1 .5 3 10) 5 7%. Now portfolio D has an equal beta but a greater expected return than portfolio C. From our analysis in the previous paragraph we know that this constitutes an arbitrage opportunity. We conclude that, to preclude arbitrage opportunities, the expected return on all well-diversified portfolios must lie on the straight line from the risk-free asset in Figure 10.3. Notice in Figure 10.3 that risk premiums are indeed proportional to portfolio betas. The risk premium is depicted by the vertical arrow, which measures the distance between the risk-free rate and the expected return on the portfolio. As in the simple CAPM, the risk premium is zero for b 5 0 and rises in direct proportion to b. 10.3 The APT, the CAPM, and the Index Model Equation 10.9 raises three questions: 1. Does the APT also apply to less-than-well-diversified portfolios? 2. Is the APT as a model of risk and return superior or inferior to the CAPM? Do we need both models? bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 334 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 335 3. Suppose a security analyst identifies a positive-alpha portfolio with some remaining residual risk. Don’t we already have a prescription for this case from the TreynorBlack (T-B) procedure applied to the index model (Chapter 8)? Is this framework preferred to the APT? The APT and the CAPM The APT is built on the foundation of well-diversified portfolios. However, we’ve seen, for example in Table 10.1, that even large portfolios may have non-negligible residual risk. Some indexed portfolios may have hundreds or thousands of stocks, but active portfolios generally cannot, as there is a limit to how many stocks can be actively analyzed in search of alpha. How does the APT stand up to these limitations? Suppose we order all portfolios in the universe by residual risk. Think of Level 0 portfolios as having zero residual risk; in other words, they are the theoretically well-diversified portfolios of the APT. Level 1 portfolios have very small residual risk, say up to 0.5%. Level 2 portfolios have yet greater residual SD, say up to 1%, and so on. If the SML described by Equation 10.9 applies to all well-diversified Level 0 portfolios, it must at least approximate the risk premiums of Level 1 portfolios. Even more important, while Level 1 risk premiums may deviate slightly from Equation 10.9, such deviations should be unbiased, with alphas equally likely to be positive or negative. Deviations should be uncorrelated with beta or residual SD and should average to zero. We can apply the same logic to portfolios of slightly higher Level 2 residual risk. Since all Level 1 portfolios are still well approximated by Equation 10.9, so must be risk premiums of Level 2 portfolios, albeit with slightly less accuracy. Here too, we may take comfort in the lack of bias and zero average deviations from the risk premiums predicted by Equation 10.9. But still, the precision of predictions of risk premiums from Equation 10.9 consistently deteriorates with increasing residual risk. (One might ask why we don’t transform Level 2 portfolios into Level 1 or even Level 0 portfolios by further diversifying, but as we’ve pointed out, this may not be feasible in practice for assets with considerable residual risk when active portfolio size or the size of the investment universe is limited.) If residual risk is sufficiently high and the impediments to complete diversification are too onerous, we cannot have full confidence in the APT and the arbitrage activities that underpin it. Despite this shortcoming, the APT is valuable. First, recall that the CAPM requires that almost all investors be mean-variance optimizers. We may well suspect that they are not. The APT frees us of this assumption. It is sufficient that a small number of sophisticated arbitrageurs scour the market for arbitrage opportunities. This alone produces an SML, Equation 10.9, that is a good and unbiased approximation for all assets but those with significant residual risk. Perhaps even more important is the fact that the APT is anchored by observable portfolios such as the market index. The CAPM is not even testable because it relies on an unobserved, all-inclusive portfolio. The reason that the APT is not fully superior to the CAPM is that at the level of individual assets and high residual risk, pure arbitrage may be insufficient to enforce Equation 10.9. Therefore, we need to turn to the CAPM as a complementary theoretical construct behind equilibrium risk premiums. It should be noted, however, that when we replace the unobserved market portfolio of the CAPM with an observed, broad index portfolio that may not be efficient, we no longer can be sure that the CAPM predicts risk premiums of all assets with no bias. Neither model therefore is free of limitations. Comparing the APT arbitrage strategy to maximization of the Sharpe ratio in the context of an index model may well be the more useful framework for analysis. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 335 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 336 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets The APT and Portfolio Optimization in a Single-Index Market The APT is couched in a single-factor market5 and applies with perfect accuracy to welldiversified portfolios. It shows arbitrageurs how to generate infinite profits if the risk premium of a well-diversified portfolio deviates from Equation 10.9. The trades executed by these arbitrageurs are the enforcers of the accuracy of this equation. In effect, the APT shows how to take advantage of security mispricing when diversification opportunities are abundant. When you lock in and scale up an arbitrage opportunity you’re sure to be rich as Croesus regardless of the composition of the rest of your portfolio, but only if the arbitrage portfolio is truly risk-free! However, if the arbitrage position is not perfectly well diversified, an increase in its scale (borrowing cash, or borrowing shares to go short) will increase the risk of the arbitrage position, potentially without bound. The APT ignores this complication. Now consider an investor who confronts the same single factor market, and whose security analysis reveals an underpriced asset (or portfolio), that is, one whose risk premium implies a positive alpha. This investor can follow the advice weaved throughout Chapters 6–8 to construct an optimal risky portfolio. The optimization process will consider both the potential profit from a position in the mispriced asset, as well as the risk of the overall portfolio and efficient diversification. As we saw in Chapter 8, the TreynorBlack (T-B) procedure can be summarized as follows.6 1. Estimate the risk premium and standard deviation of the benchmark (index) portfolio, RPM and sM. 2. Place all the assets that are mispriced into an active portfolio. Call the alpha of the active portfolio aA, its systematic-risk coefficient bA, and its residual risk s(eA). Your optimal risky portfolio will allocate to the active portfolio a weight, w*A: A w0A 2 (eA ) * ; wA E ( RM ) 2 M w0A 1 1 w0A (1 2 bA) The allocation to the passive portfolio is then, w*M 5 1 2 w*A. With this allocation, the increase in the Sharpe ratio of the optimal portfolio, SP, over that of the passive portfolio, SM, depends on the size of the information ratio of the active portfolio, IR A 5 aA/s(eA). The optimized portfolio can attain a Sharpe ratio of SP 5 "S 2M 1 IR 2A. 3. To maximize the Sharpe ratio of the risky portfolio, you maximize the IR of the active portfolio. This is achieved by allocating to each asset in the active portfolio a portfolio weight proportional to: wAi 5 ai/s2(ei). When this is done, the square of the information ratio of the active portfolio will be the sum of the squared individual information ratios: IR 2A 5 a IR 2i . Now see what happens in the T-B model when the residual risk of the active portfolio is zero. This is essentially the assumption of the APT, that a well-diversified portfolio (with zero residual risk) can be formed. When the residual risk of the active portfolio goes to zero, the position in it goes to infinity. This is precisely the same implication as the APT: When portfolios are well-diversified, you will scale up an arbitrage position without 5 The APT is easily extended to a multifactor market as we show later. The tediousness of some of the expressions involved in the T-B method should not deter anyone. The calculations are pretty straightforward, especially in a spreadsheet. The estimation of the risk parameters also is a relatively straightforward statistical task. The real difficulty is to uncover security alphas and the macro-factor risk premium, RPM. 6 bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 336 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 337 bound. Similarly, when the residual risk of an asset in the active T-B portfolio is zero, it will displace all other assets from that portfolio, and thus the residual risk of the active portfolio will be zero and elicit the same extreme portfolio response. When residual risks are nonzero, the T-B procedure produces the optimal risky portfolio, which is a compromise between seeking alpha and shunning potentially diversifiable risk. The APT ignores residual risk altogether, assuming it has been diversified away. Obviously, we have no use for the APT in this context. When residual risk can be made small through diversification, the T-B model prescribes very aggressive (large) positions in mispriced securities that exert great pressure on equilibrium risk premiums to eliminate nonzero alpha values. The T-B model does what the APT is meant to do but with more flexibility in terms of accommodating the practical limits to diversification. In this sense, Treynor and Black anticipated the development of the APT. Example 10.3 Exploiting Alpha Table 10.2 summarizes a rudimentary experiment that compares the prescriptions and predictions of the APT and T-B model in the presence of realistic values of residual risk. We use relatively small alpha values (1 and 3%), three levels of residual risk consistent with values in Table 10.1 (2, 3, and 4%), and two levels of beta (0.5 and 2) to span the likely range of reasonable parameters. The first set of columns in Table 10.2, titled Active Portfolio, show the parameter values in each example. The second set of columns, titled Zero-Net-Investment, Arbitrage (Zero-Beta), shows the weight in the active portfolio and resultant information ratio of the active portfolio. This would be the Sharpe ratio if the arbitrage position (the positivealpha, zero-beta portfolio) made up the entire risky portfolio (as would be prescribed Index Risk Premium 5 7 Index SD 5 20 Index Sharpe Ratio 5 0.35 Active Portfolio Zero-Net-Investment, Arbitrage (Zero-Beta) Portfolio Treynor-Black Procedure Alpha (%) Residual SD Beta w in Active Info Ratio w(beta 5 0) w(beta) 1 1 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 3 3 3 4 4 3 3 2 2 4 4 3 3 2 2 0.5 2 0.5 2 0.5 2 0.5 2 0.5 2 0.5 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 0.25 0.25 0.33 0.33 0.50 0.50 0.75 0.75 1.00 1.00 1.50 1.50 3.57 3.57 6.35 6.35 14.29 14.29 10.71 10.71 19.05 19.05 42.86 42.86 1.28 1.00 1.52 1.00 1.75 1.00 1.69 1.00 1.81 1.00 1.91 1.00 Sharpe Incremental Ratio Sharpe Ratio 0.43 0.43 0.48 0.48 0.61 0.61 0.83 0.83 1.06 1.06 1.54 1.54 0.18 0.18 0.15 0.15 0.11 0.11 0.08 0.08 0.06 0.06 0.04 0.04 Table 10.2 Performance of APT vs. Index Model when diversification of residual SD is incomplete bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 337 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 338 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets by the APT). The last set of columns shows the T-B position in the active portfolio that maximizes the Sharpe ratio of the overall risky portfolio. The final column shows the increment to the Sharpe ratio of the T-B portfolio relative to the APT portfolio. Keep in mind that even when the two models call for a similar weight in the active portfolio (compare w in Active for the APT model to w(beta) for the T-B model), they nevertheless prescribe a different overall risky portfolio. The APT assumes zero investment beyond what is necessary to hedge out the market risk of the active portfolio. In contrast, the T-B procedure chooses a mix of active and index portfolios to maximize the Sharpe ratio. With identical investment in the active portfolio, the T-B portfolio can still include additional investment in the index portfolio. To obtain the Sharpe ratio of the risky portfolio, we need the Sharpe ratio of the index portfolio. As an estimate, we use the average return and standard deviation of the broad market index (NYSE 1 AMEX 1 NASDAQ) over the period 1926–2012. The top row (over the column titles) of Table 10.2 shows an annual Sharpe ratio of 0.35. The rows of the table are ordered by the information ratio of the active portfolio. Table 10.2 shows that the T-B procedure noticeably improves the Sharpe ratio beyond the information ratio of the APT (for which the IR is also the Sharpe ratio). However, as the information ratio of the active portfolio increases, the difference in the T-B and APT active portfolio positions declines, as does the difference between their Sharpe ratios. Put differently, the higher the information ratio, the closer we are to a risk-free arbitrage opportunity, and the closer are the prescriptions of the APT and T-B models. 10.4 A Multifactor APT We have assumed so far that only one systematic factor affects stock returns. This simplifying assumption is in fact too simplistic. We’ve noted that it is easy to think of several factors driven by the business cycle that might affect stock returns: interest rate fluctuations, inflation rates, and so on. Presumably, exposure to any of these factors will affect a stock’s risk and hence its expected return. We can derive a multifactor version of the APT to accommodate these multiple sources of risk. Suppose that we generalize the single-factor model expressed in Equation 10.1 to a two-factor model: Ri 5 E (Ri ) 1 bi1 F1 1 bi2 F2 1 ei (10.10) In Example 10.2, factor 1 was the departure of GDP growth from expectations, and factor 2 was the unanticipated change in interest rates. Each factor has zero expected value because each measures the surprise in the systematic variable rather than the level of the variable. Similarly, the firm-specific component of unexpected return, ei , also has zero expected value. Extending such a two-factor model to any number of factors is straightforward. We can now generalize the simple APT to a more general multifactor version. But first we must introduce the concept of a factor portfolio, which is a well-diversified portfolio constructed to have a beta of 1 on one of the factors and a beta of zero on any other factor. We can think of a factor portfolio as a tracking portfolio. That is, the returns on such a portfolio track the evolution of particular sources of macroeconomic risk but are uncorrelated with other sources of risk. It is possible to form such factor portfolios because we have a large number of securities to choose from, and a relatively small number of factors. Factor portfolios will serve as the benchmark portfolios for a multifactor security market line. The multidimensional SML predicts that exposure to each risk factor contributes to the security’s total risk premium by an amount equal to the factor beta times the risk premium of the factor portfolio tracking that source of risk. We illustrate with an example. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 338 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Example 10.4 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 339 Multifactor SML Suppose that the two factor portfolios, portfolios 1 and 2, have expected returns E (r1) 5 10% and E (r2) 5 12%. Suppose further that the risk-free rate is 4%. The risk premium on the first factor portfolio is 10% 2 4% 5 6%, whereas that on the second factor portfolio is 12% 2 4% 5 8%. Now consider a well-diversified portfolio, portfolio A, with beta on the first factor, bA1 5 .5, and beta on the second factor, bA2 5 .75. The multifactor APT states that the overall risk premium on this portfolio must equal the sum of the risk premiums required as compensation for each source of systematic risk. The risk premium attributable to risk factor 1 should be the portfolio’s exposure to factor 1, bA1, multiplied by the risk premium earned on the first factor portfolio, E (r1) 2 rf. Therefore, the portion of portfolio A’s risk premium that is compensation for its exposure to the first factor is bA1 [E (r1) 2 rf] 5 .5(10% 2 4%) 5 3%, whereas the risk premium attributable to risk factor 2 is bA2[E (r2) 2 rf] 5 .75(12% 2 4%) 5 6%. The total risk premium on the portfolio should be 3% 1 6% 5 9% and the total return on the portfolio should be 4% 1 9% 5 13%. To generalize the argument in Example 10.4, note that the factor exposures of any portfolio, P, are given by its betas, bP1 and bP2. A competing portfolio, Q, can be formed by investing in factor portfolios with the following weights: bP1 in the first factor portfolio, bP2 in the second factor portfolio, and 1 2 bP1 2 bP2 in T-bills. By construction, portfolio Q will have betas equal to those of portfolio P and expected return of E (rQ ) 5 bP1E (r1) 1 bP2 E (r2) 1 (1 2 bP1 2 bP2) rf 5 rf 1 bP1 3 E (r1) 2 rf 4 1 bP2 3 E (r2) 2 rf 4 (10.11) Using the numbers in Example 10.4: E (rQ ) 5 4 1 .5 3 (10 2 4) 1 .75 3 (12 2 4) 5 13% Example 10.5 Mispricing and Arbitrage Suppose that the expected return on portfolio A from Example 10.4 were 12% rather than 13%. This return would give rise to an arbitrage opportunity. Form a portfolio from the factor portfolios with the same betas as portfolio A. This requires weights of .5 on the first factor portfolio, .75 on the second factor portfolio, and 2.25 on the risk-free asset. This portfolio has exactly the same factor betas as portfolio A: It has a beta of .5 on the first factor because of its .5 weight on the first factor portfolio, and a beta of .75 on the second factor. (The weight of 2.25 on risk-free T-bills does not affect the sensitivity to either factor.) Now invest $1 in portfolio Q and sell (short) $1 in portfolio A. Your net investment is zero, but your expected dollar profit is positive and equal to $1 3 E(rQ) 2 $1 3 E(rA) 5 $1 3 .13 2 $1 3 .12 5 $.01 Moreover, your net position is riskless. Your exposure to each risk factor cancels out because you are long $1 in portfolio Q and short $1 in portfolio A, and both of these well-diversified portfolios have exactly the same factor betas. Thus, if portfolio A’s expected return differs from that of portfolio Q’s, you can earn positive risk-free profits on a zero-net-investment position. This is an arbitrage opportunity. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 339 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 340 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Because portfolio Q in Example 10.5 has precisely the same exposures as portfolio A to the two sources of risk, their expected returns also ought to be equal. So portfolio A also ought to have an expected return of 13%. If it does not, then there will be an arbitrage opportunity.7 We conclude that any well-diversified portfolio with betas bP1 and bP2 must have the return given in Equation 10.11 if arbitrage opportunities are to be precluded. Equation 10.11 simply generalizes the one-factor SML. Finally, the extension of the multifactor SML of Equation 10.11 to individual assets is precisely the same as for the one-factor APT. Equation 10.11 cannot be satisfied by every well-diversified portfolio unless it is satisfied approximately by individual securities. Equation 10.11 thus represents the multifactor SML for an economy with multiple sources of risk. We pointed out earlier that one application of the CAPM is to provide “fair” rates of return for regulated utilities. The multifactor APT can be used to the same ends. The nearby box summarizes a study in which the APT was applied to find the cost of capital for regulated electric companies. Notice that CONCEPT CHECK 10.3 empirical estimates for interest rate and inflation risk premiums in the box are negative, as Using the factor portfolios of Example 10.4, find the equilibwe argued was reasonable in our discussion rium rate of return on a portfolio with b1 5 .2 and b2 5 1.4. of Example 10.2. 10.5 The Fama-French (FF) Three-Factor Model The currently dominant approach to specifying factors as candidates for relevant sources of systematic risk uses firm characteristics that seem on empirical grounds to proxy for exposure to systematic risk. The factors chosen are variables that on past evidence seem to predict average returns well and therefore may be capturing risk premiums. One example of this approach is the Fama and French three-factor model and its variants, which have come to dominate empirical research and industry applications:8 Rit 5 a i 1 biM RMt 1 biSMB SMBt 1 biHMLHMLt 1 eit (10.12) where SMB 5 Small Minus Big, i.e., the return of a portfolio of small stocks in excess of the return on a portfolio of large stocks. HML 5 High Minus Low, i.e., the return of a portfolio of stocks with a high book-to-market ratio in excess of the return on a portfolio of stocks with a low book-to-market ratio. Note that in this model the market index does play a role and is expected to capture systematic risk originating from macroeconomic factors. These two firm-characteristic variables are chosen because of long-standing observations that corporate capitalization (firm size) and book-to-market ratio predict deviations 7 The risk premium on portfolio A is 9% (more than the historical risk premium of the S&P 500) despite the fact that its betas, which are both below 1, might seem defensive. This highlights another distinction between multifactor and single-factor models. Whereas a beta greater than 1 in a single-factor market is aggressive, we cannot say in advance what would be aggressive or defensive in a multifactor economy where risk premiums depend on the sum of the contributions of several factors. 8 Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French, “Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies,” Journal of Finance 51 (1996), pp. 55–84. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 340 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer Elton, Gruber, and Mei* use the APT to derive the cost of capital for electric utilities. They assume that the relevant risk factors are unanticipated developments in the term structure of interest rates, the level of interest rates, inflation rates, the business cycle (measured by GDP), foreign exchange rates, and a summary measure they devise to measure other macro factors. Their first step is to estimate the risk premium associated with exposure to each risk source. They accomplish this in a two-step strategy (which we will describe in considerable detail in Chapter 13): 1. Estimate “factor loadings” (i.e., betas) of a large sample of firms. Regress returns of 100 randomly selected stocks against the systematic risk factors. They use a time-series regression for each stock (e.g., 60 months of data), therefore estimating 100 regressions, one for each stock. 2. Estimate the reward earned per unit of exposure to each risk factor. For each month, regress the return of each stock against the five betas estimated. The coefficient on each beta is the extra average return earned as beta increases, i.e., it is an estimate of the risk premium for that risk factor from that month’s data. These estimates are of course subject to sampling error. Therefore, average the risk premium estimates across the 12 months in each year. The average response of return to risk is less subject to sampling error. The risk premiums are in the middle column of the table at the top of the next column. Notice that some risk premiums are negative. The interpretation of this result is that risk premium should be positive for risk factors you don’t want exposure to, but negative for factors you do want exposure to. For example, you should desire securities that have higher returns when inflation increases and be willing to accept lower expected returns on such securities; this shows up as a negative risk premium. Factor Term structure Interest rates Exchange rates Business cycle Inflation Other macro factors Factor Risk Premium Factor Betas for Niagara Mohawk .425 2.051 2.049 .041 2.069 .530 1.0615 22.4167 1.3235 .1292 2.5220 .3046 Therefore, the expected return on any security should be related to its factor betas as follows: rf 1 .425 bterm struc 2 .051 bint rate 2.049 bex rate 1 .041 bbus cycle 2 .069 binflation 1 .530 bother Finally, to obtain the cost of capital for a particular firm, the authors estimate the firm’s betas against each source of risk, multiply each factor beta by the “cost of factor risk” from the table above, sum over all risk sources to obtain the total risk premium, and add the risk-free rate. For example, the beta estimates for Niagara Mohawk appear in the last column of the table above. Therefore, its cost of capital is WORDS FROM THE STREET Using the APT to Find Cost of Capital Cost of capital 5 rf 1 .425 3 1.0615 2 .051(22.4167) 2.049(1.3235) 1 .041(.1292) 2.069(2.5220) 1 .530(.3046) 5 rf 1 .72 In other words, the monthly cost of capital for Niagara Mohawk is .72% above the monthly risk-free rate. Its annualized risk premium is therefore .72% 3 12 5 8.64%. *Edwin J. Elton, Martin J. Gruber, and Jianping Mei, “Cost of Capital Using Arbitrage Pricing Theory: A Case Study of Nine New York Utilities,” Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments 3 (August 1994), pp. 46–68. of average stock returns from levels consistent with the CAPM. Fama and French justify this model on empirical grounds: While SMB and HML are not themselves obvious candidates for relevant risk factors, the argument is that these variables may proxy for yet-unknown more-fundamental variables. For example, Fama and French point out that firms with high ratios of book-to-market value are more likely to be in financial distress and that small stocks may be more sensitive to changes in business conditions. Thus, these variables may capture sensitivity to risk factors in the macroeconomy. More evidence on the Fama-French model appears in Chapter 13. The problem with empirical approaches such as the Fama-French model, which use proxies for extramarket sources of risk, is that none of the factors in the proposed models can be clearly identified as hedging a significant source of uncertainty. Black9 points out that 9 Fischer Black, “Beta and Return,” Journal of Portfolio Management 20 (1993), pp. 8–18. 341 bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 341 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 342 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm when researchers scan and rescan the database of security returns in search of explanatory factors (an activity often called data-snooping), they may eventually uncover past “patterns” that are due purely to chance. Black observes that return premiums to factors such as firm size have proven to be inconsistent since first discovered. However, Fama and French have shown that size and book-to-market ratios have predicted average returns in various time periods and in markets all over the world, thus mitigating potential effects of data-snooping. The firm-characteristic basis of the Fama-French factors raises the question of whether they reflect a multi-index ICAPM based on extra-market hedging demands or just represent yet-unexplained anomalies, where firm characteristics are correlated with alpha values. This is an important distinction for the debate over the proper interpretation of the model, because the validity of FF-style models may signify either a deviation from rational equilibrium (as there is no rational reason to prefer one or another of these firm characteristics per se), or that firm characteristics identified as empirically associated with average returns are correlated with other (yet unknown) risk factors. The issue is still unresolved and is discussed in Chapter 13. SUMMARY 1. Multifactor models seek to improve the explanatory power of single-factor models by explicitly accounting for the various systematic components of security risk. These models use indicators intended to capture a wide range of macroeconomic risk factors. 2. Once we allow for multiple risk factors, we conclude that the security market line also ought to be multidimensional, with exposure to each risk factor contributing to the total risk premium of the security. 3. A (risk-free) arbitrage opportunity arises when two or more security prices enable investors to construct a zero-net-investment portfolio that will yield a sure profit. The presence of arbitrage opportunities will generate a large volume of trades that puts pressure on security prices. This pressure will continue until prices reach levels that preclude such arbitrage. 4. When securities are priced so that there are no risk-free arbitrage opportunities, we say that they satisfy the no-arbitrage condition. Price relationships that satisfy the no-arbitrage condition are important because we expect them to hold in real-world markets. 5. Portfolios are called “well-diversified” if they include a large number of securities and the investment proportion in each is sufficiently small. The proportion of a security in a well-diversified portfolio is small enough so that for all practical purposes a reasonable change in that security’s rate of return will have a negligible effect on the portfolio’s rate of return. 6. In a single-factor security market, all well-diversified portfolios have to satisfy the expected return–beta relationship of the CAPM to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition. If all well-diversified portfolios satisfy the expected return–beta relationship, then individual securities also must satisfy this relationship, at least approximately. 7. The APT does not require the restrictive assumptions of the CAPM and its (unobservable) market portfolio. The price of this generality is that the APT does not guarantee this relationship for all securities at all times. 8. A multifactor APT generalizes the single-factor model to accommodate several sources of systematic risk. The multidimensional security market line predicts that exposure to each risk factor contributes to the security’s total risk premium by an amount equal to the factor beta times the risk premium of the factor portfolio that tracks that source of risk. Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 342 9. A multifactor extension of the single-factor CAPM, the ICAPM, is a model of the risk–return trade-off that predicts the same multidimensional security market line as the APT. The ICAPM suggests that priced risk factors will be those sources of risk that lead to significant hedging demand by a substantial fraction of investors. 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return arbitrage pricing theory arbitrage Law of One Price risk arbitrage single-factor model multifactor model factor loading factor beta well-diversified portfolio factor portfolio 343 KEY TERMS KEY EQUATIONS Single factor model: Ri 5 E(Ri) 1 b1F 1 ei Multifactor model (here, 2 factors, F1 and F2): Ri 5 E(Ri) 1 b1F1 1 b2F2 1 ei Single-index model: Ri 5 ai 1 bi RM 1 ei Multifactor SML (here, 2 factors, labeled 1 and 2) E(ri) 5 rf 1 b1 3 E(r1) 2 rf 4 1 b2 3 E(r2 ) 2 rf 4 5 rf 1 b1E(R1) 1 b2 E(R2) 1. Suppose that two factors have been identified for the U.S. economy: the growth rate of industrial production, IP, and the inflation rate, IR. IP is expected to be 3%, and IR 5%. A stock with a beta of 1 on IP and .5 on IR currently is expected to provide a rate of return of 12%. If industrial production actually grows by 5%, while the inflation rate turns out to be 8%, what is your revised estimate of the expected rate of return on the stock? PROBLEM SETS 2. The APT itself does not provide guidance concerning the factors that one might expect to determine risk premiums. How should researchers decide which factors to investigate? Why, for example, is industrial production a reasonable factor to test for a risk premium? Basic 3. If the APT is to be a useful theory, the number of systematic factors in the economy must be small. Why? 4. Suppose that there are two independent economic factors, F1 and F2. The risk-free rate is 6%, and all stocks have independent firm-specific components with a standard deviation of 45%. The following are well-diversified portfolios: Portfolio Beta on F1 Beta on F2 Expected Return 1.5 2.2 2.0 20.2 31% 27% A B Intermediate Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm where the risk premiums on the two factor portfolios are E(R1) and E(R2 ) What is the expected return–beta relationship in this economy? 5. Consider the following data for a one-factor economy. All portfolios are well diversified. Portfolio E(r) Beta A F 12% 6% 1.2 0.0 Suppose that another portfolio, portfolio E, is well diversified with a beta of .6 and expected return of 8%. Would an arbitrage opportunity exist? If so, what would be the arbitrage strategy? 6. Assume that both portfolios A and B are well diversified, that E(rA) 5 12%, and E(rB) 5 9%. If the economy has only one factor, and bA 5 1.2, whereas bB 5 .8, what must be the riskfree rate? bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 343 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 344 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets 7. Assume that stock market returns have the market index as a common factor, and that all stocks in the economy have a beta of 1 on the market index. Firm-specific returns all have a standard deviation of 30%. Suppose that an analyst studies 20 stocks, and finds that one-half have an alpha of 12%, and the other half an alpha of 22%. Suppose the analyst buys $1 million of an equally weighted portfolio of the positive alpha stocks, and shorts $1 million of an equally weighted portfolio of the negative alpha stocks. a. What is the expected profit (in dollars) and standard deviation of the analyst’s profit? b. How does your answer change if the analyst examines 50 stocks instead of 20 stocks? 100 stocks? 8. Assume that security returns are generated by the single-index model, Ri 5 a i 1 bi RM 1 ei Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm where Ri is the excess return for security i and RM is the market’s excess return. The risk-free rate is 2%. Suppose also that there are three securities A, B, and C, characterized by the following data: Security bi E (Ri ) s(ei ) A B C 0.8 1.0 1.2 10% 12 14 25% 10 20 a. If sM 5 20%, calculate the variance of returns of securities A, B, and C. b. Now assume that there are an infinite number of assets with return characteristics identical to those of A, B, and C, respectively. If one forms a well-diversified portfolio of type A securities, what will be the mean and variance of the portfolio’s excess returns? What about portfolios composed only of type B or C stocks? c. Is there an arbitrage opportunity in this market? What is it? Analyze the opportunity graphically. 9. The SML relationship states that the expected risk premium on a security in a one-factor model must be directly proportional to the security’s beta. Suppose that this were not the case. For example, suppose that expected return rises more than proportionately with beta as in the figure below. E(r) B C A β a. How could you construct an arbitrage portfolio? (Hint: Consider combinations of portfolios A and B, and compare the resultant portfolio to C.) b. Some researchers have examined the relationship between average returns on diversified portfolios and the b and b2 of those portfolios. What should they have discovered about the effect of b2 on portfolio return? bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 344 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 345 10. Consider the following multifactor (APT) model of security returns for a particular stock. Factor Factor Beta Inflation Industrial production Oil prices Factor Risk Premium 1.2 0.5 0.3 6% 8 3 a. If T-bills currently offer a 6% yield, find the expected rate of return on this stock if the market views the stock as fairly priced. b. Suppose that the market expected the values for the three macro factors given in column 1 below, but that the actual values turn out as given in column 2. Calculate the revised expectations for the rate of return on the stock once the “surprises” become known. Expected Rate of Change Inflation Industrial production Oil prices Actual Rate of Change 5% 3 2 4% 6 0 11. Suppose that the market can be described by the following three sources of systematic risk with associated risk premiums. Factor Risk Premium Industrial production (I) Interest rates (R) Consumer confidence (C) 6% 2 4 The return on a particular stock is generated according to the following equation: r 5 15% 1 1.0 I 1 .5R 1 .75C 1 e Find the equilibrium rate of return on this stock using the APT. The T-bill rate is 6%. Is the stock over- or underpriced? Explain. 12. As a finance intern at Pork Products, Jennifer Wainwright’s assignment is to come up with fresh insights concerning the firm’s cost of capital. She decides that this would be a good opportunity to try out the new material on the APT that she learned last semester. She decides that three promising factors would be (i) the return on a broad-based index such as the S&P 500; (ii) the level of interest rates, as represented by the yield to maturity on 10-year Treasury bonds; and (iii) the price of hogs, which are particularly important to her firm. Her plan is to find the beta of Pork Products against each of these factors by using a multiple regression and to estimate the risk premium associated with each exposure factor. Comment on Jennifer’s choice of factors. Which are most promising with respect to the likely impact on her firm’s cost of capital? Can you suggest improvements to her specification? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Factor Use the following information to Answer Problems 13–16: Orb Trust (Orb) has historically leaned toward a passive management style of its portfolios. The only model that Orb’s senior management has promoted in the past is the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Now Orb’s management has asked one of its analysts, Kevin McCracken, CFA, to investigate the use of the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) model. McCracken believes that a two-factor APT model is adequate, where the factors are the sensitivity to changes in real GDP and changes in inflation. McCracken has concluded that the factor risk premium for real GDP is 8% while the factor risk premium for inflation is 2%. He estimates for Orb’s High Growth Fund that the sensitivities to these two factors are 1.25 and 1.5, respectively. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 345 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 346 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets Using his APT results, he computes the expected return of the fund. For comparison purposes, he then uses fundamental analysis to also compute the expected return of Orb’s High Growth Fund. McCracken finds that the two estimates of the Orb High Growth Fund’s expected return are equal. McCracken asks a fellow analyst, Sue Kwon, to provide an estimate of the expected return of Orb’s Large Cap Fund based on fundamental analysis. Kwon, who manages the fund, says that the expected return is 8.5% above the risk-free rate. McCracken then applies the APT model to the Large Cap Fund. He finds that the sensitivities to real GDP and inflation are .75 and 1.25, respectively. McCracken’s manager at Orb, Jay Stiles, asks McCracken to compose a portfolio that has a unit sensitivity to real GDP growth but is not affected by inflation. McCracken is confident in his APT estimates for the High Growth Fund and the Large Cap Fund. He then computes the sensitivities for a third fund, Orb’s Utility Fund, which has sensitivities equal to 1.0 and 2.0, respectively. McCracken will use his APT results for these three funds to accomplish the task of creating a portfolio with a unit exposure to real GDP and no exposure to inflation. He calls the fund the “GDP Fund.” Stiles says such a GDP Fund would be good for clients who are retirees who live off the steady income of their investments. McCracken says that the fund would be a good choice if upcoming supply side macroeconomic policies of the government are successful. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 13. According to the APT, if the risk-free rate is 4%, what should be McCracken’s estimate of the expected return of Orb’s High Growth Fund? 14. With respect to McCracken’s APT model estimate of Orb’s Large Cap Fund and the information Kwon provides, is an arbitrage opportunity available? 15. The GDP Fund composed from the other three funds would have a weight in Utility Fund equal to (a) 22.2; (b) 23.2; or (c) .3. 16. With respect to the comments of Stiles and McCracken concerning for whom the GDP Fund would be appropriate: a. McCracken was correct and Stiles was wrong. b. Both were correct. c. Stiles was correct and McCracken was wrong. Challenge 17. Assume a universe of n (large) securities for which the largest residual variance is not larger than ns2M. Construct as many different weighting schemes as you can that generate welldiversified portfolios. 18. Derive a more general (than the numerical example in the chapter) demonstration of the APT security market line: a. For a single-factor market. b. For a multifactor market. 19. Small firms will have relatively high loadings (high betas) on the SMB (small minus big) factor. a. Explain why. b. Now suppose two unrelated small firms merge. Each will be operated as an independent unit of the merged company. Would you expect the stock market behavior of the merged firm to differ from that of a portfolio of the two previously independent firms? How does the merger affect market capitalization? What is the prediction of the Fama-French model for the risk premium on the combined firm? Do we see here a flaw in the FF model? 1. Jeffrey Bruner, CFA, uses the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) to help identify mispriced securities. A consultant suggests Bruner use arbitrage pricing theory (APT) instead. In comparing CAPM and APT, the consultant made the following arguments: a. Both the CAPM and APT require a mean-variance efficient market portfolio. b. Neither the CAPM nor APT assumes normally distributed security returns. c. The CAPM assumes that one specific factor explains security returns but APT does not. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 346 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 347 State whether each of the consultant’s arguments is correct or incorrect. Indicate, for each incorrect argument, why the argument is incorrect. 2. Assume that both X and Y are well-diversified portfolios and the risk-free rate is 8%. Portfolio X Y Expected Return 16% 12 Beta 1.00 0.25 In this situation you would conclude that portfolios X and Y: a. b. c. d. Are in equilibrium. Offer an arbitrage opportunity. Are both underpriced. Are both fairly priced. a. b. c. d. The expected return of the portfolio equals zero. The capital market line is tangent to the opportunity set. The Law of One Price remains unviolated. A risk-free arbitrage opportunity exists. 4. According to the theory of arbitrage: a. b. c. d. High-beta stocks are consistently overpriced. Low-beta stocks are consistently overpriced. Positive alpha investment opportunities will quickly disappear. Rational investors will pursue arbitrage consistent with their risk tolerance. 5. The general arbitrage pricing theory (APT) differs from the single-factor capital asset pricing model (CAPM) because the APT: a. b. c. d. Places more emphasis on market risk. Minimizes the importance of diversification. Recognizes multiple unsystematic risk factors. Recognizes multiple systematic risk factors. 6. An investor takes as large a position as possible when an equilibrium price relationship is violated. This is an example of: a. b. c. d. A dominance argument. The mean-variance efficient frontier. Arbitrage activity. The capital asset pricing model. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 3. A zero-investment portfolio with a positive alpha could arise if: 7. The feature of the general version of the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) that offers the greatest potential advantage over the simple CAPM is the: a. Identification of anticipated changes in production, inflation, and term structure of interest rates as key factors explaining the risk–return relationship. b. Superior measurement of the risk-free rate of return over historical time periods. c. Variability of coefficients of sensitivity to the APT factors for a given asset over time. d. Use of several factors instead of a single market index to explain the risk–return relationship. 8. In contrast to the capital asset pricing model, arbitrage pricing theory: a. b. c. d. Requires that markets be in equilibrium. Uses risk premiums based on micro variables. Specifies the number and identifies specific factors that determine expected returns. Does not require the restrictive assumptions concerning the market portfolio. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 347 6/21/13 3:43 PM Final PDF to printer 348 PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES One of the factors in the APT model specified by Chen, Roll, and Ross is the percent change in unanticipated inflation. Who gains and who loses when inflation changes? Go to http://hussmanfunds.com/rsi/infsurprises.htm to see a graph of the Inflation Surprise Index and Economists’ Inflation Forecasts. SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. The GDP beta is 1.2 and GDP growth is 1% better than previously expected. So you will increase your forecast for the stock return by 1.2 3 1% 5 1.2%. The revised forecast is for an 11.2% return. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 2. a. This portfolio is not well diversified. The weight on the first security does not decline as n increases. Regardless of how much diversification there is in the rest of the portfolio, you will not shed the firm-specific risk of this security. bod61671_ch10_324-348.indd 348 b. This portfolio is well diversified. Even though some stocks have three times the weight of other stocks (1.5/n versus .5/n), the weight on all stocks approaches zero as n increases. The impact of any individual stock’s firm-specific risk will approach zero as n becomes ever larger. 3. The equilibrium return is E (r) 5 rf 1 bP1[E (r1) 2 rf ] 1 bP2 [E (r2) 2 rf ]. Using the data in Example 10.4: E(r) 5 4 1 .2 3 (10 2 4) 1 1.4 3 (12 2 4) 5 16.4% 6/21/13 3:43 PM 144 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER FOURTEEN Bond Prices and Yields bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 445 for our analysis of the universe of potential investment vehicles. The bond is the basic debt security, and this chapter starts with an overview of the universe of bond markets, including Treasury, corporate, and international bonds. We turn next to bond pricing, showing how bond prices are set in accordance with market interest rates and why bond prices change with those rates. Given this background, we can compare the myriad measures of bond returns such as yield to maturity, yield to call, holding-period return, and realized compound rate of return. We show how bond prices evolve over time, discuss certain tax rules that apply to debt securities, and show how to calculate after-tax returns. Finally, we consider the impact of default or credit risk on bond pricing and look at the determinants of credit risk and the default premium built into bond yields. Credit risk is central to both collateralized debt obligations and credit default swaps, so we examine these instruments as well. PART IV IN THE PREVIOUS chapters on risk and return relationships, we treated securities at a high level of abstraction. We assumed implicitly that a prior, detailed analysis of each security already had been performed, and that its risk and return features had been assessed. We turn now to specific analyses of particular security markets. We examine valuation principles, determinants of risk and return, and portfolio strategies commonly used within and across the various markets. We begin by analyzing debt securities. A debt security is a claim on a specified periodic stream of income. Debt securities are often called fixed-income securities because they promise either a fixed stream of income or one that is determined according to a specified formula. These securities have the advantage of being relatively easy to understand because the payment formulas are specified in advance. Uncertainty about their cash flows is minimal as long as the issuer of the security is sufficiently creditworthy. That makes these securities a convenient starting point 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 446 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 14.1 Bond Characteristics A bond is a security that is issued in connection with a borrowing arrangement. The borrower issues (i.e., sells) a bond to the lender for some amount of cash; the bond is the “IOU” of the borrower. The arrangement obligates the issuer to make specified payments to the bondholder on specified dates. A typical coupon bond obligates the issuer to make semiannual payments of interest to the bondholder for the life of the bond. These are called coupon payments because in precomputer days, most bonds had coupons that investors would clip off and present to claim the interest payment. When the bond matures, the issuer repays the debt by paying the bond’s par value (equivalently, its face value). The coupon rate of the bond determines the interest payment: The annual payment is the coupon rate times the bond’s par value. The coupon rate, maturity date, and par value of the bond are part of the bond indenture, which is the contract between the issuer and the bondholder. To illustrate, a bond with par value of $1,000 and coupon rate of 8% might be sold to a buyer for $1,000. The bondholder is then entitled to a payment of 8% of $1,000, or $80 per year, for the stated life of the bond, say, 30 years. The $80 payment typically comes in two semiannual installments of $40 each. At the end of the 30-year life of the bond, the issuer also pays the $1,000 par value to the bondholder. Bonds usually are issued with coupon rates set just high enough to induce investors to pay par value to buy the bond. Sometimes, however, zero-coupon bonds are issued that make no coupon payments. In this case, investors receive par value at the maturity date but receive no interest payments until then: The bond has a coupon rate of zero. These bonds are issued at prices considerably below par value, and the investor’s return comes solely from the difference between issue price and the payment of par value at maturity. We will return to these bonds later. U.S. Treasury Quotes ASKED CHANGE YIELD (%) MATURITY COUPON BID ASKED Jun 15 13 1.125 100.8203 100.8281 0.0078 0.177 Jan 15 15 0.250 100.0391 100.0469 0.0547 0.231 Jun 30 16 1.500 104.1563 104.1875 0.1016 0.421 Jul 31 18 Nov 15 18 2.250 108.4922 108.5391 0.0938 0.790 9.000 150.3750 150.4219 0.1719 0.770 Feb 15 21 7.875 154.2344 154.3281 0.1875 1.172 Feb 15 26 6.000 149.1484 149.2266 0.1484 1.869 May 15 30 6.250 160.2190 161.0000 0.0781 2.117 Feb 15 36 4.500 138.4063 138.4844 0.1641 2.362 May 15 42 3.000 108.8047 108.8672 0.1328 2.572 Figure 14.1 Prices and yields of U.S. Treasury bonds Source: The Wall Street Journal Online, July 31, 2012. Reprinted by permission of Dow Jones & Company, Inc. © 2012 Dow Jones & Company. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. Treasury Bonds and Notes Figure 14.1 is an excerpt from the listing of Treasury issues. Treasury notes are issued with original maturities ranging between 1 and 10 years, while Treasury bonds are issued with maturities ranging from 10 to 30 years. Both bonds and notes may be purchased directly from the Treasury in denominations of only $100, but denominations of $1,000 are far more common. Both make semiannual coupon payments. The highlighted bond in Figure 14.1 matures on July 31, 2018. Its coupon rate is 2.25%. Par value typically is $1,000; thus the bond pays interest of $22.50 per year in two semiannual payments of $11.25. Payments are made in January and July of each year. Although bonds usually are sold in denominations of $1,000, the bid and ask prices are quoted as a percentage of par value.1 1 Recall that the bid price is the price at which you can sell the bond to a dealer. The ask price, which is slightly higher, is the price at which you can buy the bond from a dealer. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 446 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 447 Therefore, the ask price is 108.5391% of par, or $1,085.391. The minimum price increment, or tick size, in The Wall Street Journal listing is 1/128, so this bond may also be viewed as selling for 108 69⁄128 percent of par value.2 The last column, labeled “Ask yield,” is the yield to maturity on the bond based on the ask price. The yield to maturity is a measure of the average rate of return to an investor who purchases the bond for the ask price and holds it until its maturity date. We will have much to say about yield to maturity below. Accrued Interest and Quoted Bond Prices The bond prices that you see quoted in the financial pages are not actually the prices that investors pay for the bond. This is because the quoted price does not include the interest that accrues between coupon payment dates. If a bond is purchased between coupon payments, the buyer must pay the seller for accrued interest, the prorated share of the upcoming semiannual coupon. For example, if 30 days have passed since the last coupon payment, and there are 182 days in the semiannual coupon period, the seller is entitled to a payment of accrued interest of 30/182 of the semiannual coupon. The sale, or invoice, price of the bond would equal the stated price (sometimes called the flat price) plus the accrued interest. In general, the formula for the amount of accrued interest between two dates is Accrued interest 5 Example 14.1 Annual coupon payment Days since last coupon payment 3 2 Days separating coupon payments Accrued Interest Suppose that the coupon rate is 8%. Then the annual coupon is $80 and the semiannual coupon payment is $40. Because 30 days have passed since the last coupon payment, the accrued interest on the bond is $40 3 (30/182) 5 $6.59. If the quoted price of the bond is $990, then the invoice price will be $990 1 $6.59 5 $996.59. The practice of quoting bond prices net of accrued interest explains why the price of a maturing bond is listed at $1,000 rather than $1,000 plus one coupon payment. A purchaser of an 8% coupon bond 1 day before the bond’s maturity would receive $1,040 (par value plus semiannual interest) on the following day and so should be willing to pay a total price of $1,040 for the bond. The bond price is quoted net of accrued interest in the financial pages and thus appears as $1,000.3 Corporate Bonds Like the government, corporations borrow money by issuing bonds. Figure 14.2 is a sample of listings for a few actively traded corporate bonds. Although some bonds trade 2 Bonds traded on formal exchanges are subject to minimum tick sizes set by the exchange. For example, the minimum price increment on the 2-year Treasury bond futures contract (traded on the Chicago Board of Trade) is 1/128, although longer-term T-bonds have larger tick sizes. Private traders can negotiate their own tick size. For example, one can find price quotes on Bloomberg screens with tick sizes as low as 1/256. 3 In contrast to bonds, stocks do not trade at flat prices with adjustments for “accrued dividends.” Whoever owns the stock when it goes “ex-dividend” receives the entire dividend payment, and the stock price reflects the value of the upcoming dividend. The price therefore typically falls by about the amount of the dividend on the “ex-day.” There is no need to differentiate between reported and invoice prices for stocks. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 447 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 448 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities MOODY'S/S&P/ FITCH HIGH LOW LAST May 2013 A2 /A+ /AA– 103.7060 103.4240 103.6590 1.3090 0.5662 5.750% Jan 2022 A3 /A– /A 111.8040 100.3290 109.4040 0.2034 4.5187 BUD3876843 2.500% Jul 2022 A3 /A /A 104.1200 101.8410 102.1360 0.4110 2.2590 JPMORGAN CHASE & CO JPM.KPG 4.750% May 2013 A2 /A /A+ 103.1790 102.6250 103.1790 0.2720 0.4663 HOUSEHOLD FIN CORP HBC.IGQ 4.750% Jul 2013 Baa1 /A /AA– 105.3220 103.0760 103.3780 0.2280 1.1635 ANHEUSER BUSCH INBEV WORLDWIDE BUD3876840 1.375% Jul 2017 A3 /A /A 101.3000 100.9150 101.0460 –0.0820 1.1569 ISSUER NAME SYMBOL COUPON MATURITY WACHOVIA CORP GLOBAL MTN WFC.PO 5.500% GOLDMAN SACHS GROUP INC GD.AEH ANHEUSER BUSCH INBEV WORLDWIDE CHANGE YIELD % Figure 14.2 Listing of corporate bonds Source: FINRA (Financial Industry Regulatory Authority), August 1, 2012. electronically on the NYSE Bonds platform, most bonds are traded over-the-counter in a network of bond dealers linked by a computer quotation system. In practice, the bond market can be quite “thin,” with few investors interested in trading a particular issue at any particular time. The bond listings in Figure 14.2 include the coupon, maturity, price, and yield to maturity of each bond. The “rating” column is the estimation of bond safety given by the three major bond-rating agencies—Moody’s, Standard & Poor’s, and Fitch. Bonds with gradations of A ratings are safer than those with B ratings or below. As a general rule, safer bonds with higher ratings promise lower yields to maturity than other bonds with similar maturities. We will return to this topic toward the end of the chapter. Call Provisions on Corporate Bonds Some corporate bonds are issued with call provisions allowing the issuer to repurchase the bond at a specified call price before the maturity date. For example, if a company issues a bond with a high coupon rate when market interest rates are high, and interest rates later fall, the firm might like to retire the high-coupon debt and issue new bonds at a lower coupon rate to reduce interest payments. This is called refunding. Callable bonds typically come with a period of call protection, an initial time during which the bonds are not callable. Such bonds are referred to as deferred callable bonds. The option to call the bond is valuable to the firm, allowing it to buy back the bonds and refinance at lower interest rates when market rates fall. Of course, the firm’s CONCEPT CHECK 14.1 benefit is the bondholder’s burden. Holders of called bonds must forfeit their bonds for the call price, thereby Suppose that Verizon issues two bonds with giving up the attractive coupon rate on their original identical coupon rates and maturity dates. One investment. To compensate investors for this risk, callbond is callable, however, whereas the other is not. Which bond will sell at a higher price? able bonds are issued with higher coupons and promised yields to maturity than noncallable bonds. Convertible Bonds Convertible bonds give bondholders an option to exchange each bond for a specified number of shares of common stock of the firm. The conversion ratio is the number of shares for which each bond may be exchanged. Suppose a convertible bond is issued at par value of $1,000 and is convertible into 40 shares of a firm’s bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 448 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 449 stock. The current stock price is $20 per share, so the option to convert is not profitable now. Should the stock price later rise to $30, however, each bond may be converted profitably into $1,200 worth of stock. The market conversion value is the current value of the shares for which the bonds may be exchanged. At the $20 stock price, for example, the bond’s conversion value is $800. The conversion premium is the excess of the bond value over its conversion value. If the bond were selling currently for $950, its premium would be $150. Convertible bondholders benefit from price appreciation of the company’s stock. Again, this benefit comes at a price: Convertible bonds offer lower coupon rates and stated or promised yields to maturity than do nonconvertible bonds. However, the actual return on the convertible bond may exceed the stated yield to maturity if the option to convert becomes profitable. We discuss convertible and callable bonds further in Chapter 20. Puttable Bonds While the callable bond gives the issuer the option to extend or retire the bond at the call date, the extendable or put bond gives this option to the bondholder. If the bond’s coupon rate exceeds current market yields, for instance, the bondholder will choose to extend the bond’s life. If the bond’s coupon rate is too low, it will be optimal not to extend; the bondholder instead reclaims principal, which can be invested at current yields. Floating-Rate Bonds Floating-rate bonds make interest payments that are tied to some measure of current market rates. For example, the rate might be adjusted annually to the current T-bill rate plus 2%. If the 1-year T-bill rate at the adjustment date is 4%, the bond’s coupon rate over the next year would then be 6%. This arrangement means that the bond always pays approximately current market rates. The major risk involved in floaters has to do with changes in the firm’s financial strength. The yield spread is fixed over the life of the security, which may be many years. If the financial health of the firm deteriorates, then investors will demand a greater yield premium than is offered by the security. In this case, the price of the bond will fall. Although the coupon rate on floaters adjusts to changes in the general level of market interest rates, it does not adjust to changes in the financial condition of the firm. Preferred Stock Although preferred stock strictly speaking is considered to be equity, it often is included in the fixed-income universe. This is because, like bonds, preferred stock promises to pay a specified stream of dividends. However, unlike bonds, the failure to pay the promised dividend does not result in corporate bankruptcy. Instead, the dividends owed simply cumulate, and the common stockholders may not receive any dividends until the preferred stockholders have been paid in full. In the event of bankruptcy, preferred stockholders’ claims to the firm’s assets have lower priority than those of bondholders but higher priority than those of common stockholders. Preferred stock commonly pays a fixed dividend. Therefore, it is in effect a perpetuity, providing a level cash flow indefinitely. In contrast, floating-rate preferred stock is much like floating-rate bonds. The dividend rate is linked to a measure of current market interest rates and is adjusted at regular intervals. Unlike interest payments on bonds, dividends on preferred stock are not considered tax-deductible expenses to the firm. This reduces their attractiveness as a source of capital to issuing firms. On the other hand, there is an offsetting tax advantage to preferred stock. When one corporation buys the preferred stock of another corporation, it pays taxes on only 30% of the dividends received. For example, if the firm’s tax bracket is 35%, and it receives $10,000 in preferred-dividend payments, it will pay taxes on only $3,000 of bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 449 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 450 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities that income: Total taxes owed on the income will be .35 3 $3,000 5 $1,050. The firm’s effective tax rate on preferred dividends is therefore only .30 3 35% 5 10.5%. Given this tax rule, it is not surprising that most preferred stock is held by corporations. Preferred stock rarely gives its holders full voting privileges in the firm. However, if the preferred dividend is skipped, the preferred stockholders may then be provided some voting power. Other Domestic Issuers There are, of course, several issuers of bonds in addition to the Treasury and private corporations. For example, state and local governments issue municipal bonds. The outstanding feature of these is that interest payments are tax-free. We examined municipal bonds, the value of the tax exemption, and the equivalent taxable yield of these bonds in Chapter 2. Government agencies such as the Federal Home Loan Bank Board, the Farm Credit agencies, and the mortgage pass-through agencies Ginnie Mae, Fannie Mae, and Freddie Mac also issue considerable amounts of bonds. These too were reviewed in Chapter 2. International Bonds International bonds are commonly divided into two categories, foreign bonds and Eurobonds. Foreign bonds are issued by a borrower from a country other than the one in which the bond is sold. The bond is denominated in the currency of the country in which it is marketed. For example, if a German firm sells a dollar-denominated bond in the United States, the bond is considered a foreign bond. These bonds are given colorful names based on the countries in which they are marketed. For example, foreign bonds sold in the United States are called Yankee bonds. Like other bonds sold in the United States, they are registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission. Yen-denominated bonds sold in Japan by non-Japanese issuers are called Samurai bonds. British pound-denominated foreign bonds sold in the United Kingdom are called bulldog bonds. In contrast to foreign bonds, Eurobonds are denominated in one currency, usually that of the issuer, but sold in other national markets. For example, the Eurodollar market refers to dollar-denominated bonds sold outside the United States (not just in Europe), although London is the largest market for Eurodollar bonds. Because the Eurodollar market falls outside U.S. jurisdiction, these bonds are not regulated by U.S. federal agencies. Similarly, Euroyen bonds are yen-denominated bonds selling outside Japan, Eurosterling bonds are pound-denominated Eurobonds selling outside the United Kingdom, and so on. Innovation in the Bond Market Issuers constantly develop innovative bonds with unusual features; these issues illustrate that bond design can be extremely flexible. Here are examples of some novel bonds. They should give you a sense of the potential variety in security design. Inverse Floaters These are similar to the floating-rate bonds we described earlier, except that the coupon rate on these bonds falls when the general level of interest rates rises. Investors in these bonds suffer doubly when rates rise. Not only does the present value of each dollar of cash flow from the bond fall as the discount rate rises, but the level of those cash flows falls as well. Of course, investors in these bonds benefit doubly when rates fall. Asset-Backed Bonds Miramax once issued bonds with coupon rates tied to the financial performance of Pulp Fiction and other films. Domino’s Pizza has issued bonds with bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 450 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 451 payments backed by revenues from its pizza franchises. These are examples of asset-backed securities. The income from a specified group of assets is used to service the debt. More conventional asset-backed securities are mortgage-backed securities or securities backed by auto or credit card loans, as we discussed in Chapter 2. Catastrophe Bonds Oriental Land Company, which manages Tokyo Disneyland, issued a bond in 1999 with a final payment that depended on whether there had been an earthquake near the park. More recently, FIFA (the Fédération Internationale de Football Association) issued catastrophe bonds with payments that would be halted if terrorism forced the cancellation of the 2006 World Cup. These bonds are a way to transfer “catastrophe risk” from the firm to the capital markets. Investors in these bonds receive compensation for taking on the risk in the form of higher coupon rates. But in the event of a catastrophe, the bondholders will give up all or part of their investments. “Disaster” can be defined by total insured losses or by criteria such as wind speed in a hurricane or Richter level in an earthquake. Issuance of catastrophe bonds has grown in recent years as insurers have sought ways to spread their risks across a wider spectrum of the capital market. Indexed Bonds Indexed bonds make payments that are tied to a general price index or the price of a particular commodity. For example, Mexico has issued bonds with payments that depend on the price of oil. Some bonds are indexed to the general price level. The United States Treasury started issuing such inflation-indexed bonds in January 1997. They are called Treasury Inflation Protected Securities (TIPS). By tying the par value of the bond to the general level of prices, coupon payments as well as the final repayment of par value on these bonds increase in direct proportion to the Consumer Price Index. Therefore, the interest rate on these bonds is a risk-free real rate. To illustrate how TIPS work, consider a newly issued bond with a 3-year maturity, par value of $1,000, and a coupon rate of 4%. For simplicity, we will assume the bond makes annual coupon payments. Assume that inflation turns out to be 2%, 3%, and 1% in the next 3 years. Table 14.1 shows how the bond cash flows will be calculated. The first payment comes at the end of the first year, at t 5 1. Because inflation over the year was 2%, the par value of the bond increases from $1,000 to $1,020; because the coupon rate is 4%, the coupon payment is 4% of this amount, or $40.80. Notice that par value increases by the inflation rate, and because the coupon payments are 4% of par, they too increase in proportion to the general price level. Therefore, the cash flows paid by the bond are fixed in real terms. When the bond matures, the investor receives a final coupon payment of $42.44 plus the (price-level-indexed) repayment of principal, $1,061.11.4 Inflation in Year Coupon Principal Time Just Ended Par Value Payment 1 Repayment 5 Total Payment 0 1 2 3 2% 3 1 $1,000.00 1,020.00 1,050.60 1,061.11 $40.80 42.02 42.44 $ 0 0 1,061.11 $ 40.80 42.02 1,103.55 Table 14.1 Principal and interest payments for a Treasury Inflation Protected Security 4 By the way, total nominal income (i.e., coupon plus that year’s increase in principal) is treated as taxable income in each year. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 451 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 452 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities The nominal rate of return on the bond in the first year is Nominal return 5 Interest 1 Price appreciation 40.80 1 20 5 5 6.08% Initial price 1,000 The real rate of return is precisely the 4% real yield on the bond: Real return 5 1 1 Nominal return 1.0608 215 2 1 5 .04, or 4% 1 1 Inflation 1.02 One can show in a similar manner (see Problem 18 in the end-of-chapter problems) that the rate of return in each of the 3 years is 4% as long as the real yield on the bond remains constant. If real yields do change, then there will be capital gains or losses on the bond. In mid-2013, the real yield on long-term TIPS bonds was less than 0.5%. 14.2 Bond Pricing Because a bond’s coupon and principal repayments all occur months or years in the future, the price an investor would be willing to pay for a claim to those payments depends on the value of dollars to be received in the future compared to dollars in hand today. This “present value” calculation depends in turn on market interest rates. As we saw in Chapter 5, the nominal risk-free interest rate equals the sum of (1) a real risk-free rate of return and (2) a premium above the real rate to compensate for expected inflation. In addition, because most bonds are not riskless, the discount rate will embody an additional premium that reflects bond-specific characteristics such as default risk, liquidity, tax attributes, call risk, and so on. We simplify for now by assuming there is one interest rate that is appropriate for discounting cash flows of any maturity, but we can relax this assumption easily. In practice, there may be different discount rates for cash flows accruing in different periods. For the time being, however, we ignore this refinement. To value a security, we discount its expected cash flows by the appropriate discount rate. The cash flows from a bond consist of coupon payments until the maturity date plus the final payment of par value. Therefore, Bond value 5 Present value of coupons 1 Present value of par value If we call the maturity date T and call the interest rate r, the bond value can be written as T Coupon Par value Bond value 5 a t 1 ( ) (1 1 r)T 1 1 r t51 (14.1) The summation sign in Equation 14.1 directs us to add the present value of each coupon payment; each coupon is discounted based on the time until it will be paid. The first term on the right-hand side of Equation 14.1 is the present value of an annuity. The second term is the present value of a single amount, the final payment of the bond’s par value. You may recall from an introductory finance class that the present value of a $1 annuity 1 1 R. We call this that lasts for T periods when the interest rate equals r is B1 2 r (1 1 r)T bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 452 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 453 1 (1 1 r)T the PV factor, that is, the present value of a single payment of $1 to be received in T periods. Therefore, we can write the price of the bond as expression the T-period annuity factor for an interest rate of r.5 Similarly, we call Price 5 Coupon 3 1 1 1 B1 2 R 1 Par value 3 r (1 1 r)T (1 1 r ) T (14.2) 5 Coupon 3 Annuity factor(r, T) 1 Par value 3 PV factor(r, T) Example 14.2 Bond Pricing We discussed earlier an 8% coupon, 30-year maturity bond with par value of $1,000 paying 60 semiannual coupon payments of $40 each. Suppose that the interest rate is 8% annually, or r 5 4% per 6-month period. Then the value of the bond can be written as 60 $1,000 $40 Price 5 a 1 t (14.3) (1.04)60 t51 (1.04) 5 $40 3 Annuity factor(4%, 60) 1 $1,000 3 PV factor(4%, 60) It is easy to confirm that the present value of the bond’s 60 semiannual coupon payments of $40 each is $904.94 and that the $1,000 final payment of par value has a present value of $95.06, for a total bond value of $1,000. You can calculate the value directly from Equation 14.2, perform these calculations on any financial calculator (see Example 14.3 below), use a spreadsheet program (see the Excel Applications box), or use a set of present value tables. In this example, the coupon rate equals the market interest rate, and the bond price equals par value. If the interest rate were not equal to the bond’s coupon rate, the bond would not sell at par value. For example, if the interest rate were to rise to 10% (5% per 6 months), the bond’s price would fall by $189.29 to $810.71, as follows: $40 3 Annuity factor(5%, 60) 1 $1,000 3 PV factor(5%, 60) 5 $757.17 1 $53.54 5 $810.71 At a higher interest rate, the present value of the payments to be received by the bondholder is lower. Therefore, bond prices fall as market interest rates rise. This illustrates a crucial general rule in bond valuation.6 5 Here is a quick derivation of the formula for the present value of an annuity. An annuity lasting T periods can be viewed as equivalent to a perpetuity whose first payment comes at the end of the current period less another perpetuity whose first payment comes at the end of the (T 1 1)st period. The immediate perpetuity net of the delayed perpetuity provides exactly T payments. We know that the value of a $1 per period perpetuity is $1/r. Therefore, 1 1 the present value of the delayed perpetuity is $1/r discounted for T additional periods, or 3 . r (1 1 r)T The present value of the annuity is the present value of the first perpetuity minus the present value of the delayed 1 1 perpetuity, or B 1 2 R. r (1 1 r)T 6 Here is a trap to avoid. You should not confuse the bond’s coupon rate, which determines the interest paid to the bondholder, with the market interest rate. Once a bond is issued, its coupon rate is fixed. When the market interest rate increases, investors discount any fixed payments at a higher discount rate, which implies that present values and bond prices fall. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 453 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 454 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Bond prices are tedious to calculate without a spreadsheet or a financial calculator, but they are easy to calculate with either. Financial calculators designed with present and future value formulas already programmed can greatly simplify calculations of the sort we just encountered in Example 14.2. The basic financial calculator uses five keys that correspond to the inputs for time-value-of-money problems such as bond pricing: 1. n is the number of time periods. In the case of a bond, n equals the number of periods until the bond matures. If the bond makes semiannual payments, n is the number of half-year periods or, equivalently, the number of semiannual coupon payments. For example, if the bond has 10 years until maturity, you would enter 20 for n, since each payment period is one-half year. 2. i is the interest rate per period, expressed as a percentage (not as a decimal). For example, if the interest rate is 6%, you would enter 6, not .06. 3. PV is the present value. Many calculators require that PV be entered as a negative number, in recognition of the fact that purchase of the bond is a cash outflow, while the receipt of coupon payments and face value are cash inflows. 4. FV is the future value or face value of the bond. In general, FV is interpreted as a one-time future payment of a cash flow, which, for bonds, is the face (i.e., par) value. 5. PMT is the amount of any recurring payment. For coupon bonds, PMT is the coupon payment; for zero-coupon bonds, PMT will be zero. Given any four of these inputs, the calculator will solve for the fifth. We can illustrate with the bond in Example 14.2. Example 14.3 Bond Pricing on a Financial Calculator To find the bond’s price when the annual market interest rate is 8%, you would enter these inputs (in any order): n i FV PMT 60 4 1,000 40 The bond has a maturity of 30 years, so it makes 60 semiannual payments. The semiannual market interest rate is 4%. The bond will provide a one-time cash flow of $1,000 when it matures. Each semiannual coupon payment is $40. On most calculators, you now punch the “compute” key (labeled COMP or CPT) and then enter PV to obtain the bond price, that is the present value today of the bond’s cash flows. If you do this, you should find a value of 21,000. The negative sign signifies that while the investor receives cash flows from the bond, the price paid to buy the bond is a cash outflow, or a negative cash flow. If you want to find the value of the bond when the interest rate is 10% (the second part of Example 14.2), just enter 5% for the semiannual interest rate (type “5” and then “i”), and when you compute PV, you will find that it is 2810.71. Figure 14.3 shows the price of the 30-year, 8% coupon bond for a range of interest rates, including 8%, at which the bond sells at par, and 10%, at which it sells for $810.71. The negative slope illustrates the inverse relationship between prices and yields. The shape of the curve in Figure 14.3 implies that an increase in the interest rate results in a price bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 454 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 455 decline that is smaller than the price gain resulting from a decrease of equal magnitude in the interest rate. This property of bond prices is called convexity because of the convex shape of the bond price curve. This curvature reflects the fact that progressive increases in the interest rate result in progressively smaller reductions in the bond price.7 Therefore, the price curve becomes flatter at higher interest rates. We return to convexity in Chapter 16. CONCEPT CHECK 14.2 Calculate the price of the 30-year, 8% coupon bond for a market interest rate of 3% per half-year. Compare the capital gains for the interest rate decline to the losses incurred when the rate increases to 5%. Bond Price ($) Corporate bonds typically are issued at par value. This means that the underwriters 4,000 of the bond issue (the firms that market the 3,500 bonds to the public for the issuing corpora3,000 tion) must choose a coupon rate that very 2,500 closely approximates market yields. In a primary issue, the underwriters attempt to 2,000 sell the newly issued bonds directly to their 1,500 customers. If the coupon rate is inadequate, 1,000 investors will not pay par value for the 810.71 bonds. 500 After the bonds are issued, bondholders 0 may buy or sell bonds in secondary mar0 5 8 10 15 20 kets. In these markets, bond prices fluctuate Interest Rate (%) inversely with the market interest rate. The inverse relationship between price and yield is a central feature of fixedFigure 14.3 The inverse relationship between bond prices income securities. Interest rate fluctuations and yields. Price of an 8% coupon bond with 30-year represent the main source of risk in the maturity making semiannual payments fixed-income market, and we devote considerable attention in Chapter 16 to assessing the sensitivity of bond prices to market yields. For now, however, we simply highlight one key factor that determines that sensitivity, namely, the maturity of the bond. As a general rule, keeping all other factors the same, the longer the maturity of the bond, the greater the sensitivity of price to fluctuations in the interest rate. For example, consider Table 14.2, which presents the price of an 8% coupon bond at different market yields and times to maturity. For any departure of the interest rate from 8% (the rate at which the bond sells at par value), the change in the bond price is greater for longer times to maturity. This makes sense. If you buy the bond at par with an 8% coupon rate, and market rates subsequently rise, then you suffer a loss: You have tied up your money earning 8% when alternative investments offer higher returns. This is reflected in a capital loss on 7 The progressively smaller impact of interest increases results largely from the fact that at higher rates the bond is worth less. Therefore, an additional increase in rates operates on a smaller initial base, resulting in a smaller price decline. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 455 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 456 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Table 14.2 Bond Price at Given Market Interest Rate Bond prices at different interest rates (8% coupon bond, coupons paid semiannually) Time to Maturity 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% 1 year 1,059.11 1,038.83 1,019.13 1,000.00 981.41 10 years 20 years 30 years 1,541.37 1,985.04 2,348.65 1,327.03 1,547.11 1,695.22 1,148.77 1,231.15 1,276.76 1,000.00 1,000.00 1,000.00 875.35 828.41 810.71 the bond—a fall in its market price. The longer the period for which your money is tied up, the greater the loss, and correspondingly the greater the drop in the bond price. In Table 14.2, the row for 1-year maturity bonds shows little price sensitivity—that is, with only 1 year’s earnings at stake, changes in interest rates are not too threatening. But for 30-year maturity bonds, interest rate swings have a large impact on bond prices. The force of discounting is greatest for the longest-term bonds. This is why short-term Treasury securities such as T-bills are considered to be the safest. They are free not only of default risk but also largely of price risk attributable to interest rate volatility. Bond Pricing between Coupon Dates Equation 14.2 for bond prices assumes that the next coupon payment is in precisely one payment period, either a year for an annual payment bond or 6 months for a semiannual payment bond. But you probably want to be able to price bonds all 365 days of the year, not just on the one or two dates each year that it makes a coupon payment! In principle, the fact that the bond is between coupon dates does not affect the pricing problem. The procedure is always the same: Compute the present value of each remaining payment and sum up. But if you are between coupon dates, there will be fractional periods remaining until each payment, and this does complicate the arithmetic computations. Fortunately, bond pricing functions are included in most spreadsheet programs such as Excel. The spreadsheet allows you to enter today’s date as well as the maturity date of the bond, and so can provide prices for bonds at any date. The nearby box shows you how. As we pointed out earlier, bond prices are typically quoted net of accrued interest. These prices, which appear in the financial press, are called flat prices. The actual invoice price that a buyer pays for the bond includes accrued interest. Thus, Invoice price 5 Flat price 1 Accrued interest When a bond pays its coupon, flat price equals invoice price, because at that moment accrued interest reverts to zero. However, this will be the exceptional case, not the rule. Excel pricing functions provide the flat price of the bond. To find the invoice price, we need to add accrued interest. Fortunately, Excel also provides functions that count the days since the last coupon payment date and thus can be used to compute accrued interest. The nearby box also illustrates how to use these functions. The box provides examples using bonds that have just paid a coupon and so have zero accrued interest, as well as a bond that is between coupon dates. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 456 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer eXcel APPLICATIONS: Bond Pricing E xcel and most other spreadsheet programs provide built-in functions to compute bond prices and yields. They typically ask you to input both the date you buy the bond (called the settlement date) and the maturity date of the bond. The Excel function for bond price is 5 PRICE(settlement date, maturity date, annual coupon rate, yield to maturity, redemption value as percent of par value, number of coupon payments per year) For the 2.25% coupon July 2018 maturity bond highlighted in Figure 14.1, we would enter the values in Spreadsheet 14.1. (Notice that in spreadsheets, we must enter interest rates as decimals, not percentages). Alternatively, we could simply enter the following function in Excel: 5 PRICE(DATE(2012,7,31), DATE(2018,7,31), .0225, .0079, 100, 2) The DATE function in Excel, which we use for both the settlement and maturity date, uses the format DATE(year,month,day). The first date is July 31, 2012, when the bond is purchased, and the second is July 31, 2018, when it matures. Most bonds pay coupons either on the 15th or the last business day of the month. Notice that the coupon rate and yield to maturity are expressed as decimals, not percentages. In most cases, redemption value is 100 (i.e., 100% of par value), and the resulting price similarly is expressed as a percent of par value. Occasionally, however, you may encounter bonds that pay off at a premium or discount to par value. One example would be callable bonds, discussed shortly. The value of the bond returned by the pricing function is 108.5392 (cell B12), which nearly matches the price reported in Table 14.1. (The yield to maturity is A 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 B 2.25% coupon bond, maturing July 31, 2018 Settlement date Maturity date Annual coupon rate Yield to maturity Redemption value (% of face value) Coupon payments per year 7/31/2012 7/31/2018 0.0225 0.0079 100 2 Flat price (% of par) Days since last coupon Days in coupon period Accrued interest Invoice price 108.5392 0 184 0 108.5392 Spreadsheet 14.1 Bond Pricing in Excel reported to only three decimal places, which results in a little rounding error.) This bond has just paid a coupon. In other words, the settlement date is precisely at the beginning of the coupon period, so no adjustment for accrued interest is necessary. To illustrate the procedure for bonds between coupon payments, consider the 6.25% coupon May 2030 bond, also appearing in Figure 14.1. Using the entries in column D of the spreadsheet, we find in cell D12 that the (flat) price of the bond is 161.002, which matches the price given in the figure except for a few cents’ rounding error. What about the bond’s invoice price? Rows 13 through 16 make the necessary adjustments. The function described in cell C13 counts the days since the last coupon. This day count is based on the bond’s settlement date, maturity date, coupon period (1 5 annual; 2 5 semiannual), and day count convention (choice 1 uses actual days). The function described in cell C14 counts the total days in each coupon payment period. Therefore, the entries for accrued interest in row 15 are the semiannual coupon multiplied by the fraction of a coupon period that has elapsed since the last payment. Finally, the invoice prices in row 16 are the sum of flat price plus accrued interest. As a final example, suppose you wish to find the price of the bond in Example 14.2. It is a 30-year maturity bond with a coupon rate of 8% (paid semiannually). The market interest rate given in the latter part of the example is 10%. However, you are not given a specific settlement or maturity date. You can still use the PRICE function to value the bond. Simply choose an arbitrary settlement date (January 1, 2000, is convenient) and let the maturity date be 30 years hence. The appropriate inputs appear in column F of the spreadsheet, with the resulting price, 81.0707% of face value, appearing in cell F16. C Formula in column B = DATE (2012, 7, 31) = DATE (2018, 7, 31) =PRICE(B4,B5,B6,B7,B8,B9) =COUPDAYBS(B4,B5,2,1) =COUPDAYS(B4,B5,2,1) =(B13/B14)*B6*100/2 =B12 +B15 D E 6.25% coupon bond, maturing May 2030 F G 8% coupon bond, 30-year maturity 7/31/2012 5/15/2030 0.0625 0.02117 100 2 1/1/2000 1/1/2030 0.08 0.1 100 2 161.0020 77 184 1.308 162.3097 81.0707 0 182 0 81.0707 eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 457 bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 457 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 458 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 14.3 Bond Yields Most bonds do not sell for par value. But ultimately, barring default, they will mature to par value. Therefore, we would like a measure of rate of return that accounts for both current income and the price increase or decrease over the bond’s life. The yield to maturity is the standard measure of the total rate of return. However, it is far from perfect, and we will explore several variations of this measure. Yield to Maturity In practice, an investor considering the purchase of a bond is not quoted a promised rate of return. Instead, the investor must use the bond price, maturity date, and coupon payments to infer the return offered by the bond over its life. The yield to maturity (YTM) is defined as the interest rate that makes the present value of a bond’s payments equal to its price. This interest rate is often interpreted as a measure of the average rate of return that will be earned on a bond if it is bought now and held until maturity. To calculate the yield to maturity, we solve the bond price equation for the interest rate given the bond’s price. Example 14.4 Yield to Maturity Suppose an 8% coupon, 30-year bond is selling at $1,276.76. What average rate of return would be earned by an investor purchasing the bond at this price? We find the interest rate at which the present value of the remaining 60 semiannual payments equals the bond price. This is the rate consistent with the observed price of the bond. Therefore, we solve for r in the following equation: 60 $1,000 $40 $1,276.76 5 a 1 t ( ) ( 1 1 r 1 1 r)60 t51 or, equivalently, 1,276.76 5 40 3 Annuity factor(r, 60) 1 1,000 3 PV factor(r, 60) These equations have only one unknown variable, the interest rate, r. You can use a financial calculator or spreadsheet to confirm that the solution is r 5 .03, or 3%, per half-year.8 This is the bond’s yield to maturity. The financial press reports yields on an annualized basis, and annualizes the bond’s semiannual yield using simple interest techniques, resulting in an annual percentage rate, or APR. Yields annualized using simple interest are also called “bond equivalent yields.” Therefore, the semiannual yield would be doubled and reported in the newspaper as a bond equivalent yield of 6%. The effective annual yield of the bond, however, accounts for compound interest. If one earns 3% interest every 6 months, then after 1 year, each dollar invested grows with interest to $1 3 (1.03)2 5 $1.0609, and the effective annual interest rate on the bond is 6.09%. 8 On your financial calculator, you would enter the following inputs: n 5 60 periods; PV 5 21276.76; FV 5 1000; PMT 5 40; then you would compute the interest rate (COMP i or CPT i). Notice that we enter the present value, or PV, of the bond as minus $1,276.76. Again, this is because most calculators treat the initial purchase price of the bond as a cash outflow. Spreadsheet 14.2 shows how to find yield to maturity using Excel. Without a financial calculator or spreadsheet, you still could solve the equation, but you would need to use a trial-and-error approach. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 458 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 459 Excel also provides a function for yield to maturity that is especially useful in-between coupon dates. It is 5 YIELD(settlement date, maturity date, annual coupon rate, bond price, redemption value as percent of par value, number of coupon payments per year) The bond price used in the function should be the reported flat price, without accrued interest. For example, to find the yield to maturity of the bond in Example 14.4, we would use column B of Spreadsheet 14.2. If the coupons were paid only annually, we would change the entry for payments per year to 1 (see cell D8), and the yield would fall slightly to 5.99%. The bond’s yield to maturity is the internal rate of return on an investment in the bond. The yield to maturity can be interpreted as the compound rate of return over the life of the bond under the assumption that all bond coupons can be reinvested at that yield.9 Yield to maturity is widely accepted as a proxy for average return. Yield to maturity differs from the current yield of a bond, which is the bond’s annual coupon payment divided by the bond price. For example, for the 8%, 30-year bond currently selling at $1,276.76, the current yield would be $80/$1,276.76 5 .0627, or 6.27%, per year. In contrast, recall that the effective annual yield to maturity is 6.09%. For this bond, which is selling at a premium over par value ($1,276 rather than $1,000), the coupon rate (8%) exceeds the current yield (6.27%), which exceeds the yield to maturity (6.09%). The coupon rate exceeds current yield because the coupon rate divides the coupon payments by par value ($1,000) rather than by the bond price ($1,276). In turn, the current yield exceeds yield to maturity because the yield to maturity accounts for the built-in capital loss on the bond; the bond bought today for $1,276 will eventually fall in value to $1,000 at maturity. Example 14.4 illustrates a general rule: For premium bonds (bonds selling above par value), coupon rate is greater than current yield, which in turn is greater than yield A 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 B C Semiannual coupons Settlement date Maturity date Annual coupon rate Bond price (flat) Redemption value (% of face value) Coupon payments per year Yield to maturity (decimal) D E Annual coupons 1/1/2000 1/1/2030 0.08 127.676 100 2 1/1/2000 1/1/2030 0.08 127.676 100 1 0.0600 0.0599 The formula entered here is: =YIELD(B3,B4,B5,B6,B7,B8) Spreadsheet 14.2 Finding yield to maturity in Excel eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 9 If the reinvestment rate does not equal the bond’s yield to maturity, the compound rate of return will differ from YTM. This is demonstrated below in Examples 14.6 and 14.7. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 459 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 460 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities to maturity. For discount bonds (bonds selling below par value), these relationships are reversed (see Concept Check 3). It is common to hear people talking loosely about the yield on a bond. In these cases, they almost always are referring to the yield to maturity. CONCEPT CHECK 14.3 What will be the relationship among coupon rate, current yield, and yield to maturity for bonds selling at discounts from par? Illustrate using the 8% (semiannual payment) coupon bond, assuming it is selling at a yield to maturity of 10%. Yield to Call Prices ($) Yield to maturity is calculated on the assumption that the bond will be held until maturity. What if the bond is callable, however, and may be retired prior to the maturity date? How should we measure average rate of return for bonds subject to a call provision? Figure 14.4 illustrates the risk of call to the bondholder. The top line is the value of a “straight” (i.e., noncallable) bond with par value $1,000, an 8% coupon rate, and a 30-year time to maturity as a function of the market interest rate. If interest rates fall, the bond price, which equals the present value of the promised payments, can rise substantially. Now consider a bond that has the same coupon rate and maturity date but is callable at 110% of par value, or $1,100. When interest rates fall, the present value of the bond’s scheduled payments rises, but the call provision allows the issuer to repurchase the bond at the call price. If the call price is less than the present value of the scheduled payments, the issuer may call the bond back from the bondholder. The bottom line in Figure 14.4 is the value of the callable bond. At high interest rates, the risk of call is negligible because the present value of scheduled payments is less than the call price; therefore the values of the straight and callable bonds converge. At lower rates, however, the values of the bonds 2,000 begin to diverge, with the difference reflect1,800 ing the value of the firm’s option to reclaim 1,600 the callable bond at the call price. At very Straight Bond 1,400 low rates, the present value of scheduled pay1,200 1,100 ments exceeds the call price, so the bond is 1,000 Callable called. Its value at this point is simply the call 800 Bond price, $1,100. 600 This analysis suggests that bond market 400 analysts might be more interested in a bond’s 200 yield to call rather than yield to maturity, 0 especially if the bond is likely to be called. 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 The yield to call is calculated just like the Interest Rate (%) yield to maturity except that the time until call replaces time until maturity, and the call price replaces the par value. This computaFigure 14.4 Bond prices: Callable and straight debt. tion is sometimes called “yield to first call,” Coupon 5 8%; maturity 5 30 years; semiannual as it assumes the issuer will call the bond as payments. soon as it may do so. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 460 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Example 14.5 Bond Prices and Yields 461 Yield to Call Suppose the 8% coupon, 30-year maturity bond sells for $1,150 and is callable in 10 years at a call price of $1,100. Its yield to maturity and yield to call would be calculated using the following inputs: Coupon payment Number of semiannual periods Final payment Price Yield to Call Yield to Maturity $40 20 periods $1,100 $1,150 $40 60 periods $1,000 $1,150 Yield to call is then 6.64%. [To confirm this on a calculator, input n 5 20; PV 5 (2)1150; FV 5 1100; PMT 5 40; compute i as 3.32%, or 6.64% bond equivalent yield.] Yield to maturity is 6.82%. [To confirm, input n 5 60; PV 5 (2)1150; FV 5 1000; PMT 5 40; compute i as 3.41% or 6.82% bond equivalent yield.] In Excel, you can calculate yield to call as 5 YIELD(DATE(2000,01,01), DATE(2010,01,01), .08, 115, 110, 2). Notice that redemption value is input as 110, i.e., 110% of par value. We have noted that most callable bonds are issued with an initial period of call protection. In addition, an implicit form of call protection operates for bonds selling at deep discounts from their call prices. Even if interest rates fall a bit, deep-discount bonds still will sell below the call price and thus will not be subject to a call. Premium bonds that might be selling near their call prices, however, are especially apt to be called if rates fall further. If interest rates fall, a callable premium bond is likely to provide a lower return than could be earned on a discount bond whose potential price appreciation is not limited by the likelihood of a call. Investors in premium bonds therefore may be more interested in the bond’s yield to call than its yield to maturity because it may appear to them that the bond will be retired at the call date. CONCEPT CHECK 14.4 a. The yield to maturity on two 10-year maturity bonds currently is 7%. Each bond has a call price of $1,100. One bond has a coupon rate of 6%, the other 8%. Assume for simplicity that bonds are called as soon as the present value of their remaining payments exceeds their call price. What will be the capital gain on each bond if the market interest rate suddenly falls to 6%? b. A 20-year maturity 9% coupon bond paying coupons semiannually is callable in 5 years at a call price of $1,050. The bond currently sells at a yield to maturity of 8%. What is the yield to call? Realized Compound Return versus Yield to Maturity We have noted that yield to maturity will equal the rate of return realized over the life of the bond if all coupons are reinvested at an interest rate equal to the bond’s yield to maturity. Consider, for example, a 2-year bond selling at par value paying a 10% coupon once a year. The yield to maturity is 10%. If the $100 coupon payment is reinvested at an interest bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 461 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 462 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities A: Reinvestment Rate 5 10% $1,100 Cash Flow: Time: 0 $100 1 2 $1,100 Future Value: = $1,100 100 × 1.10 = $ 110 $1,210 B: Reinvestment Rate 5 8% rate of 10%, the $1,000 investment in the bond will grow after 2 years to $1,210, as illustrated in Figure 14.5, panel A. The coupon paid in the first year is reinvested and grows with interest to a second-year value of $110, which together with the second coupon payment and payment of par value in the second year results in a total value of $1,210. To summarize, the initial value of the investment is V0 5 $1,000. The final value in 2 years is V2 5 $1,210. The compound rate of return, therefore, is calculated as follows: V0 (1 1 r)2 5 V2 $1,000 (1 1 r)2 5 $1,210 $1,100 r 5 .10 5 10% Cash Flow: Time: 0 Future Value: $100 1 2 $1,100 = $1,100 100 × 1.08 = $ 108 $1,208 Figure 14.5 Growth of invested funds Example 14.6 With a reinvestment rate equal to the 10% yield to maturity, the realized compound return equals yield to maturity. But what if the reinvestment rate is not 10%? If the coupon can be invested at more than 10%, funds will grow to more than $1,210, and the realized compound return will exceed 10%. If the reinvestment rate is less than 10%, so will be the realized compound return. Consider the following example. Realized Compound Return If the interest rate earned on the first coupon is less than 10%, the final value of the investment will be less than $1,210, and the realized compound return will be less than 10%. To illustrate, suppose the interest rate at which the coupon can be invested is only 8%. The following calculations are illustrated in Figure 14.5, panel B. Future value of first coupon payment with interest earnings 5 $100 3 1.08 5 $ 108 1 Cash payment in second year (final coupon plus par value) $1,100 5 Total value of investment with reinvested coupons $1,208 The realized compound return is the compound rate of growth of invested funds, assuming that all coupon payments are reinvested. The investor purchased the bond for par at $1,000, and this investment grew to $1,208. V0(1 1 r)2 5 V2 $1,000(1 1 r)2 5 $1,208 r 5 .0991 5 9.91% Example 14.6 highlights the problem with conventional yield to maturity when reinvestment rates can change over time. Conventional yield to maturity will not equal realized bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 462 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 463 compound return. However, in an economy with future interest rate uncertainty, the rates at which interim coupons will be reinvested are not yet known. Therefore, although realized compound return can be computed after the investment period ends, it cannot be computed in advance without a forecast of future reinvestment rates. This reduces much of the attraction of the realized return measure. Forecasting the realized compound yield over various holding periods or investment horizons is called horizon analysis. The forecast of total return depends on your forecasts of both the price of the bond when you sell it at the end of your horizon and the rate at which you are able to reinvest coupon income. The sales price depends in turn on the yield to maturity at the horizon date. With a longer investment horizon, however, reinvested coupons will be a larger component of your final proceeds. Example 14.7 Horizon Analysis Suppose you buy a 30-year, 7.5% (annual payment) coupon bond for $980 (when its yield to maturity is 7.67%) and plan to hold it for 20 years. Your forecast is that the bond’s yield to maturity will be 8% when it is sold and that the reinvestment rate on the coupons will be 6%. At the end of your investment horizon, the bond will have 10 years remaining until expiration, so the forecast sales price (using a yield to maturity of 8%) will be $966.45. The 20 coupon payments will grow with compound interest to $2,758.92. (This is the future value of a 20-year $75 annuity with an interest rate of 6%.) On the basis of these forecasts, your $980 investment will grow in 20 years to $966.45 1 $2,758.92 5 $3,725.37. This corresponds to an annualized compound return of 6.90%: V0(1 1 r)20 5 V20 $980(1 1 r)20 5 $3,725.37 r 5 .0690 5 6.90% Examples 14.6 and 14.7 demonstrate that as interest rates change, bond investors are actually subject to two sources of offsetting risk. On the one hand, when rates rise, bond prices fall, which reduces the value of the portfolio. On the other hand, reinvested coupon income will compound more rapidly at those higher rates. This reinvestment rate risk will offset the impact of price risk. In Chapter 16, we will explore this trade-off in more detail and will discover that by carefully tailoring their bond portfolios, investors can precisely balance these two effects for any given investment horizon. 14.4 Bond Prices over Time As we noted earlier, a bond will sell at par value when its coupon rate equals the market interest rate. In these circumstances, the investor receives fair compensation for the time value of money in the form of the recurring coupon payments. No further capital gain is necessary to provide fair compensation. When the coupon rate is lower than the market interest rate, the coupon payments alone will not provide investors as high a return as they could earn elsewhere in the market. To receive a competitive return on such an investment, investors also need some price appreciation on their bonds. The bonds, therefore, must sell below par value to provide a “builtin” capital gain on the investment. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 463 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 464 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Example 14.8 Fair Holding-Period Return To illustrate built-in capital gains or losses, suppose a bond was issued several years ago when the interest rate was 7%. The bond’s annual coupon rate was thus set at 7%. (We will suppose for simplicity that the bond pays its coupon annually.) Now, with 3 years left in the bond’s life, the interest rate is 8% per year. The bond’s market price is the present value of the remaining annual coupons plus payment of par value. That present value is10 $70 3 Annuity factor(8%, 3) 1 $1,000 3 PV factor(8%, 3) 5 $974.23 which is less than par value. In another year, after the next coupon is paid and remaining maturity falls to two years, the bond would sell at $70 3 Annuity factor(8%, 2) 1 $1,000 3 PV factor(8%, 2) 5 $982.17 thereby yielding a capital gain over the year of $7.94. If an investor had purchased the bond at $974.23, the total return over the year would equal the coupon payment plus capital gain, or $70 1 $7.94 5 $77.94. This represents a rate of return of $77.94/$974.23, or 8%, exactly the rate of return currently available elsewhere in the market. When bond prices are set according to the present value formula, any discount from par value provides an anticipated capital gain that will augment a below-market At what price will the bond in Example 14.8 sell coupon rate by just enough to provide a fair total rate of in yet another year, when only 1 year remains return. Conversely, if the coupon rate exceeds the market until maturity? What is the rate of return to an interest rate, the interest income by itself is greater than investor who purchases the bond when its price that available elsewhere in the market. Investors will bid is $982.17 and sells it 1 year hence? up the price of these bonds above their par values. As the bonds approach maturity, they will fall in value because fewer of these above-market coupon payments remain. The resulting capital losses offset the large coupon payments so that the bondholder again receives only a competitive rate of return. Problem 14 at the end of the chapter asks you to work through the case of the highcoupon bond. Figure 14.6 traces out the price paths of high- and low-coupon bonds (net of accrued interest) as time to maturity approaches, at least for the case in which the market interest rate is constant. The low-coupon bond enjoys capital gains, whereas the highcoupon bond suffers capital losses.11 We use these examples to show that each bond offers investors the same total rate of return. Although the capital gains versus income components differ, the price of each bond is set to provide competitive rates, as we should expect in well-functioning capital markets. Security returns all should be comparable on an after-tax risk-adjusted basis. If they are not, investors will try to sell low-return securities, thereby driving down their prices until the total return at the now-lower price is competitive with other securities. CONCEPT CHECK 14.5 10 Using a calculator, enter n 5 3, i 5 8, PMT 5 70, FV 5 1000, and compute PV. If interest rates are volatile, the price path will be “jumpy,” vibrating around the price path in Figure 14.6 and reflecting capital gains or losses as interest rates fluctuate. Ultimately, however, the price must reach par value at the maturity date, so the price of the premium bond will fall over time while that of the discount bond will rise. 11 bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 464 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 465 Price (% of Par Value) Prices should continue to adjust until all securities are fairly priced in that 160 expected returns are comparable, given 140 appropriate risk and tax adjustments. We see evidence of this price 120 adjustment in Figure 14.1. Compare 100 the highlighted bond with the one just below it. The July 2018 bond 80 has a coupon rate of 2.25%, while 60 the November 2018 bond has a much higher coupon rate, 9%. But 40 Coupon = 12% the higher coupon rate on that bond Coupon = 4% 20 does not mean that it offers a higher return; instead, it sells at a much 0 higher price. The yields to maturity on 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 the two bonds are nearly identical, a Time (years) shade below .8%. This makes sense, since investors should care about their total return, including both coupon Figure 14.6 Price path of two 30-year maturity bonds, each income as well as price change. In the selling at a yield to maturity of 8%. Bond price approaches par end, prices of similar-maturity bonds value as maturity date approaches. adjust until yields are pretty much equalized. Of course, the yields across bonds in Figure 14.1 are not all equal. Clearly, longer term bonds at this time offered higher promised yields, a common pattern, and one that reflects the relative risks of the bonds. We will explore the relation between yield and time to maturity in the next chapter. Yield to Maturity versus Holding-Period Return In Example 14.8, the holding-period return and the yield to maturity were equal. The bond yield started and ended the year at 8%, and the bond’s holding-period return also equaled 8%. This turns out to be a general result. When the yield to maturity is unchanged over the period, the rate of return on the bond will equal that yield. As we noted, this should not be surprising: The bond must offer a rate of return competitive with those available on other securities. However, when yields fluctuate, so will a bond’s rate of return. Unanticipated changes in market rates will result in unanticipated changes in bond returns and, after the fact, a bond’s holding-period return can be better or worse than the yield at which it initially sells. An increase in the bond’s yield acts to reduce its price, which reduces the holding period return. In this event, the holding period return is likely to be less than the initial yield to maturity.12 Conversely, a decline in yield will result in a holding-period return greater than the initial yield. 12 We have to be a bit careful here. When yields increase, coupon income can be reinvested at higher rates, which offsets the impact of the initial price decline. If your holding period is sufficiently long, the positive impact of the higher reinvestment rate can more than offset the initial price decline. But common performance evaluation periods for portfolio managers are no more than 1 year, and over these shorter horizons the price impact will almost always dominate the impact of the reinvestment rate. We discuss the trade-off between price risk and reinvestment rate risk more fully in Chapter 16. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 465 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 466 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Example 14.9 Yield to Maturity versus Holding-Period Return Consider a 30-year bond paying an annual coupon of $80 and selling at par value of $1,000. The bond’s initial yield to maturity is 8%. If the yield remains at 8% over the year, the bond price will remain at par, so the holding-period return also will be 8%. But if the yield falls below 8%, the bond price will increase. Suppose the yield falls and the price increases to $1,050. Then the holding-period return is greater than 8%: Holding-period return 5 CONCEPT CHECK $80 1 ($1,050 2 $1,000) 5 .13, or 13% $1,000 14.6 Show that if yield to maturity increases, then holding-period return is less than initial yield. For example, suppose in Example 14.9 that by the end of the first year, the bond’s yield to maturity is 8.5%. Find the 1-year holding-period return and compare it to the bond’s initial 8% yield to maturity. Here is another way to think about the difference between yield to maturity and holding-period return. Yield to maturity depends only on the bond’s coupon, current price, and par value at maturity. All of these values are observable today, so yield to maturity can be easily calculated. Yield to maturity can be interpreted as a measure of the average rate of return if the investment in the bond is held until the bond matures. In contrast, holding-period return is the rate of return over a particular investment period and depends on the market price of the bond at the end of that holding period; of course this price is not known today. Because bond prices over the holding period will respond to unanticipated changes in interest rates, holding-period return can at most be forecast. Zero-Coupon Bonds and Treasury Strips Original-issue discount bonds are less common than coupon bonds issued at par. These are bonds that are issued intentionally with low coupon rates that cause the bond to sell at a discount from par value. The most common example of this type of bond is the zero-coupon bond, which carries no coupons and provides all its return in the form of price appreciation. Zeros provide only one cash flow to their owners, on the maturity date of the bond. U.S. Treasury bills are examples of short-term zero-coupon instruments. If the bill has face value of $10,000, the Treasury issues or sells it for some amount less than $10,000, agreeing to repay $10,000 at maturity. All of the investor’s return comes in the form of price appreciation. Longer-term zero-coupon bonds are commonly created from coupon-bearing notes and bonds. A bond dealer who purchases a Treasury coupon bond may ask the Treasury to break down the cash flows to be paid by the bond into a series of independent securities, where each security is a claim to one of the payments of the original bond. For example, a 10-year coupon bond would be “stripped” of its 20 semiannual coupons, and each coupon payment would be treated as a stand-alone zero-coupon bond. The maturities of these bonds would thus range from 6 months to 10 years. The final payment of principal would be treated as another stand-alone zero-coupon security. Each of the payments is now treated as an independent security and is assigned its own CUSIP number (by the Committee on Uniform Securities Identification Procedures), the security identifier that allows for electronic trading over the Fedwire system, a network that connects all Federal Reserve banks and their bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 466 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 467 Bond Prices and Yields 30 27 24 21 18 15 12 9 6 3 0 Price ($) branches. The payments are still considered obligations of the U.S. Treasury. The Treasury pro1,000 900 gram under which coupon stripping is performed 800 is called STRIPS (Separate Trading of Registered 700 Interest and Principal of Securities), and these 600 zero-coupon securities are called Treasury strips. 500 400 What should happen to prices of zeros as time 300 passes? On their maturity dates, zeros must sell 200 for par value. Before maturity, however, they 100 should sell at discounts from par, because of the 0 time value of money. As time passes, price should approach par value. In fact, if the interest rate is Time (years) constant, a zero’s price will increase at exactly Today Maturity Date the rate of interest. To illustrate, consider a zero with 30 years until maturity, and suppose the market interest rate is 10% per year. The price of the bond today Figure 14.7 The price of a 30-year zero-coupon bond is $1,000/(1.10)30 5 $57.31. Next year, with only over time at a yield to maturity of 10%. Price equals 29 years until maturity, if the yield is still 10%, 1,000/(1.10)T, where T is time until maturity. 29 the price will be $1,000/(1.10) 5 $63.04, a 10% increase over its previous-year value. Because the par value of the bond is now discounted for one less year, its price has increased by the 1-year discount factor. Figure 14.7 presents the price path of a 30-year zero-coupon bond for an annual market interest rate of 10%. The bond prices rise exponentially, not linearly, until its maturity. After-Tax Returns The tax authorities recognize that the “built-in” price appreciation on original-issue discount (OID) bonds such as zero-coupon bonds represents an implicit interest payment to the holder of the security. The IRS, therefore, calculates a price appreciation schedule to impute taxable interest income for the built-in appreciation during a tax year, even if the asset is not sold or does not mature until a future year. Any additional gains or losses that arise from changes in market interest rates are treated as capital gains or losses if the OID bond is sold during the tax year. Example 14.10 Taxation of Original-Issue Discount Bonds If the interest rate originally is 10%, the 30-year zero would be issued at a price of $1,000/(1.10)30 5 $57.31. The following year, the IRS calculates what the bond price would be if the yield were still 10%. This is $1,000/(1.10)29 5 $63.04. Therefore, the IRS imputes interest income of $63.04 2 $57.31 5 $5.73. This amount is subject to tax. Notice that the imputed interest income is based on a “constant yield method” that ignores any changes in market interest rates. If interest rates actually fall, let’s say to 9.9%, the bond price will be $1,000/(1.099)29 5 $64.72. If the bond is sold, then the difference between $64.72 and $63.04 is treated as capital gains income and taxed at the capital gains tax rate. If the bond is not sold, then the price difference is an unrealized capital gain and does not result in taxes in that year. In either case, the investor must pay taxes on the $5.73 of imputed interest at the rate on ordinary income. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 467 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 468 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities The procedure illustrated in Example 14.10 applies as well to the taxation of other original-issue discount bonds, even if they are not zero-coupon bonds. Consider, as an example, a 30-year maturity bond that is issued with a coupon rate of 4% and a yield to maturity of 8%. For simplicity, we will assume that the bond pays coupons once annually. Because of the low coupon rate, the bond will be issued at a price far below par value, specifically at $549.69. If the bond’s yield to maturity is still 8%, then its price in 1 year will rise to $553.66. (Confirm this for yourself.) This would provide a pretax holding-period return (HPR) of exactly 8%: HPR 5 $40 1 ($553.66 2 $549.69) 5 .08 $549.69 The increase in the bond price based on a constant yield, however, is treated as interest income, so the investor is required to pay taxes on the explicit coupon income, $40, as well as the imputed interest income of $553.66 2 $549.69 5 $3.97. If the bond’s yield actually changes during the year, the difference between the bond’s price and the constant-yield value of $553.66 would be treated as capital gains income if the bond is sold. CONCEPT CHECK 14.7 Suppose that the yield to maturity of the 4% coupon, 30-year maturity bond falls to 7% by the end of the first year and that the investor sells the bond after the first year. If the investor’s federal plus state tax rate on interest income is 38% and the combined tax rate on capital gains is 20%, what is the investor’s aftertax rate of return? 14.5 Default Risk and Bond Pricing Although bonds generally promise a fixed flow of income, that income stream is not riskless unless the investor can be sure the issuer will not default on the obligation. While U.S. government bonds may be treated as free of default risk, this is not true of corporate bonds. Therefore, the actual payments on these bonds are uncertain, for they depend to some degree on the ultimate financial status of the firm. Bond default risk, usually called credit risk, is measured by Moody’s Investor Services, Standard & Poor’s Corporation, and Fitch Investors Service, all of which provide financial information on firms as well as quality ratings of large corporate and municipal bond issues. International sovereign bonds, which also entail default risk, especially in emerging markets, also are commonly rated for default risk. Each rating firm assigns letter grades to the bonds of corporations and municipalities to reflect their assessment of the safety of the bond issue. The top rating is AAA or Aaa, a designation awarded to only about a dozen firms. Moody’s modifies each rating class with a 1, 2, or 3 suffix (e.g., Aaa1, Aaa2, Aaa3) to provide a finer gradation of ratings. The other agencies use a 1 or 2 modification. Those rated BBB or above (S&P, Fitch) or Baa and above (Moody’s) are considered investment-grade bonds, whereas lower-rated bonds are classified as speculativegrade or junk bonds. Defaults on low-grade issues are not uncommon. For example, bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 468 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 469 almost half of the bonds rated CCC by Standard & Poor’s at issue have defaulted within 10 years. Highly rated bonds rarely default, but even these bonds are not free of credit risk. For example, in 2001 WorldCom sold $11.8 billion of bonds with an investment-grade rating. Only a year later, the firm filed for bankruptcy and its bondholders lost more than 80% of their investment. Certain regulated institutional investors such as insurance companies have not always been allowed to invest in speculative-grade bonds. Figure 14.8 provides the definitions of each bond rating classification. Bond Ratings Very High Quality High Quality Speculative Very Poor Standard & Poor’s AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC D Moody’s Aaa Aa A Baa Ba B Caa C At times both Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s have used adjustments to these ratings: S&P uses plus and minus signs: A+ is the strongest A rating and A− the weakest. Moody’s uses a 1, 2, or 3 designation, with 1 indicating the strongest. Moody’s S&P Aaa AAA Aa AA A A Baa BBB Ba B Caa Ca BB B CCC CC Debt rated in these categories is regarded, on balance, as predominantly speculative with respect to capacity to pay interest and repay principal in accordance with the terms of the obligation. BB and Ba indicate the lowest degree of speculation, and CC and Ca the highest degree of speculation. Although such debt will likely have some quality and protective characteristics, these are outweighed by large uncertainties or major risk exposures to adverse conditions. Some issues may be in default. C D C D This rating is reserved for income bonds on which no interest is being paid. Debt rated D is in default, and payment of interest and/or repayment of principal is in arrears. Debt rated Aaa and AAA has the highest rating. Capacity to pay interest and principal is extremely strong. Debt rated Aa and AA has a very strong capacity to pay interest and repay principal. Together with the highest rating, this group comprises the highgrade bond class. Debt rated A has a strong capacity to pay interest and repay principal, although it is somewhat more susceptible to the adverse effects of changes in circumstances and economic conditions than debt in higher-rated categories. Debt rated Baa and BBB is regarded as having an adequate capacity to pay interest and repay principal. Whereas it normally exhibits adequate protection parameters, adverse economic conditions or changing circumstances are more likely to lead to a weakened capacity to pay interest and repay principal for debt in this category than in higher-rated categories. These bonds are medium-grade obligations. Figure 14.8 Definitions of each bond rating class Source: Stephen A. Ross and Randolph W. Westerfield, Corporate Finance, Copyright 1988 (St. Louis: Times Mirror/ Mosby College Publishing, reproduced with permission from the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc.). Data from various editions of Standard & Poor’s Bond Guide and Moody’s Bond Guide. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 469 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 470 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Junk Bonds Junk bonds, also known as high-yield bonds, are nothing more than speculative-grade (low-rated or unrated) bonds. Before 1977, almost all junk bonds were “fallen angels,” that is, bonds issued by firms that originally had investment-grade ratings but that had since been downgraded. In 1977, however, firms began to issue “original-issue junk.” Much of the credit for this innovation is given to Drexel Burnham Lambert, and especially its trader Michael Milken. Drexel had long enjoyed a niche as a junk bond trader and had established a network of potential investors in junk bonds. Firms not able to muster an investment-grade rating were happy to have Drexel (and other investment bankers) market their bonds directly to the public, as this opened up a new source of financing. Junk issues were a lower-cost financing alternative than borrowing from banks. High-yield bonds gained considerable notoriety in the 1980s when they were used as financing vehicles in leveraged buyouts and hostile takeover attempts. Shortly thereafter, however, the junk bond market suffered. The legal difficulties of Drexel and Michael Milken in connection with Wall Street’s insider trading scandals of the late 1980s tainted the junk bond market. At the height of Drexel’s difficulties, the high-yield bond market nearly dried up. Since then, the market has rebounded dramatically. However, it is worth noting that the average credit quality of newly issued high-yield debt issued today is higher than the average quality in the boom years of the 1980s. Of course, junk bonds are more vulnerable to economic distress than investment-grade bonds. During the financial crisis of 2008–2009, prices on these bonds fell dramatically, and their yields to maturity rose equally dramatically. The spread between yields on B-rated bonds and Treasuries widened from around 3% in early 2007 to an astonishing 19% by the beginning of 2009. Determinants of Bond Safety Bond rating agencies base their quality ratings largely on an analysis of the level and trend of some of the issuer’s financial ratios. The key ratios used to evaluate safety are 1. Coverage ratios—Ratios of company earnings to fixed costs. For example, the times-interest-earned ratio is the ratio of earnings before interest payments and taxes to interest obligations. The fixed-charge coverage ratio includes lease payments and sinking fund payments with interest obligations to arrive at the ratio of earnings to all fixed cash obligations (sinking funds are described below). Low or falling coverage ratios signal possible cash flow difficulties. 2. Leverage ratio, debt-to-equity ratio—A too-high leverage ratio indicates excessive indebtedness, signaling the possibility the firm will be unable to earn enough to satisfy the obligations on its bonds. 3. Liquidity ratios—The two most common liquidity ratios are the current ratio (current assets/current liabilities) and the quick ratio (current assets excluding inventories/current liabilities). These ratios measure the firm’s ability to pay bills coming due with its most liquid assets. 4. Profitability ratios—Measures of rates of return on assets or equity. Profitability ratios are indicators of a firm’s overall financial health. The return on assets (earnings before interest and taxes divided by total assets) or return on equity (net income/equity) are the most popular of these measures. Firms with higher returns on assets or equity should be better able to raise money in security markets because they offer prospects for better returns on the firm’s investments. 5. Cash flow-to-debt ratio—This is the ratio of total cash flow to outstanding debt. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 470 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 471 Bond Prices and Yields 3-year medians EBIT interest coverage multiple EBITDA interest coverage multiple Funds from operations/total debt (%) Free operating cash flow/total debt (%) Total debt/EBITDA multiple Return on capital (%) Total debt/total debt 1 equity (%) AAA AA A BBB BB B CCC 23.8 25.5 203.3 127.6 0.4 27.6 12.4 19.5 24.6 79.9 44.5 0.9 27.0 28.3 8.0 10.2 48.0 25.0 1.6 17.5 37.5 4.7 6.5 35.9 17.3 2.2 13.4 42.5 2.5 3.5 22.4 8.3 3.5 11.3 53.7 1.2 1.9 11.5 2.8 5.3 8.7 75.9 0.4 0.9 5.0 (2.1) 7.9 3.2 113.5 Table 14.3 Financial ratios by rating class, long-term debt Note: EBITDA is earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization Source: Corporate Rating Criteria, Standard & Poor’s, 2006. ROE Standard & Poor’s periodically computes median values of selected ratios for firms in several rating classes, which we present in Table 14.3. Of course, ratios must be evaluated in the context of industry standards, and analysts differ in the weights they place on particular ratios. Nevertheless, Table 14.3 demonstrates the tendency of ratios to improve along with the firm’s rating class. And default rates vary dramatically with bond rating. Historically, only about 1% of industrial bonds originally rated AA or better at issuance had defaulted after 15 years. That ratio is around 7.5% for BBB-rated bonds, and 40% for B-rated bonds. Credit risk clearly varies dramatically across rating classes. Many studies have tested whether financial ratios can in fact be used to predict default risk. One of the best-known series of tests was conducted by Edward Altman, who used discriminant analysis to predict bankruptcy. With this technique a firm is assigned a score based on its financial characteristics. If its score exceeds a cut-off value, the firm is deemed creditworthy. A score below the cut-off value indicates significant bankruptcy risk in the near future. To illustrate the technique, suppose that we were to collect data on the return on equity (ROE) and coverage ratios of a sample of firms, and then keep records of any corporate bankruptcies. In Figure 14.9 we plot the ROE and coverage ratios for each firm, using X for firms that eventually went bankrupt and O for those that remained solvent. Clearly, the X and O firms show different patterns of data, with the solvent firms typically showing higher values for the two ratios. The discriminant analysis determines the equation of the line that best separates the X and O observations. Suppose that the equation of the line is .75 5 .9 3 ROE 1 .4 3 Coverage. Then, based Coverage Ratio on its own financial ratios, each firm is assigned a “Z-score” equal to .9 3 ROE 1 .4 3 Coverage. If its Z-score exceeds .75, the firm plots above the line and is considered a safe bet; Z-scores below Figure 14.9 Discriminant analysis .75 foretell financial difficulty. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 471 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 472 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Altman found the following equation to best separate failing and nonfailing firms: Z 5 3.1 Shareholders’ equity EBIT Sales 1 1.0 1 .42 Total assets Assets Total liabilities 1 .85 Retained earnings Working capital 1 .72 Total assets Total assets where EBIT 5 earnings before interest and taxes.13 Z-scores below 1.23 indicate vulnerability to bankruptcy, scores between 1.23 and 2.90 are a gray area, and scores above 2.90 are considered safe. CONCEPT CHECK 14.8 Suppose we add a new variable equal to current liabilities/current assets to Altman’s equation. Would you expect this variable to receive a positive or negative coefficient? Bond Indentures A bond is issued with an indenture, which is the contract between the issuer and the bondholder. Part of the indenture is a set of restrictions that protect the rights of the bondholders. Such restrictions include provisions relating to collateral, sinking funds, dividend policy, and further borrowing. The issuing firm agrees to these protective covenants in order to market its bonds to investors concerned about the safety of the bond issue. Sinking Funds Bonds call for the payment of par value at the end of the bond’s life. This payment constitutes a large cash commitment for the issuer. To help ensure the commitment does not create a cash flow crisis, the firm agrees to establish a sinking fund to spread the payment burden over several years. The fund may operate in one of two ways: 1. The firm may repurchase a fraction of the outstanding bonds in the open market each year. 2. The firm may purchase a fraction of the outstanding bonds at a special call price associated with the sinking fund provision. The firm has an option to purchase the bonds at either the market price or the sinking fund price, whichever is lower. To allocate the burden of the sinking fund call fairly among bondholders, the bonds chosen for the call are selected at random based on serial number.14 The sinking fund call differs from a conventional bond call in two important ways. First, the firm can repurchase only a limited fraction of the bond issue at the sinking fund call price. At best, some indentures allow firms to use a doubling option, which allows repurchase of double the required number of bonds at the sinking fund call price. Second, while callable bonds generally have call prices above par value, the sinking fund call price usually is set at the bond’s par value. 13 Altman’s original work was published in Edward I. Altman, “Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis, and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy,” Journal of Finance 23 (September 1968). This equation is from his updated study, Corporate Financial Distress and Bankruptcy, 2nd ed. (New York: Wiley, 1993), p. 29. Altman’s analysis is updated and extended in W. H. Beaver, M. F. McNichols, and J-W. Rhie, “Have Financial Statements become Less Informative? Evidence from the Ability of Financial Ratios to Predict Bankruptcy,” Review of Accounting Studies 10 (2005), pp. 93–122. 14 Although it is less common, the sinking fund provision also may call for periodic payments to a trustee, with the payments invested so that the accumulated sum can be used for retirement of the entire issue at maturity. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 472 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 473 Although sinking funds ostensibly protect bondholders by making principal repayment more likely, they can hurt the investor. The firm will choose to buy back discount bonds (selling below par) at market price, while exercising its option to buy back premium bonds (selling above par) at par. Therefore, if interest rates fall and bond prices rise, firms will benefit from the sinking fund provision that enables them to repurchase their bonds at below-market prices. In these circumstances, the firm’s gain is the bondholder’s loss. One bond issue that does not require a sinking fund is a serial bond issue, in which the firm sells bonds with staggered maturity dates. As bonds mature sequentially, the principal repayment burden for the firm is spread over time, just as it is with a sinking fund. One advantage of serial bonds over sinking fund issues is that there is no uncertainty introduced by the possibility that a particular bond will be called for the sinking fund. The disadvantage of serial bonds, however, is that bonds of different maturity dates are not interchangeable, which reduces the liquidity of the issue. Subordination of Further Debt One of the factors determining bond safety is total outstanding debt of the issuer. If you bought a bond today, you would be understandably distressed to see the firm tripling its outstanding debt tomorrow. Your bond would be riskier than it appeared when you bought it. To prevent firms from harming bondholders in this manner, subordination clauses restrict the amount of additional borrow& Mobil Corp. debenture 8s, due 2032: Rating — Aa2 ing. Additional debt might be required to be subordinated AUTH----$250,000,000. in priority to existing debt; that is, in the event of bankOUTSTG----Dec. 31, 1993, $250,000,000. DATED----Oct. 30, 1991. ruptcy, subordinated or junior debtholders will not be INTEREST----F&A 12. TRUSTEE----Chemical Bank. paid unless and until the prior senior debt is fully paid off. DENOMINATION----Fully registered, $1,000 and Dividend Restrictions Covenants also limit the dividends firms may pay. These limitations protect the bondholders because they force the firm to retain assets rather than paying them out to stockholders. A typical restriction disallows payments of dividends if cumulative dividends paid since the firm’s inception exceed cumulative retained earnings plus proceeds from sales of stock. Collateral Some bonds are issued with specific collateral behind them. Collateral is a particular asset that the bondholders receive if the firm defaults on the bond. If the collateral is property, the bond is called a mortgage bond. If the collateral takes the form of other securities held by the firm, the bond is a collateral trust bond. In the case of equipment, the bond is known as an equipment obligation bond. This last form of collateral is used most commonly by firms such as railroads, where the equipment is fairly standard and can be easily sold to another firm should the firm default. Collateralized bonds generally are considered safer than general debenture bonds, which are unsecured, meaning they do not provide for specific collateral. Credit risk of unsecured bonds depends on the general earning power of the firm. If the firm defaults, debenture owners become general creditors of the firm. Because they are safer, collateralized bonds generally offer lower yields than general debentures. Figure 14.10 shows the terms of a bond issued by Mobil as described in Moody’s Industrial Manual. The bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 473 integral multiplies thereof. Transferable and exchangeable without service charge. CALLABLE----As a whole or in part, at any time, on or after Aug. 12, 2002, at the option of Co. on at least 30 but not more than the 60 days' notice to each Aug. 11 as follows: 2003..........105.007 2006..........104.256 2009..........103.505 2012..........102.754 2015..........102.003 2018..........101.252 2021..........100.501 2004..........104.756 2007..........104.005 2010..........103.254 2013..........102.503 2016..........101.752 2019..........101.001 2022..........100.250 2005..........104.506 2008..........103.755 2011..........103.004 2014..........102.253 2017..........101.502 2020..........100.751 and thereafter at 100 plus accrued interest. SECURITY----Not secured. Ranks equally with all other unsecured and unsubordinated indebtedness of Co. Co. nor any Affiliate will not incur any indebtedness; provided that Co. will not create as security for any indebtedness for borrowed money, any mortgage, pledge, security interest or lien on any stock or indebtedness is directly owned by Co. without effectively providing that the debt securities shall be secured equally and ratably with such indebtedness. so long as such indebtedness shall be so secured. INDENTURE MODIFICATION----Indenture may be modified, except as provided with, consent of 66 2/3% of debs. outstg. RIGHTS ON DEFAULT----Trustee, or 25% of debs. outstg., may declare principal due and payable (30 days' grace for payment of interest). LISTED----On New York Stock Exchange. PURPOSE----Proceeds used for general corporate purposes. OFFERED----($250,000,000) at 99.51 plus accrued interest (proceeds to Co., 99.11) on Aug. 5, 1992 thru Merrill Lynch & Co., Donaldson, Lufkin & Jenerette Securities Corp., PaineWebber Inc., Prudential Securities Inc., Smith Barney, Harris Upham & Co. Inc. and associates. Figure 14.10 Callable bond issued by Mobil Source: Mergent’s Industrial Manual, Mergent’s Investor Services, 1994. Reprinted with permission. All rights reserved. 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 474 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities bond is registered and listed on the NYSE. It was issued in 1991 but was not callable until 2002. Although the call price started at 105.007% of par value, it declines gradually until reaching par after 2020. Most of the terms of the bond are typical and illustrate many of the indenture provisions we have mentioned. However, in recent years there has been a marked trend away from the use of call provisions. Yield to Maturity and Default Risk Because corporate bonds are subject to default risk, we must distinguish between the bond’s promised yield to maturity and its expected yield. The promised or stated yield will be realized only if the firm meets the obligations of the bond issue. Therefore, the stated yield is the maximum possible yield to maturity of the bond. The expected yield to maturity must take into account the possibility of a default. For example, at the height of the financial crisis in October 2008, as Ford Motor Company struggled, its bonds due in 2028 were rated CCC and were selling at about 33% of par value, resulting in a yield to maturity of about 20%. Investors did not really believe the expected rate of return on these bonds was 20%. They recognized that there was a decent chance that bondholders would not receive all the payments promised in the bond contract and that the yield based on expected cash flows was far less than the yield based on promised cash flows. As it turned out, of course, Ford weathered the storm, and investors who purchased its bonds made a very nice profit: The bonds were selling in mid-2012 for about 110% of par value, more than triple their value in 2008. Example 14.11 Expected vs. Promised Yield to Maturity Suppose a firm issued a 9% coupon bond 20 years ago. The bond now has 10 years left until its maturity date, but the firm is having financial difficulties. Investors believe that the firm will be able to make good on the remaining interest payments, but at the maturity date, the firm will be forced into bankruptcy, and bondholders will receive only 70% of par value. The bond is selling at $750. Yield to maturity (YTM) would then be calculated using the following inputs: Coupon payment Number of semiannual periods Final payment Price Expected YTM Stated YTM $45 20 periods $700 $750 $45 20 periods $1,000 $750 The yield to maturity based on promised payments is 13.7%. Based on the expected payment of $700 at maturity, however, the yield to maturity would be only 11.6%. The stated yield to maturity is greater than the yield investors actually expect to receive. Example 14.11 suggests that when a bond becomes more subject to default risk, its price will fall, and therefore its promised yield to maturity will rise. Similarly, the default premium, the spread between the stated yield to maturity and that on otherwisecomparable Treasury bonds, will rise. However, its expected yield to maturity, which ultimately is tied to the systematic risk of the bond, will be far less affected. Let’s continue Example 14.11. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 474 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Example 14.12 475 Bond Prices and Yields Default Risk and the Default Premium Suppose that the condition of the firm in Example 14.11 deteriorates further, and investors now believe that the bond will pay off only 55% of face value at maturity. Investors now demand an expected yield to maturity of 12% (i.e., 6% semiannually), which is .4% higher than in Example 14.11. But the price of the bond will fall from $750 to $688 [n 5 20; i 5 6; FV 5 550; PMT 5 $45]. At this price, the stated yield to maturity based on promised cash flows is 15.2%. While the expected yield to maturity has increased by .4%, the drop in price has caused the promised yield to maturity to rise by 1.5%. To compensate for the possibility of default, corporate CONCEPT CHECK 14.9 bonds must offer a default premium. The default premium is the difference between the promised yield on a What is the expected yield to maturity in Example corporate bond and the yield of an otherwise-identical 14.12 if the firm is in even worse condition? government bond that is riskless in terms of default. If the Investors expect a final payment of only $500, firm remains solvent and actually pays the investor all of and the bond price has fallen to $650. the promised cash flows, the investor will realize a higher yield to maturity than would be realized from the government bond. If, however, the firm goes bankrupt, the corporate bond is likely to provide a lower return than the government bond. The corporate bond has the potential for both better and worse performance than the default-free Treasury bond. In other words, it is riskier. The pattern of default premiums offered on risky bonds is sometimes called the risk structure of interest rates. The greater the default risk, the higher the default premium. Figure 14.11 shows spreads between yields to maturity of bonds of different risk classes. You can see here clear evidence of credit-risk premiums on promised yields. Note, for example, the incredible run-up of credit spreads during the financial 20 crisis of 2008–2009. 12 8 4 2012 2009 2006 2003 2000 1997 1994 1991 1988 1985 1982 1979 1976 –4 1973 0 1970 A credit default swap (CDS) is in effect an insurance policy on the default risk of a bond or loan. To illustrate, the annual premium in July 2012 on a 5-year German government CDS was about 0.75%, meaning that the CDS buyer would pay the seller an annual premium of $.75 for each $100 of bond principal. The seller collects these annual payments for the term of the contract but must compensate the buyer for loss of bond value in the event of a default.15 Yield Spread (%) Credit Default Swaps High Yield Baa-Rated Aaa-Rated 16 Figure 14.11 Yield spreads between corporate and 10-year Treasury bonds Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. 15 Actually, credit default swaps may pay off even short of an actual default. The contract specifies the particular “credit events” that will trigger a payment. For example, restructuring (rewriting the terms of a firm’s outstanding debt as an alternative to formal bankruptcy proceedings) may be defined as a triggering credit event. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 475 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 476 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities As originally envisioned, credit default swaps were designed to allow lenders to buy protection against default risk. The natural buyers of CDSs would then be large bondholders or banks that wished to enhance the creditworthiness of their outstanding loans. Even if the borrower had a shaky credit standing, the “insured” debt would be as safe as the issuer of the CDS. An investor holding a bond with a BB rating could, in principle, raise the effective quality of the debt to AAA by buying a CDS on the issuer. This insight suggests how CDS contracts should be priced. If a BB-rated corporate bond bundled with insurance via a CDS is effectively equivalent to a AAA-rated bond, then the premium on the swap ought to approximate the yield spread between AAA-rated and BB-rated bonds.16 The risk structure of interest rates and CDS prices ought to be tightly aligned. Figure 14.12, panel A, shows the premiums on 5-year CDSs on German government debt between 2008 and 2012. Even as the strongest economy in the eurozone, German CDS prices nevertheless reflect financial strain, first in the deep recession of 2009 and then again in 2011 as the prospects of defaults (and German-led bailouts) of Greece and A: Premiums on German Sovereign Debt CDS Contracts Premium (bp/year) 200 150 100 50 May 12 Jan 12 Sep 11 May 11 Jan 11 Sep 10 May 10 Jan 10 Sep 09 May 09 Jan 09 Sep 08 May 08 Jan 08 0 B: Premiums on Spanish Sovereign Debt CDS Contracts Premium (bp/year) 900 750 500 250 May 12 Jan 12 Sep 11 May 11 Jan 11 Sep 10 May 10 Jan 10 Sep 09 May 09 Jan 09 Sep 08 May 08 Jan 08 0 Figure 14.12 Pricing of 5-year credit default swaps Source: Bloomberg, August 1, 2012, http://www.bloomberg.com/quote/CDBR1U5:IND/chart. 16 We say approximately because there are some differences between highly rated bonds and bonds synthetically enhanced with credit default swaps. For example, the term of the swap may not match the maturity of the bond. Tax treatment of coupon payments versus swap payments may differ, as may the liquidity of the bonds. Finally, some CDSs may entail one-time up-front payments as well as annual premiums. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 476 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer The credit crisis of 2008–2009, when lending among banks and other financial institutions effectively seized up, was in large measure a crisis of transparency. The biggest problem was a widespread lack of confidence in the financial standing of counterparties to a trade. If one institution could not be confident that another would remain solvent, it would understandably be reluctant to offer it a loan. When doubt about the credit exposure of customers and trading partners spiked to levels not seen since the Great Depression, the market for loans dried up. Credit default swaps were particularly cited for fostering doubts about counterparty reliability. By August 2008, $63 trillion of such swaps were reportedly outstanding. (By comparison, U.S. gross domestic product in 2008 was about $14 trillion.) As the subprime mortgage market collapsed and the economy entered a deep recession, the potential obligations on these contracts ballooned to levels previously considered unimaginable and the ability of CDS sellers to honor their commitments appeared in doubt. For example, the huge insurance firm AIG alone had sold more than $400 billion of CDS contracts on subprime mortgages and other loans and was days from insolvency. But AIG’s insolvency could have triggered the insolvency of other firms that had relied on its promise of protection against loan defaults. These in turn might have triggered further defaults. In the end, the government felt compelled to rescue AIG to prevent a chain reaction of insolvencies. Counterparty risk and lax reporting requirements made it effectively impossible to tease out firms’ exposures to credit risk. One problem was that CDS positions do not have to be accounted for on balance sheets. And the possibility of one default setting off a sequence of further defaults means that lenders may be exposed to the default of an institution with which they do not even directly trade. Such knock-on effects create systemic risk, in which the entire financial system can freeze up. With the ripple effects of bad debt extending in ever-widening circles, lending to anyone can seem imprudent. In the aftermath of the credit crisis, the Dodd-Frank Act called for new regulation and reforms. One proposal is for a central clearinghouse for credit derivatives such as CDS contracts. Such a system would foster transparency of positions, would allow the clearinghouse to replace traders’ offsetting long and short positions with a single net position, and would require daily recognition of gains or losses on positions through a margin or collateral account. If losses were to mount, positions would have to be unwound before growing to unsustainable levels. Allowing traders to accurately assess counterparty risk, and limiting such risk through margin accounts and the extra back-up of the clearinghouse, would go a long way in limiting systemic risk. WORDS FROM THE STREET Credit Default Swaps, Systemic Risk, and the Financial Crisis of 2008–2009 other eurozone countries worsened. As its perceived credit risk increased, so did the cost of insuring its debt. Panel B of Figure 14.12 shows the premiums on 5-year CDS contracts on Spanish government debt. Spain’s economy was far shakier than Germany’s, and its CDS prices reflected this fact. By the summer of 2012, its 5-year CDS premiums were around 600 basis points, about eight times the price to insure German debt. While CDSs were conceived as a form of bond insurance, it wasn’t long before investors realized that they could be used to speculate on the financial health of particular issuers. As Figure 14.12 makes clear, someone in early 2011 wishing to bet against Spain might have purchased CDS contracts on its sovereign debt and would have profited as CDS prices spiked over the next 18 months. The nearby box discusses the role of credit default swaps in the financial crisis of 2008–2009. Credit Risk and Collateralized Debt Obligations Collateralized debt obligations, or CDOs, emerged in the last decade as a major mechanism to reallocate credit risk in the fixed-income markets. To create a CDO, a financial institution, commonly a bank, first would establish a legally distinct entity to buy and later resell a portfolio of bonds or other loans. A common vehicle for this purpose was the socalled Structured Investment Vehicle (SIV).17 An SIV raises funds, often by issuing shortterm commercial paper, and uses the proceeds to buy corporate bonds or other forms of debt 17 The legal separation of the bank from the SIV allows the ownership of the loans to be conducted off the bank’s balance sheet, and thus avoids capital requirements the bank would otherwise encounter. 477 bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 477 7/25/13 2:41 AM Final PDF to printer 478 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Senior-Subordinated Tranche Structure Senior tranche Bank Typical Terms 70–90% of notional principal, coupon similar to Aa-Aaa rated bonds Mezzanine 1 5–15% of principal, investment-grade rating Mezzanine 2 5–15% of principal, higherquality junk rating <2%, unrated, coupon rate with 20% credit spread Structured investment vehicle, SIV Equity/first loss/ residual tranche Figure 14.13 Collateralized debt obligations such as mortgage loans or credit card debt. These loans are first pooled together and then split into a series of classes known as tranches. (Tranche is the French word for “slice.”) Each tranche is given a different level of seniority in terms of its claims on the underlying loan pool, and each can be sold as a stand-alone security. As the loans in the underlying pool make their interest payments, the proceeds are distributed to pay interest to each tranche in order of seniority. This priority structure implies that each tranche has a different exposure to credit risk. Figure 14.13 illustrates a typical setup. The senior tranche is on top. Its investors may account for perhaps 80% of the principal of the entire pool. But it has first claim on all the debt service. Using our numbers, even if 20% of the debt pool defaults, the senior tranche can be paid in full. Once the highest seniority tranche is paid off, the next-lower class (e.g., the mezzanine 1 tranche in Figure 14.13) receives the proceeds from the pool of loans until its claims also are satisfied. Using junior tranches to insulate senior tranches from credit risk in this manner, one can create Aaa-rated bonds even from a junk-bond portfolio. Of course, shielding senior tranches from default risk means that the risk is concentrated on the lower tranches. The bottom tranche—called alternatively the equity, first-loss, or residual tranche—has last call on payments from the pool of loans, or, put differently, is at the head of the line in terms of absorbing default or delinquency risk. Not surprisingly, investors in tranches with the greatest exposure to credit risk demand the highest coupon rates. Therefore, while the lower mezzanine and equity tranches bear the most risk, they will provide the highest returns if credit experience turns out favorably. Mortgage-backed CDOs were an investment disaster in 2007–2009. These were CDOs formed by pooling subprime mortgage loans made to individuals whose credit standing did not allow them to qualify for conventional mortgages. When home prices stalled in 2007 and interest rates on these typically adjustable-rate loans reset to market levels, mortgage delinquencies and home foreclosures soared, and investors in these securities lost billions of dollars. Even investors in highly rated tranches experienced large losses. Not surprisingly, the rating agencies that had certified these tranches as investmentgrade came under considerable fire. Questions were raised concerning conflicts of interest: Because the rating agencies are paid by bond issuers, the agencies were accused of responding to pressure to ease their standards. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 478 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 1. Fixed-income securities are distinguished by their promise to pay a fixed or specified stream of income to their holders. The coupon bond is a typical fixed-income security. 479 SUMMARY 2. Treasury notes and bonds have original maturities greater than 1 year. They are issued at or near par value, with their prices quoted net of accrued interest. 3. Callable bonds should offer higher promised yields to maturity to compensate investors for the fact that they will not realize full capital gains should the interest rate fall and the bonds be called away from them at the stipulated call price. Bonds often are issued with a period of call protection. In addition, discount bonds selling significantly below their call price offer implicit call protection. 4. Put bonds give the bondholder rather than the issuer the option to terminate or extend the life of the bond. 5. Convertible bonds may be exchanged, at the bondholder’s discretion, for a specified number of shares of stock. Convertible bondholders “pay” for this option by accepting a lower coupon rate on the security. 6. Floating-rate bonds pay a coupon rate at a fixed premium over a reference short-term interest rate. Risk is limited because the rate is tied to current market conditions. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 7. The yield to maturity is the single interest rate that equates the present value of a security’s cash flows to its price. Bond prices and yields are inversely related. For premium bonds, the coupon rate is greater than the current yield, which is greater than the yield to maturity. The order of these inequalities is reversed for discount bonds. 8. The yield to maturity is often interpreted as an estimate of the average rate of return to an investor who purchases a bond and holds it until maturity. This interpretation is subject to error, however. Related measures are yield to call, realized compound yield, and expected (versus promised) yield to maturity. 9. Prices of zero-coupon bonds rise exponentially over time, providing a rate of appreciation equal to the interest rate. The IRS treats this built-in price appreciation as imputed taxable interest income to the investor. 10. When bonds are subject to potential default, the stated yield to maturity is the maximum possible yield to maturity that can be realized by the bondholder. In the event of default, however, that promised yield will not be realized. To compensate bond investors for default risk, bonds must offer default premiums, that is, promised yields in excess of those offered by default-free government securities. If the firm remains healthy, its bonds will provide higher returns than government bonds. Otherwise the returns may be lower. 11. Bond safety is often measured using financial ratio analysis. Bond indentures are another safeguard to protect the claims of bondholders. Common indentures specify sinking fund requirements, collateralization of the loan, dividend restrictions, and subordination of future debt. 12. Credit default swaps provide insurance against the default of a bond or loan. The swap buyer pays an annual premium to the swap seller, but collects a payment equal to lost value if the loan later goes into default. 13. Collateralized debt obligations are used to reallocate the credit risk of a pool of loans. The pool is sliced into tranches, with each tranche assigned a different level of seniority in terms of its claims on the cash flows from the underlying loans. High seniority tranches are usually quite safe, with credit risk concentrated on the lower level tranches. Each tranche can be sold as a stand-alone security. debt securities bond par value face value bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 479 coupon rate bond indenture zero-coupon bonds callable bonds convertible bonds put bond floating-rate bonds yield to maturity Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm KEY TERMS 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 480 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities current yield premium bonds discount bonds realized compound return horizon analysis reinvestment rate risk KEY EQUATIONS credit risk investment-grade bonds speculative-grade or junk bonds sinking fund subordination clauses collateral debenture default premium credit default swap (CDS) collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) Price of a coupon bond: Price 5 Coupon 3 1 1 1 B1 2 R 1 Par value 3 r (1 1 r ) T (1 1 r ) T Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 5 Coupon 3 Annuity factor(r, T) 1 Par value 3 PV factor(r, T) PROBLEM SETS 1. Define the following types of bonds: a. b. c. d. e. f. g. h. i. j. k. l. Basic Catastrophe bond. Eurobond. Zero-coupon bond. Samurai bond. Junk bond. Convertible bond. Serial bond. Equipment obligation bond. Original issue discount bond. Indexed bond. Callable bond. Puttable bond. 2. Two bonds have identical times to maturity and coupon rates. One is callable at 105, the other at 110. Which should have the higher yield to maturity? Why? 3. The stated yield to maturity and realized compound yield to maturity of a (default-free) zerocoupon bond will always be equal. Why? Intermediate 4. Why do bond prices go down when interest rates go up? Don’t lenders like high interest rates? 5. A bond with an annual coupon rate of 4.8% sells for $970. What is the bond’s current yield? 6. Which security has a higher effective annual interest rate? a. A 3-month T-bill selling at $97,645 with par value $100,000. b. A coupon bond selling at par and paying a 10% coupon semiannually. 7. Treasury bonds paying an 8% coupon rate with semiannual payments currently sell at par value. What coupon rate would they have to pay in order to sell at par if they paid their coupons annually? (Hint: What is the effective annual yield on the bond?) 8. Consider a bond with a 10% coupon and with yield to maturity 5 8%. If the bond’s yield to maturity remains constant, then in 1 year, will the bond price be higher, lower, or unchanged? Why? 9. Consider an 8% coupon bond selling for $953.10 with 3 years until maturity making annual coupon payments. The interest rates in the next 3 years will be, with certainty, r1 5 8%, r2 5 10%, and r3 5 12%. Calculate the yield to maturity and realized compound yield of the bond. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 480 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 481 10. Assume you have a 1-year investment horizon and are trying to choose among three bonds. All have the same degree of default risk and mature in 10 years. The first is a zero-coupon bond that pays $1,000 at maturity. The second has an 8% coupon rate and pays the $80 coupon once per year. The third has a 10% coupon rate and pays the $100 coupon once per year. a. If all three bonds are now priced to yield 8% to maturity, what are their prices? b. If you expect their yields to maturity to be 8% at the beginning of next year, what will their prices be then? What is your before-tax holding-period return on each bond? If your tax bracket is 30% on ordinary income and 20% on capital gains income, what will your aftertax rate of return be on each? c. Recalculate your answer to (b) under the assumption that you expect the yields to maturity on each bond to be 7% at the beginning of next year. 11. A 20-year maturity bond with par value of $1,000 makes semiannual coupon payments at a coupon rate of 8%. Find the bond equivalent and effective annual yield to maturity of the bond if the bond price is: 12. Repeat Problem 11 using the same data, but assuming that the bond makes its coupon payments annually. Why are the yields you compute lower in this case? 13. Fill in the table below for the following zero-coupon bonds, all of which have par values of $1,000. Price Maturity (years) Bond-Equivalent Yield to Maturity $400 $500 $500 — — $400 20 20 10 10 10 — — — — 10% 8% 8% 14. Consider a bond paying a coupon rate of 10% per year semiannually when the market interest rate is only 4% per half-year. The bond has 3 years until maturity. a. Find the bond’s price today and 6 months from now after the next coupon is paid. b. What is the total (6-month) rate of return on the bond? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. $950. b. $1,000. c. $1,050. 15. A bond with a coupon rate of 7% makes semiannual coupon payments on January 15 and July 15 of each year. The Wall Street Journal reports the ask price for the bond on January 30 at 100.125. What is the invoice price of the bond? The coupon period has 182 days. 16. A bond has a current yield of 9% and a yield to maturity of 10%. Is the bond selling above or below par value? Explain. 17. Is the coupon rate of the bond in Problem 16 more or less than 9%? 18. Return to Table 14.1 and calculate both the real and nominal rates of return on the TIPS bond in the second and third years. 19. A newly issued 20-year maturity, zero-coupon bond is issued with a yield to maturity of 8% and face value $1,000. Find the imputed interest income in the first, second, and last year of the bond’s life. 20. A newly issued 10-year maturity, 4% coupon bond making annual coupon payments is sold to the public at a price of $800. What will be an investor’s taxable income from the bond over the coming year? The bond will not be sold at the end of the year. The bond is treated as an originalissue discount bond. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 481 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 482 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 21. A 30-year maturity, 8% coupon bond paying coupons semiannually is callable in 5 years at a call price of $1,100. The bond currently sells at a yield to maturity of 7% (3.5% per half-year). a. What is the yield to call? b. What is the yield to call if the call price is only $1,050? c. What is the yield to call if the call price is $1,100, but the bond can be called in 2 years instead of 5 years? 22. A 10-year bond of a firm in severe financial distress has a coupon rate of 14% and sells for $900. The firm is currently renegotiating the debt, and it appears that the lenders will allow the firm to reduce coupon payments on the bond to one-half the originally contracted amount. The firm can handle these lower payments. What is the stated and expected yield to maturity of the bonds? The bond makes its coupon payments annually. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 23. A 2-year bond with par value $1,000 making annual coupon payments of $100 is priced at $1,000. What is the yield to maturity of the bond? What will be the realized compound yield to maturity if the 1-year interest rate next year turns out to be (a) 8%, (b) 10%, (c) 12%? 24. Suppose that today’s date is April 15. A bond with a 10% coupon paid semiannually every January 15 and July 15 is listed in The Wall Street Journal as selling at an ask price of 101.25. If you buy the bond from a dealer today, what price will you pay for it? 25. Assume that two firms issue bonds with the following characteristics. Both bonds are issued at par. Issue size Maturity Coupon Collateral Callable Call price Sinking fund ABC Bonds XYZ Bonds $1.2 billion 10 years* 9% First mortgage Not callable None None $150 million 20 years 10% General debenture In 10 years 110 Starting in 5 years *Bond is extendible at the discretion of the bondholder for an additional 10 years. Ignoring credit quality, identify four features of these issues that might account for the lower coupon on the ABC debt. Explain. 26. An investor believes that a bond may temporarily increase in credit risk. Which of the following would be the most liquid method of exploiting this? a. The purchase of a credit default swap. b. The sale of a credit default swap. c. The short sale of the bond. 27. Which of the following most accurately describes the behavior of credit default swaps? a. When credit risk increases, swap premiums increase. b. When credit and interest rate risk increases, swap premiums increase. c. When credit risk increases, swap premiums increase, but when interest rate risk increases, swap premiums decrease. 28. What would be the likely effect on the yield to maturity of a bond resulting from: a. An increase in the issuing firm’s times-interest-earned ratio. b. An increase in the issuing firm’s debt-to-equity ratio. c. An increase in the issuing firm’s quick ratio. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 482 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 483 Issue size Original maturity Current price (% of par) Current coupon Coupon adjusts Coupon reset rule Callable Call price Sinking fund Yield to maturity Price range since issued 9% Coupon Notes Floating-Rate Note $250 million 20 years 93 9% Fixed coupon — 10 years after issue 106 None 9.9% $85–$112 $280 million 10 years 98 8% Every year 1-year T-bill rate 1 2% 10 years after issue 102.50 None — $97–$102 Why is the price range greater for the 9% coupon bond than the floating-rate note? What factors could explain why the floating-rate note is not always sold at par value? Why is the call price for the floating-rate note not of great importance to investors? Is the probability of a call for the fixed-rate note high or low? If the firm were to issue a fixed-rate note with a 15-year maturity, what coupon rate would it need to offer to issue the bond at par value? f. Why is an entry for yield to maturity for the floating-rate note not appropriate? a. b. c. d. e. 30. Masters Corp. issues two bonds with 20-year maturities. Both bonds are callable at $1,050. The first bond is issued at a deep discount with a coupon rate of 4% and a price of $580 to yield 8.4%. The second bond is issued at par value with a coupon rate of 8¾%. a. What is the yield to maturity of the par bond? Why is it higher than the yield of the discount bond? b. If you expect rates to fall substantially in the next 2 years, which bond would you prefer to hold? c. In what sense does the discount bond offer “implicit call protection”? 31. A newly issued bond pays its coupons once annually. Its coupon rate is 5%, its maturity is 20 years, and its yield to maturity is 8%. a. Find the holding-period return for a 1-year investment period if the bond is selling at a yield to maturity of 7% by the end of the year. b. If you sell the bond after 1 year, what taxes will you owe if the tax rate on interest income is 40% and the tax rate on capital gains income is 30%? The bond is subject to original-issue discount tax treatment. c. What is the after-tax holding-period return on the bond? d. Find the realized compound yield before taxes for a 2-year holding period, assuming that (1) you sell the bond after 2 years, (2) the bond yield is 7% at the end of the second year, and (3) the coupon can be reinvested for 1 year at a 3% interest rate. e. Use the tax rates in (b) above to compute the after-tax 2-year realized compound yield. Remember to take account of OID tax rules. Challenge Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 29. A large corporation issued both fixed- and floating-rate notes 5 years ago, with terms given in the following table: 1. Leaf Products may issue a 10-year maturity fixed-income security, which might include a sinking fund provision and either refunding or call protection. a. Describe a sinking fund provision. b. Explain the impact of a sinking fund provision on: i. The expected average life of the proposed security. ii. Total principal and interest payments over the life of the proposed security. c. From the investor’s point of view, explain the rationale for demanding a sinking fund provision. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 483 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 484 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 2. Bonds of Zello Corporation with a par value of $1,000 sell for $960, mature in 5 years, and have a 7% annual coupon rate paid semiannually. a. Calculate the: i. Current yield. ii. Yield to maturity (to the nearest whole percent, i.e., 3%, 4%, 5%, etc.). iii. Realized compound yield for an investor with a 3-year holding period and a reinvestment rate of 6% over the period. At the end of 3 years the 7% coupon bonds with 2 years remaining will sell to yield 7%. b. Cite one major shortcoming for each of the following fixed-income yield measures: i. Current yield. ii. Yield to maturity. iii. Realized compound yield. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 3. On May 30, 2012, Janice Kerr is considering one of the newly issued 10-year AAA corporate bonds shown in the following exhibit. Description Coupon Price Callable Call Price Sentinal, due May 30, 2022 Colina, due May 30, 2022 6.00% 6.20% 100 100 Noncallable Currently callable NA 102 a. Suppose that market interest rates decline by 100 basis points (i.e., 1%). Contrast the effect of this decline on the price of each bond. b. Should Kerr prefer the Colina over the Sentinal bond when rates are expected to rise or to fall? c. What would be the effect, if any, of an increase in the volatility of interest rates on the prices of each bond? 4. A convertible bond has the following features: Coupon Maturity Market price of bond Market price of underlying common stock Annual dividend Conversion ratio 5.25% June 15, 2030 $77.50 $28.00 $1.20 20.83 shares Calculate the conversion premium for this bond. 5. a. Explain the impact on the offering yield of adding a call feature to a proposed bond issue. b. Explain the impact on the bond’s expected life of adding a call feature to a proposed bond issue. c. Describe one advantage and one disadvantage of including callable bonds in a portfolio. 6. a. An investment in a coupon bond will provide the investor with a return equal to the bond’s yield to maturity at the time of purchase if: i. The bond is not called for redemption at a price that exceeds its par value. ii. All sinking fund payments are made in a prompt and timely fashion over the life of the issue. iii. The reinvestment rate is the same as the bond’s yield to maturity and the bond is held until maturity. iv. All of the above. b. A bond with a call feature: i. Is attractive because the immediate receipt of principal plus premium produces a high return. ii. Is more apt to be called when interest rates are high because the interest savings will be greater. iii. Will usually have a higher yield to maturity than a similar noncallable bond. iv. None of the above. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 484 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 14 Bond Prices and Yields 485 c. In which one of the following cases is the bond selling at a discount? i. Coupon rate is greater than current yield, which is greater than yield to maturity. ii. Coupon rate, current yield, and yield to maturity are all the same. iii. Coupon rate is less than current yield, which is less than yield to maturity. iv. Coupon rate is less than current yield, which is greater than yield to maturity. d. Consider a 5-year bond with a 10% coupon that has a present yield to maturity of 8%. If interest rates remain constant, 1 year from now the price of this bond will be: i. Higher. ii. Lower. iii. The same. iv. Par. 1. Go to the Web site of Standard & Poor’s at www.standardandpoors.com. Look for Rating Services (Find a Rating). Find the ratings on bonds of at least 10 companies. Try to choose a sample with a wide range of ratings. Then go to a Web site such as money.msn.com or finance.yahoo.com and obtain, for each firm, as many of the financial ratios tabulated in Table 14.3 as you can find. Which ratios seem to best explain credit ratings? 2. At www.bondsonline.com review the Industrial Spreads for various ratings (click the links on the left-side menus to follow the links to Today’s Markets, Corporate Bond Spreads). These are spreads above U.S. Treasuries of comparable maturities. What factors tend to explain the yield differences? How might these yield spreads differ during an economic boom versus a recession? SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. The callable bond will sell at the lower price. Investors will not be willing to pay as much if they know that the firm retains a valuable option to reclaim the bond for the call price if interest rates fall. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES 2. At a semiannual interest rate of 3%, the bond is worth $40 3 Annuity factor (3%, 60) 1 $1,000 3 PV factor(3%, 60) 5 $1,276.76, which results in a capital gain of $276.76. This exceeds the capital loss of $189.29 (i.e., $1,000 2 $810.71) when the semiannual interest rate increased to 5%. 3. Yield to maturity exceeds current yield, which exceeds coupon rate. Take as an example the 8% coupon bond with a yield to maturity of 10% per year (5% per half-year). Its price is $810.71, and therefore its current yield is 80/810.71 5 .0987, or 9.87%, which is higher than the coupon rate but lower than the yield to maturity. 4. a. The bond with the 6% coupon rate currently sells for 30 3 Annuity factor(3.5%, 20) 1 1,000 3 PV factor(3.5%, 20) 5 $928.94. If the interest rate immediately drops to 6% (3% per half-year), the bond price will rise to $1,000, for a capital gain of $71.06, or 7.65%. The 8% coupon bond currently sells for $1,071.06. If the interest rate falls to 6%, the present value of the scheduled payments increases to $1,148.77. However, the bond will be called at $1,100, for a capital gain of only $28.94, or 2.70%. b. The current price of the bond can be derived from its yield to maturity. Using your calculator, set: n 5 40 (semiannual periods); payment 5 $45 per period; future value 5 $1,000; interest rate 5 4% per semiannual period. Calculate present value as $1,098.96. Now we can calculate yield to call. The time to call is 5 years, or 10 semiannual periods. The price at which the bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 485 7/17/13 3:51 PM Final PDF to printer 486 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities bond will be called is $1,050. To find yield to call, we set: n 5 10 (semiannual periods); payment 5 $45 per period; future value 5 $1,050; present value 5 $1,098.96. Calculate yield to call as 3.72%. 5. Price 5 $70 3 Annuity factor(8%, 1) 1 $1,000 3 PV factor(8%, 1) 5 $990.74 Rate of return to investor 5 $70 1 ($990.74 2 $982.17) 5 .080 5 8% $982.17 6. By year-end, remaining maturity is 29 years. If the yield to maturity were still 8%, the bond would still sell at par and the holding-period return would be 8%. At a higher yield, price and return will be lower. Suppose, for example, that the yield to maturity rises to 8.5%. With annual payments of $80 and a face value of $1,000, the price of the bond will be $946.70 [n 5 29; i 5 8.5%; PMT 5 $80; FV 5 $1,000]. The bond initially sold at $1,000 when issued at the start of the year. The holding-period return is HPR 5 80 1 (946.70 2 1,000) 5 .0267 5 2.67% 1,000 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm which is less than the initial yield to maturity of 8%. bod61671_ch14_445-486.indd 486 7. At the lower yield, the bond price will be $631.67 [n 5 29, i 5 7%, FV 5 $1,000, PMT 5 $40]. Therefore, total after-tax income is Coupon $40 3 (1 2 .38) Imputed interest ($553.66 2 $549.69) 3 (1 2 .38) Capital gains ($631.67 2 $553.66) 3 (1 2 .20) Total income after taxes Rate of return 5 89.67/549.69 5 .163 5 16.3%. 5 $24.80 5 2.46 5 62.41 $89.67 8. It should receive a negative coefficient. A high ratio of liabilities to assets is a bad omen for a firm, and that should lower its credit rating. 9. The coupon payment is $45. There are 20 semiannual periods. The final payment is assumed to be $500. The present value of expected cash flows is $650. The expected yield to maturity is 6.317% semiannual or annualized, 12.63%, bond equivalent yield. 7/17/13 3:51 PM 15 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER FIFTEEN The Term Structure of Interest Rates IN CHAPTER 14 we assumed for the sake of simplicity that the same constant interest rate is used to discount cash flows of any maturity. In the real world this is rarely the case. We have seen, for example, that in 2012 short-term Treasury bonds and notes carried yields to maturity less than 1% while the longest-term bonds offered yields of about 2.5%. At the time that these bond prices were quoted, anyway, the longer-term securities had higher yields. This, in fact, is a typical pattern, but as we shall see below, the relationship between time to maturity and yield to maturity can vary dramatically from one period to another. In this chapter we explore the pattern of interest rates for different-term assets. We attempt to identify the factors that account for that pattern and determine what information may be derived from an analysis of the so-called term structure of interest rates, the structure of interest rates for discounting cash flows of different maturities. We demonstrate how the prices of Treasury bonds may be derived from prices and yields of stripped zero-coupon Treasury securities. We also examine the extent to which the term structure reveals market-consensus forecasts of future interest rates and how the presence of interest rate risk may affect those inferences. Finally, we show how traders can use the term structure to compute forward rates that represent interest rates on “forward,” or deferred, loans, and consider the relationship between forward rates and future interest rates. 15.1 The Yield Curve bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 487 PART IV Figure 14.1 demonstrated that bonds of different maturities typically sell at different yields to maturity. When these bond prices and yields were compiled, long-term bonds sold at higher yields than short-term bonds. Practitioners commonly summarize the relationship between yield and maturity graphically in a yield curve, which is a plot of yield to maturity as a function of time to maturity. The yield curve is one of the key concerns of fixed-income investors. It is central to bond valuation and, as well, allows investors to gauge their expectations for future interest rates against those of the market. Such a comparison is often the starting point in the formulation of a fixed-income portfolio strategy. 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 488 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Treasury Yield Curve Treasury Yield Curve Yields as of 4:30 P.M. Eastern time Yields as of 4:30 P.M. Eastern time Treasury Yield Curve Yields as of 4:30 P.M. Eastern time Treasury Yield Curve Yields as of 4:30 P.M. Eastern time Percent 6.0 Percent 6.0 Percent 6.50 Percent 8.60 5.0 5.0 6.25 8.40 4.0 4.0 8.20 6.00 8.00 3.0 3.0 5.75 2.0 2.0 1.0 1.0 0.0 1 3 6 2 5 10 30 Maturities Months Year A. (January 2006) Flat Yield Curve 7.80 5.50 7.60 7.40 5.25 1 3 6 1 2 56 710 30 Months Year Maturities B. (December 2012) Rising Yield Curve 3 6 1 2 3 5 10 30 Months Year Maturities C. (September 11, 2000) Inverted Yield Curve 3 6 1 2 3 45 710 30 Months Year Maturities D. (October 4, 1989) Hump-Shaped Yield Curve Figure 15.1 Treasury yield curves Source: Various editions of The Wall Street Journal. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal, © 1989, 2000, 2006, and 2012 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. In 2012, the yield curve was rising, with long-term bonds offering yields higher than those of short-term bonds. But the relationship between yield and maturity can vary widely. Figure 15.1 illustrates yield curves of several different shapes. Panel A is the almost-flat curve of early 2006. Panel B is a more typical upward-sloping curve from 2012. Panel C is a downward-sloping or “inverted” curve, and panel D is hump-shaped, first rising and then falling. Bond Pricing If yields on different-maturity bonds are not all equal, how should we value coupon bonds that make payments at many different times? For example, suppose that yields on zerocoupon Treasury bonds of different maturities are as given in Table 15.1. The table tells us that zero-coupon bonds with 1-year maturity sell at a yield to maturity of y1 5 5%, 2-year zeros sell at yields of y2 5 6%, and 3-year zeros sell at yields of y3 5 7%. Which of these rates should we use to discount bond cash flows? The answer: all of them. The trick is to consider each bond cash flow—either coupon or principal payment—as at least potentially sold off separately as a stand-alone zero-coupon bond. Recall the Treasury STRIPS program we introduced in the last chapter (Section 14.4). Stripped Treasuries are zero-coupon bonds created by selling each coupon or principal payment from a whole Treasury bond as a separate cash flow. For example, a 1-year Table 15.1 Prices and yields to maturity on zero-coupon bonds ($1,000 face value) bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 488 Maturity (years) Yield to Maturity (%) Price 1 2 3 4 5% 6 7 8 $952.38 5 $1,000/1.05 $890.00 5 $1,000/1.062 $816.30 5 $1,000/1.073 $735.03 5 $1,000/1.084 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 489 maturity T-bond paying semiannual coupons can be split into a 6-month maturity zero (by selling the first coupon payment as a stand-alone security) and a 12-month zero (corresponding to payment of final coupon and principal). Treasury stripping suggests exactly how to value a coupon bond. If each cash flow can be (and in practice often is) sold off as a separate security, then the value of the whole bond should be the same as the value of its cash flows bought piece by piece in the STRIPS market. What if it weren’t? Then there would be easy profits to be made. For example, if investment bankers ever noticed a bond selling for less than the amount at which the sum of its parts could be sold, they would buy the bond, strip it into stand-alone zerocoupon securities, sell off the stripped cash flows, and profit by the price difference. If the bond were selling for more than the sum of the values of its individual cash flows, they would run the process in reverse: buy the individual zero-coupon securities in the STRIPS market, reconstitute (i.e., reassemble) the cash flows into a coupon bond, and sell the whole bond for more than the cost of the pieces. Both bond stripping and bond reconstitution offer opportunities for arbitrage—the exploitation of mispricing among two or more securities to clear a riskless economic profit. Any violation of the Law of One Price, that identical cash flow bundles must sell for identical prices, gives rise to arbitrage opportunities. Now, we know how to value each stripped cash flow. We simply look up its appropriate discount rate in The Wall Street Journal. Because each coupon payment matures at a different time, we discount by using the yield appropriate to its particular maturity—this is the yield on a Treasury strip maturing at the time of that cash flow. We can illustrate with an example. Example 15.1 Valuing Coupon Bonds Suppose the yields on stripped Treasuries are as given in Table 15.1, and we wish to value a 10% coupon bond with a maturity of 3 years. For simplicity, assume the bond makes its payments annually. Then the first cash flow, the $100 coupon paid at the end of the first year, is discounted at 5%; the second cash flow, the $100 coupon at the end of the second year, is discounted at 6%; and the final cash flow consisting of the final coupon plus par value, or $1,100, is discounted at 7%. The value of the coupon bond is therefore 1,100 100 100 1 1 5 95.238 1 89.000 1 897.928 5 $1,082.17 2 1.05 1.06 1.073 Calculate the yield to maturity of the coupon bond in Example 15.1, and you may be surprised. Its yield to maturity is 6.88%; so while its maturity matches that of the 3-year zero in Table 15.1, its yield is a bit lower.1 This reflects the fact that the 3-year coupon bond may usefully be thought of as a portfolio of three implicit zero-coupon bonds, one corresponding to each cash flow. The yield on the coupon bond is then an amalgam of the yields on each of the three components of the “portfolio.” Think about what this means: If their coupon rates differ, bonds of the same maturity generally will not have the same yield to maturity. What then do we mean by “the” yield curve? In fact, in practice, traders refer to several yield curves. The pure yield curve refers to the curve for stripped, or zero-coupon, 1 Remember that the yield to maturity of a coupon bond is the single interest rate at which the present value of cash flows equals market price. To calculate the bond’s yield to maturity on your calculator or spreadsheet, set n 5 3; price 5 21,082.17; future value 5 1,000; payment 5 100. Then compute the interest rate. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 489 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 490 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Treasuries. In contrast, the on-the-run yield curve refers to the plot of yield as a function of maturity for recently issued coupon bonds selling at or near par value. As we’ve just seen, there may be significant differences in these two curves. The yield curves published in the financial press, for example, in Figure 15.1, are typically on-the-run curves. On-the-run Treasuries have the greatest liquidity, so traders have keen interest in their yield curve. CONCEPT CHECK 15.1 Calculate the price and yield to maturity of a 3-year bond with a coupon rate of 4% making annual coupon payments. Does its yield match that of either the 3-year zero or the 10% coupon bond considered in Example 15.1? Why is the yield spread between the 4% bond and the zero smaller than the yield spread between the 10% bond and the zero? 15.2 The Yield Curve and Future Interest Rates We’ve told you what the yield curve is, but we haven’t yet had much to say about where it comes from. For example, why is the curve sometimes upward-sloping and other times downward-sloping? How do expectations for the evolution of interest rates affect the shape of today’s yield curve? These questions do not have simple answers, so we will begin with an admittedly idealized framework, and then extend the discussion to more realistic settings. To start, consider a world with no uncertainty, specifically, one in which all investors already know the path of future interest rates. The Yield Curve under Certainty If interest rates are certain, what should we make of the fact that the yield on the 2-year zero coupon bond in Table 15.1 is greater than that on the 1-year zero? It can’t be that one bond is expected to provide a higher rate of return than the other. This would not be possible in a certain world—with no risk, all bonds (in fact, all securities!) must offer identical returns, or investors will bid up the price of the high-return bond until its rate of return is no longer superior to that of other bonds. Instead, the upward-sloping yield curve is evidence that short-term rates are going to be higher next year than they are now. To see why, consider two 2-year bond strategies. The first strategy entails buying the 2-year zero offering a 2-year yield to maturity of y2 5 6%, and holding it until maturity. The zero with face value $1,000 is purchased today for $1,000/1.062 5 $890 and matures in 2 years to $1,000. The total 2-year growth factor for the investment is therefore $1,000/$890 5 1.062 5 1.1236. Now consider an alternative 2-year strategy. Invest the same $890 in a 1-year zerocoupon bond with a yield to maturity of 5%. When that bond matures, reinvest the proceeds in another 1-year bond. Figure 15.2 illustrates these two strategies. The interest rate that 1-year bonds will offer next year is denoted as r2. Remember, both strategies must provide equal returns—neither entails any risk. Therefore, the proceeds after 2 years to either strategy must be equal: Buy and hold 2-year zero 5 Roll over 1-year bonds $890 3 1.062 5 $890 3 1.05 3 (1 1 r2 ) We find next year’s interest rate by solving 1 1 r2 5 1.062/1.05 5 1.0701, or r2 5 7.01%. So while the 1-year bond offers a lower yield to maturity than the 2-year bond (5% versus 6%), bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 490 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 0 1 2 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 491 Time Line Alternative 1: Buy and hold 2-year zero 2-Year Investment $890 ×1.062 = $1000 $890 Alternative 2: Buy a 1-year zero, and reinvest proceeds in another 1-year zero 1-Year Investment $890 1-Year Investment $890 × 1.05 = $934.50 $934.50(1 + r2) Figure 15.2 Two 2-year investment programs we see that it has a compensating advantage: It allows you to roll over your funds into another short-term bond next year when rates will be higher. Next year’s interest rate is higher than today’s by just enough to make rolling over 1-year bonds equally attractive as investing in the 2-year bond. To distinguish between yields on long-term bonds versus short-term rates that will be available in the future, practitioners use the following terminology. They call the yield to maturity on zero-coupon bonds the spot rate, meaning the rate that prevails today for a time period corresponding to the zero’s maturity. In contrast, the short rate for a given time interval (e.g., 1 year) refers to the interest rate for that interval available at different points in time. In our example, the short rate today is 5%, and the short rate next year will be 7.01%. Not surprisingly, the 2-year spot rate is an average of today’s short rate and next year’s short rate. But because of compounding, that average is a geometric one.2 We see this by again equating the total return on the two competing 2-year strategies: (1 1 y2 )2 5 (1 1 r1 ) 3 (1 1 r2 ) 1 1 y2 5 3(1 1 r1 ) 3 (1 1 r2 )4 1/2 (15.1) Equation 15.1 begins to tell us why the yield curve might take on different shapes at different times. When next year’s short rate, r2, is greater than this year’s short rate, r1, the average of the two rates is higher than today’s rate, so y2 . r1 and the yield curve slopes upward. If next year’s short rate were less than r1, the yield curve would slope downward. 2 In an arithmetic average, we add n numbers and divide by n. In a geometric average, we multiply n numbers and take the nth root. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 491 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 492 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Thus, at least in part, the yield curve reflects the market’s assessments of coming interest rates. The following example uses a similar analysis to find the short rate that will prevail in year 3. Example 15.2 Finding a Future Short Rate Now we compare two 3-year strategies. One is to buy a 3-year zero, with a yield to maturity from Table 15.1 of 7%, and hold it until maturity. The other is to buy a 2-year zero yielding 6%, and roll the proceeds into a 1-year bond in year 3, at the short rate r3. The growth factor for the invested funds under each policy will be: Buy and hold 3-year zero 5 Buy 2-year zero; roll proceeds into 1-year bond (1 1 y3)3 5 (1 1 y2)2 3 (1 1 r3) 1.073 5 1.062 3 (1 1 r3) which implies that r3 5 1.073/1.062 2 1 5 .09025 5 9.025%. Again, notice that the yield on the 3-year bond reflects a geometric average of the discount factors for the next 3 years: 1 1 y3 5 [(1 1 r1) 3 (1 1 r2) 3 (1 1 r3)]1/3 1.07 5 [1.05 3 1.0701 3 1.09025]1/3 We conclude that the yield or spot rate on a long-term bond reflects the path of short rates anticipated by the market over the life of the bond. CONCEPT CHECK 15.2 Use Table 15.1 to find the short rate that will prevail in the fourth year. Confirm that the discount factor on the 4-year zero is a geometric average of 11 the short rates in the next 4 years. Figure 15.3 summarizes the results of our analysis and emphasizes the difference between short rates and spot rates. The top line presents the short rates for each year. The lower lines present spot rates—or, equivalently, yields to maturity on zero-coupon bonds for different holding periods—extending from the present to each relevant maturity date. Holding-Period Returns We’ve argued that the multiyear cumulative returns on all of our competing bonds ought to be equal. What about holding-period returns over shorter periods such as a year? You might think that bonds selling at higher yields to maturity will offer higher 1-year returns, but this is not the case. In fact, once you stop to think about it, it’s clear that this cannot be true. In a world of certainty, all bonds must offer identical returns, or investors will flock to the higher-return securities, bidding up their prices, and reducing their returns. We can illustrate by using the bonds in Table 15.1. Example 15.3 Holding-Period Returns on Zero-Coupon Bonds The 1-year bond in Table 15.1 can be bought today for $1,000/1.05 5 $952.38 and will mature to its par value in 1 year. It pays no coupons, so total investment income is just its price appreciation, and its rate of return is ($1,000 2 $952.38)/$952.38 5 .05. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 492 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 493 The 2-year bond can be bought for $1,000/1.062 5 $890.00. Next year, the bond will have a remaining maturity of 1 year and the 1-year interest rate will be 7.01%. Therefore, its price next year will be $1,000/1.0701 5 $934.49, and its 1-year holding-period rate of return will be ($934.49 2 $890.00)/$890.00 5 .05, for an identical 5% rate of return. CONCEPT CHECK 15.3 Show that the rate of return on the 3-year zero in Table 15.1 also will be 5%. Hint: Next year, the bond will have a maturity of 2 years. Use the short rates derived in Figure 15.3 to compute the 2-year spot rate that will prevail a year from now. Forward Rates The following equation generalizes our approach to inferring a future short rate from the yield curve of zero-coupon bonds. It equates the total return on two n-year investment strategies: buying and holding an n-year zero-coupon bond versus buying an (n 2 1)-year zero and rolling over the proceeds into a 1-year bond. (1 1 yn )n 5 (1 1 yn21 )n21 3 (1 1 rn ) (15.2) where n denotes the period in question, and yn is the yield to maturity of a zero-coupon bond with an n-period maturity. Given the observed yield curve, we can solve Equation 15.2 for the short rate in the last period: (1 1 rn ) 5 (1 1 yn )n (1 1 yn21 )n21 1 2 3 4 r1 = 5% r2 = 7.01% r3 = 9.025% r4 = 11.06% (15.3) Year Short Rate in Each Year Current Spot Rates (Yields to Maturity) for Various Maturities y1 = 5% 1-Year Investment y2 = 6% 2-Year Investment y3 = 7% 3-Year Investment y4 = 8% 4-Year Investment Figure 15.3 Short rates versus spot rates bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 493 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 494 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Equation 15.3 has a simple interpretation. The numerator on the right-hand side is the total growth factor of an investment in an n-year zero held until maturity. Similarly, the denominator is the growth factor of an investment in an (n 2 1)-year zero. Because the former investment lasts for one more year than the latter, the difference in these growth factors must be the rate of return available in year n when the (n 2 1)-year zero can be rolled over into a 1-year investment. Of course, when future interest rates are uncertain, as they are in reality, there is no meaning to inferring “the” future short rate. No one knows today what the future interest rate will be. At best, we can speculate as to its expected value and associated uncertainty. Nevertheless, it still is common to use Equation 15.3 to investigate the implications of the yield curve for future interest rates. Recognizing that future interest rates are uncertain, we call the interest rate that we infer in this matter the forward interest rate rather than the future short rate, because it need not be the interest rate that actually will prevail at the future date. If the forward rate for period n is denoted fn, we then define fn by the equation (1 1 fn) 5 (1 1 yn)n (1 1 yn21)n21 (15.4) Equivalently, we may rewrite Equation 15.4 as (1 1 yn)n 5 (1 1 yn21)n21(1 1 fn) (15.5) In this formulation, the forward rate is defined as the “break-even” interest rate that equates the return on an n-period zero-coupon bond to that of an (n 2 1)-period zero-coupon bond rolled over into a 1-year bond in year n. The actual total returns on the two n-year strategies will be equal if the short interest rate in year n turns out to equal fn. Example 15.4 Forward Rates Suppose a bond trader uses the data presented in Table 15.1. The forward rate for year 4 would be computed as 1 1 f4 5 (1 1 y4)4 (1 1 y3)3 5 1.084 5 1.1106 1.073 Therefore, the forward rate is f4 5 .1106, or 11.06%. We emphasize again that the interest rate that actually will prevail in the future need not equal the forward rate, which is calculated from today’s data. Indeed, it is not even necessarily the case that the forward rate equals the expected value of the future CONCEPT CHECK 15.4 short interest rate. This is an issue that we address in the next section. For now, howYou’ve been exposed to many “rates” in the last few pages. ever, we note that forward rates equal future Explain the differences between spot rates, short rates, and forward rates. short rates in the special case of interest rate certainty. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 494 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer eXcel APPLICATIONS: Spot and Forward Yields T he spreadsheet below (available at www.mhhe.com/ bkm) can be used to estimate prices and yields of coupon bonds and to calculate the forward rates for both single-year and multiyear periods. Spot yields are derived for the yield curve of bonds that are selling at their par value, also referred to as the current coupon or “on-the-run” bond yield curve. The spot rates for each maturity date are used to calculate the present value of each period’s cash flow. The sum of these cash flows is the price of the bond. Given its price, the bond’s yield to maturity can then be computed. If you were to err and use the yield to maturity of the on-the-run A B C D Forward Rate Calculations 56 57 Spot Rate 1-yr for. 2-yr for. 58 59 Period 60 1 8.0000% 7.9792% 7.6770% 61 2 7.9896% 7.3757% 6.9205% 62 3 7.7846% 6.4673% 6.2695% 63 4 7.4537% 6.0720% 6.3065% 5 7.1760% 6.5414% 6.2920% 64 6 7.0699% 6.0432% 6.4299% 65 7 6.9227% 6.8181% 5.8904% 66 8 6.9096% 4.9707% 5.3993% 67 bond to discount each of the bond’s coupon payments, you could find a significantly different price. That difference is calculated in the worksheet. Excel Questions 1. Change the spot rate in the spreadsheet to 8% for all maturities. The forward rates will all be 8%. Why is this not surprising? 2. The spot rates in column B decrease for longer maturities, and the forward rates decrease even more rapidly with maturity. What happens to the pattern of forward rates if you input spot rates that increase with maturity? Why? E F G H 3-yr for. 4-yr for. 5-yr for. 6-yr for. 7.2723% 6.6369% 6.3600% 6.2186% 6.4671% 5.9413% 5.8701% 5.2521% 6.9709% 6.6131% 6.2807% 6.3682% 6.0910% 5.9134% 5.6414% 5.2209% 6.8849% 6.4988% 6.3880% 6.0872% 6.0387% 5.7217% 5.5384% 5.1149% 6.7441% 6.5520% 6.1505% 6.0442% 5.8579% 5.6224% 5.3969% 5.1988% 15.3 Interest Rate Uncertainty and Forward Rates Let us turn now to the more difficult analysis of the term structure when future interest rates are uncertain. We have argued so far that, in a certain world, different investment strategies with common terminal dates must provide equal rates of return. For example, two consecutive 1-year investments in zeros would need to offer the same total return as an equal-sized investment in a 2-year zero. Therefore, under certainty, (1 1 r1)(1 1 r2 ) 5 (1 1 y2 )2 (15.6) What can we say when r2 is not known today? For example, suppose that today’s rate is r1 5 5% and that the expected short rate for the following year is E(r2) 5 6%. If investors cared only about the expected value of the interest rate, then the yield to maturity on a 2-year zero would be determined by using the expected short rate in Equation 15.6: (1 1 y2 )2 5 (1 1 r1 ) 3 3 1 1 E(r2 ) 4 5 1.05 3 1.06 The price of a 2-year zero would be $1,000/(1 1 y2)2 5 $1,000/(1.05 3 1.06) 5 $898.47. But now consider a short-term investor who wishes to invest only for 1 year. She can purchase the 1-year zero for $1,000/1.05 5 $952.38, and lock in a riskless 5% return because she knows that at the end of the year, the bond will be worth its maturity value of $1,000. She also can purchase the 2-year zero. Its expected rate of return also is 5%: Next year, the bond will have 1 year to maturity, and we expect that the 1-year interest rate will be 6%, implying a price of $943.40 and a holding-period return of 5%. 495 bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 495 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 496 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities But the rate of return on the 2-year bond is risky. If next year’s interest rate turns out to be above expectations, that is, greater than 6%, the bond price will be below $943.40; conversely if r2 turns out to be less than 6%, the bond price will exceed $943.40. Why should this short-term investor buy the risky 2-year bond when its expected return is 5%, no better than that of the risk-free 1-year bond? Clearly, she would not hold the 2-year bond unless it offered a higher expected rate of return. This requires that the 2-year bond sell at a price lower than the $898.47 value we derived when we ignored risk. Example 15.5 Bond Prices and Forward Rates with Interest Rate Risk Suppose that most investors have short-term horizons and therefore are willing to hold the 2-year bond only if its price falls to $881.83. At this price, the expected holdingperiod return on the 2-year bond is 7% (because 943.40/881.83 5 1.07). The risk premium of the 2-year bond, therefore, is 2%; it offers an expected rate of return of 7% versus the 5% risk-free return on the 1-year bond. At this risk premium, investors are willing to bear the price risk associated with interest rate uncertainty. When bond prices reflect a risk premium, however, the forward rate, f2, no longer equals the expected short rate, E(r2). Although we have assumed that E(r2) 5 6%, it is easy to confirm that f2 5 8%. The yield to maturity on the 2-year zeros selling at $881.83 is 6.49%, and 1 1 f2 5 (1 1 y2)2 1 1 y1 5 1.06492 5 1.08 1.05 The result in Example 15.5—that the forward rate exceeds the expected short rate— should not surprise us. We defined the forward rate as the interest rate that would need to prevail in the second year to make the long- and short-term investments equally attractive, ignoring risk. When we account for risk, it is clear that short-term investors will shy away from the long-term bond unless it offers an expected return greater than that of the 1-year bond. Another way of putting this is to say that investors will require a risk premium to hold the longer-term bond. The risk-averse investor would be willing to hold the long-term bond only if the expected value of the short rate is less than the break-even value, f2, because the lower the expectation of r2, the greater the anticipated return on the long-term bond. Therefore, if most individuals are short-term investors, bonds must have prices that make f2 greater than E(r2). The forward rate will embody a premium compared with the expected future short-interest rate. This liquidity premium compensates short-term investors for the uncertainty about the price at which they will be able to sell their long-term bonds at the end of the year.3 CONCEPT CHECK 15.5 Suppose that the required liquidity premium for the short-term investor is 1%. What must E(r2) be if f2 is 7%? Perhaps surprisingly, we also can imagine scenarios in which long-term bonds can be perceived by investors to be safer than short-term bonds. To see how, we now consider a “long-term” investor, who wishes to invest for a full 2-year period. Suppose that the investor 3 Liquidity refers to the ability to sell an asset easily at a predictable price. Because long-term bonds have greater price risk, they are considered less liquid in this context and thus must offer a premium. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 496 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 497 can purchase a $1,000 par value 2-year zero-coupon bond for $890 and lock in a guaranteed yield to maturity of y2 5 6%. Alternatively, the investor can roll over two 1-year investments. In this case an investment of $890 would grow in 2 years to 890 3 1.05 3 (1 1 r2), which is an uncertain amount today because r2 is not yet known. The break-even year-2 interest rate is, once again, the forward rate, 7.01%, because the forward rate is defined as the rate that equates the terminal value of the two investment strategies. The expected value of the payoff of the rollover strategy is 890 3 1.05 3 [1 1 E(r2)]. If E(r2) equals the forward rate, f2, then the expected value of the payoff from the rollover strategy will equal the known payoff from the 2-year-maturity bond strategy. Is this a reasonable presumption? Once again, it is only if the investor does not care about the uncertainty surrounding the final value of the rollover strategy. Whenever that risk is important, however, the long-term investor will not be willing to engage in the rollover strategy unless its expected return exceeds that of the 2-year bond. In this case the investor would require that (1.05)3 1 1 E(r2)4 . (1.06)2 5 (1.05)(1 1 f2) which implies that E(r2) exceeds f2. The investor would require that the expected value of next year’s short rate exceed the forward rate. Therefore, if all investors were long-term investors, no one would be willing to hold short-term bonds unless those bonds offered a reward for bearing interest rate risk. In this situation bond prices would be set at levels such that rolling over short bonds resulted in greater expected return than holding long bonds. This would cause the forward rate to be less than the expected future spot rate. For example, suppose that in fact E(r2) 5 8%. The liquidity premium therefore is negative: f2 2 E(r2) 5 7.01% 2 8% 5 2.99%. This is exactly opposite from the conclusion that we drew in the first case of the short-term investor. Clearly, whether forward rates will equal expected future short rates depends on investors’ readiness to bear interest rate risk, as well as their willingness to hold bonds that do not correspond to their investment horizons. 15.4 Theories of the Term Structure The Expectations Hypothesis The simplest theory of the term structure is the expectations hypothesis. A common version of this hypothesis states that the forward rate equals the market consensus expectation of the future short interest rate; that is, f2 5 E(r2), and liquidity premiums are zero. If f2 5 E(r2), we may relate yields on long-term bonds to expectations of future interest rates. In addition, we can use the forward rates derived from the yield curve to infer market expectations of future short rates. For example, with (1 1 y2)2 5 (1 1 r1) 3 (1 1 f2 ) from Equation 15.5, if the expectations hypothesis is correct we may also write that (1 1 y2)2 5 (1 1 r1) 3 [1 1 E(r2 )]. The yield to maturity would thus be determined solely by current and expected future one-period interest rates. An upward-sloping yield curve would be clear evidence that investors anticipate increases in interest rates. CONCEPT CHECK 15.6 If the expectations hypothesis is valid, what can we conclude about the premiums necessary to induce investors to hold bonds of different maturities from their investment horizons? bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 497 7/17/13 4:03 PM WORDS FROM THE STREET Final PDF to printer The Expectations Hypothesis and Forward Inflation Rates Forward rates derived from conventional bonds are nominal interest rates. But using price-level-indexed bonds such as TIPS, we can also calculate forward real interest rates. Recall that the difference between the real rate and the nominal rate is approximately the expected inflation rate. Therefore, comparing real and nominal forward rates might give us a glimpse of the market’s expectation of future inflation rates. The real versus nominal spread is a sort of forward inflation rate. As part of its monetary policy, the Federal Reserve Board periodically reduces its target federal funds rate in an attempt to stimulate the economy. The following page capture from a Bloomberg screen shows the minuteby-minute spread between the 5-year forward nominal interest rate and forward real rate on one day the Fed announced such a policy change. The spread immediately widened at the announcement, signifying that the market expected the more expansionary monetary policy to eventually result in a higher inflation rate. The increase in the inflation rate implied by the graph is fairly mild, about .05%, from about 2.53% to 2.58%, but the impact of the announcement is very clear, and the speed of adjustment to the announcement was impressive. By the way, nothing limits us to nominal bonds when using the expectations hypothesis. The nearby box points out that we can apply the theory to the term structure of real interest rates as well, and thereby learn something about market expectations of coming inflation rates. Liquidity Preference We noted earlier that short-term investors will be unwilling to hold long-term bonds unless the forward rate exceeds the expected short interest rate, f2 . E(r2), whereas long-term investors will be unwilling to hold short bonds unless E(r2) . f2. In other words, both groups of investors CONCEPT CHECK 15.7 require a premium to hold bonds with maturities different from their investment horizons. Advocates of the The liquidity premium hypothesis also holds liquidity preference theory of the term structure believe that issuers of bonds prefer to issue long-term that short-term investors dominate the market so that the bonds to lock in borrowing costs. How would forward rate will generally exceed the expected short this preference contribute to a positive liquidity rate. The excess of f2 over E(r2), the liquidity premium, is premium? predicted to be positive. To illustrate the differing implications of these theories for the term structure of interest rates, suppose the short interest rate is expected to be constant indefinitely. Suppose that r1 5 5% and that E(r2) 5 5%, E(r3) 5 5%, and so on. Under the expectations hypothesis the 2-year yield to maturity could be derived from the following: (1 1 y2)2 5 (1 1 r1) 3 1 1 E(r2) 4 5 (1.05)(1.05) so that y2 equals 5%. Similarly, yields on bonds of all maturities would equal 5%. 498 bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 498 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 499 In contrast, under the liquidity preference theory, f2 would exceed E(r2). To illustrate, suppose the liquidity premium is 1%, so f2 is 6%. Then, for 2-year bonds: (1 1 y2)2 5 (1 1 r1)(1 1 f2) 5 1.05 3 1.06 5 1.113 implying that 1 1 y2 5 1.055. Similarly, if f3 also equals 6%, then the yield on 3-year bonds would be determined by (1 1 y3)3 5 (1 1 r1)(1 1 f2)(1 1 f3) 5 1.05 3 1.06 3 1.06 5 1.17978 7.0 YTM E(r) Forward Rate A Interest Rate (%) 6.5 6.0 Constant Liquidity Premium 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 0 1 2 7.0 3 4 YTM 5 6 Maturity E(r) 7 8 9 10 Forward Rate B Interest Rate (%) 6.5 6.0 5.5 Liquidity Premium Increases with Maturity 5.0 4.5 4.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Maturity 7 8 9 10 Figure 15.4 Yield curves. Panel A, Constant expected short rate. Liquidity premium of 1%. Result is a rising yield curve. Panel B, Declining expected short rates. Increasing liquidity premiums. Result is a rising yield curve despite falling expected interest rates. (continued on next page) bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 499 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 500 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities implying that 1 1 y3 5 1.0567. The plot of the yield curve in this situation would be given as in Figure 15.4, panel A. Such an upward-sloping yield curve is commonly observed in practice. If interest rates are expected to change over time, then the liquidity premium may be overlaid on the path of expected spot rates to determine the forward interest rate. Then the yield to maturity for each date will be an average of the single-period forward rates. Several such possibilities for increasing and declining interest rates appear in Figure 15.4, panels B to D. 7.0 YTM E(r) Forward Rate C Interest Rate (%) 6.5 6.0 5.5 5.0 Constant Liquidity Premium 4.5 4.0 0 1 2 7.0 3 4 YTM 5 6 Maturity E(r) 7 8 9 10 8 9 10 Forward Rate D Interest Rate (%) 6.5 Liquidity Premium Increases with Maturity 6.0 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Maturity 7 Figure 15.4 (Concluded) Panel C, Declining expected short rates. Constant liquidity premiums. Result is a hump-shaped yield curve. Panel D, Increasing expected short rates. Increasing liquidity premiums. Result is a sharply rising yield curve. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 500 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 501 15.5 Interpreting the Term Structure If the yield curve reflects expectations of future short rates, then it offers a potentially powerful tool for fixed-income investors. If we can use the term structure to infer the expectations of other investors in the economy, we can use those expectations as benchmarks for our own analysis. For example, if we are relatively more optimistic than other investors that interest rates will fall, we will be more willing to extend our portfolios into longer-term bonds. Therefore, in this section, we will take a careful look at what information can be gleaned from a careful analysis of the term structure. Unfortunately, while the yield curve does reflect expectations of future interest rates, it also reflects other factors such as liquidity premiums. Moreover, forecasts of interest rate changes may have different investment implications depending on whether those changes are driven by changes in the expected inflation rate or the real rate, and this adds another layer of complexity to the proper interpretation of the term structure. We have seen that under certainty, 1 plus the yield to maturity on a zero-coupon bond is simply the geometric average of 1 plus the future short rates that will prevail over the life of the bond. This is the meaning of Equation 15.1, which we give in general form here: 1 1 yn 5 3(1 1 r1)(1 1 r2)c(1 1 rn) 4 1/n When future rates are uncertain, we modify Equation 15.1 by replacing future short rates with forward rates: 1 1 yn 5 3(1 1 r1)(1 1 f2)(1 1 f3)c(1 1 fn) 4 1/n (15.7) Thus there is a direct relationship between yields on various maturity bonds and forward interest rates. First, we ask what factors can account for a rising yield curve. Mathematically, if the yield curve is rising, fn11 must exceed yn. In words, the yield curve is upward-sloping at any maturity date, n, for which the forward rate for the coming period is greater than the yield at that maturity. This rule follows from the notion of the yield to maturity as an average (albeit a geometric average) of forward rates. If the yield curve is to rise as one moves to longer maturities, it must be the case that extension to a longer maturity results in the inclusion of a “new” forward rate that is higher than the average of the previously observed rates. This is analogous to the observation that if a new student’s test score is to increase the class average, that student’s score must exceed the class’s average without her score. To increase the yield to maturity, an aboveaverage forward rate must be added to the other rates used in the averaging computation. Example 15.6 Forward Rates and the Slopes of the Yield Curve If the yield to maturity on 3-year zero-coupon bonds is 7%, then the yield on 4-year bonds will satisfy the following equation: (1 1 y4 )4 5 (1.07)3(1 1 f4 ) If f4 5 .07, then y4 also will equal .07. (Confirm this!) If f4 is greater than 7%, y4 will exceed 7%, and the yield curve will slope upward. For example, if f4 5 .08, then (1 1 y4)4 5 (1.07)3(1.08) 5 1.3230, and y4 5 .0725. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 501 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 502 PART IV CONCEPT CHECK Fixed-Income Securities 15.8 Look back at Table 15.1. Show that y4 will exceed y3 if and only if the forward interest rate for period 4 is greater than 7%, which is the yield to maturity on the 3-year bond, y3. Given that an upward-sloping yield curve is always associated with a forward rate higher than the spot, or current, yield to maturity, we ask next what can account for that higher forward rate. Unfortunately, there always are two possible answers to this question. Recall that the forward rate can be related to the expected future short rate according to this equation: fn 5 E(rn) 1 Liquidity premium (15.8) where the liquidity premium might be necessary to induce investors to hold bonds of maturities that do not correspond to their preferred investment horizons. By the way, the liquidity premium need not be positive, although that is the position generally taken by advocates of the liquidity premium hypothesis. We showed previously that if most investors have long-term horizons, the liquidity premium in principle could be negative. In any case, Equation 15.8 shows that there are two reasons that the forward rate could be high. Either investors expect rising interest rates, meaning that E(rn) is high, or they require a large premium for holding longer-term bonds. Although it is tempting to infer from a rising yield curve that investors believe that interest rates will eventually increase, this is not a valid inference. Indeed, panel A in Figure 15.4 provides a simple counter-example to this line of reasoning. There, the short rate is expected to stay at 5% forever. Yet there is a constant 1% liquidity premium so that all forward rates are 6%. The result is that the yield curve continually rises, starting at a level of 5% for 1-year bonds, but eventually approaching 6% for longterm bonds as more and more forward rates at 6% are averaged into the yields to maturity. Therefore, although it is true that expectations of increases in future interest rates can result in a rising yield curve, the converse is not true: A rising yield curve does not in and of itself imply expectations of higher future interest rates. The effects of possible liquidity premiums confound any simple attempt to extract expectations from the term structure. But estimating the market’s expectations is crucial because only by comparing your own expectations to those reflected in market prices can you determine whether you are relatively bullish or bearish on interest rates. One very rough approach to deriving expected future spot rates is to assume that liquidity premiums are constant. An estimate of that premium can be subtracted from the forward rate to obtain the market’s expected interest rate. For example, again making use of the example plotted in panel A of Figure 15.4, the researcher would estimate from historical data that a typical liquidity premium in this economy is 1%. After calculating the forward rate from the yield curve to be 6%, the expectation of the future spot rate would be determined to be 5%. This approach has little to recommend it for two reasons. First, it is next to impossible to obtain precise estimates of a liquidity premium. The general approach to doing so would be to compare forward rates and eventually realized future short rates and to calculate the average difference between the two. However, the deviations between the two values can be quite large and unpredictable because of unanticipated economic events that affect the realized short rate. The data are too noisy to calculate a reliable estimate of the expected premium. Second, there is no reason to believe that the liquidity premium should be constant. Figure 15.5 shows the rate of return variability of prices of long-term Treasury bonds since 1971. Interest rate risk fluctuated dramatically during the period. So we should expect risk premiums on various maturity bonds to fluctuate, and empirical evidence suggests that liquidity premiums do in fact fluctuate over time. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 502 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 503 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 2013 2011 2009 2007 2005 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 1985 1983 1981 1979 1977 1975 1973 1971 Standard Deviation of Monthly Returns (%) Still, very steep yield curves are interpreted by 6.0 many market professionals as warning signs of 5.0 impending rate increases. In fact, the yield curve is 4.0 a good predictor of the business cycle as a whole, because long-term rates 3.0 tend to rise in anticipation of an expansion in eco2.0 nomic activity. The usually observed upward slope of the yield 1.0 curve, especially for short maturities, is the empiri0.0 cal basis for the liquidity premium doctrine that long-term bonds offer a positive liquidity premium. Because the yield curve Figure 15.5 Price volatility of long-term Treasury bonds normally has an upward slope due to risk premiums, a downward-sloping yield curve is taken as a strong indication that yields are more likely than not to fall. The prediction of declining interest rates is in turn often interpreted as a signal of a coming recession. Short-term rates exceeded long-term ones in each of the seven recessions since 1970. For this reason, it is not surprising that the slope of the yield curve is one of the key components of the index of leading economic indicators. Figure 15.6 presents a history of yields on 90-day Treasury bills and 10-year Treasury bonds. Yields on the longer-term bonds generally exceed those on the bills, meaning that the yield curve generally slopes upward. Moreover, the exceptions to this rule do seem to precede episodes of falling short rates, which, if anticipated, would induce a downward-sloping yield curve. For example, the figure shows that 1980–1981 were years in which 90-day yields exceeded long-term yields. These years preceded both a drastic drop in the general level of rates and a steep recession. Why might interest rates fall? There are two factors to consider: the real rate and the inflation premium. Recall that the nominal interest rate is composed of the real rate plus a factor to compensate for the effect of inflation: 1 1 Nominal rate 5 (1 1 Real rate)(1 1 Inflation rate) or, approximately, Nominal rate < Real rate 1 Inflation rate Therefore, an expected change in interest rates can be due to changes in either expected real rates or expected inflation rates. Usually, it is important to distinguish between these two possibilities because the economic environments associated with them may vary substantially. High real rates may indicate a rapidly expanding economy, high government budget deficits, and tight monetary policy. Although high inflation rates can arise out of a rapidly expanding economy, inflation also may be caused by rapid expansion of the money supply or supply-side shocks to the economy such as interruptions in oil supplies. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 503 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 504 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 16 10-Year Treasury 90-Day T-Bills Difference Interest Rate (%) 12 8 4 2014 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 −4 1970 0 Figure 15.6 Term spread: Yields on 10-year versus 90-day Treasury securities These factors have very different implications for investments. Even if we conclude from an analysis of the yield curve that rates will fall, we need to analyze the macroeconomic factors that might cause such a decline. 15.6 Forward Rates as Forward Contracts We have seen that forward rates may be derived from the yield curve, using Equation 15.5. In general, forward rates will not equal the eventually realized short rate, or even today’s expectation of what that short rate will be. But there is still an important sense in which the forward rate is a market interest rate. Suppose that you wanted to arrange now to make a loan at some future date. You would agree today on the interest rate that will be charged, but the loan would not commence until some time in the future. How would the interest rate on such a “forward loan” be determined? Perhaps not surprisingly, it would be the forward rate of interest for the period of the loan. Let’s use an example to see how this might work. Example 15.7 Forward Interest Rate Contract Suppose the price of 1-year maturity zero-coupon bonds with face value $1,000 is $952.38 and the price of 2-year zeros with $1,000 face value is $890. The yield to maturity on the 1-year bond is therefore 5%, while that on the 2-year bond is 6%. The forward rate for the second year is thus f2 5 bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 504 (1 1 y2)2 (1 1 y1) 215 1.062 2 1 5 .0701, or 7.01% 1.05 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 505 Now consider the strategy laid out in the following table. In the first column we present data for this example, and in the last column we generalize. We denote by B0(T ) today’s price of a zero-coupon bond with face value $1,000 maturing at time T. Initial Cash Flow Buy a 1-year zero-coupon bond Sell 1.0701 2-year zeros 2952.38 1890 3 1.0701 5 952.38 0 In General 2B0(1) 1B0(2) 3 (1 1 f2) 0 The initial cash flow (at time 0) is zero. You pay $952.38, or in general B0(1), for a zero maturing in 1 year, and you receive $890, or in general B0(2), for each zero you sell maturing in 2 years. By selling 1.0701 of these bonds, you set your initial cash flow to zero.4 At time 1, the 1-year bond matures and you receive $1,000. At time 2, the 2-year maturity zero-coupon bonds that you sold mature, and you have to pay 1.0701 3 $1,000 5 $1,070.10. Your cash flow stream is shown in Figure 15.7, panel A. Notice that you have created a “synthetic” forward loan: You effectively will borrow $1,000 a year from now, and repay $1,070.10 a year later. The rate on this forward loan is therefore 7.01%, precisely equal to the forward rate for the second year. In general, to construct the synthetic forward loan, you sell (1 1 f2) 2-year zeros for every 1-year zero that you buy. This makes your initial cash flow zero because the prices of the 1- and 2-year zeros differ by the factor (1 1 f2); notice that B0(1) 5 $1,000 (1 1 y1) while B0(2) 5 A: Forward Rate = 7.01% $1,000 $1,000 5 2 (1 1 y1)(1 1 f2) (1 1 y2) $1,000 0 1 2 −$1,070.10 B: For a General Forward Rate. The short rates in the two periods are r1 (which is observable today) and r2 (which is not). The rate that can be locked in for a one-period-ahead loan is f2. $1,000 0 r1 1 r2 2 −$1,000(1 + f2) Figure 15.7 Engineering a synthetic forward loan 4 Of course, in reality one cannot sell a fraction of a bond, but you can think of this part of the transaction as follows. If you sold one of these bonds, you would effectively be borrowing $890 for a 2-year period. Selling 1.0701 of these bonds simply means that you are borrowing $890 3 1.0701 5 $952.38. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 505 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 506 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities Therefore, when you sell (1 1 f2) 2-year zeros you generate just enough cash to buy one 1-year zero. Both zeros mature to a face value of $1,000, so the difference between the cash inflow at time 1 and the cash outflow at time 2 is the same factor, 1 1 f2, as illustrated in Figure 15.7, panel B. As a result, f2 is the rate on the forward loan. Obviously, you can construct a synthetic forward loan for periods beyond the second year, and you can construct such loans for multiple periods. Challenge Problems 18 and 19 at the end of the chapter lead you through some of these variants. CONCEPT CHECK 15.9 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Suppose that the price of 3-year zero-coupon bonds is $816.30. What is the forward rate for the third year? How would you construct a synthetic 1-year forward loan that commences at t 5 2 and matures at t 5 3? SUMMARY 1. The term structure of interest rates refers to the interest rates for various terms to maturity embodied in the prices of default-free zero-coupon bonds. 2. In a world of certainty all investments must provide equal total returns for any investment period. Short-term holding-period returns on all bonds would be equal in a risk-free economy, and all equal to the rate available on short-term bonds. Similarly, total returns from rolling over short-term bonds over longer periods would equal the total return available from long-maturity bonds. 3. The forward rate of interest is the break-even future interest rate that would equate the total return from a rollover strategy to that of a longer-term zero-coupon bond. It is defined by the equation (1 1 yn)n(1 1 fn11) 5 (1 1 yn11)n11 where n is a given number of periods from today. This equation can be used to show that yields to maturity and forward rates are related by the equation (1 1 yn)n 5 (1 1 r1)(1 1 f2)(1 1 f3) c(1 1 fn) 4. A common version of the expectations hypothesis holds that forward interest rates are unbiased estimates of expected future interest rates. However, there are good reasons to believe that forward rates differ from expected short rates because of a risk premium known as a liquidity premium. A positive liquidity premium can cause the yield curve to slope upward even if no increase in short rates is anticipated. Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm KEY TERMS bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 506 5. The existence of liquidity premiums makes it extremely difficult to infer expected future interest rates from the yield curve. Such an inference would be made easier if we could assume the liquidity premium remained reasonably stable over time. However, both empirical and theoretical considerations cast doubt on the constancy of that premium. 6. Forward rates are market interest rates in the important sense that commitments to forward (i.e., deferred) borrowing or lending arrangements can be made at these rates. term structure of interest rates yield curve bond stripping bond reconstitution pure yield curve on-the-run yield curve spot rate short rate forward interest rate liquidity premium expectations hypothesis liquidity preference theory 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 Forward rate of interest: 1 1 fn 5 The Term Structure of Interest Rates (1 1 yn)n 507 KEY EQUATIONS (1 1 yn21)n21 Yield to maturity given sequence of forward rates: 1 1 yn 5 [(1 1 r1) (1 1 f2) (1 1 f3) ? ? ? (1 1 fn)]1/n Liquidity premium 5 Forward rate 2 Expected short rate 1. What is the relationship between forward rates and the market’s expectation of future short rates? Explain in the context of both the expectations and liquidity preference theories of the term structure of interest rates. PROBLEM SETS 2. Under the expectations hypothesis, if the yield curve is upward-sloping, the market must expect an increase in short-term interest rates. True/false/uncertain? Why? Basic 3. Under the liquidity preference theory, if inflation is expected to be falling over the next few years, long-term interest rates will be higher than short-term rates. True/false/uncertain? Why? a. Upward sloping. b. Downward sloping. c. Flat. 5. Which of the following is true according to the pure expectations theory? Forward rates: a. Exclusively represent expected future short rates. b. Are biased estimates of market expectations. c. Always overestimate future short rates. 6. Assuming the pure expectations theory is correct, an upward-sloping yield curve implies: a. Interest rates are expected to increase in the future. b. Longer-term bonds are riskier than short-term bonds. c. Interest rates are expected to decline in the future. 7. The following is a list of prices for zero-coupon bonds of various maturities. Calculate the yields to maturity of each bond and the implied sequence of forward rates. Maturity (Years) Price of Bond 1 2 3 4 $943.40 898.47 847.62 792.16 Intermediate Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 4. If the liquidity preference hypothesis is true, what shape should the term structure curve have in a period where interest rates are expected to be constant? 8. Assuming that the expectations hypothesis is valid, compute the expected price path of the 4-year bond in the previous problem as time passes. What is the rate of return of the bond in each year? Show that the expected return equals the forward rate for each year. 9. Consider the following $1,000 par value zero-coupon bonds: Bond Years to Maturity A B C D 1 2 3 4 YTM(%) 5% 6 6.5 7 According to the expectations hypothesis, what is the expected 1-year interest rate 3 years from now? bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 507 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 508 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 10. The term structure for zero-coupon bonds is currently: Maturity (Years) YTM (%) 1 4% 2 5 3 6 Next year at this time, you expect it to be: Maturity (Years) YTM (%) 1 5% 2 6 3 7 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. What do you expect the rate of return to be over the coming year on a 3-year zero-coupon bond? b. Under the expectations theory, what yields to maturity does the market expect to observe on 1- and 2-year zeros at the end of the year? Is the market’s expectation of the return on the 3-year bond greater or less than yours? 11. The yield to maturity on 1-year zero-coupon bonds is currently 7%; the YTM on 2-year zeros is 8%. The Treasury plans to issue a 2-year maturity coupon bond, paying coupons once per year with a coupon rate of 9%. The face value of the bond is $100. a. At what price will the bond sell? b. What will the yield to maturity on the bond be? c. If the expectations theory of the yield curve is correct, what is the market expectation of the price that the bond will sell for next year? d. Recalculate your answer to (c) if you believe in the liquidity preference theory and you believe that the liquidity premium is 1%. 12. Below is a list of prices for zero-coupon bonds of various maturities. Maturity (Years) Price of $1,000 Par Bond (Zero-Coupon) 1 $943.40 2 873.52 3 816.37 a. An 8.5% coupon $1,000 par bond pays an annual coupon and will mature in 3 years. What should the yield to maturity on the bond be? b. If at the end of the first year the yield curve flattens out at 8%, what will be the 1-year holding-period return on the coupon bond? 13. Prices of zero-coupon bonds reveal the following pattern of forward rates: Year 1 2 3 Forward Rate 5% 7 8 In addition to the zero-coupon bond, investors also may purchase a 3-year bond making annual payments of $60 with par value $1,000. a. What is the price of the coupon bond? b. What is the yield to maturity of the coupon bond? c. Under the expectations hypothesis, what is the expected realized compound yield of the coupon bond? d. If you forecast that the yield curve in 1 year will be flat at 7%, what is your forecast for the expected rate of return on the coupon bond for the 1-year holding period? bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 508 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 509 14. You observe the following term structure: Effective Annual YTM 1-year zero-coupon bond 2-year zero-coupon bond 3-year zero-coupon bond 4-year zero-coupon bond 6.1% 6.2 6.3 6.4 a. If you believe that the term structure next year will be the same as today’s, will the 1-year or the 4-year zeros provide a greater expected 1-year return? b. What if you believe in the expectations hypothesis? 16. Suppose that a 1-year zero-coupon bond with face value $100 currently sells at $94.34, while a 2-year zero sells at $84.99. You are considering the purchase of a 2-year-maturity bond making annual coupon payments. The face value of the bond is $100, and the coupon rate is 12% per year. a. What is the yield to maturity of the 2-year zero? The 2-year coupon bond? b. What is the forward rate for the second year? c. If the expectations hypothesis is accepted, what are (1) the expected price of the coupon bond at the end of the first year and (2) the expected holding-period return on the coupon bond over the first year? d. Will the expected rate of return be higher or lower if you accept the liquidity preference hypothesis? 17. The current yield curve for default-free zero-coupon bonds is as follows: Maturity (Years) YTM (%) 1 2 3 10% 11 12 a. What are the implied 1-year forward rates? b. Assume that the pure expectations hypothesis of the term structure is correct. If market expectations are accurate, what will be the pure yield curve (that is, the yields to maturity on 1- and 2-year zero coupon bonds) next year? c. If you purchase a 2-year zero-coupon bond now, what is the expected total rate of return over the next year? What if you purchase a 3-year zero-coupon bond? (Hint: Compute the current and expected future prices.) Ignore taxes. d. What should be the current price of a 3-year maturity bond with a 12% coupon rate paid annually? If you purchased it at that price, what would your total expected rate of return be over the next year (coupon plus price change)? Ignore taxes. Challenge Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 15. The yield to maturity (YTM) on 1-year zero-coupon bonds is 5% and the YTM on 2-year zeros is 6%. The yield to maturity on 2-year-maturity coupon bonds with coupon rates of 12% (paid annually) is 5.8%. What arbitrage opportunity is available for an investment banking firm? What is the profit on the activity? 18. Suppose that the prices of zero-coupon bonds with various maturities are given in the following table. The face value of each bond is $1,000. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 509 Maturity (Years) Price 1 2 3 4 5 $925.93 853.39 782.92 715.00 650.00 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 510 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities a. Calculate the forward rate of interest for each year. b. How could you construct a 1-year forward loan beginning in year 3? Confirm that the rate on that loan equals the forward rate. c. Repeat (b) for a 1-year forward loan beginning in year 4. 19. Continue to use the data in the preceding problem. Suppose that you want to construct a 2-year maturity forward loan commencing in 3 years. a. Suppose that you buy today one 3-year maturity zero-coupon bond. How many 5-year maturity zeros would you have to sell to make your initial cash flow equal to zero? b. What are the cash flows on this strategy in each year? c. What is the effective 2-year interest rate on the effective 3-year-ahead forward loan? d. Confirm that the effective 2-year interest rate equals (1 1 f4) 3 (1 1 f5) 2 1. You therefore can interpret the 2-year loan rate as a 2-year forward rate for the last 2 years. Alternatively, show that the effective 2-year forward rate equals (1 1 y5)5 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm (1 1 y3)3 21 1. Briefly explain why bonds of different maturities have different yields in terms of the expectations and liquidity preference hypotheses. Briefly describe the implications of each hypothesis when the yield curve is (1) upward-sloping and (2) downward-sloping. 2. Which one of the following statements about the term structure of interest rates is true? a. The expectations hypothesis indicates a flat yield curve if anticipated future short-term rates exceed current short-term rates. b. The expectations hypothesis contends that the long-term rate is equal to the anticipated shortterm rate. c. The liquidity premium theory indicates that, all else being equal, longer maturities will have lower yields. d. The liquidity preference theory contends that lenders prefer to buy securities at the short end of the yield curve. 3. The following table shows yields to maturity of zero-coupon Treasury securities. Term to Maturity (Years) 1 2 3 4 5 10 Yield to Maturity (%) 3.50% 4.50 5.00 5.50 6.00 6.60 a. Calculate the forward 1-year rate of interest for year 3. b. Describe the conditions under which the calculated forward rate would be an unbiased estimate of the 1-year spot rate of interest for that year. c. Assume that a few months earlier, the forward 1-year rate of interest for that year had been significantly higher than it is now. What factors could account for the decline in the forward rate? 4. The 6-month Treasury bill spot rate is 4%, and the 1-year Treasury bill spot rate is 5%. What is the implied 6-month forward rate for 6 months from now? 5. The tables below show, respectively, the characteristics of two annual-pay bonds from the same issuer with the same priority in the event of default, and spot interest rates. Neither bond’s price is consistent with the spot rates. Using the information in these tables, recommend either bond A or bond B for purchase. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 510 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 511 Bond Characteristics Coupons Maturity Coupon rate Yield to maturity Price Bond A Bond B Annual 3 years 10% 10.65% 98.40 Annual 3 years 6% 10.75% 88.34 Spot Interest Rates Spot Rates (Zero-Coupon) 1 5% 2 8 3 11 6. Sandra Kapple is a fixed-income portfolio manager who works with large institutional clients. Kapple is meeting with Maria VanHusen, consultant to the Star Hospital Pension Plan, to discuss management of the fund’s approximately $100 million Treasury bond portfolio. The current U.S. Treasury yield curve is given in the following table. VanHusen states, “Given the large differential between 2- and 10-year yields, the portfolio would be expected to experience a higher return over a 10-year horizon by buying 10-year Treasuries, rather than buying 2-year Treasuries and reinvesting the proceeds into 2-year T-bonds at each maturity date.” Maturity Yield Maturity Yield 1 year 2 3 4 5 2.00% 2.90 3.50 3.80 4.00 6 years 7 8 9 10 4.15% 4.30 4.45 4.60 4.70 a. Indicate whether VanHusen’s conclusion is correct, based on the pure expectations hypothesis. b. VanHusen discusses with Kapple alternative theories of the term structure of interest rates and gives her the following information about the U.S. Treasury market: Maturity (years) Liquidity premium (%) 2 .55 3 .55 4 .65 5 .75 6 .90 7 1.10 8 1.20 9 1.50 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Term (Years) 10 1.60 Use this additional information and the liquidity preference theory to determine what the slope of the yield curve implies about the direction of future expected short-term interest rates. 7. A portfolio manager at Superior Trust Company is structuring a fixed-income portfolio to meet the objectives of a client. The portfolio manager compares coupon U.S. Treasuries with zerocoupon stripped U.S. Treasuries and observes a significant yield advantage for the stripped bonds: Term Coupon U.S. Treasuries Zero-Coupon Stripped U.S. Treasuries 3 years 5.50% 5.80% 7 6.75 7.25 10 7.25 7.60 30 7.75 8.20 Briefly discuss why zero-coupon stripped U.S. Treasuries could yield more than coupon U.S. Treasuries with the same final maturity. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 511 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 512 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 8. The shape of the U.S. Treasury yield curve appears to reflect two expected Federal Reserve reductions in the federal funds rate. The current short-term interest rate is 5%. The first reduction of approximately 50 basis points (bp) is expected 6 months from now and the second reduction of approximately 50 bp is expected 1 year from now. The current U.S. Treasury term premiums are 10 bp per year for each of the next 3 years (out through the 3-year benchmark). However, the market also believes that the Federal Reserve reductions will be reversed in a single 100-bp increase in the federal funds rate 2½ years from now. You expect liquidity premiums to remain 10 bp per year for each of the next 3 years (out through the 3-year benchmark). Describe or draw the shape of the Treasury yield curve out through the 3-year benchmark. Which term structure theory supports the shape of the U.S. Treasury yield curve you’ve described? 9. U.S. Treasuries represent a significant holding in many pension portfolios. You decide to analyze the yield curve for U.S. Treasury notes. a. Using the data in the table below, calculate the 5-year spot and forward rates assuming annual compounding. Show your calculations. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm U.S. Treasury Note Yield Curve Data Years to Maturity Par Coupon Yield to Maturity Calculated Spot Rates Calculated Forward Rates 1 2 3 4 5 5.00 5.20 6.00 7.00 7.00 5.00 5.21 6.05 7.16 ? 5.00 5.42 7.75 10.56 ? b. Define and describe each of the following three concepts: i. Short rate ii. Spot rate iii. Forward rate Explain how these concepts are related. c. You are considering the purchase of a zero-coupon U.S. Treasury note with 4 years to maturity. On the basis of the above yield-curve analysis, calculate both the expected yield to maturity and the price for the security. Show your calculations. 10. The spot rates of interest for five U.S. Treasury securities are shown in the following exhibit. Assume all securities pay interest annually. Spot Rates of Interest Term to Maturity Spot Rate of Interest 1 year 2 3 4 5 13.00% 12.00 11.00 10.00 9.00 a. Compute the 2-year implied forward rate for a deferred loan beginning in 3 years. b. Compute the price of a 5-year annual-pay Treasury security with a coupon rate of 9% by using the information in the exhibit. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 512 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 513 E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES Go to www.smartmoney.com. Access the Living Yield Curve (look for the Economy and Bonds tab), a moving picture of the yield curve. Is the yield curve usually upward- or downward-sloping? What about today’s yield curve? How much does the slope of the curve vary? Which varies more: short-term or long-term rates? Can you explain why this might be the case? SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. The price of the 3-year bond paying a $40 coupon is At this price, the yield to maturity is 6.945% [n 5 3; PV 5 (2)922.65; FV 5 1,000; PMT 5 40]. This bond’s yield to maturity is closer to that of the 3-year zero-coupon bond than is the yield to maturity of the 10% coupon bond in Example 15.1. This makes sense: This bond’s coupon rate is lower than that of the bond in Example 15.1. A greater fraction of its value is tied up in the final payment in the third year, and so it is not surprising that its yield is closer to that of a pure 3-year zero-coupon security. 2. We compare two investment strategies in a manner similar to Example 15.2: Buy and hold 4-year zero 5 Buy 3-year zero; roll proceeds into 1-year bond (1 1 y4 )4 5 (1 1 y3 )3 3 (1 1 r4 ) 1.084 5 1.073 3 (1 1 r4 ) which implies that r4 5 1.084/1.073 2 1 5 .11056 5 11.056%. Now we confirm that the yield on the 4-year zero is a geometric average of the discount factors for the next 3 years: 1 1 y4 5 3(1 1 r1 ) 3 (1 1 r2 ) 3 (1 1 r3 ) 3 (1 1 r4 ) 4 1/4 1.08 5 3 1.05 3 1.0701 3 1.09025 3 1.11056 4 1/4 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 40 40 1040 1 1 5 38.095 1 35.600 1 848.950 5 $922.65 2 1.05 1.06 1.073 3. The 3-year bond can be bought today for $1,000/1.073 5 $816.30. Next year, it will have a remaining maturity of 2 years. The short rate in year 2 will be 7.01% and the short rate in year 3 will be 9.025%. Therefore, the bond’s yield to maturity next year will be related to these short rates according to (1 1 y2 )2 5 1.0701 3 1.09025 5 1.1667 and its price next year will be $1,000/(1 1 y2)2 5 $1,000/1.1667 5 $857.12. The 1-year holdingperiod rate of return is therefore ($857.12 2 $816.30)/$816.30 5 .05, or 5%. 4. The n-period spot rate is the yield to maturity on a zero-coupon bond with a maturity of n periods. The short rate for period n is the one-period interest rate that will prevail in period n. Finally, the forward rate for period n is the short rate that would satisfy a “break-even condition” equating the total returns on two n-period investment strategies. The first strategy is an investment in an n-period zero-coupon bond; the second is an investment in an n 2 1 period zero-coupon bond “rolled over” into an investment in a one-period zero. Spot rates and forward rates are observable today, but because interest rates evolve with uncertainty, future short rates are not. In the special case in which there is no uncertainty in future interest rates, the forward rate calculated from the yield curve would equal the short rate that will prevail in that period. 5. 7% 2 1% 5 6%. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 513 7/17/13 4:03 PM Final PDF to printer 514 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 6. The risk premium will be zero. 7. If issuers prefer to issue long-term bonds, they will be willing to accept higher expected interest costs on long bonds over short bonds. This willingness combines with investors’ demands for higher rates on long-term bonds to reinforce the tendency toward a positive liquidity premium. 8. In general, from Equation 15.5, (1 1 yn)n 5 (1 1 yn21)n21 3 (1 1 fn). In this case, (1 1 y4 )4 5 (1.07)3 3 (1 1 f4 ). If f4 5 .07, then (1 1 y4 )4 5 (1.07)4 and y4 5 .07. If f4 is greater than .07, then y4 also will be greater, and conversely if f4 is less than .07, then y4 will be as well. 1,000 1/3 b 2 1 5 .07 5 7.0% 816.30 The forward rate for the third year is therefore 9. The 3-year yield to maturity is a f3 5 (1 1 y3 )3 (1 1 y2 )2 215 1.073 2 1 5 .0903 5 9.03% 1.062 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm (Alternatively, note that the ratio of the price of the 2-year zero to the price of the 3-year zero is 1 1 f3 5 1.0903.) To construct the synthetic loan, buy one 2-year maturity zero, and sell 1.0903 3-year maturity zeros. Your initial cash flow is zero, your cash flow at time 2 is 1$1,000, and your cash flow at time 3 is 2$1,090.30, which corresponds to the cash flows on a 1-year forward loan commencing at time 2 with an interest rate of 9.03%. bod61671_ch15_487-514.indd 514 7/17/13 4:03 PM 18 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER EIGHTEEN Equity Valuation Models AS OUR DISCUSSION of market efficiency indicated, finding undervalued securities is hardly easy. At the same time, there are enough chinks in the armor of the efficient market hypothesis that the search for such securities should not be dismissed out of hand. Moreover, it is the ongoing search for mispriced securities that maintains a nearly efficient market. Even minor mispricing would allow a stock market analyst to earn his salary. This chapter describes the valuation models that stock market analysts use to uncover mispriced securities. The models presented are those used by fundamental analysts, those analysts who use information concerning the current and prospective profitability of a company to assess its fair market value. We start with a discussion of alternative measures of the value of a company. From there, we progress to quantitative tools called dividend discount models, which security analysts commonly use to measure the value of a firm as an ongoing concern. Next we turn to price–earnings, or P/E, ratios, explaining why they are of such interest to analysts but also highlighting some of their shortcomings. We explain how P/E ratios are tied to dividend valuation models and, more generally, to the growth prospects of the firm. We close the chapter with a discussion and extended example of free cash flow models used by analysts to value firms based on forecasts of the cash flows that will be generated from the firms’ business endeavors. Finally, we apply the several valuation tools covered in the chapter to a real firm and find some disparity in their conclusions—a conundrum that will confront any security analyst—and consider reasons for these discrepancies. The purpose of fundamental analysis is to identify stocks that are mispriced relative to some measure of “true” value that can be derived from observable financial data. There are many convenient sources of relevant data. For U.S. companies, the Securities and Exchange Commission provides information at its EDGAR Web site, www.sec.gov/edgar.shtml. The SEC requires all public companies (except foreign companies and companies with less than $10 million in assets and 500 shareholders) to file registration statements, periodic reports, and other forms electronically through EDGAR. Anyone can access and download this information. Many Web sites such bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 591 PART V 18.1 Valuation by Comparables 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 592 PART V Security Analysis as finance.yahoo.com, money.msn.com, or finance.google.com also provide analysis and data derived from the EDGAR reports. Table 18.1 shows some financial highlights for Microsoft as well as some comparable data for other firms in the software applications industry. The price per share of Microsoft’s common stock is $30.63, and the total market value or capitalization of those shares (called market cap for short) is $258 billion. Under the heading “Valuation,” Table 18.1 shows the ratio of Microsoft’s stock price to five benchmarks. Its share price is 15.4 times its (per share) earnings in the most recent 12 months, 3.9 times its recent book value, 3.5 times its sales, and 10.9 times its cash flow. The last valuation ratio, PEG, is the P/E ratio divided by the growth rate of earnings. We would expect more rapidly growing firms to sell at higher multiples of current earnings (more on this below), so PEG normalizes the P/E ratio by the growth rate. These valuation ratios are commonly used to assess the valuation of one firm compared to others in the same industry, and we will consider all of them. The column to the right gives comparable ratios for other firms in the software applications industry. For example, an analyst might note that Microsoft’s price/earnings ratio and price/CF ratio are both below the industry average. Microsoft’s ratio of market value to book value, the net worth of the company as reported on the balance sheet, is also below industry norms, 3.9 versus 10.5. These ratios might indicate that its stock is underpriced. However, Microsoft is a more mature firm than many in the industry, and perhaps this discrepancy reflects a lower expected future growth rate. In fact, its PEG ratio is nearly identical to the industry average. Clearly, rigorous valuation models will be necessary to sort through these sometimes conflicting signals of value. Limitations of Book Value Shareholders in a firm are sometimes called “residual claimants,” which means that the value of their stake is what is left over when the liabilities of the firm are subtracted from Table 18.1 Financial highlights for Microsoft Corporation, September 12, 2012 Price per share Common shares outstanding (billion) Market capitalization ($ billion) Latest 12 Months Sales ($ billion) EBITDA ($ billion) Net income ($ billion) Earnings per share Valuation Price/Earnings Price/Book Price/Sales Price/Cash flow PEG Profitability ROE (%) ROA (%) Operating profit margin (%) Net profit margin (%) $ 30.63 8.38 $258 $ 73.72 $ 30.71 $ 16.98 $ 2.00 Microsoft 15.4 3.9 3.5 10.9 1.1 27.5 15.0 37.9 23.0 Industry Avg 17.5 10.5 20.5 1.2 24.9 23.2 Source: Compiled from data available at finance.yahoo.com, September 12, 2012. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 592 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 593 its assets. Shareholders’ equity is this net worth. However, the values of both assets and liabilities recognized in financial statements are based on historical—not current—values. For example, the book value of an asset equals the original cost of acquisition less some adjustment for depreciation, even if the market price of that asset has changed over time. Moreover, depreciation allowances are used to allocate the original cost of the asset over several years, but do not reflect loss of actual value. Whereas book values are based on original cost, market values measure current values of assets and liabilities. The market value of the shareholders’ equity investment equals the difference between the current values of all assets and liabilities. We’ve emphasized that current values generally will not match historical ones. Equally or even more important, many assets, such as the value of a good brand name or specialized expertise developed over many years, may not even be included on the financial statements. Market prices therefore reflect the value of the firm as a going concern. It would be unusual if the market price of a stock were exactly equal to its book value. Can book value represent a “floor” for the stock’s price, below which level the market price can never fall? Although Microsoft’s book value per share in 2012 was less than its market price, other evidence disproves this notion. While it is not common, there are always some firms selling at a market price below book value. In 2012, for example, such troubled firms included Sprint/Nextel, Bank of America, Mitsubishi, and AOL. A better measure of a floor for the stock price is the firm’s liquidation value per share. This represents the amount of money that could be realized by breaking up the firm, selling its assets, repaying its debt, and distributing the remainder to the shareholders. If the market price of equity drops below liquidation value, the firm becomes attractive as a takeover target. A corporate raider would find it profitable to buy enough shares to gain control and then actually to liquidate. Another measure of firm value is the replacement cost of assets less liabilities. Some analysts believe the market value of the firm cannot remain for long too far above its replacement cost because if it did, competitors would enter the market. The resulting competitive pressure would drive down the market value of all firms until they fell to replacement cost. This idea is popular among economists, and the ratio of market price to replacement cost is known as Tobin’s q, after the Nobel Prize–winning economist James Tobin. In the long run, according to this view, the ratio of market price to replacement cost will tend toward 1, but the evidence is that this ratio can differ significantly from 1 for very long periods. Although focusing on the balance sheet can give some useful information about a firm’s liquidation value or its replacement cost, the analyst must usually turn to expected future cash flows for a better estimate of the firm’s value as a going concern. We therefore turn to the quantitative models that analysts use to value common stock based on forecasts of future earnings and dividends. 18.2 Intrinsic Value versus Market Price The most popular model for assessing the value of a firm as a going concern starts from the observation that an investor in stock expects a return consisting of cash dividends and capital gains or losses. We begin by assuming a 1-year holding period and supposing that ABC stock has an expected dividend per share, E(D1), of $4; the current price of a share, P0, is $48; and the expected price at the end of a year, E(P1), is $52. For now, don’t worry about how you derive your forecast of next year’s price. At this point we ask only whether the stock seems attractively priced today given your forecast of next year’s price. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 593 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 594 PART V Security Analysis The expected holding-period return is E(D1) plus the expected price appreciation, E(P1) 2 P0, all divided by the current price, P0: E(D1) 1 3 E(P1) 2 P0 4 P0 4 1 (52 2 48) 5 5 .167, or 16.7% 48 Expected HPR 5 E(r) 5 Thus, the stock’s expected holding-period return is the sum of the expected dividend yield, E(D1)/P0, and the expected rate of price appreciation, the capital gains yield, [E(P1) 2 P0]/P0. But what is the required rate of return for ABC stock? The CAPM states that when stock market prices are at equilibrium levels, the rate of return that investors can expect to earn on a security is rf 1 b[E(rM) 2 rf ]. Thus, the CAPM may be viewed as providing an estimate of the rate of return an investor can reasonably expect to earn on a security given its risk as measured by beta. This is the return that investors will require of any other investment with equivalent risk. We will denote this required rate of return as k. If a stock is priced “correctly,” it will offer investors a “fair” return, that is, its expected return will equal its required return. Of course, the goal of a security analyst is to find stocks that are mispriced. For example, an underpriced stock will provide an expected return greater than the required return. Suppose that rf 5 6%, E(rM) 2 rf 5 5%, and the beta of ABC is 1.2. Then the value of k is k 5 6% 1 1.2 3 5% 5 12% The expected holding-period return, 16.7%, therefore exceeds the required rate of return based on ABC’s risk by a margin of 4.7%. Naturally, the investor will want to include more of ABC stock in the portfolio than a passive strategy would indicate. Another way to see this is to compare the intrinsic value of a share of stock to its market price. The intrinsic value, denoted V0, is defined as the present value of all cash payments to the investor in the stock, including dividends as well as the proceeds from the ultimate sale of the stock, discounted at the appropriate risk-adjusted interest rate, k. If the intrinsic value, or the investor’s own estimate of what the stock is really worth, exceeds the market price, the stock is considered undervalued and a good investment. For ABC, using a 1-year investment horizon and a forecast that the stock can be sold at the end of the year at price P1 5 $52, the intrinsic value is V0 5 E (D1) 1 E (P1) $4 1 $52 5 5 $50 11k 1.12 Equivalently, at a price of $50, the investor would derive a 12% rate of return—just equal to the required rate of return—on an investment in the stock. However, at the current price of $48, the stock is underpriced compared to intrinsic value. At this price, it provides better than a fair rate of return relative to its risk. Using the terminology of the CAPM, it is a positive-alpha stock, and investors will want to buy more of it than they would following a passive strategy. If the intrinsic value turns out to be lower than the current market price, investors should buy less of it than under the passive strategy. It might even pay to go short on ABC stock, as we discussed in Chapter 3. In market equilibrium, the current market price will reflect the intrinsic value estimates of all market participants. This means the individual investor whose V0 estimate differs bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 594 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 595 from the market price, P0, in effect must disagree with some or all of the market consensus estimates of E(D1), E(P1), or k. A common term for the market consensus value of the required rate of return, k, is the market capitalization rate, which we use often throughout this chapter. CONCEPT CHECK 18.1 You expect the price of IBX stock to be $59.77 per share a year from now. Its current market price is $50, and you expect it to pay a dividend 1 year from now of $2.15 per share. a. What are the stock’s expected dividend yield, rate of price appreciation, and holding-period return? b. If the stock has a beta of 1.15, the risk-free rate is 6% per year, and the expected rate of return on the market portfolio is 14% per year, what is the required rate of return on IBX stock? c. What is the intrinsic value of IBX stock, and how does it compare to the current market price? 18.3 Dividend Discount Models Consider an investor who buys a share of Steady State Electronics stock, planning to hold it for 1 year. The intrinsic value of the share is the present value of the dividend to be received at the end of the first year, D1, and the expected sales price, P1. We will henceforth use the simpler notation P1 instead of E(P1) to avoid clutter. Keep in mind, though, that future prices and dividends are unknown, and we are dealing with expected values, not certain values. We’ve already established V0 5 D1 1 P1 11k (18.1) Although this year’s dividends are fairly predictable given a company’s history, you might ask how we can estimate P1, the year-end price. According to Equation 18.1, V1 (the year-end intrinsic value) will be V1 5 D2 1 P2 11k If we assume the stock will be selling for its intrinsic value next year, then V1 5 P1, and we can substitute this value for P1 into Equation 18.1 to find V0 5 D1 D2 1 P2 1 (1 1 k)2 11k This equation may be interpreted as the present value of dividends plus sales price for a 2-year holding period. Of course, now we need to come up with a forecast of P2. Continuing in the same way, we can replace P2 by (D3 1 P3)/(1 1 k), which relates P0 to the value of dividends plus the expected sales price for a 3-year holding period. More generally, for a holding period of H years, we can write the stock value as the present value of dividends over the H years, plus the ultimate sale price, PH: V0 5 bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 595 D1 D2 DH 1 PH 1 1 c1 2 (1 1 k)H (1 1 k) 11k (18.2) 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 596 PART V Security Analysis Note the similarity between this formula and the bond valuation formula developed in Chapter 14. Each relates price to the present value of a stream of payments (coupons in the case of bonds, dividends in the case of stocks) and a final payment (the face value of the bond, or the sales price of the stock). The key differences in the case of stocks are the uncertainty of dividends, the lack of a fixed maturity date, and the unknown sales price at the horizon date. Indeed, one can continue to substitute for price indefinitely, to conclude V0 5 D3 D1 D2 1 1 1c 2 ( ) ( 11k 11k 1 1 k)3 (18.3) Equation 18.3 states that the stock price should equal the present value of all expected future dividends into perpetuity. This formula is called the dividend discount model (DDM) of stock prices. It is tempting, but incorrect, to conclude from Equation 18.3 that the DDM focuses exclusively on dividends and ignores capital gains as a motive for investing in stock. Indeed, we assume explicitly in Equation 18.1 that capital gains (as reflected in the expected sales price, P1) are part of the stock’s value. Our point is that the price at which you can sell a stock in the future depends on dividend forecasts at that time. The reason only dividends appear in Equation 18.3 is not that investors ignore capital gains. It is instead that those capital gains will reflect dividend forecasts at the time the stock is sold. That is why in Equation 18.2 we can write the stock price as the present value of dividends plus sales price for any horizon date. PH is the present value at time H of all dividends expected to be paid after the horizon date. That value is then discounted back to today, time 0. The DDM asserts that stock prices are determined ultimately by the cash flows accruing to stockholders, and those are dividends.1 The Constant-Growth DDM Equation 18.3 as it stands is still not very useful in valuing a stock because it requires dividend forecasts for every year into the indefinite future. To make the DDM practical, we need to introduce some simplifying assumptions. A useful and common first pass at the problem is to assume that dividends are trending upward at a stable growth rate that we will call g. For example, if g 5 .05, and the most recently paid dividend was D0 5 3.81, expected future dividends are D1 5 D0(1 1 g) 5 3.81 3 1.05 5 4.00 D2 5 D0(1 1 g)2 5 3.81 3 (1.05)2 5 4.20 D3 5 D0(1 1 g)3 5 3.81 3 (1.05)3 5 4.41 and so on. Using these dividend forecasts in Equation 18.3, we solve for intrinsic value as V0 5 D0 (1 1 g)2 D0 (1 1 g) D0 (1 1 g)3 c 1 1 1 2 (1 1 k) (1 1 k)3 11k 1 If investors never expected a dividend to be paid, then this model implies that the stock would have no value. To reconcile the DDM with the fact that non-dividend-paying stocks do have a market value, one must assume that investors expect that some day it may pay out some cash, even if only a liquidating dividend. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 596 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 597 This equation can be simplified to2 V0 5 D0(1 1 g) D1 5 k2g k2g (18.4) Note in Equation 18.4 that we divide D1 (not D0) by k 2 g to calculate intrinsic value. If the market capitalization rate for Steady State is 12%, we can use Equation 18.4 to show that the intrinsic value of a share of Steady State stock is $3.81(1 1 .05) $4.00 5 5 $57.14 .12 2 .05 .12 2 .05 Equation 18.4 is called the constant-growth DDM, or the Gordon model, after Myron J. Gordon, who popularized the model. It should remind you of the formula for the present value of a perpetuity. If dividends were expected not to grow, then the dividend stream would be a simple perpetuity, and the valuation formula would be3 V0 5 D1/k. Equation 18.4 is a generalization of the perpetuity formula to cover the case of a growing perpetuity. As g increases (for a given value of D1), the stock price also rises. Example 18.1 Preferred Stock and the DDM Preferred stock that pays a fixed dividend can be valued using the constant-growth dividend discount model. The constant-growth rate of dividends is simply zero. For example, to value a preferred stock paying a fixed dividend of $2 per share when the discount rate is 8%, we compute V0 5 $2 5 $25 .08 2 0 D1 We prove that the intrinsic value, V0, of a stream of cash dividends growing at a constant rate g is equal to k2g as follows. By definition, 2 V0 5 D1(1 1 g) D1(1 1 g)2 D1 1 1 1c 2 11k (1 1 k ) (1 1 k )3 (a) Multiplying through by (1 1 k)/(1 1 g), we obtain D1(1 1 g) D1 D1 (1 1 k ) V 5 1c 1 1 (1 1 g ) 0 (1 1 g ) (1 1 k ) (1 1 k )2 (b) Subtracting equation (a) from equation (b), we find that D1 11k V 2 V0 5 (1 1 g ) 11g 0 which implies (k 2 g)V0 D1 5 (1 1 g ) (1 1 g ) D1 V0 5 k2g 3 Recall from introductory finance that the present value of a $1 per year perpetuity is 1/k. For example, if k 5 10%, the value of the perpetuity is $1/.10 5 $10. Notice that if g 5 0 in Equation 18.4, the constant-growth DDM formula is the same as the perpetuity formula. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 597 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 598 PART V Security Analysis Example 18.2 The Constant-Growth DDM High Flyer Industries has just paid its annual dividend of $3 per share. The dividend is expected to grow at a constant rate of 8% indefinitely. The beta of High Flyer stock is 1.0, the risk-free rate is 6%, and the market risk premium is 8%. What is the intrinsic value of the stock? What would be your estimate of intrinsic value if you believed that the stock was riskier, with a beta of 1.25? Because a $3 dividend has just been paid and the growth rate of dividends is 8%, the forecast for the year-end dividend is $3 3 1.08 5 $3.24. The market capitalization rate (using the CAPM) is 6% 1 1.0 3 8% 5 14%. Therefore, the value of the stock is V0 5 D1 $3.24 5 5 $54 k2g .14 2 .08 If the stock is perceived to be riskier, its value must be lower. At the higher beta, the market capitalization rate is 6% 1 1.25 3 8% 5 16%, and the stock is worth only $3.24 5 $40.50 .16 2 .08 The constant-growth DDM is valid only when g is less than k. If dividends were expected to grow forever at a rate faster than k, the value of the stock would be infinite. If an analyst derives an estimate of g greater than k, that growth rate must be unsustainable in the long run. The appropriate valuation model to use in this case is a multistage DDM such as those discussed below. The constant-growth DDM is so widely used by stock market analysts that it is worth exploring some of its implications and limitations. The constant-growth rate DDM implies that a stock’s value will be greater: 1. The larger its expected dividend per share. 2. The lower the market capitalization rate, k. 3. The higher the expected growth rate of dividends. Another implication of the constant-growth model is that the stock price is expected to grow at the same rate as dividends. To see this, suppose Steady State stock is selling at its intrinsic value of $57.14, so that V0 5 P0. Then D1 P0 5 k2g Note that price is proportional to dividends. Therefore, next year, when the dividends paid to Steady State stockholders are expected to be higher by g 5 5%, price also should increase by 5%. To confirm this, note D2 5 $4(1.05) 5 $4.20 D2 $4.20 P1 5 5 5 $60.00 k2g .12 2 .05 which is 5% higher than the current price of $57.14. To generalize, P1 5 D1(1 1 g) D2 D1 (1 1 g) 5 P0(1 1 g) 5 5 k2g k2g k2g Therefore, the DDM implies that in the case of constant growth of dividends, the rate of price appreciation in any year will equal that constant-growth rate, g. For a stock bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 598 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 599 whose market price equals its intrinsic value (V0 5 P0), the expected holding-period return will be E(r) 5 Dividend yield 1 Capital gains yield P1 2 P0 D1 D1 5 1 5 1g (18.5) P0 P0 P0 This formula offers a means to infer the market capitalization rate of a stock, for if the stock is selling at its intrinsic value, then E(r) 5 k, implying that k 5 D1/P0 1 g. By observing the dividend yield, D1/P0, and estimating the growth rate of dividends, we can compute k. This equation is also known as the discounted cash flow (DCF) formula. This approach is often used in rate hearings for regulated public utilities. The regulatory agency responsible for approving utility pricing decisions is mandated to allow the firms to charge just enough to cover costs plus a “fair” profit, that is, one that allows a competitive return on the investment the firm has made in its productive capacity. In turn, that return is taken to be the expected return investors require on the stock of the firm. The D1/P0 1 g formula provides a means to infer that required return. Example 18.3 The Constant-Growth Model Suppose that Steady State Electronics wins a major contract for its new computer chip. The very profitable contract will enable it to increase the growth rate of dividends from 5% to 6% without reducing the current dividend from the projected value of $4.00 per share. What will happen to the stock price? What will happen to future expected rates of return on the stock? The stock price ought to increase in response to the good news about the contract, and indeed it does. The stock price jumps from its original value of $57.14 to a postannouncement price of D1 $4.00 5 5 $66.67 k2g .12 2 .06 Investors who are holding the stock when the good news about the contract is announced will receive a substantial windfall. On the other hand, at the new price the expected rate of return on the stock is 12%, just as it was before the new contract was announced. E(r) 5 D1 $4.00 1g5 1 .06 5 .12, or 12% P0 $66.67 This result makes sense. Once the news about the contract is reflected in the stock price, the expected rate of return will be consistent with the risk of the stock. Because the risk of the stock has not changed, neither should the expected rate of return. CONCEPT CHECK 18.2 a. IBX’s stock dividend at the end of this year is expected to be $2.15, and it is expected to grow at 11.2% per year forever. If the required rate of return on IBX stock is 15.2% per year, what is its intrinsic value? b. If IBX’s current market price is equal to this intrinsic value, what is next year’s expected price? c. If an investor were to buy IBX stock now and sell it after receiving the $2.15 dividend a year from now, what is the expected capital gain (i.e., price appreciation) in percentage terms? What are the dividend yield and the holding-period return? bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 599 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 600 PART V Security Analysis Convergence of Price to Intrinsic Value Now suppose that the current market price of ABC stock is only $48 per share and, therefore, that the stock is undervalued by $2 per share. In this case the expected rate of price appreciation depends on an additional assumption about whether the discrepancy between the intrinsic value and the market price will disappear, and if so, when. One fairly common assumption is that the discrepancy will never disappear and that the market price will trend upward at rate g forever. This implies that the discrepancy between intrinsic value and market price also will grow at the same rate. In our example: Now Next Year V0 5 $50 P0 5 $48 V0 2 P0 5 $2 V1 5 $50 3 1.04 5 $52 P1 5 $48 3 1.04 5 $49.92 V1 2 P1 5 $2 3 1.04 5 $2.08 Under this assumption the expected HPR will exceed the required rate, because the dividend yield is higher than it would be if P0 were equal to V0. In our example the dividend yield would be 8.33% instead of 8%, so that the expected HPR would be 12.33% rather than 12%: D1 $4 E(r) 5 1g5 1 .04 5 .0833 1 .04 5 .1233 P0 $48 An investor who identifies this undervalued stock can get an expected dividend that exceeds the required yield by 33 basis points. This excess return is earned each year, and the market price never catches up to intrinsic value. An alternative assumption is that the gap between market price and intrinsic value will disappear by the end of the year. In that case we would have P1 5 V1 5 $52, and P1 2 P0 D1 4 52 2 48 E(r) 5 1 5 1 5 .0833 1 .0833 5 .1667 P0 P0 48 48 The assumption of complete catch-up to intrinsic value produces a much larger 1-year HPR. In future years, however, the stock is expected to generate only fair rates of return. Many stock analysts assume that a stock’s price will approach its intrinsic value gradually over time—for example, over a 5-year period. This puts their expected 1-year HPR somewhere between the bounds of 12.33% and 16.67%. Stock Prices and Investment Opportunities Consider two companies, Cash Cow, Inc., and Growth Prospects, each with expected earnings in the coming year of $5 per share. Both companies could in principle pay out all of these earnings as dividends, maintaining a perpetual dividend flow of $5 per share. If the market capitalization rate were k 5 12.5%, both companies would then be valued at D1/k 5 $5/.125 5 $40 per share. Neither firm would grow in value, because with all earnings paid out as dividends, and no earnings reinvested in the firm, both companies’ capital stock and earnings capacity would remain unchanged over time; earnings4 and dividends would not grow. 4 Actually, we are referring here to earnings net of the funds necessary to maintain the productivity of the firm’s capital, that is, earnings net of “economic depreciation.” In other words, the earnings figure should be interpreted as the maximum amount of money the firm could pay out each year in perpetuity without depleting its productive capacity. For this reason, the net earnings number may be quite different from the accounting earnings figure that the firm reports in its financial statements. We explore this further in the next chapter. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 600 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 601 Dividends per Share ($) Now suppose one of the firms, Growth Prospects, 12 engages in projects that generate a return on investment of 15%, which is greater than the required rate 10 of return, k 5 12.5%. It would be foolish for such a High Reinvestment 8 company to pay out all of its earnings as dividends. 6 If Growth Prospects retains or plows back some of its earnings into its profitable projects, it can earn a Low Reinvestment 4 15% rate of return for its shareholders, whereas if 2 it pays out all earnings as dividends, it forgoes the 0 projects, leaving shareholders to invest the dividends 0 10 20 30 in other opportunities at a fair market rate of only Year 12.5%. Suppose, therefore, that Growth Prospects chooses a lower dividend payout ratio (the fraction Figure 18.1 Dividend growth for two earnings of earnings paid out as dividends), reducing payout reinvestment policies from 100% to 40%, maintaining a plowback ratio (the fraction of earnings reinvested in the firm) at 60%. The plowback ratio is also referred to as the earnings retention ratio. The dividend of the company, therefore, will be $2 (40% of $5 earnings) instead of $5. Will share price fall? No—it will rise! Although dividends initially fall under the earnings reinvestment policy, subsequent growth in the assets of the firm because of reinvested profits will generate growth in future dividends, which will be reflected in today’s share price. Figure 18.1 illustrates the dividend streams generated by Growth Prospects under two dividend policies. A low-reinvestment-rate plan allows the firm to pay higher initial dividends, but results in a lower dividend growth rate. Eventually, a high-reinvestment-rate plan will provide higher dividends. If the dividend growth generated by the reinvested earnings is high enough, the stock will be worth more under the high-reinvestment strategy. How much growth will be generated? Suppose Growth Prospects starts with plant and equipment of $100 million and is all equity financed. With a return on investment or equity (ROE) of 15%, total earnings are ROE 3 $100 million 5 .15 3 $100 million 5 $15 million. There are 3 million shares of stock outstanding, so earnings per share are $5, as posited above. If 60% of the $15 million in this year’s earnings is reinvested, then the value of the firm’s assets will increase by .60 3 $15 million 5 $9 million, or by 9%. The percentage increase in assets is the rate at which income was generated (ROE) times the plowback ratio (the fraction of earnings reinvested in the firm), which we will denote as b. Now endowed with 9% more assets, the company earns 9% more income, and pays out 9% higher dividends. The growth rate of the dividends, therefore, is5 g 5 ROE 3 b 5 .15 3 .60 5 .09 If the stock price equals its intrinsic value, it should sell at P0 5 D1 $2 5 5 $57.14 k2g .125 2 .09 5 We can derive this relationship more generally by noting that with a fixed ROE, earnings (which equal ROE 3 book value) will grow at the same rate as the book value of the firm. Abstracting from issuance of new shares of stock, the growth rate of book value equals reinvested earnings/book value. Therefore, g5 bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 601 Reinvested earnings Book value 5 Reinvested earnings Total earnings 3 Total earnings Book value 5 b 3 ROE 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 602 PART V Security Analysis When Growth Prospects pursued a no-growth policy and paid out all earnings as dividends, the stock price was only $40. Therefore, you can think of $40 as the value per share of the assets the company already has in place. When Growth Prospects decided to reduce current dividends and reinvest some of its earnings in new investments, its stock price increased. The increase in the stock price reflects the fact that the planned investments provide an expected rate of return greater than the required rate. In other words, the investment opportunities have positive net present value. The value of the firm rises by the NPV of these investment opportunities. This net present value is also called the present value of growth opportunities, or PVGO. Therefore, we can think of the value of the firm as the sum of the value of assets already in place, or the no-growth value of the firm, plus the net present value of the future investments the firm will make, which is the PVGO. For Growth Prospects, PVGO 5 $17.14 per share: Price 5 No-growth value per share 1 PVGO E1 P0 5 1 PVGO k 57.14 5 40 1 17.14 (18.6) We know that in reality, dividend cuts almost always are accompanied by steep drops in stock prices. Does this contradict our analysis? Not necessarily: Dividend cuts are usually taken as bad news about the future prospects of the firm, and it is the new information about the firm—not the reduced dividend yield per se—that is responsible for the stock price decline. For example, when J.P. Morgan cut its quarterly dividend from 38 cents to 5 cents a share in 2009, its stock price actually increased by about 5%. The company was able to convince investors that the cut would conserve cash and prepare the firm to weather a severe recession. When investors were convinced that the dividend cut made sense, the stock price actually increased. Similarly, when BP announced in the wake of the massive 2010 Gulf oil spill that it would suspend dividends for the rest of the year, its stock price did not budge. The cut already had been widely anticipated, so it was not new information. These examples show that stock price declines in response to dividend cuts are really a response to the information conveyed by the cut. It is important to recognize that growth per se is not what investors desire. Growth enhances company value only if it is achieved by investment in projects with attractive profit opportunities (i.e., with ROE . k). To see why, let’s now consider Growth Prospects’s unfortunate sister company, Cash Cow, Inc. Cash Cow’s ROE is only 12.5%, just equal to the required rate of return, k. The net present value of its investment opportunities is zero. We’ve seen that following a zero-growth strategy with b 5 0 and g 5 0, the value of Cash Cow will be E1 / k 5 $5/.125 5 $40 per share. Now suppose Cash Cow chooses a plowback ratio of b 5 .60, the same as Growth Prospects’s plowback. Then g would increase to g 5 ROE 3 b 5 .125 3 .60 5 .075 but the stock price is still $40: P0 5 D1 $2 5 5 $40 k2g .125 2 .075 which is no different from the no-growth strategy. In the case of Cash Cow, the dividend reduction used to free funds for reinvestment in the firm generates only enough growth to maintain the stock price at the current level. This is as it should be: If the firm’s projects yield only what investors can bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 602 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 603 earn on their own, shareholders cannot be made better off by a high-reinvestment-rate policy. This demonstrates that “growth” is not the same as growth opportunities. To justify reinvestment, the firm must engage in projects with better prospective returns than those shareholders can find elsewhere. Notice also that the PVGO of Cash Cow is zero: PVGO 5 P0 2 E1/k 5 40 2 40 5 0. With ROE 5 k, there is no advantage to plowing funds back into the firm; this shows up as PVGO of zero. In fact, this is why firms with considerable cash flow but limited investment prospects are called “cash cows.” The cash these firms generate is best taken out of, or “milked from,” the firm. Example 18.4 Growth Opportunities Takeover Target is run by entrenched management that insists on reinvesting 60% of its earnings in projects that provide an ROE of 10%, despite the fact that the firm’s capitalization rate is k 5 15%. The firm’s year-end dividend will be $2 per share, paid out of earnings of $5 per share. At what price will the stock sell? What is the present value of growth opportunities? Why would such a firm be a takeover target for another firm? Given current management’s investment policy, the dividend growth rate will be g 5 ROE 3 b 5 10% 3 .60 5 6% and the stock price should be P0 5 $2 5 $22.22 .15 2 .06 The present value of growth opportunities is PVGO 5 Price per share 2 No-growth value per share 5 $22.22 2 E1 /k 5 $22.22 2 $5/.15 5 2$11.11 PVGO is negative. This is because the net present value of the firm’s projects is negative: The rate of return on those assets is less than the opportunity cost of capital. Such a firm would be subject to takeover, because another firm could buy the firm for the market price of $22.22 per share and increase the value of the firm by changing its investment policy. For example, if the new management simply paid out all earnings as dividends, the value of the firm would increase to its no-growth value, E1/k 5 $5/.15 5 $33.33. CONCEPT CHECK 18.3 a. Calculate the price of a firm with a plowback ratio of .60 if its ROE is 20%. Current earnings, E1, will be $5 per share, and k 5 12.5%. b. What if ROE is 10%, which is less than the market capitalization rate? Compare the firm’s price in this instance to that of a firm with the same ROE and E1, but a plowback ratio of b 5 0. Life Cycles and Multistage Growth Models As useful as the constant-growth DDM formula is, you need to remember that it is based on a simplifying assumption, namely, that the dividend growth rate will be constant forever. In fact, firms typically pass through life cycles with very different dividend profiles in bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 603 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 604 PART V Security Analysis different phases. In early years, there are ample opportunities for profitable reinvestment in the company. Payout ratios are low, and growth is correspondingly rapid. In later years, the firm matures, production capacity is sufficient to meet market demand, competitors enter the market, and attractive opportunities for reinvestment may become harder to find. In this mature phase, the firm may choose to increase the dividend payout ratio, rather than retain earnings. The dividend level increases, but thereafter it grows at a slower rate because the company has fewer growth opportunities. Table 18.2 illustrates this pattern. It gives Value Line’s forecasts of return on capital, dividend payout ratio, and 3-year projected growth rate in earnings per share for a sample of the firms included in the computer software industry versus those of East Coast electric utilities. (We compare return on capital rather than return on equity because the latter is affected by leverage, which tends to be far greater in the electric utility industry than in the software industry. Return on capital measures operating income per dollar of total longterm financing, regardless of whether the source of the capital supplied is debt or equity. We will return to this issue in the next chapter.) By and large, the software firms have attractive investment opportunities. The median return on capital of these firms is forecast to be 16.5%, and the firms have responded with high plowback ratios. Most of these firms pay no dividends at all. The high return on capital and high plowback result in rapid growth. The median projected growth rate of earnings per share in this group is 13.2%. Table 18.2 Financial ratios in two industries Ticker Computer Software Adobe Systems Cognizant Compuware Intuit Microsoft Oracle Red Hat Parametric Tech SAP Median Electric Utilities (East Coast) Central Hudson G&E Consolidated Edison Duke Energy Northeast Utilities Pennsylvania Power Public Service Enterprise South Carolina E & G Southern Company Tampa Electric United Illuminating Median ADBE CTSH CPWR INTU MSFT ORCL RHT PMTC SAP CHG ED DUK NU PPL PEG SCG SO TE UIL Return on Capital (%) Payout Ratio (%) Growth Rate 2014–2016 12.0% 18.5 13.5 20.0 31.5 20.5 13.0 15.0 16.5 16.5% 0.0% 0.0 0.0 22.0 34.0 12.0 0.0 0.0 28.0 0.0% 13.2% 20.5 16.6 10.9 11.7 7.0 18.2 16.0 9.1 13.2% 6.0% 6.5 5.5 6.0 7.0 7.5 6.0 7.0 7.5 6.0 6.3% 66.0% 58.0 66.0 53.0 58.0 53.0 57.0 69.0 59.0 71.0 58.5% 2.0% 2.9 4.0 7.7 7.7 6.3 3.8 5.1 8.3 2.1 4.5% Source: Value Line Investment Survey, July and August, 2012. Reprinted with permission of Value Line Investment Survey. © 2012 Value Line Publishing, Inc. All rights reserved. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 604 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 605 In contrast, the electric utilities are more representative of mature firms. Their median return on capital is lower, 6.3%; dividend payout is higher, 58.5%; and median growth is lower, 4.5%. We conclude that the higher payouts of the electric utilities reflect their more limited opportunities to reinvest earnings at attractive rates of return. To value companies with temporarily high growth, analysts use a multistage version of the dividend discount model. Dividends in the early high-growth period are forecast and their combined present value is calculated. Then, once the firm is projected to settle down to a steady-growth phase, the constant-growth DDM is applied to value the remaining stream of dividends. We can illustrate this with a real-life example. Figure 18.2 is a Value Line Investment Survey report on Honda Motor Co. Some of the relevant information for 2012 is highlighted. Honda’s beta appears at the circled A, its recent stock price at the B, the per-share dividend payments at the C, the ROE (referred to as return on shareholder equity) at the D, and the dividend payout ratio (referred to as all dividends to net profits) at the E.6 The rows ending at C, D, and E are historical time series. The boldfaced, italicized entries under 2013 are estimates for that year. Similarly, the entries in the far right column (labeled 15–17) are forecasts for some time between 2015–2017, which we will take to be 2016. Value Line projects fairly rapid growth in the near term, with dividends rising from $.78 in 2013 to $1.00 in 2016. This growth rate cannot be sustained indefinitely. We can obtain dividend inputs for this initial period by using the explicit forecasts for 2013 and 2016 and linear interpolation for the years between: 2013 2014 $.78 $.85 2015 2016 $ .92 $1.00 Now let us assume the dividend growth rate levels off in 2016. What is a good guess for that steady-state growth rate? Value Line forecasts a dividend payout ratio of .25 and an ROE of 10%, implying long-term growth will be g 5 ROE 3 b 5 10.0% 3 (1 2 .25) 5 7.5% Our estimate of Honda’s intrinsic value using an investment horizon of 2016 is therefore obtained from Equation 18.2, which we restate here: V2012 5 5 D2013 D2014 D2015 D2016 1 P2016 1 1 1 (1 1 k)2 (1 1 k)3 (1 1 k)4 11k 1.00 1 P2016 .78 .92 .85 1 1 1 2 3 (1 1 k) (1 1 k) (1 1 k)4 11k Here, P2016 represents the forecast price at which we can sell our shares at the end of 2016, when dividends are assumed to enter their constant-growth phase. That price, according to the constant-growth DDM, should be P2016 5 D2017 D2016(1 1 g) 1.00 3 1.075 5 5 k2g k2g k 2 .075 The only variable remaining to be determined to calculate intrinsic value is the market capitalization rate, k. 6 Because Honda is a Japanese firm, Americans would hold its shares via ADRs, or American Depository Receipts. ADRs are not shares of the firm, but are claims to shares of the underlying foreign stock that are then traded in U.S. security markets. Value Line notes that each Honda ADR is a claim on one common share, but in other cases, each ADR may represent a claim to multiple shares or even fractional shares. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 605 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 606 PART V Security Analysis B A C D E Figure 18.2 Value Line Investment Survey report on Honda Motor Co. Source: Jason A. Smith, Value Line Investment Survey, May 25, 2012. Reprinted with permission of Value Line Investment Survey © 2012 Value Line Publishing, Inc. All rights reserved. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 606 7/25/13 2:42 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 607 One way to obtain k is from the CAPM. Observe from the Value Line report that Honda’s beta is .95. The risk-free rate on long-term Treasury bonds in 2012 was about 2.0%.7 Suppose that the market risk premium were forecast at 8%, roughly in line with its historical average. This would imply that the forecast for the market return was Risk-free rate 1 Market risk premium 5 2% 1 8% 5 10% Therefore, we can solve for the market capitalization rate as k 5 rf 1 b 3 E(rM) 2 rf 4 5 2% 1 .95(10% 2 2%) 5 9.6% Our forecast for the stock price in 2016 is thus P2016 5 $1.00 3 1.075 5 $51.19 .096 2 .075 and today’s estimate of intrinsic value is V2012 5 .78 .85 .92 1.00 1 51.19 1 1 1 5 $38.29 (1.096)2 (1.096)3 (1.096)4 1.096 We know from the Value Line report that Honda’s actual price was $32.88 (at the circled B). Our intrinsic value analysis indicates that the stock was underpriced. Should we increase our holdings? Perhaps. But before betting the farm, stop to consider how firm our estimate is. We’ve had to guess at dividends in the near future, the ultimate growth rate of those dividends, and the appropriate discount rate. Moreover, we’ve assumed Honda will follow a relatively simple two-stage growth process. In practice, the growth of dividends can follow more complicated patterns. Even small errors in these approximations could upset a conclusion. For example, suppose that we have overestimated Honda’s growth prospects and that the actual ROE in the post-2016 period will be 9% rather than 10%. Using the lower return on equity in the dividend discount model would result in an intrinsic value in 2012 of only $28.77, which is less than the stock price. Our conclusion regarding intrinsic value versus price is reversed. The exercise also highlights the importance of performing sensitivity analysis when you attempt to value stocks. Your estimates of stock values are no better than your assumptions. Sensitivity analysis will highlight the inputs that need to be most carefully examined. For example, even modest changes in the estimated ROE for the post-2016 period can result in big changes in intrinsic value. Similarly, small changes in the assumed capitalization rate would change intrinsic value substantially. On the other hand, reasonable changes in the dividends forecast between 2013 and 2016 would have a small impact on intrinsic value. CONCEPT CHECK 18.4 Confirm that the intrinsic value of Honda using ROE 5 9% is $28.77. (Hint: First calculate the stock price in 2016. Then calculate the present value of all interim dividends plus the present value of the 2016 sales price.) 7 When valuing long-term assets such as stocks, it is common to treat the long-term Treasury bond, rather than short-term T-bills, as the risk-free asset. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 607 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 608 PART V Security Analysis Multistage Growth Models The two-stage growth model that we just considered for Honda is a good start toward realism, but clearly we could do even better if our valuation model allowed for more flexible patterns of growth. Multistage growth models allow dividends per share to grow at several different rates as the firm matures. Many analysts use three-stage growth models. They may assume an initial period of high dividend growth (or instead make yearby-year forecasts of dividends for the short term), a final period of sustainable growth, and a transition period between, during which dividend growth rates taper off from the initial rapid rate to the ultimate sustainable rate. These models are conceptually no harder to work with than a two-stage model, but they require many more calculations and can be tedious to do by hand. It is easy, however, to build an Excel spreadsheet for such a model. Spreadsheet 18.1 is an example of such a model. Column B contains the inputs we have used so far for Honda. Column E contains dividend forecasts. In cells E2 through E5 we present the Value Line estimates for the next 4 years. Dividend growth in this period is about 8.6% annually. Rather than assume a sudden transition to constant dividend growth starting in 2016, we assume instead that the dividend growth rate in 2016 will be 8.6% and that it will decline steadily through 2027, finally reaching the constant terminal growth rate of 7.5% (see column F). Each dividend in the transition period is the previous year’s dividend times that year’s growth rate. Terminal value once the firm enters a constant-growth stage (cell G17) is computed from the constant-growth DDM. Finally, investor cash flow in each period (column H) equals dividends in each year plus the terminal value in 2027. The present value of these cash flows is computed in cell H19 as $40.29, about 5% higher than the value we found from the two-stage model. We obtain a greater intrinsic value in this case because we assume that dividend growth only gradually declines to its steadystate value. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 A Inputs beta mkt_prem rf k_equity plowback roe term_gwth B C D Year 0.95 0.08 0.02 0.0960 0.75 0.1 0.075 Value line forecasts of annual dividends Transitional period with slowing dividend growth Beginning of constant growth period 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 E F G Dividend Div growth Term value 0.78 0.85 0.92 1.00 1.09 0.0863 1.18 0.0852 1.28 0.0841 1.38 0.0829 1.50 0.0818 1.62 0.0807 1.75 0.0795 1.88 0.0784 2.03 0.0773 2.18 0.0761 2.35 0.0750 2.52 0.0750 129.18 40.29 I = PV of CF E17*(1+F17)/(B5 − F17) Spreadsheet 18.1 A three-stage growth model for Honda Motor Co. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 608 H Investor CF 0.78 0.85 0.92 1.00 1.09 1.18 1.28 1.38 1.50 1.62 1.75 1.88 2.03 2.18 2.35 131.71 NPV(B5,H2:H17) eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 609 18.4 Price–Earnings Ratio The Price–Earnings Ratio and Growth Opportunities Much of the real-world discussion of stock market valuation concentrates on the firm’s price–earnings multiple, the ratio of price per share to earnings per share, commonly called the P/E ratio. Our discussion of growth opportunities shows why stock market analysts focus on the P/E ratio. Both companies considered, Cash Cow and Growth Prospects, had earnings per share (EPS) of $5, but Growth Prospects reinvested 60% of earnings in prospects with an ROE of 15%, whereas Cash Cow paid out all earnings as dividends. Cash Cow had a price of $40, giving it a P/E multiple of 40/5 5 8.0, whereas Growth Prospects sold for $57.14, giving it a multiple of 57.14/5 5 11.4. This observation suggests the P/E ratio might serve as a useful indicator of expectations of growth opportunities. We can see how growth opportunities are reflected in P/E ratios by rearranging Equation 18.6 to P0 1 PVGO 5 ¢1 1 ≤ E1 k E/k (18.7) When PVGO 5 0, Equation 18.7 shows that P0 5 E1/k. The stock is valued like a nongrowing perpetuity of E1, and the P/E ratio is just 1/k. However, as PVGO becomes an increasingly dominant contributor to price, the P/E ratio can rise dramatically. The ratio of PVGO to E/k has a straightforward interpretation. It is the ratio of the component of firm value due to growth opportunities to the component of value due to assets already in place (i.e., the no-growth value of the firm, E/k). When future growth opportunities dominate the estimate of total value, the firm will command a high price relative to current earnings. Thus a high P/E multiple indicates that a firm enjoys ample growth opportunities. P/E multiples do vary with growth prospects. Between 1996 and 2012, for example, FedEx’s P/E ratio averaged about 17.4 while Consolidated Edison’s (an electric utility) average P/E was only 15.7. These numbers do not necessarily imply that FedEx was overpriced compared to Con Ed. If investors believed FedEx would grow faster than Con Ed, the higher price per dollar of earnings would be justified. That is, an investor might well pay a higher price per dollar of current earnings if he or she expects that earnings stream to grow more rapidly. In fact, FedEx’s growth rate has been consistent with its higher P/E multiple. Over this period, its earnings per share grew at 10.2% per year while Con Ed’s earnings growth rate was only 1.6%. Figure 18.4 on page 615 shows the EPS history of the two companies. We conclude that the P/E ratio reflects the market’s optimism concerning a firm’s growth prospects. Analysts must decide whether they are more or less optimistic than the belief implied by the market multiple. If they are more optimistic, they will recommend buying the stock. There is a way to make these insights more precise. Look again at the constant-growth DDM formula, P0 5 D1/(k 2 g). Now recall that dividends equal the earnings that are not reinvested in the firm: D1 5 E1(1 2 b). Recall also that g 5 ROE 3 b. Hence, substituting for D1 and g, we find that P0 5 bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 609 E1(1 2 b) k 2 ROE 3 b 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 610 PART V Security Analysis implying the P/E ratio is P0 12b 5 E1 k 2 ROE 3 b (18.8) It is easy to verify that the P/E ratio increases with ROE. This makes sense, because highROE projects give the firm good opportunities for growth.8 We also can verify that the P/E ratio increases for higher plowback, b, as long as ROE exceeds k. This too makes sense. When a firm has good investment opportunities, the market will reward it with a higher P/E multiple if it exploits those opportunities more aggressively by plowing back more earnings into those opportunities. Remember, however, that growth is not desirable for its own sake. Examine Table 18.3 where we use Equation 18.8 to compute both growth rates and P/E ratios for different combinations of ROE and b. Although growth always increases with the plowback rate (move across the rows in panel A), the P/E ratio does not (move across the rows in panel B). In the top row of panel B, the P/E falls as the plowback rate increases. In the middle row, it is unaffected by plowback. In the third row, it increases. This pattern has a simple interpretation. When the expected ROE is less than the required return, k, investors prefer that the firm pay out earnings as dividends rather than reinvest earnings in the firm at an inadequate rate of return. That is, for ROE lower than k, the value of the firm falls as plowback increases. Conversely, when ROE exceeds k, the firm offers attractive investment opportunities, so the value of the firm is enhanced as those opportunities are more fully exploited by increasing the plowback rate. Finally, where ROE just equals k, the firm offers “break-even” investment opportunities with a fair rate of return. In this case, investors are indifferent between reinvestment of earnings in the firm or elsewhere at the market capitalization rate, because the rate of return in either case is 12%. Therefore, the stock price is unaffected by the plowback rate. We conclude that the higher the plowback rate, the higher the growth rate, but a higher plowback rate does not necessarily mean a higher P/E ratio. Higher plowback increases P/E only if investments undertaken by the firm offer an expected rate of return greater than the market capitalization rate. Otherwise, increasing plowback hurts investors because more money is sunk into projects with inadequate rates of return. Table 18.3 Effect of ROE and plowback on growth and the P/E ratio Plowback Rate (b) 0 ROE 10% 12 14 0 0 0 10% 12 14 8.33 8.33 8.33 .25 .50 A. Growth rate, g 2.5% 5.0% 3.0 6.0 3.5 7.0 B. P/E ratio 7.89 7.14 8.33 8.33 8.82 10.00 .75 7.5% 9.0 10.5 5.56 8.33 16.67 Assumption: k 5 12% per year. 8 Note that Equation 18.8 is a simple rearrangement of the DDM formula, with ROE 3 b 5 g. Because that formula requires that g , k, Equation 18.8 is valid only when ROE 3 b , k. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 610 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 611 Notwithstanding these fine points, P/E ratios frequently are taken as proxies for the expected growth in dividends or earnings. In fact, a common Wall Street rule of thumb is that the growth rate ought to be roughly equal to the P/E ratio. In other words, the ratio of P/E to g, often called the PEG ratio, should be about 1.0. Peter Lynch, the famous portfolio manager, puts it this way in his book One Up on Wall Street: The P/E ratio of any company that’s fairly priced will equal its growth rate. I’m talking here about growth rate of earnings here. . . . If the P/E ratio of Coca Cola is 15, you’d expect the company to be growing at about 15% per year, etc. But if the P/E ratio is less than the growth rate, you may have found yourself a bargain. Example 18.5 P/E Ratio versus Growth Rate Let’s try Lynch’s rule of thumb. Assume that rf 5 8% rM 2 rf 5 8% b 5 .4 (roughly the value when Peter Lynch was writing) (about the historical average market risk premium) (a typical value for the plowback ratio in the United States) Therefore, rM 5 rf 1 market risk premium 5 8% 1 8% 5 16%, and k 5 16% for an average (b 5 1) company. If we also accept as reasonable that ROE 5 16% (the same value as the expected return on the stock), we conclude that g 5 ROE 3 b 5 16% 3 .4 5 6.4% and P 1 2 .4 5 5 6.26 E .16 2 .064 Thus, the P/E ratio and g are about equal using these assumptions, consistent with the rule of thumb. However, note that this rule of thumb, like almost all others, will not work in all circumstances. For example, the yield on long-term Treasury bonds today is more like 2%, so a comparable forecast of rM today would be rf 1 Market risk premium 5 2% 1 8% 5 10% If we continue to focus on a firm with b 5 1, and if ROE still is about the same as k, then g 5 10% 3 .4 5 4.0% while P 1 2 .4 5 5 10 E .10 2 .04 The P/E ratio and g now diverge and the PEG ratio is now 2.5. Nevertheless, lowerthan-average PEG ratios are still widely seen as signaling potential underpricing. The importance of growth opportunities is most evident in the valuation of start-up firms. For example, in the dot-com boom of the late 1990s, many companies that had yet to turn a profit were valued by the market at billions of dollars. The perceived value of these companies was exclusively as growth opportunities. For example, the online auction firm eBay had 1998 profits of $2.4 million, far less than the $45 million profit earned by the traditional auctioneer Sotheby’s; yet eBay’s market value was more than 10 times greater: bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 611 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 612 PART V Security Analysis $22 billion versus $1.9 billion. (As it turns out, the market was quite right to value eBay so much more aggressively than Sotheby’s. Its net income in 2011 was $1.8 billion, more than 10 times that of Sotheby’s. Of course, when company valuation is determined primarily by growth opportunities, those values can be very sensitive to reassessments of such prospects. When the market became more skeptical of the business prospects of most Internet retailers at the close of the 1990s, that is, as it revised the estimates of growth opportunities downward, their stock prices plummeted. As perceptions of future prospects wax and wane, share price can swing wildly. Growth prospects are intrinsically difficult to tie down; ultimately, however, those prospects drive the value of the most dynamic firms in the economy. The nearby box contains a simple valuation analysis. As Facebook headed toward its highly anticipated IPO in 2012, there was widespread speculation about the price at which it would eventually trade in the stock market. Notice that the discussion in the article focused on two key questions. First, what was a reasonable projection of the growth rate of Facebook’s profits? Second, what multiple of earnings was appropriate to translate an earnings forecast into a price forecast? These are precisely the questions addressed by our stock valuation models. CONCEPT CHECK 18.5 ABC stock has an expected ROE of 12% per year, expected earnings per share of $2, and expected dividends of $1.50 per share. Its market capitalization rate is 10% per year. a. What are its expected growth rate, its price, and its P/E ratio? b. If the plowback ratio were .4, what would be the expected dividend per share, the growth rate, price, and the P/E ratio? P/E Ratios and Stock Risk One important implication of any stock-valuation model is that (holding all else equal) riskier stocks will have lower P/E multiples. We can see this quite easily in the context of the constant-growth model by examining the formula for the P/E ratio (Equation 18.8): P 12b 5 E k2g Riskier firms will have higher required rates of return, that is, higher values of k. Therefore, the P/E multiple will be lower. This is true even outside the context of the constantgrowth model. For any expected earnings and dividend stream, the present value of those cash flows will be lower when the stream is perceived to be riskier. Hence the stock price and the ratio of price to earnings will be lower. Of course, you can find many small, risky, start-up companies with very high P/E multiples. This does not contradict our claim that P/E multiples should fall with risk; instead it is evidence of the market’s expectations of high growth rates for those companies. This is why we said that high-risk firms will have lower P/E ratios holding all else equal. Given a growth projection, the P/E multiple will be lower when risk is perceived to be higher. Pitfalls in P/E Analysis No description of P/E analysis is complete without mentioning some of its pitfalls. First, consider that the denominator in the P/E ratio is accounting earnings, which are influenced by somewhat arbitrary accounting rules such as the use of historical cost in depreciation bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 612 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer WHAT IS FACEBOOK WORTH? As investors dug into the company’s freshly released financials Wednesday, analysts and investors began circulating a range of values—from as little as $50 billion to as much as $125 billion—for the social-networking Web site. It will be months before the market sets a final price, but already the valuation question has become a tug of war over two essential questions: Just how fast can the company continue to grow? And can it extract value from advertising in the way it plans? Facebook’s revenue grew 88% in 2011, and net income grew 65%. Facebook’s growth has already decelerated from 154% from 2009 to 2010 to the 88% it experienced last year. Francis Gaskins, president of IPOdesktop.com, which analyzes IPOs for investors, says he doesn’t believe Facebook is worth more than $50 billion—50 times its reported profits for 2011 of $1 billion, or more than triple the market’s average price-to-earnings ratio. Google Inc.’s profits are 10 times that of Facebook, but its stock-market value is $190 billion, he notes. A $100 billion valuation “would have us believe that Facebook is worth 53% of Google, even though Google’s sales and profits are 10 times that of Facebook,” he said. Martin Pyykkonen, an analyst at Denver banking boutique Wedge Partners, is more bullish, saying the value could top $100 billion. He says Facebook could trade at 15 to 18 times next year’s expected earnings before interest, taxes, and certain noncash charges, a cash-flow measure known as EBITDA. By comparison, he says, mature companies trade at 8 to 10 times EBITDA. Microsoft Corp. trades at 7 times, and Google about 10 times. While that math only justifies an $81 billion valuation, he says Facebook may be able to unlock faster growth in ad spending and reach $5.5 billion in EBITDA, which could justify a higher multiple of 20 times, implying a $110 billion valuation. Source: Randall Smith, “Facebook’s $100 Billion Question,” The Wall Street Journal, February 3, 2012. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal, Copyright © 2012 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. WORDS FROM THE STREET Facebook’s $100 Billion Question and inventory valuation. In times of high inflation, historic cost depreciation and inventory costs will tend to underrepresent true economic values, because the replacement cost of both goods and capital equipment will rise with the general level of prices. As Figure 18.3 demonstrates, P/E ratios generally have been inversely related to the inflation rate. In part, this reflects the market’s assessment that earnings in high inflation periods are of “lower quality,” artificially distorted by inflation, and warranting lower P/E ratios. Earnings management is the practice of using flexibility in accounting rules to improve the apparent profitability of the firm. We will have much to say on this topic in the next chapter on interpreting financial statements. A version of earnings management that became common in the 1990s was the reporting of “pro forma earnings” measures. 60 50 40 30 P/E Ratio 20 10 0 1955 Inflation Rate 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Figure 18.3 P/E ratios of the S&P 500 Index and inflation 613 bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 613 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 614 PART V Security Analysis Pro forma earnings are calculated ignoring certain expenses, for example, restructuring charges, stock-option expenses, or write-downs of assets from continuing operations. Firms argue that ignoring these expenses gives a clearer picture of the underlying profitability of the firm. Comparisons with earlier periods probably would make more sense if those costs were excluded. But when there is too much leeway for choosing what to exclude, it becomes hard for investors or analysts to interpret the numbers or to compare them across firms. The lack of standards gives firms considerable leeway to manage earnings. Even GAAP allows firms considerable discretion to manage earnings. For example, in the late 1990s, Kellogg took restructuring charges, which are supposed to be one-time events, nine quarters in a row. Were these really one-time events, or were they more appropriately treated as ordinary expenses? Given the available leeway in managing earnings, the justified P/E multiple becomes difficult to gauge. Another confounding factor in the use of P/E ratios is related to the business cycle. We were careful in deriving the DDM to define earnings as being net of economic depreciation, that is, the maximum flow of income that the firm could pay out without depleting its productive capacity. But reported earnings are computed in accordance with generally accepted accounting principles and need not correspond to economic earnings. Beyond this, however, notions of a normal or justified P/E ratio, as in Equation 18.7 or 18.8, assume implicitly that earnings rise at a constant rate, or, put another way, on a smooth trend line. In contrast, reported earnings can fluctuate dramatically around a trend line over the course of the business cycle. Another way to make this point is to note that the “normal” P/E ratio predicted by Equation 18.8 is the ratio of today’s price to the trend value of future earnings, E1. The P/E ratio reported in the financial pages of the newspaper, by contrast, is the ratio of price to the most recent past accounting earnings. Current accounting earnings can differ considerably from future economic earnings. Because ownership of stock conveys the right to future as well as current earnings, the ratio of price to most recent earnings can vary substantially over the business cycle, as accounting earnings and the trend value of economic earnings diverge by greater and lesser amounts. As an example, Figure 18.4 graphs the earnings per share of FedEx and Con Ed since 1996. Note that FedEx’s EPS is far more variable. Because the market values the entire stream of future dividends generated by the company, when earnings are temporarily depressed, the P/E ratio should tend to be high—that is, the denominator of the ratio responds more sensitively to the business cycle than the numerator. This pattern is borne out well. Figure 18.5 graphs the P/E ratios of the two firms. FedEx has greater earnings volatility and more variability in its P/E ratio. Its clearly higher average growth rate shows up in its generally higher P/E ratio. The only period in which Con Ed’s ratio exceeded FedEx’s was in 2012, a year when FedEx’s earnings rose at a far faster rate than its underlying trend. The market seems to have decided that this earnings performance was not likely to be sustainable, and FedEx’s price rose less dramatically than its annual earnings. Consequently, its P/E ratio declined. This example shows why analysts must be careful in using P/E ratios. There is no way to say P/E ratio is overly high or low without referring to the company’s long-run growth prospects, as well as to current earnings per share relative to the long-run trend line. Nevertheless, Figures 18.4 and 18.5 demonstrate a clear relation between P/E ratios and growth. Despite considerable short-run fluctuations, FedEx’s EPS clearly trended upward over the period. Con Ed’s earnings were essentially flat. FedEx’s growth prospects are reflected in its consistently higher P/E multiple. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 614 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Combining P/E Analysis and the DDM Earnings per Share (1992 = 1.0) 5 FedEx 4 3 2 Con Ed 1 0 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2010 2012 Figure 18.4 Earnings growth for two companies 25 20 P/E FedEx 15 10 P/E Con Ed Some analysts use P/E 5 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 ratios in conjunction with earnings forecasts to estimate the price of a stock at an investor’s horizon Figure 18.5 Price–earnings ratios date. The Honda analysis in Figure 18.2 shows that Value Line forecast a P/E ratio for 2016 of 14. EPS for 2016 was forecast at $4, implying a price in 2016 of 14 3 $4 5 $56. Given an estimate of $56 for the 2016 sales price, we would compute intrinsic value in 2012 as V2012 5 615 6 P/E Ratio This analysis suggests that P/E ratios should vary across industries, and in fact they do. Figure 18.6 shows P/E ratios in 2012 for a sample of industries. Notice that the industries with the highest multiples— such as business software or biotech—have attractive investment opportunities and relatively high growth rates, whereas the industries with the lowest ratios—for example, aerospace or computer manufacturers—are in more mature or less profitable industries with limited growth opportunities. The relationship between P/E and growth is not perfect, which is not surprising in light of the pitfalls discussed in this section, but as a general rule, the P/E multiple does appear to track growth opportunities. Equity Valuation Models .78 .92 1.00 1 56 .85 1 1 5 $41.62 1 (1.096)2 (1.096)3 (1.096)4 1.096 Other Comparative Valuation Ratios The price–earnings ratio is an example of a comparative valuation ratio. Such ratios are used to assess the valuation of one firm versus another based on a fundamental indicator such as earnings. For example, an analyst might compare the P/E ratios of two firms in the bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 615 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 616 PART V Security Analysis Biotech Business Software Heavy Construction Trucking Auto Manufacturers Restaurants Food Products Application Software Asset Management Chemical Products Pharmaceuticals Integrated Oil & Gas Home Improvement Electric Utilities Industrial Metals Iron Steel Telecom Services Computer Systems Health Care Plans Money Center Banks Aerospace/Defense 57.8 34.7 32.4 28.0 25.3 21.4 21.1 17.5 17.5 17.4 17.2 16.8 16.5 15.6 14.9 14.8 14.7 13.1 11.8 11.3 8.5 0 10 20 30 P/E Ratio 40 50 60 Figure 18.6 P/E ratios for different industries Source: Yahoo! Finance, finance.yahoo.com, September 12, 2012. same industry to test whether the market is valuing one firm “more aggressively” than the other. Other such comparative ratios are commonly used: Price-to-Book Ratio This is the ratio of price per share divided by book value per share. As we noted earlier in this chapter, some analysts view book value as a useful measure of value and therefore treat the ratio of price to book value as an indicator of how aggressively the market values the firm. Price-to-Cash-Flow Ratio Earnings as reported on the income statement can be affected by the company’s choice of accounting practices, and thus are commonly viewed as subject to some imprecision and even manipulation. In contrast, cash flow—which tracks cash actually flowing into or out of the firm—is less affected by accounting decisions. As a result, some analysts prefer to use the ratio of price to cash flow per share rather than price to earnings per share. Some analysts use operating cash flow when calculating this ratio; others prefer “free cash flow,” that is, operating cash flow net of new investment. Price-to-Sales Ratio Many start-up firms have no earnings. As a result, the price– earnings ratio for these firms is meaningless. The price-to-sales ratio (the ratio of stock price to the annual sales per share) has recently become a popular valuation benchmark for these firms. Of course, price-to-sales ratios can vary markedly across industries, because profit margins vary widely. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 616 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 617 40 35 Price Earnings 30 25 20 15 Price Cash Flow 10 Price Sales 5 0 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Figure 18.7 Market valuation statistics Be Creative Sometimes a standard valuation ratio will simply not be available, and you will have to devise your own. In the 1990s, some analysts valued retail Internet firms based on the number of hits their Web sites received. As it turns out, they valued these firms using too-generous “price-to-hits” ratios. Nevertheless, in a new investment environment, these analysts used the information available to them to devise the best valuation tools they could. Figure 18.7 presents the behavior of several valuation measures. While the levels of these ratios differ considerably, for the most part, they track each other fairly closely, with upturns and downturns at the same times. 18.5 Free Cash Flow Valuation Approaches An alternative approach to the dividend discount model values the firm using free cash flow, that is, cash flow available to the firm or its equityholders net of capital expenditures. This approach is particularly useful for firms that pay no dividends, for which the dividend discount model would be difficult to implement. But free cash flow models may be applied to any firm and can provide useful insights about firm value beyond the DDM. One approach is to discount the free cash flow for the firm (FCFF) at the weightedaverage cost of capital to obtain the value of the firm, and subtract the then-existing value of debt to find the value of equity. Another is to focus from the start on the free cash flow to equityholders (FCFE), discounting those directly at the cost of equity to obtain the market value of equity. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 617 7/17/13 4:08 PM Final PDF to printer 618 PART V Security Analysis The free cash flow to the firm is the after-tax cash flow generated by the firm’s operations, net of investments in capital, and net working capital. It includes cash flows available to both debt- and equityholders.9 It equals: FCFF 5 EBIT (1 2 tc ) 1 Depreciation 2 Capital expenditures 2 Increase in NWC (18.9) where EBIT 5 earnings before interest and taxes tc 5 the corporate tax rate NWC 5 net working capital Alternatively, we can focus on cash flow available to equityholders. This will differ from free cash flow to the firm by after-tax interest expenditures, as well as by cash flow associated with net issuance or repurchase of debt (i.e., principal repayments minus proceeds from issuance of new debt). FCFE 5 FCFF 2 Interest expense 3 (1 2 tc ) 1 Increases in net debt (18.10) A free cash flow to the firm valuation model discounts year-by-year cash flows plus some estimate of terminal value, VT. In Equation 18.11, we use the constant-growth model to estimate terminal value and discount at the weighted-average cost of capital. T FCFFt VT FCFFT11 Firm value 5 a t 1 T , where VT 5 ( ) ( ) WACC 2g 1 1 WACC 1 1 WACC t51 (18.11) To find equity value, we subtract the existing market value of debt from the derived value of the firm. Alternatively, we can discount free cash flows to equity (FCFE) at the cost of equity, kE. T FCFEt VT FCFET11 Intrinsic value of equity 5 a t 1 T , where VT 5 ( ) ( ) kE 2 g 1 1 k 1 1 kE t51 E (18.12) As in the dividend discount model, free cash flow models use a terminal value to avoid adding the present values of an infinite sum of cash flows. That terminal value may simply be the present value of a constant-growth perpetuity (as in the formulas above) or it may be based on a multiple of EBIT, book value, earnings, or free cash flow. As a general rule, estimates of intrinsic value depend critically on terminal value. Spreadsheet 18.2 presents a free cash flow valuation of Honda using the data supplied by Value Line in Figure 18.2. We start with the free cash flow to the firm approach given in Equation 18.9. Panel A of the spreadsheet lays out values supplied by Value Line. Entries for middle years are interpolated from beginning and final values. Panel B calculates free cash flow. The sum of after-tax profits in row 11 (from Value Line) plus after-tax interest payments in row 12 [i.e., interest expense 3 (1 2 tc )] equals EBIT(1 2 tc ). In row 13 we subtract the change in net working capital, in row 14 we add back depreciation, and in row 15 we subtract capital expenditures. The result in row 17 is the free cash flow to the firm, FCFF, for each year between 2013 and 2016. To find the present value of these cash flows, we will discount at WACC, which is calculated in panel C. WACC is the weighted average of the after-tax cost of debt and the 9 This is firm cash flow assuming all-equity financing. Any tax advantage to debt financing is recognized by using an after-tax cost of debt in the computation of weighted-average cost of capital. This issue is discussed in any introductory corporate finance text. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 618 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 A 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 B A. Input data P/E Cap spending/shr LT Debt Shares EPS Working Capital B. Cash flow calculations Profits (after tax) Interest (after tax) Chg Working Cap Depreciation Cap Spending I Equity Valuation Models C D E F G 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 14.35 2.65 30000 1800 3.10 36825 14.25 2.70 28500 1800 3.75 37750 14.17 2.82 27333 1798 3.83 41173 14.08 2.93 26167 1797 3.92 44597 14.00 3.05 25000 1795 4.00 48020 5700.0 702.0 6850.0 666.9 925.0 7250.0 4860.0 6970.0 639.6 3423.3 7166.67 5064.9 7090.0 612.3 3423.3 7083 5269.8 7210.0 585.0 3423.3 7000.0 5474.8 8981.9 6815.0 6288.0 4481.8 6092.5 4313.5 Terminal value 5896.9 104098.2 4145.3 83203.2 assumes fixed debt ratio after 2016 7000.0 FCFF FCFE C. Discount rate calculations Current beta 0.95 Unlevered beta 0.767 terminal growth 0.02 tax_rate 0.35 r_debt 0.036 risk-free rate 0.02 market risk prem 0.08 MV equity 81795 0.27 Debt/Value 0.950 Levered beta 0.096 k_equity 0.077 WACC PV factor for FCFF 1.000 PV factor for FCFE 1.000 0.25 0.934 0.095 0.077 0.929 0.913 0.23 0.919 0.094 0.077 0.862 0.835 0.22 0.904 0.092 0.077 0.800 0.765 100940 0.20 0.891 0.091 0.078 0.742 0.701 D. Present values PV(FCFF) PV(FCFE) 8341 6225 5421 3744 4875 3299 4378 2905 H J K L 619 M = (1-tax_rate) × r_debt × LT Debt from Value Line current beta/[1 + (1-tax)*debt/equity] from Value Line YTM in 2012 on A+ rated LT debt Spreadsheet 18.2 Free cash flow valuation of Honda Motor Co. *2012 P/E ratio is from Yahoo! Finance. Other inputs are from Value Line. 0.091 0.078 0.742 0.701 77283 58307 Row 3 × Row 11 linear trend from initial to final value unlevered beta × [1 + (1-tax)*debt/equity] from CAPM and levered beta (1-t)*r_debt*D/V + k_equity*(1-D/V) Discount each year at WACC Discount each year at k_equity Intrinsic val Equity val Intrin/share 100298 70298 39.05 74479 74479 41.38 eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm cost of equity in each year. When computing WACC, we must account for the change in leverage forecast by Value Line. To compute the cost of equity, we will use the CAPM as in our earlier (dividend discount model) valuation exercise, but accounting for the fact that equity beta will decline each year as the firm reduces leverage.10 10 Call bL the firm’s equity beta at the initial level of leverage as provided by Value Line. Equity betas reflect both business risk and financial risk. When a firm changes its capital structure (debt/equity mix), it changes financial risk, and therefore equity beta changes. How should we recognize the change in financial risk? As you may remember from an introductory corporate finance class, you must first unleverage beta. This leaves us with business risk. We use the following formula to find unleveraged beta, bU (where D/E is the firm’s current debt-equity ratio): bL bU 5 1 1 (D/E)(1 2 tc ) Then, we re-leverage beta in any particular year using the forecast capital structure for that year (which reintroduces the financial risk associated with that year’s capital structure): bL 5 bU 3 1 1 (D/E)(1 2 tc ) 4 bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 619 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 620 PART V Security Analysis To find Honda’s cost of debt, we note that its long-term bonds were rated A1 in 2012 and that yields to maturity on this quality debt at the time were about 3.6%. Honda’s debtto-value ratio (assuming its debt is selling near par value) is computed in row 29. In 2012, the ratio was .27. Based on Value Line forecasts, it will fall to .20 by 2016. We interpolate the debt-to-value ratio for the intermediate years. WACC is computed in row 32. WACC increases slightly over time as the debt-to-value ratio declines between 2012 and 2016. The present value factor for cash flows accruing in each year is the previous year’s factor divided by (1 1 WACC) for that year. The present value of each cash flow (row 37) is the free cash flow times the cumulative discount factor. The terminal value of the firm (cell H17) is computed from the constant-growth model as FCFF2016 3 (1 1 g)/(WACC2016 2 g), where g (cell B23) is the assumed value for the steady growth rate. We assume in the spreadsheet that g 5 .02, roughly in line with the long-run growth rate of the broad economy.11 Terminal value is also discounted back to 2012 (cell H37), and the intrinsic value of the firm is thus found as the sum of discounted free cash flows between 2013 and 2016 plus the discounted terminal value. Finally, the value of debt in 2012 is subtracted from firm value to arrive at the intrinsic value of equity in 2012 (cell K37), and value per share is calculated in cell L37 as equity value divided by number of shares in 2012. The free cash flow to equity approach yields a similar intrinsic value for the stock.12 FCFE (row 18) is obtained from FCFF by subtracting after-tax interest expense and net debt repurchases. The cash flows are then discounted at the equity rate. Like WACC, the cost of equity changes each period as leverage changes. The present value factor for equity cash flows is presented in row 34. Equity value is reported in cell J38, which is put on a per share basis in cell L38. Spreadsheet 18.2 is available at the Online Learning Center for this text, www.mhhe. com/bkm. Comparing the Valuation Models In principle, the free cash flow approach is fully consistent with the dividend discount model and should provide the same estimate of intrinsic value if one can extrapolate to a period in which the firm begins to pay dividends growing at a constant rate. This was demonstrated in two famous papers by Modigliani and Miller.13 However, in practice, you will find that values from these models may differ, sometimes substantially. This is due to the fact that in practice, analysts are always forced to make simplifying assumptions. For example, how long will it take the firm to enter a constant-growth stage? How should depreciation best be treated? What is the best estimate of ROE? Answers to questions like these can have a big impact on value, and it is not always easy to maintain consistent assumptions across the models. 11 In the long run a firm can’t grow forever at a rate higher than the aggregate economy. So by the time we assert that growth is in a stable stage, it seems reasonable that the growth rate should not be significantly greater than that of the overall economy (although it can be less if the firm is in a declining industry). 12 Over the 2013–2016 period, Value Line predicts that Honda will retire a considerable fraction of its outstanding debt. The implied debt repurchases are a use of cash and reduce the cash flow available to equity. Such repurchases cannot be sustained indefinitely, however, for debt outstanding would soon be run down to zero. Therefore, in our estimate of the terminal value of equity, we compute the final cash flow assuming that starting in 2016 Honda will begin issuing enough debt to maintain its debt-to-value ratio. This approach is consistent with the assumption of constant growth and constant discount rates after 2016. 13 Franco Modigliani and M. Miller, “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment,” American Economic Review, June 1958, and “Dividend Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares,” Journal of Business, October 1961. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 620 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 621 We have now valued Honda using several approaches, with estimates of intrinsic value as follows: Model Two-stage dividend discount model DDM with earnings multiple terminal value Three-stage DDM Free cash flow to the firm Free cash flow to equity Market price (from Value Line) Intrinsic Value $38.81 41.62 40.29 39.05 41.38 32.88 What should we make of these differences? All the estimates are somewhat higher than Honda’s actual stock price, perhaps indicating that they use an unrealistically high value for the ultimate constant growth rate. For example, in the long run, it seems unlikely that Honda will be able to grow as rapidly as Value Line’s forecast for 2016 growth, 7.5%. The two-stage dividend discount model is the most conservative of the estimates, largely because it assumes that Honda’s dividend growth rate will fall to its terminal value after only 3 years. In contrast, the three-stage DDM allows growth to taper off over a longer period. Given the consistency with which all these estimates exceed market price, perhaps the stock is indeed underpriced compared to its intrinsic value. On balance, however, this valuation exercise suggests that finding bargains is not as easy as it seems. While these models are easy to apply, establishing proper inputs is more of a challenge. This should not be surprising. In even a moderately efficient market, finding profit opportunities will be more involved than analyzing Value Line data for a few hours. These models are extremely useful to analysts, however, because they provide ballpark estimates of intrinsic value. More than that, they force rigorous thought about underlying assumptions and highlight the variables with the greatest impact on value and the greatest payoff to further analysis. The Problem with DCF Models Our estimates of Honda’s intrinsic value are all based on discounted cash flow (DCF) models, in which we calculate the present value of forecasted cash flows and a terminal sales price at some future date. It is clear from the calculations for Honda that most of the action in these models is in the terminal value and that this value can be highly sensitive to even small changes in some input values (see, for example, Concept Check 18.4). Therefore, you must recognize that DCF valuation estimates are almost always going to be imprecise. Growth opportunities and future growth rates are especially hard to pin down. For this reason, many value investors employ a hierarchy of valuation. They view the most reliable components of value as the items on the balance sheet that allow for the most precise estimates of market value. Real estate, plant, and equipment would fall in this category. A somewhat less reliable component of value is the economic profit on assets already in place. For example, a company like Intel earns a far higher ROE on its investments in chipmaking facilities than its cost of capital. The present value of these “economic profits,” or economic value added,14 is a major component of Intel’s market value. This component of value is less certain than its balance sheet assets, however, because there is always a concern that new competitors will enter the market, force down prices and profit margins, and reduce the return on Intel’s investments. Thus, one needs to carefully assess the barriers to entry that protect Intel’s pricing and profit margins. We noted some of these barriers in the last chapter, where we discussed the role of industry analysis, market structure, and competitive position (see Section 17.7). 14 We discuss economic value added in greater detail in the next chapter. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 621 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 622 PART V Security Analysis Finally, the least reliable components of value are growth opportunities, the purported ability of firms like Intel to invest in positive-NPV ventures that contribute to high market valuations today. Value investors don’t deny that such opportunities exist, but they are skeptical that precise values can be attached to them and, therefore, tend to be less willing to make investment decisions that depend on the value of those opportunities. 18.6 The Aggregate Stock Market The most popular approach to valuing the overall stock market is the earnings multiplier approach applied at the aggregate level. The first step is to forecast corporate profits for the coming period. Then we derive an estimate of the earnings multiplier, the aggregate P/E ratio, based on a forecast of long-term interest rates. The product of the two forecasts is the estimate of the end-of-period level of the market. The forecast of the P/E ratio of the market is sometimes derived from a graph similar to that in Figure 18.8, which plots the earnings yield (earnings per share divided by price per share, the reciprocal of the P/E ratio) of the S&P 500 and the yield to maturity on 10-year Treasury bonds. The two series clearly move in tandem over time and suggest that this relationship and the current yield on 10-year Treasury bonds could help in forecasting the earnings yield on the S&P 500. Given that earnings yield, a forecast of earnings could be used to predict the level of the S&P in some future period. Let’s consider a simple example of this procedure. 16 14 Yield (%) 12 Treasury Yield 10 8 6 Earnings Yield 4 2 0 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Figure 18.8 Earnings yield of S&P 500 versus 10-year Treasury-bond yield Example 18.6 Forecasting the Aggregate Stock Market In mid-2012, the forecast for 12-month earnings per share for the S&P 500 portfolio was about $110. The 10-year Treasury bond yield was about 2.9%. As a first approach, we might posit that the spread between the earnings yield and the Treasury yield, which was around 3.9%, will remain at that level by the end of the year. Given a Treasury yield of 2.9%, this would imply an earnings yield for the S&P of 6.8%, and a bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 622 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 623 P/E ratio of 1/.068 5 14.7. Our forecast for the level of the S&P index would then be 14.7 3 110 5 1,617. Given a current value for the S&P 500 of 1,457, this would imply a 1-year capital gain on the index of 160/1,457 5 11.0%. Of course, there is uncertainty regarding all three inputs into this analysis: the actual earnings on the S&P 500 stocks, the level of Treasury yields at year-end, and the spread between the Treasury yield and the earnings yield. One would wish to perform sensitivity or scenario analysis to examine the impact of changes in all of these variables. To illustrate, consider Table 18.4, which shows a simple scenario analysis treating possible effects of variation in the Treasury bond yield. The scenario analysis shows that forecast level of the stock market varies inversely and with dramatic sensitivity to interest rate changes. Pessimistic Scenario Treasury bond yield Earnings yield Resulting P/E ratio EPS forecast Forecast for S&P 500 3.4% 7.3% 13.7 110 1,507 Most Likely Scenario 2.9% 6.8% 14.7 110 1,617 Optimistic Scenario 2.4% 6.3% 15.9 110 1,749 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Some analysts use an aggregate version of the dividend discount model rather than an earnings multiplier approach. All of these models, however, rely heavily on forecasts of such macroeconomic variables as GDP, interest rates, and the rate of inflation, which are difficult to predict accurately. Because stock prices reflect expectations of future dividends, which are tied to the economic fortunes of firms, it is not surprising that the performance of a broad-based stock index like the S&P 500 is taken as a leading economic indicator, that is, a predictor of the performance of the aggregate economy. Stock prices are viewed as embodying consensus forecasts of economic activity and are assumed to move up or down in anticipation of movements in the economy. The government’s index of leading economic indicators, which is taken to predict the progress of the business cycle, is made up in part of recent stock market performance. However, the predictive value of the market is far from perfect. A well-known joke, often attributed to Paul Samuelson, is that the market has forecast eight of the last five recessions. Table 18.4 S&P 500 index forecasts under various scenarios Forecast for the earnings yield on the S&P 500 equals Treasury bond yield plus 3.9%. The P/E ratio is the reciprocal of the forecast earnings yield. 1. One approach to firm valuation is to focus on the firm’s book value, either as it appears on the balance sheet or as adjusted to reflect current replacement cost of assets or liquidation value. Another approach is to focus on the present value of expected future dividends. SUMMARY 2. The dividend discount model holds that the price of a share of stock should equal the present value of all future dividends per share, discounted at an interest rate commensurate with the risk of the stock. 3. Dividend discount models give estimates of the intrinsic value of a stock. If price does not equal intrinsic value, the rate of return will differ from the equilibrium return based on the stock’s risk. The actual return will depend on the rate at which the stock price is predicted to revert to its intrinsic value. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 623 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 624 PART V Security Analysis 4. The constant-growth version of the DDM asserts that if dividends are expected to grow at a constant rate forever, the intrinsic value of the stock is determined by the formula V0 5 D1 k2g This version of the DDM is simplistic in its assumption of a constant value of g. There are more-sophisticated multistage versions of the model for more-complex environments. When the constant-growth assumption is reasonably satisfied and the stock is selling for its intrinsic value, the formula can be inverted to infer the market capitalization rate for the stock: k5 D1 1g P0 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 5. The constant-growth dividend discount model is best suited for firms that are expected to exhibit stable growth rates over the foreseeable future. In reality, however, firms progress through life cycles. In early years, attractive investment opportunities are ample and the firm responds with high plowback ratios and rapid dividend growth. Eventually, however, growth rates level off to more sustainable values. Three-stage growth models are well suited to such a pattern. These models allow for an initial period of rapid growth, a final period of steady dividend growth, and a middle, or transition, period in which the dividend growth rate declines from its initial high rate to the lower sustainable rate. 6. Stock market analysts devote considerable attention to a company’s price-to-earnings ratio. The P/E ratio is a useful measure of the market’s assessment of the firm’s growth opportunities. Firms with no growth opportunities should have a P/E ratio that is just the reciprocal of the capitalization rate, k. As growth opportunities become a progressively more important component of the total value of the firm, the P/E ratio will increase. 7. The expected growth rate of earnings is related both to the firm’s expected profitability and to its dividend policy. The relationship can be expressed as g 5 (ROE on new investment) 3 (1 2 Dividend payout ratio) 8. You can relate any DDM to a simple capitalized earnings model by comparing the expected ROE on future investments to the market capitalization rate, k. If the two rates are equal, then the stock’s intrinsic value reduces to expected earnings per share (EPS) divided by k. 9. Many analysts form their estimates of a stock’s value by multiplying their forecast of next year’s EPS by a predicted P/E multiple. Some analysts mix the P/E approach with the dividend discount model. They use an earnings multiplier to forecast the terminal value of shares at a future date, and add the present value of that terminal value with the present value of all interim dividend payments. Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm KEY TERMS bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 624 10. The free cash flow approach is the one used most often in corporate finance. The analyst first estimates the value of the entire firm as the present value of expected future free cash flows to the entire firm and then subtracts the value of all claims other than equity. Alternatively, the free cash flows to equity can be discounted at a discount rate appropriate to the risk of the stock. 11. The models presented in this chapter can be used to explain and forecast the behavior of the aggregate stock market. The key macroeconomic variables that determine the level of stock prices in the aggregate are interest rates and corporate profits. book value liquidation value replacement cost Tobin’s q intrinsic value of a share market capitalization rate dividend discount model (DDM) constant-growth DDM dividend payout ratio plowback ratio earnings retention ratio present value of growth opportunities (PVGO) price–earnings multiple earnings management 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Intrinsic value: V0 5 Equity Valuation Models D2 D1 D H 1 PH 1 1 c1 (1 1 k)H 11k (1 1 k)2 Constant growth DDM: V0 5 KEY EQUATIONS D1 k2g Growth opportunities: Price 5 Determinant of P/E ratio: 625 E1 1 PVGO k P0 1 PVGO 5 ¢1 1 ≤ E1 k E1/k Free cash flow to the firm: FCFF 5 EBIT(1 2 tc) 1 Depreciation 2 Capital expenditures 2 Increases in NWC 1. In what circumstances would you choose to use a dividend discount model rather than a free cash flow model to value a firm? PROBLEM SETS 2. In what circumstances is it most important to use multistage dividend discount models rather than constant-growth models? 3. If a security is underpriced (i.e., intrinsic value . price), then what is the relationship between its market capitalization rate and its expected rate of return? Basic 4. Deployment Specialists pays a current (annual) dividend of $1.00 and is expected to grow at 20% for 2 years and then at 4% thereafter. If the required return for Deployment Specialists is 8.5%, what is the intrinsic value of Deployment Specialists stock? 5. Jand, Inc., currently pays a dividend of $1.22, which is expected to grow indefinitely at 5%. If the current value of Jand’s shares based on the constant-growth dividend discount model is $32.03, what is the required rate of return? 6. A firm pays a current dividend of $1.00 which is expected to grow at a rate of 5% indefinitely. If current value of the firm’s shares is $35.00, what is the required return applicable to the investment based on the constant-growth dividend discount model (DDM)? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Free cash flow to equity: FCFE 5 FCFF 2 Interest expense 3 (1 2 tc) 1 Increases in net debt 7. Tri-coat Paints has a current market value of $41 per share with earnings of $3.64. What is the present value of its growth opportunities (PVGO) if the required return is 9%? 8. a. Computer stocks currently provide an expected rate of return of 16%. MBI, a large computer company, will pay a year-end dividend of $2 per share. If the stock is selling at $50 per share, what must be the market’s expectation of the growth rate of MBI dividends? b. If dividend growth forecasts for MBI are revised downward to 5% per year, what will happen to the price of MBI stock? What (qualitatively) will happen to the company’s price– earnings ratio? Intermediate 9. a. MF Corp. has an ROE of 16% and a plowback ratio of 50%. If the coming year’s earnings are expected to be $2 per share, at what price will the stock sell? The market capitalization rate is 12%. b. What price do you expect MF shares to sell for in 3 years? 10. The market consensus is that Analog Electronic Corporation has an ROE 5 9%, has a beta of 1.25, and plans to maintain indefinitely its traditional plowback ratio of 2/3. This year’s earnings were $3 per share. The annual dividend was just paid. The consensus estimate of the coming year’s market return is 14%, and T-bills currently offer a 6% return. a. Find the price at which Analog stock should sell. b. Calculate the P/E ratio. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 625 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 626 PART V Security Analysis c. Calculate the present value of growth opportunities. d. Suppose your research convinces you Analog will announce momentarily that it will immediately reduce its plowback ratio to 1/3. Find the intrinsic value of the stock. The market is still unaware of this decision. Explain why V0 no longer equals P0 and why V0 is greater or less than P0. 11. The FI Corporation’s dividends per share are expected to grow indefinitely by 5% per year. a. If this year’s year-end dividend is $8 and the market capitalization rate is 10% per year, what must the current stock price be according to the DDM? b. If the expected earnings per share are $12, what is the implied value of the ROE on future investment opportunities? c. How much is the market paying per share for growth opportunities (i.e., for an ROE on future investments that exceeds the market capitalization rate)? 12. The stock of Nogro Corporation is currently selling for $10 per share. Earnings per share in the coming year are expected to be $2. The company has a policy of paying out 50% of its earnings each year in dividends. The rest is retained and invested in projects that earn a 20% rate of return per year. This situation is expected to continue indefinitely. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. Assuming the current market price of the stock reflects its intrinsic value as computed using the constant-growth DDM, what rate of return do Nogro’s investors require? b. By how much does its value exceed what it would be if all earnings were paid as dividends and nothing were reinvested? c. If Nogro were to cut its dividend payout ratio to 25%, what would happen to its stock price? What if Nogro eliminated the dividend? 13. The risk-free rate of return is 8%, the expected rate of return on the market portfolio is 15%, and the stock of Xyrong Corporation has a beta coefficient of 1.2. Xyrong pays out 40% of its earnings in dividends, and the latest earnings announced were $10 per share. Dividends were just paid and are expected to be paid annually. You expect that Xyrong will earn an ROE of 20% per year on all reinvested earnings forever. a. What is the intrinsic value of a share of Xyrong stock? b. If the market price of a share is currently $100, and you expect the market price to be equal to the intrinsic value 1 year from now, what is your expected 1-year holding-period return on Xyrong stock? 14. The Digital Electronic Quotation System (DEQS) Corporation pays no cash dividends currently and is not expected to for the next 5 years. Its latest EPS was $10, all of which was reinvested in the company. The firm’s expected ROE for the next 5 years is 20% per year, and during this time it is expected to continue to reinvest all of its earnings. Starting in year 6, the firm’s ROE on new investments is expected to fall to 15%, and the company is expected to start paying out 40% of its earnings in cash dividends, which it will continue to do forever after. DEQS’s market capitalization rate is 15% per year. a. What is your estimate of DEQS’s intrinsic value per share? b. Assuming its current market price is equal to its intrinsic value, what do you expect to happen to its price over the next year? The year after? c. What effect would it have on your estimate of DEQS’s intrinsic value if you expected DEQS to pay out only 20% of earnings starting in year 6? eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 15. Recalculate the intrinsic value of Honda in each of the following scenarios by using the threestage growth model of Spreadsheet 18.1 (available at www.mhhe.com/bkm; link to Chapter 18 material). Treat each scenario independently. a. ROE in the constant-growth period will be 9%. b. Honda’s actual beta is 1.0. c. The market risk premium is 8.5%. eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 626 16. Recalculate the intrinsic value of Honda shares using the free cash flow model of Spreadsheet 18.2 (available at www.mhhe.com/bkm; link to Chapter 18 material) under each of the following assumptions. Treat each scenario independently. 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 627 a. Honda’s P/E ratio starting in 2016 will be 15. b. Honda’s unlevered beta is 0.7. c. The market risk premium is 9%. 17. The Duo Growth Company just paid a dividend of $1 per share. The dividend is expected to grow at a rate of 25% per year for the next 3 years and then to level off to 5% per year forever. You think the appropriate market capitalization rate is 20% per year. a. What is your estimate of the intrinsic value of a share of the stock? b. If the market price of a share is equal to this intrinsic value, what is the expected dividend yield? c. What do you expect its price to be 1 year from now? Is the implied capital gain consistent with your estimate of the dividend yield and the market capitalization rate? a. What is your estimate of GG’s intrinsic value per share? b. Assuming its current market price is equal to its intrinsic value, what do you expect to happen to its price over the next year? 19. The MoMi Corporation’s cash flow from operations before interest and taxes was $2 million in the year just ended, and it expects that this will grow by 5% per year forever. To make this happen, the firm will have to invest an amount equal to 20% of pretax cash flow each year. The tax rate is 35%. Depreciation was $200,000 in the year just ended and is expected to grow at the same rate as the operating cash flow. The appropriate market capitalization rate for the unleveraged cash flow is 12% per year, and the firm currently has debt of $4 million outstanding. Use the free cash flow approach to value the firm’s equity. 20. Chiptech, Inc., is an established computer chip firm with several profitable existing products as well as some promising new products in development. The company earned $1 a share last year, and just paid out a dividend of $.50 per share. Investors believe the company plans to maintain its dividend payout ratio at 50%. ROE equals 20%. Everyone in the market expects this situation to persist indefinitely. a. What is the market price of Chiptech stock? The required return for the computer chip industry is 15%, and the company has just gone ex-dividend (i.e., the next dividend will be paid a year from now, at t 5 1). b. Suppose you discover that Chiptech’s competitor has developed a new chip that will eliminate Chiptech’s current technological advantage in this market. This new product, which will be ready to come to the market in 2 years, will force Chiptech to reduce the prices of its chips to remain competitive. This will decrease ROE to 15%, and, because of falling demand for its product, Chiptech will decrease the plowback ratio to .40. The plowback ratio will be decreased at the end of the second year, at t 5 2: The annual year-end dividend for the second year (paid at t 5 2) will be 60% of that year’s earnings. What is your estimate of Chiptech’s intrinsic value per share? (Hint: Carefully prepare a table of Chiptech’s earnings and dividends for each of the next 3 years. Pay close attention to the change in the payout ratio in t 5 2.) c. No one else in the market perceives the threat to Chiptech’s market. In fact, you are confident that no one else will become aware of the change in Chiptech’s competitive status until the competitor firm publicly announces its discovery near the end of year 2. What will be the rate of return on Chiptech stock in the coming year (i.e., between t 5 0 and t 5 1)? In the second year (between t 5 1 and t 5 2)? The third year (between t 5 2 and t 5 3)? (Hint: Pay attention to when the market catches on to the new situation. A table of dividends and market prices over time might help.) bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 627 Challenge Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 18. The Generic Genetic (GG) Corporation pays no cash dividends currently and is not expected to for the next 4 years. Its latest EPS was $5, all of which was reinvested in the company. The firm’s expected ROE for the next 4 years is 20% per year, during which time it is expected to continue to reinvest all of its earnings. Starting in year 5, the firm’s ROE on new investments is expected to fall to 15% per year. GG’s market capitalization rate is 15% per year. 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 628 PART V Security Analysis 1. At Litchfield Chemical Corp. (LCC), a director of the company said that the use of dividend discount models by investors is “proof ” that the higher the dividend, the higher the stock price. a. Using a constant-growth dividend discount model as a basis of reference, evaluate the director’s statement. b. Explain how an increase in dividend payout would affect each of the following (holding all other factors constant): i. Sustainable growth rate. ii. Growth in book value. 2. Helen Morgan, CFA, has been asked to use the DDM to determine the value of Sundanci, Inc. Morgan anticipates that Sundanci’s earnings and dividends will grow at 32% for 2 years and 13% thereafter. Calculate the current value of a share of Sundanci stock by using a two-stage dividend discount model and the data from Tables 18A and 18B. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 3. Abbey Naylor, CFA, has been directed to determine the value of Sundanci’s stock using the Free Cash Flow to Equity (FCFE) model. Naylor believes that Sundanci’s FCFE will grow at 27% for 2 years and 13% thereafter. Capital expenditures, depreciation, and working capital are all expected to increase proportionately with FCFE. a. Calculate the amount of FCFE per share for the year 2011, using the data from Table 18A. b. Calculate the current value of a share of Sundanci stock based on the two-stage FCFE model. c. i. Describe one limitation of the two-stage DDM model that is addressed by using the twostage FCFE model. ii. Describe one limitation of the two-stage DDM model that is not addressed by using the two-stage FCFE model. Table 18A Sundanci actual 2010 and 2011 financial statements for fiscal years ending May 31 ($ million, except pershare data) Income Statement Revenue Depreciation Other operating costs 2011 $ 474 $ 598 20 23 368 460 Income before taxes 86 115 Taxes 26 35 Net income 60 80 Dividends 18 24 Earnings per share $0.714 $0.952 Dividend per share $0.214 $0.286 Common shares outstanding (millions) 84.0 84.0 Balance Sheet 2010 2011 Current assets $ 201 $ 326 474 489 Total assets 675 815 Current liabilities 57 141 Long-term debt 0 0 Net property, plant and equipment Total liabilities Shareholders’ equity Total liabilities and equity Capital expenditures bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 628 2010 57 141 618 674 675 815 34 38 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Required rate of return on equity 14% Growth rate of industry 13% Industry P/E ratio 26 Equity Valuation Models 629 Table 18B Selected financial information 4. Christie Johnson, CFA, has been assigned to analyze Sundanci using the constant dividend growth price/earnings (P/E) ratio model. Johnson assumes that Sundanci’s earnings and dividends will grow at a constant rate of 13%. a. Calculate the P/E ratio based on information in Tables 18A and 18B and on Johnson’s assumptions for Sundanci. b. Identify, within the context of the constant dividend growth model, how each of the following factors would affect the P/E ratio. 5. Dynamic Communication is a U.S. industrial company with several electronics divisions. The company has just released its 2013 annual report. Tables 18C and 18D present a summary of Dynamic’s financial statements for the years 2012 and 2013. Selected data from the financial statements for the years 2009 to 2011 are presented in Table 18E. a. A group of Dynamic shareholders has expressed concern about the zero growth rate of dividends in the last 4 years and has asked for information about the growth of the company. Calculate Dynamic’s sustainable growth rates in 2010 and 2013. Your calculations should use beginning-of-year balance sheet data. b. Determine how the change in Dynamic’s sustainable growth rate (2013 compared to 2010) was affected by changes in its retention ratio and its financial leverage. (Note: Your calculations should use beginning-of-year balance sheet data.) Table 18C $ Million 2013 2012 Cash and equivalents Accounts receivable $ 149 295 $ Inventory Total current assets 275 $ 719 285 $ 633 Gross fixed assets Accumulated depreciation Net fixed assets 9,350 (6,160) $3,190 8,900 (5,677) $3,223 Total assets $3,909 $3,856 Accounts payable Notes payable Accrued taxes and expenses $ 228 0 0 $ 220 0 0 Total current liabilities $ 228 $ 220 Long-term debt $1,650 $1,800 Common stock 50 50 Additional paid-in capital Retained earnings Total shareholders’ equity 0 1,981 $2,031 0 1,786 $1,836 Total liabilities and shareholders’ equity $3,909 $3,856 bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 629 83 265 Dynamic Communication balance sheets Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm • Risk (beta) of Sundanci. • Estimated growth rate of earnings and dividends. • Market risk premium. 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 630 PART V Security Analysis Table 18D Dynamic Communication statements of income (U.S. $ millions except for share data) 2013 2012 Total revenues Operating costs and expenses Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA) Depreciation and amortization $3,425 2,379 $1,046 $3,300 2,319 $ 981 483 454 Operating income (EBIT) $ 563 $ 527 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Interest expense 104 107 Income before taxes Taxes (40%) Net income $ 459 184 $ 275 $ 420 168 $ 252 Dividends Change in retained earnings $ 80 $ 195 $ 80 $ 172 Earnings per share Dividends per share $ 2.75 $ 0.80 $ 2.52 $ 0.80 100 100 Number of shares outstanding (millions) Table 18E Dynamic Communication selected data from financial statements (U.S. $ millions except for share data) Total revenues Operating income (EBIT) Interest expense Net income Dividends per share Total assets Long-term debt Total shareholders’ equity Number of shares outstanding (millions) 2011 2010 2009 $3,175 495 104 $ 235 $ 0.80 $3,625 $1,750 $1,664 $3,075 448 101 $ 208 $ 0.80 $3,414 $1,700 $1,509 $3,000 433 99 $ 200 $ 0.80 $3,230 $1,650 $1,380 100 100 100 6. Mike Brandreth, an analyst who specializes in the electronics industry, is preparing a research report on Dynamic Communication. A colleague suggests to Brandreth that he may be able to determine Dynamic’s implied dividend growth rate from Dynamic’s current common stock price, using the Gordon growth model. Brandreth believes that the appropriate required rate of return for Dynamic’s equity is 8%. a. Assume that the firm’s current stock price of $58.49 equals intrinsic value. What sustained rate of dividend growth as of December 2013 is implied by this value? Use the constantgrowth dividend discount model (i.e., the Gordon growth model). b. The management of Dynamic has indicated to Brandreth and other analysts that the company’s current dividend policy will be continued. Is the use of the Gordon growth model to value Dynamic’s common stock appropriate or inappropriate? Justify your response based on the assumptions of the Gordon growth model. 7. Peninsular Research is initiating coverage of a mature manufacturing industry. John Jones, CFA, head of the research department, gathered the following fundamental industry and market data to help in his analysis: Forecast industry earnings retention rate Forecast industry return on equity Industry beta Government bond yield Equity risk premium bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 630 40% 25% 1.2 6% 5% 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Equity Valuation Models 631 a. Compute the price-to-earnings (P0 /E1) ratio for the industry based on this fundamental data. b. Jones wants to analyze how fundamental P/E ratios might differ among countries. He gathered the following economic and market data: Fundamental Factors Forecast growth in real GDP Government bond yield Equity risk premium Country A Country B 5% 10% 5% 2% 6% 4% Determine whether each of these fundamental factors would cause P/E ratios to be generally higher for Country A or higher for Country B. 8. Janet Ludlow’s firm requires all its analysts to use a two-stage dividend discount model (DDM) and the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) to value stocks. Using the CAPM and DDM, Ludlow has valued QuickBrush Company at $63 per share. She now must value SmileWhite Corporation. a. Calculate the required rate of return for SmileWhite by using the information in the following table: Beta Market price Intrinsic value Notes: Risk-free rate Expected market return 1.35 $45.00 $63.00 SmileWhite 1.15 $30.00 ? 4.50% 14.50% b. Ludlow estimates the following EPS and dividend growth rates for SmileWhite: First 3 years Years thereafter 12% per year 9% per year Estimate the intrinsic value of SmileWhite by using the table above, and the two-stage DDM. Dividends per share in the most recent year were $1.72. c. Recommend QuickBrush or SmileWhite stock for purchase by comparing each company’s intrinsic value with its current market price. d. Describe one strength of the two-stage DDM in comparison with the constant-growth DDM. Describe one weakness inherent in all DDMs. 9. Rio National Corp. is a U.S.-based company and the largest competitor in its industry. Tables 18F–18I present financial statements and related information for the company. Table 18J presents relevant industry and market data. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm QuickBrush The portfolio manager of a large mutual fund comments to one of the fund’s analysts, Katrina Shaar: “We have been considering the purchase of Rio National Corp. equity shares, so I would like you to analyze the value of the company. To begin, based on Rio National’s past performance, you can assume that the company will grow at the same rate as the industry.” a. Calculate the value of a share of Rio National equity on December 31, 2013, using the Gordon constant-growth model and the capital asset pricing model. b. Calculate the sustainable growth rate of Rio National on December 31, 2013. Use 2013 beginning-of-year balance sheet values. 10. While valuing the equity of Rio National Corp. (from the previous problem), Katrina Shaar is considering the use of either cash flow from operations (CFO) or free cash flow to equity (FCFE) in her valuation process. a. State two adjustments that Shaar should make to cash flow from operations to obtain free cash flow to equity. b. Shaar decides to calculate Rio National’s FCFE for the year 2013, starting with net income. Determine for each of the five supplemental notes given in Table 18H whether an adjustment should be made to net income to calculate Rio National’s free cash flow to equity for the year 2013, and the dollar amount of any adjustment. c. Calculate Rio National’s free cash flow to equity for the year 2013. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 631 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 632 PART V Security Analysis Table 18F Rio National Corp. summary year-end balance sheets (U.S. $ millions) 2013 2012 Cash Accounts receivable Inventory $ 13.00 30.00 209.06 $ 5.87 27.00 189.06 Current assets Gross fixed assets Accumulated depreciation $252.06 474.47 (154.17) $221.93 409.47 (90.00) 320.30 319.47 Total assets Accounts payable Notes payable Current portion of long-term debt $572.36 $ 25.05 0.00 0.00 $541.40 $ 26.05 0.00 0.00 Current liabilities Long-term debt $ 25.05 240.00 $ 26.05 245.00 Total liabilities Common stock Retained earnings $265.05 160.00 147.31 $271.05 150.00 120.35 Total shareholders’ equity $307.31 $270.35 Total liabilities and shareholders’ equity $572.36 $541.40 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Net fixed assets Table 18G Rio National Corp. summary income statement for the year ended December 31, 2013 (U.S. $ millions) Revenue Total operating expenses Operating profit Gain on sale 127.06 4.00 Earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation & amortization (EBITDA) Depreciation and amortization 131.06 Earnings before interest & taxes (EBIT) Interest Income tax expense 59.89 (16.80) (12.93) Net income Table 18H Rio National Corp. supplemental notes for 2013 Note 1: Note 2: Note 3: Note 4: Note 5: bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 632 $300.80 (173.74) (71.17) $ 30.16 Rio National had $75 million in capital expenditures during the year. A piece of equipment that was originally purchased for $10 million was sold for $7 million at year-end, when it had a net book value of $3 million. Equipment sales are unusual for Rio National. The decrease in long-term debt represents an unscheduled principal repayment; there was no new borrowing during the year. On January 1, 2013, the company received cash from issuing 400,000 shares of common equity at a price of $25.00 per share. A new appraisal during the year increased the estimated market value of land held for investment by $2 million, which was not recognized in 2013 income. 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 18 Dividends paid (U.S. $ millions) $3.20 Weighted-average shares outstanding during 2013 Dividend per share Earnings per share Beta 16,000,000 $0.20 $1.89 1.80 Equity Valuation Models 633 Table 18I Rio National Corp. common equity data for 2013 Note: The dividend payout ratio is expected to be constant. 4.00% 9.00% 19.90 12.00% Table 18J Industry and market data December 31, 2013 11. Shaar (from the previous problem) has revised slightly her estimated earnings growth rate for Rio National and, using normalized (underlying) EPS, which is adjusted for temporary impacts on earnings, now wants to compare the current value of Rio National’s equity to that of the industry, on a growth-adjusted basis. Selected information about Rio National and the industry is given in Table 18K. Compared to the industry, is Rio National’s equity overvalued or undervalued on a P/E-togrowth (PEG) basis, using normalized (underlying) earnings per share? Assume that the risk of Rio National is similar to the risk of the industry. Table 18K Rio National Estimated earnings growth rate 11.00% Current share price Normalized (underlying) EPS for 2011 Weighted-average shares outstanding during 2011 Rio National Corp. vs. industry $25.00 $1.71 16,000,000 Industry Estimated earnings growth rate Median price/earnings (P/E) ratio 12.00% 19.90 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Risk-free rate of return Expected rate of return on market index Median industry price/earnings (P/E) ratio Expected industry earnings growth rate E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES Go to the MoneyCentral Investor page at moneycentral.msn.com/investor/home.asp. Use the Research Wizard function under Guided Research to obtain fundamentals, price history, price target, catalysts, and comparison for Walmart (WMT). For comparison, use Target (TGT), BJ’s Wholesale Club (BJ), and the industry. 1. What has been the 1-year sales and income growth for Walmart? 2. What has been the company’s 5-year profit margin? How does that compare with the other two firms’ profit margins and the industry’s profit margin? 3. What have been the percentage price changes for the last 3, 6, and 12 months? How do they compare with the other firms’ price changes and the industry’s price changes? 4. What are the estimated high and low prices for Walmart for the coming year based on its current P/E multiple? 5. Compare the price performance of Walmart with that of Target and BJ’s. Which of the companies appears to be the most expensive in terms of current earnings? Which of the companies is the least expensive in terms of current earnings? 6. What are the firms’ Stock Scouter Ratings? How are these ratings interpreted? bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 633 7/17/13 4:09 PM Final PDF to printer 634 PART V Security Analysis SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. a. Dividend yield 5 $2.15/$50 5 4.3%. Capital gains yield 5 (59.77 2 50) /50 5 19.54%. Total return 5 4.3% 1 19.54% 5 23.84%. b. k 5 6% 1 1.15(14% 2 6%) 5 15.2%. c. V0 5 ($2.15 1 $59.77)/1.152 5 $53.75, which exceeds the market price. This would indicate a “buy” opportunity. 2. a. D1/(k 2 g) 5 $2.15/(.152 2 .112) 5 $53.75. b. P1 5 P0(1 1 g) 5 $53.75(1.112) 5 $59.77. c. The expected capital gain equals $59.77 2 $53.75 5 $6.02, for a percentage gain of 11.2%. The dividend yield is D1/P0 5 2.15/53.75 5 4%, for a holding-period return of 4% 1 11.2% 5 15.2%. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 3. a. g 5 ROE 3 b 5 20% 3 .60 5 12%. D1 5 .4 3 E1 5 .4 3 $5 5 $2. P0 5 $2/(.125 2 .12) 5 $400. b. When the firm invests in projects with ROE less than k, its stock price falls. If b 5 .60, then g 5 10% 3 .60 5 6% and P0 5 $2/(.125 2 .06) 5 $30.77. In contrast, if b 5 0, then P0 5 $5/.125 5 $40. 1.00 1 P2016 .78 .92 .85 1 1 1 2 3 (1.096) (1.096) (1.096) (1.096)4 Now compute the sales price in 2016 using the constant-growth dividend discount model. The growth rate will be g 5 ROE 3 b 5 9% 3 .75 5 6.75%. 1.00 3 (1 1 g) $1.0675 P2016 5 5 5 $37.46 k2g .096 2 .0675 4. V2012 5 Therefore, V2012 5 $28.77. 5. a. ROE 5 12%. b 5 $.50/$2.00 5 .25. g 5 ROE 3 b 5 12% 3 .25 5 3%. P0 5 D1/(k 2 g) 5 $1.50/(.10 2 .03) 5 $21.43. P0/E1 5 $21.43/$2.00 5 10.71. b. If b 5 .4, then .4 3 $2 5 $.80 would be reinvested and the remainder of earnings, or $1.20, would be paid as dividends. g 5 12% 3 .4 5 4.8%. P0 5 D1/(k 2 g) 5 $1.20/(.10 2 .048) 5 $23.08. P0/E1 5 $23.08/$2.00 5 11.54. bod61671_ch18_591-634.indd 634 7/17/13 4:09 PM 20 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER TWENTY Options Markets: Introduction crowding out the previously existing overthe-counter options market. Option contracts are traded now on several exchanges. They are written on common stock, stock indexes, foreign exchange, agricultural commodities, precious metals, and interest rate futures. In addition, the over-the-counter market has enjoyed a tremendous resurgence in recent years as trading in custom-tailored options has exploded. Popular and potent tools in modifying portfolio characteristics, options have become essential tools a portfolio manager must understand. This chapter is an introduction to options markets. It explains how puts and calls work and examines their investment characteristics. Popular option strategies are considered next. Finally, we examine a range of securities with embedded options such as callable or convertible bonds, and we take a quick look at some so-called exotic options. PART VI DERIVATIVE SECURITIES, OR more simply derivatives, play a large and increasingly important role in financial markets. These are securities whose prices are determined by, or “derive from,” the prices of other securities. Options and futures contracts are both derivative securities. Their payoffs depend on the value of other securities. Swaps, which we will discuss in Chapter 23, also are derivatives. Because the value of derivatives depends on the value of other securities, they can be powerful tools for both hedging and speculation. We will investigate these applications in the next four chapters, starting in this chapter with options. Trading of standardized options contracts on a national exchange started in 1973 when the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) began listing call options. These contracts were almost immediately a great success, bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 678 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 679 20.1 The Option Contract A call option gives its holder the right to purchase an asset for a specified price, called the exercise, or strike, price, on or before some specified expiration date. For example, a February call option on IBM stock with exercise price $195 entitles its owner to purchase IBM stock for a price of $195 at any time up to and including the expiration date in February. The holder of the call is not required to exercise the option. She will choose to exercise only if the market value of the underlying asset exceeds the exercise price. In that case, the option holder may “call away” the asset for the exercise price. Otherwise, the option may be left unexercised. If it is not exercised before the expiration date of the contract, a call option simply expires and becomes valueless. Therefore, if the stock price is greater than the exercise price on the expiration date, the value of the call option equals the difference between the stock price and the exercise price; but if the stock price is less than the exercise price at expiration, the call will be worthless. The net profit on the call is the value of the option minus the price originally paid to purchase it. The purchase price of the option is called the premium. It represents the compensation the purchaser of the call must pay for the right to exercise the option only when exercise is desirable. Sellers of call options, who are said to write calls, receive premium income now as payment against the possibility they will be required at some later date to deliver the asset in return for an exercise price less than the market value of the asset. If the option is left to expire worthless, the writer of the call clears a profit equal to the premium income derived from the initial sale of the option. But if the call is exercised, the profit to the option writer is the premium income minus the difference between the value of the stock that must be delivered and the exercise price that is paid for those shares. If that difference is larger than the initial premium, the writer will incur a loss. Example 20.1 Profits and Losses on a Call Option Consider the February 2013 expiration call option on a share of IBM with an exercise price of $195 selling on January 18, 2013, for $3.65. Exchange-traded options expire on the third Friday of the expiration month, which for this option was February 15. Until the expiration date, the call holder may buy shares of IBM for $195. On January 18, IBM sells for $194.47. Because the stock price is only $194.47, it clearly would not make sense at the moment to exercise the option to buy at $195. Indeed, if IBM remains below $195 by the expiration date, the call will be left to expire worthless. On the other hand, if IBM is selling above $195 at expiration, the call holder will find it optimal to exercise. For example, if IBM sells for $197 on February 15, the option will be exercised, as it will give its holder the right to pay $195 for a stock worth $197. The value of each option on the expiration date would then be Value at expiration 5 Stock price 2 Exercise price 5 $197 2 $195 5 $2 Despite the $2 payoff at expiration, the call holder still realizes a loss of $1.65 on the investment because the initial purchase price was $3.65: Profit 5 Final value 2 Original investment 5 $2.00 2 $3.65 5 2$1.65 bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 679 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 680 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Nevertheless, exercise of the call is optimal at expiration if the stock price exceeds the exercise price because the exercise proceeds will offset at least part of the purchase price. The call buyer will clear a profit if IBM is selling above $198.65 at the expiration date. At that stock price, the proceeds from exercise will just cover the original cost of the call. A put option gives its holder the right to sell an asset for a specified exercise or strike price on or before some expiration date. A February expiration put on IBM with an exercise price of $195 entitles its owner to sell IBM stock to the put writer at a price of $195 at any time before expiration in February even if the market price of IBM is less than $195. Whereas profits on call options increase when the asset price rises, profits on put options increase when the asset price falls. A put will be exercised only if the exercise price is greater than the price of the underlying asset, that is, only if its holder can deliver for the exercise price an asset with market value less than that amount. (One doesn’t need to own the shares of IBM to exercise the IBM put option. Upon exercise, the investor’s broker purchases the necessary shares of IBM at the market price and immediately delivers, or “puts them,” to an option writer for the exercise price. The owner of the put profits by the difference between the exercise price and market price.) Example 20.2 Profits and Losses on a Put Option Now consider the February 2013 expiration put option on IBM with an exercise price of $195, selling on January 18 for $5.00. It entitled its owner to sell a share of IBM for $195 at any time until February 15. If the holder of the put buys a share of IBM and immediately exercises the right to sell it at $195, net proceeds will be $195 2 $194.47 5 $.53. Obviously, an investor who pays $5 for the put has no intention of exercising it immediately. If, on the other hand, IBM were selling for $188 at expiration, the put would turn out to be a profitable investment. Its value at expiration would be Value at expiration 5 Exercise price 2 Stock price 5 $195 2 $188 5 $7 and the investor’s profit would be $7 2 $5 5 $2. This is a holding period return of $2/$5 5 .40, or 40%—over only 28 days! Obviously, put option sellers on January 18 (who are on the other side of the transaction) did not consider this outcome very likely. An option is described as in the money when its exercise would produce a positive cash flow. Therefore, a call option is in the money when the asset price is greater than the exercise price, and a put option is in the money when the asset price is less than the exercise price. Conversely, a call is out of the money when the asset price is less than the exercise price; no one would exercise the right to purchase for the strike price an asset worth less than that amount. A put option is out of the money when the exercise price is less than the asset price. Options are at the money when the exercise price and asset price are equal. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 680 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 681 Options Trading Some options trade on over-the-counter markets. The OTC PRICES AT CLOSE JANUARY 18, 2013 market offers the advantage that the terms of the option contract—the exercise price, expiration date, and number I B M (IBM) Underlying Stock Price: 194.47 of shares committed—can be tailored to the needs of the Call Put traders. The costs of establishing an OTC option contract, Open Open Expiration Strike Last Volume Interest Last Volume Interest however, are higher than for exchange-traded options. 185 9.15 Jan 307 2431 0.76 302 2488 Options contracts traded on exchanges are standard185 10.60 Feb 299 2 1.82 710 3645 185 12.00 Apr 41 706 3.60 104 2047 ized by allowable expiration dates and exercise prices for 185 14.35 Jul 37 134 6.55 37 1354 190 4.40 Jan 815 5697 1.75 507 2496 each listed option. Each stock option contract provides 190 6.75 Feb 402 2808 3.00 3553 10377 for the right to buy or sell 100 shares of stock (except 190 8.85 Apr 107 1866 5.20 527 2177 190 10.95 Jul 15 645 8.54 6 1142 when stock splits occur after the contract is listed and 195 0.01 Jan 2451 11718 0.70 4090 8862 195 3.65 Feb 1337 11902 5.00 860 3156 the contract is adjusted for the terms of the split). 195 5.90 Apr 1785 2928 7.30 934 1141 195 8.45 Jul 13 5773 10.85 22 3419 Standardization of the terms of listed option contracts 200 1.10 Jan 1248 2966 5.55 637 6199 means all market participants trade in a limited and uni200 1.61 Feb 1053 5530 8.09 546 967 200 3.70 Apr 629 3236 10.05 375 1903 form set of securities. This increases the depth of trad200 6.10 Jul 80 1257 ... ... 1105 ing in any particular option, which lowers trading costs and results in a more competitive market. Exchanges, therefore, offer two important benefits: ease of trading, which flows from a central marketplace where buyFigure 20.1 Stock options on IBM closing prices ers and sellers or their representatives congregate; and as of January 18, 2013 a liquid secondary market where buyers and sellers of Source: The Wall Street Journal Online, January 18, 2013. options can transact quickly and cheaply. Until recently, most options trading in the United States took place on the Chicago Board Options Exchange. However, by 2003 the International Securities Exchange, an electronic exchange based in New York, displaced the CBOE as the largest options market. Options trading in Europe is uniformly transacted in electronic exchanges. Figure 20.1 is a selection of listed stock option quotations for IBM. The last recorded price on the New York Stock Exchange for IBM shares was $194.47 per share.1 The exercise (or strike) prices bracket the stock price. While exercise prices generally are set at five-point intervals, larger intervals sometimes are set for stocks selling above $100, and intervals of $2.50 may be used for stocks selling at low prices. If the stock price moves outside the range of exercise prices of the existing set of options, new options with appropriate exercise prices may be offered. Therefore, at any time, both in-the-money and out-of-themoney options will be listed, as in this example. Figure 20.1 shows both call and put options listed for each expiration date and exercise price. The three sets of columns for each option report closing price, trading volume in contracts, and open interest (number of outstanding contracts). When we compare prices of call options with the same expiration date but different exercise prices in Figure 20.1, we see that the value of a call is lower when the exercise price is higher. This makes sense, because the right to purchase a share at a lower exercise price is more valuable than the right to purchase at a higher price. Thus the February expiration IBM call option with strike price $195 sells for $3.65 whereas the $200 exercise price February call sells for 1 Occasionally, this price may not match the closing price listed for the stock on the stock market page. This is because some NYSE stocks also trade on exchanges that close after the NYSE, and the stock pages may reflect the more recent closing price. The options exchanges, however, close with the NYSE, so the closing NYSE stock price is appropriate for comparison with the closing option price. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 681 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 682 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives only $1.61. Conversely, put options are worth more when the exercise price is higher: You would rather have the right to sell shares for $200 than for $195 and this is reflected in the prices of the puts. The February expiration put option with strike price $200 sells for $8.09, whereas the $195 exercise price February put sells for only $5. If an option does not trade on a given day, three dots will appear in the volume and price columns. Because trading is infrequent, it is not unusual to find option prices that appear out of line with other prices. You might see, for example, two calls with different exercise prices that seem to sell for the same price. This discrepancy arises because the last trades for these options may have occurred at different times during the day. At any moment, the call with the lower exercise price must be worth more than an otherwise-identical call with a higher exercise price. Expirations of most exchange-traded options tend to be fairly short, ranging up to only several months. For larger firms and several stock indexes, however, longer-term options are traded with expirations ranging up to several years. These options are called LEAPS (for Long-Term Equity AnticiPation Securities). CONCEPT CHECK 20.1 a. What will be the proceeds and net profits to an investor who purchases the February expiration IBM calls with exercise price $195 if the stock price at expiration is $205? What if the stock price at expiration is $185? b. Now answer part (a) for an investor who purchases a February expiration IBM put option with exercise price $195. American and European Options An American option allows its holder to exercise the right to purchase (if a call) or sell (if a put) the underlying asset on or before the expiration date. European options allow for exercise of the option only on the expiration date. American options, because they allow more leeway than their European counterparts, generally will be more valuable. Virtually all traded options in the United States are American style. Foreign currency options and stock index options are notable exceptions to this rule, however. Adjustments in Option Contract Terms Because options convey the right to buy or sell shares at a stated price, stock splits would radically alter their value if the terms of the options contract were not adjusted to account for the stock split. For example, reconsider the IBM call options in Figure 20.1. If IBM were to announce a 2-for-1 split, its share price would fall from about $195 to about $97.50. A call option with exercise price $195 would be just about worthless, with virtually no possibility that the stock would sell at more than $195 before the options expired. To account for a stock split, the exercise price is reduced by a factor of the split, and the number of options held is increased by that factor. For example, each original call option with exercise price of $195 would be altered after a 2-for-1 split to two new options, with each new option carrying an exercise price of $97.50. A similar adjustment is made for stock dividends of more than 10%; the number of shares covered by each option is increased in proportion to the stock dividend, and the exercise price is reduced by that proportion. In contrast to stock dividends, cash dividends do not affect the terms of an option contract. Because payment of a cash dividend reduces the selling price of the stock without bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 682 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 683 inducing offsetting adjustments in the option contract, the value of the option is affected by dividend policy. Other things being equal, call option values are lower for high-dividend payout policies, because such policies slow the rate of increase of stock prices; conversely, put values are higher for high-dividend payouts. (Of course, the option values do not necessarily rise or fall on the dividend payment or ex-dividend dates. Dividend payments are anticipated, so the effect of the payment already is built into the original option price.) CONCEPT CHECK 20.2 Suppose that IBM’s stock price at the exercise date is $200, and the exercise price of the call is $195. What is the payoff on one option contract? After a 2-for-1 split, the stock price is $100, the exercise price is $97.50, and the option holder now can purchase 200 shares. Show that the split leaves the payoff from the option unaffected. The Options Clearing Corporation The Options Clearing Corporation (OCC), the clearinghouse for options trading, is jointly owned by the exchanges on which stock options are traded. Buyers and sellers of options who agree on a price will strike a deal. At this point, the OCC steps in. The OCC places itself between the two traders, becoming the effective buyer of the option from the writer and the effective writer of the option to the buyer. All individuals, therefore, deal only with the OCC, which effectively guarantees contract performance. When an option holder exercises an option, the OCC arranges for a member firm with clients who have written that option to make good on the option obligation. The member firm selects from its clients who have written that option to fulfill the contract. The selected client must deliver 100 shares of stock at a price equal to the exercise price for each call option contract written or must purchase 100 shares at the exercise price for each put option contract written. Because the OCC guarantees contract performance, it requires option writers to post margin to guarantee that they can fulfill their contract obligations. The margin required is determined in part by the amount by which the option is in the money, because that value is an indicator of the potential obligation of the option writer. When the required margin exceeds the posted margin, the writer will receive a margin call. In contrast, the holder of the option need not post margin because the holder will exercise the option only if it is profitable to do so. After purchase of the option, no further money is at risk. Margin requirements are determined in part by the other securities held in the investor’s portfolio. For example, a call option writer owning the stock against which the option is written can satisfy the margin requirement simply by allowing a broker to hold that stock in the brokerage account. The stock is then guaranteed to be available for delivery should the call option be exercised. If the underlying security is not owned, however, the margin requirement is determined by the value of the underlying security as well as by the amount by which the option is in or out of the money. Out-of-the-money options require less margin from the writer, for expected payouts are lower. Other Listed Options Options on assets other than stocks are also widely traded. These include options on market indexes and industry indexes, on foreign currency, and even on the futures prices of agricultural products, gold, silver, fixed-income securities, and stock indexes. We will discuss these in turn. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 683 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 684 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Index Options An index option is a call or put based on a stock market index such as the S&P 500 or the NASDAQ 100. Index options are traded on several broad-based indexes as well as on several industry-specific indexes and even commodity price indexes. We discussed many of these indexes in Chapter 2. The construction of the indexes can vary across contracts or exchanges. For example, the S&P 100 index is a value-weighted average of the 100 stocks in the Standard & Poor’s 100 stock group. The weights are proportional to the market value of outstanding equity for each stock. The Dow Jones Industrial Index, by contrast, is a price-weighted average of 30 stocks. Option contracts on many foreign stock indexes also trade. For example, options on the (Japanese) Nikkei Stock Index trade on the Singapore as well as the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. Options on European indexes such as the Financial Times Share Exchange (FTSE 100) trade on the NYSE-Euronext Exchange. The Chicago Board Options Exchange also lists options on industry indexes such as the oil or high-tech industries. In contrast to stock options, index options do not require that the call writer actually “deliver the index” upon exercise or that the put writer “purchase the index.” Instead, a cash settlement procedure is used. The payoff that would accrue upon exercise of the option is calculated, and the option writer simply pays that amount to the option holder. The payoff is equal to the difference between the exercise price of the option and the value of the index. For example, if the S&P index is at 1400 when a call option on the index with exercise price 1390 is exercised, the holder of the call receives a cash payment of the difference, 1400 2 1390, times the contract multiplier of $100, or $1,000 per contract. Options on the major indexes, that is, the S&P 100 (often called the OEX after its ticker symbol), the S&P 500 (the SPX), the NASDAQ 100 (the NDX), and the Dow Jones Industrials (the DJX), are the most actively traded contracts on the CBOE. Together, these contracts dominate CBOE volume. Futures Options Futures options give their holders the right to buy or sell a specified futures contract, using as a futures price the exercise price of the option. Although the delivery process is slightly complicated, the terms of futures options contracts are designed in effect to allow the option to be written on the futures price itself. The option holder receives upon exercise a net payoff equal to the difference between the current futures price on the specified asset and the exercise price of the option. Thus if the futures price is, say, $37, and the call has an exercise price of $35, the holder who exercises the call option on the futures gets a payoff of $2. Foreign Currency Options A currency option offers the right to buy or sell a quantity of foreign currency for a specified amount of domestic currency. Currency option contracts call for purchase or sale of the currency in exchange for a specified number of U.S. dollars. Contracts are quoted in cents or fractions of a cent per unit of foreign currency. There is an important difference between currency options and currency futures options. The former provide payoffs that depend on the difference between the exercise price and the exchange rate at expiration. The latter are foreign exchange futures options that provide payoffs that depend on the difference between the exercise price and the exchange rate futures price at expiration. Because exchange rates and exchange rate futures prices generally are not equal, the options and futures-options contracts will have different values, even with identical expiration dates and exercise prices. Trading volume in currency futures options dominates trading in currency options. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 684 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 685 Interest Rate Options Options are traded on Treasury notes and bonds, Treasury bills, and government bonds of other major economies such as the U.K. or Japan. Options on several interest rates also trade. Among these are contracts on Treasury bond, Treasury note, federal funds, LIBOR, Euribor,2 and Eurodollar futures. 20.2 Values of Options at Expiration Call Options Recall that a call option gives the right to purchase a security at the exercise price. Suppose you hold a call option on FinCorp stock with an exercise price of $100, and FinCorp is now selling at $110. You can exercise your option to purchase the stock at $100 and simultaneously sell the shares at the market price of $110, clearing $10 per share. Yet if the shares sell below $100, you can sit on the option and do nothing, realizing no further gain or loss. The value of the call option at expiration equals Payoff to call holder 5 b ST 2 X 0 if ST . X if ST # X where ST is the value of the stock at expiration and X is the exercise price. This formula emphasizes the option property because the payoff cannot be negative. The option is exercised only if ST exceeds X. If ST is less than X, the option expires with zero value. The loss to the option holder in this case equals the price originally paid for the option. More generally, the profit to the option holder is the option payoff at expiration minus the original purchase price. The value at expiration of the call with exercise price $100 is given by the schedule: Stock price: Option value: $90 0 $100 0 $110 10 $120 20 $130 30 For stock prices at or below $100, the option is worthless. Above $100, the option is worth the excess of the stock price over $100. The option’s value increases by $1 for each dollar increase in the stock price. This relationship can be depicted graphically as in Figure 20.2. The solid line in Figure 20.2 is the value of the call at expiration. The net profit to the holder of the call equals the gross payoff less the initial investment in the call. Suppose the call cost $14. Then the profit to the call holder would be given by the dashed (bottom) line of Figure 20.2. At option expiration, the investor suffers a loss of $14 if the stock price is less than or equal to $100. Profits do not become positive until the stock price at expiration exceeds $114. The breakeven point is $114, because at that price the payoff to the call, ST 2 X 5 $114 2 $100 5 $14, equals the initial cost of the call. Conversely, the writer of the call incurs losses if the stock price is high. In that scenario, the writer will receive a call and will be obligated to deliver a stock worth ST for only X dollars: Payoff to call writer 5 b 2(ST 2 X) 0 if ST . X if ST # X 2 The Euribor market is similar to the LIBOR market (see Chapter 2), but the interest rate charged in the Euribor market is the interbank rate for euro-denominated deposits. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 685 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 686 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives $30 Payoff = Value at Expiration $20 $10 0 80 −$10 90 100 Cost of Option 110 120 ST The call writer, who is exposed to losses if the stock price increases, is willing to bear this risk in return for the option premium. Figure 20.3 depicts the payoff and profit diagrams for the call writer. These are the mirror images of the corresponding diagrams for call holders. The break-even point for the option writer also is $114. The (negative) payoff at that point just offsets the premium originally received when the option was written. Profit Put Options −$14 A put option is the right to sell an asset at the exercise price. In this case, the holder will not exercise the option unless the asset Figure 20.2 Payoff and profit to call option at expiration is worth less than the exercise price. For example, if FinCorp shares were to fall to $90, a put option with exercise price $100 could be exercised to clear $10 for its holder. The holder would purchase a share for $90 and simultaneously deliver it to the put option writer for the exercise price of $100. The value of a put option at expiration is Payoff to put holder 5 b 0 X 2 ST if ST $ X if ST , X The solid line in Figure 20.4 illustrates the payoff at expiration to the holder of a put option on FinCorp stock with an exercise price of $100. If the stock price at expiration is above $100, the put has no value, as the right to sell the shares at $100 would not be exercised. Below a price of $100, the put value at expiration increases by $1 for each dollar the stock price falls. The dashed line in Figure 20.4 is a graph of the put option owner’s profit at expiration, net of the initial cost of the put. Writing puts naked (i.e., writing a put without an offsetting short position in the stock for hedging purposes) exposes the writer to losses if the market falls. Writing naked, deep-out-of-the-money puts $14 was once considered an attractive way to generate income, as it was believed that ST 0 $100 $114 as long as the market did not fall sharply before the option expiration, the option Profit premium could be collected without the put holder ever exercising the option against the writer. Because only sharp Payoff drops in the market could result in losses to the put writer, the strategy was not viewed as overly risky. However, in the wake of the market crash of October 1987, such put writers suffered huge losses. ParFigure 20.3 Payoff and profit to call writers at expiration ticipants now perceive much greater risk to this strategy. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 686 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 CONCEPT CHECK 687 Options Markets: Introduction 20.3 Consider these four option strategies: (i) buy a call; (ii) write a call; (iii) buy a put; (iv) write a put. a. For each strategy, plot both the payoff and profit diagrams as a function of the final stock price. b. Why might one characterize both buying calls and writing puts as “bullish” strategies? What is the difference between them? c. Why might one characterize both buying puts and writing calls as “bearish” strategies? What is the difference between them? Option versus Stock Investments Purchasing call options is a bullish strat$100 egy; that is, the calls provide profits when stock prices increase. Purchasing puts, in contrast, is a bearish strategy. Symmetrically, writing calls is bearish, whereas Payoff = Value of Put at Expiration writing puts is bullish. Because option valProfit ues depend on the price of the underlying stock, purchase of options may be viewed as a substitute for direct purchase or sale of Price of Put a stock. Why might an option strategy be S 0 $100 preferable to direct stock transactions? For example, why would you purchase a call option rather than buy shares of stock directly? Maybe you have some information that leads you to believe the stock will Figure 20.4 Payoff and profit to put option at expiration increase in value from its current level, which in our examples we will take to be $100. You know your analysis could be incorrect, however, and that shares also could fall in price. Suppose a 6-month maturity call option with exercise price $100 currently sells for $10, and the interest rate for the period is 3%. Consider these three strategies for investing a sum of money, say, $10,000. For simplicity, suppose the firm will not pay any dividends until after the 6-month period. T Strategy A: Invest entirely in stock. Buy 100 shares, each selling for $100. Strategy B: Invest entirely in at-the-money call options. Buy 1,000 calls, each selling for $10. (This would require 10 contracts, each for 100 shares.) Strategy C: Purchase 100 call options for $1,000. Invest your remaining $9,000 in 6-month T-bills, to earn 3% interest. The bills will grow in value from $9,000 to $9,000 3 1.03 5 $9,270. Let us trace the possible values of these three portfolios when the options expire in 6 months as a function of the stock price at that time: Stock Price Portfolio Portfolio A: All stock Portfolio B: All options Portfolio C: Call plus bills bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 687 $95 $100 $105 $110 $115 $120 $9,500 0 9,270 $10,000 0 9,270 $10,500 5,000 9,770 $11,000 10,000 10,270 $11,500 15,000 10,770 $12,000 20,000 11,270 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 688 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Portfolio A will be worth 100 times the share price. Portfolio B is worthless unless shares sell for more than the exercise price of the call. Once that point is reached, the portfolio is worth 1,000 times the excess of the stock price over the exercise price. Finally, portfolio C is worth $9,270 from the investment in T-bills plus any profits from the 100 call options. Remember that each of these portfolios involves the same $10,000 initial investment. The rates of return on these three portfolios are as follows: Stock Price Portfolio Portfolio A: All stock Portfolio B: All options Portfolio C: Call plus bills $95 $100 $105 $110 $115 $120 25.0% 2100.0 27.3 0.0% 2100.0 27.3 5.0% 250.0 22.3 10.0% 0.0 2.7 15.0% 50.0 7.7 20.0% 100.0 12.7 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 100 102 104 106 108 110 112 114 116 118 120 Rate of Return (%) These rates of return are graphed in Figure 20.5. Comparing the returns of portfolios B and C to those of the simple investment in stock represented by portfolio A, we see that options offer two interesting features. First, an option offers leverage. Compare the returns of portfolios B and A. Unless the stock increases from its initial value of $100, the value of portfolio B falls precipitously to zero—a rate of return of negative 100%. Conversely, modest increases in the rate of return on the stock result in disproportionate increases in the option rate of return. For example, a 4.3% increase in the stock price from $115 to $120 would increase the rate of return on the call from 50% to 100%. In this sense, calls are a levered investment on the stock. Their values respond more than proportionately to changes in the stock value. Figure 20.5 vividly illustrates this point. The slope of the all-option portfolio is far steeper than that of the all-stock 100 portfolio, reflecting its greater propor80 tional sensitivity to the value of the underlying security. The leverage factor 60 is the reason investors (illegally) exploit40 ing inside information commonly choose options as their investment vehicle. 20 The potential insurance value of ST 0 options is the second interesting feature, as portfolio C shows. The T-bill-plus−20 option portfolio cannot be worth less −40 than $9,270 after 6 months, as the option can always be left to expire worthless. −60 The worst possible rate of return on portA: All Stocks −80 folio C is 27.3%, compared to a (theoB: All Options retically) worst possible rate of return on C: Call Plus Bills −100 the stock of 2100% if the company were −120 to go bankrupt. Of course, this insurance comes at a price: When the share price increases, portfolio C, the option-plusbills portfolio, does not perform as well Figure 20.5 Rate of return to three strategies as portfolio A, the all-stock portfolio. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 688 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 689 This simple example makes an important point. Although options can be used by speculators as effectively leveraged stock positions, as in portfolio B, they also can be used by investors who desire to tailor their risk exposures in creative ways, as in portfolio C. For example, the call-plus-bills strategy of portfolio C provides a rate of return profile quite unlike that of the stock alone. The absolute limitation on downside risk is a novel and attractive feature of this strategy. We next discuss several option strategies that provide other novel risk profiles that might be attractive to hedgers and other investors. 20.3 Option Strategies An unlimited variety of payoff patterns can be achieved by combining puts and calls with various exercise prices. We explain in this section the motivation and structure of some of the more popular ones. Protective Put Imagine you would like to invest in a stock, but you are unwilling to bear potential losses beyond some given level. Investing in the stock alone seems risky to you because in principle you could lose all the money you invest. You might consider instead investing in stock and purchasing a put option on the stock. Table 20.1 shows the total value of your portfolio at option expiration: Whatever happens to the stock price, you are guaranteed a payoff at least equal to the put option’s exercise price because the put gives you the right to sell your shares for that price. Example 20.3 Protective Put Suppose the strike price is X 5 $100 and the stock is selling at $97 at option expiration. Then the value of your total portfolio is $100. The stock is worth $97 and the value of the expiring put option is X 2 ST 5 $100 2 $97 5 $3 Another way to look at it is that you are holding the stock and a put contract giving you the right to sell the stock for $100. The right to sell locks in a minimum portfolio value of $100. On the other hand, if the stock price is above $100, say, $104, then the right to sell a share at $100 is worthless. You allow the put to expire unexercised, ending up with a share of stock worth ST 5 $104. Figure 20.6 illustrates the payoff and profit to this protective put strategy. The solid line in Figure 20.6, panel C is the total payoff. The dashed line is displaced downward by the cost of establishing the position, S0 1 P. Notice that potential losses are limited. It is instructive to compare the profit on the protective put strategy with that of the stock investment. For simplicity, consider an at-the-money protective put, so that X 5 S0. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 689 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 690 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Table 20.1 Value of a protective put portfolio at option expiration Stock 1 Put 5 TOTAL ST " X ST + X ST X 2 ST X ST 0 ST Payoff of Stock A: Stock ST X Payoff of Option + B: Put ST X Payoff of Protective Put Payoff Profit = C: Protective Put X X ST X − (S0 + P) Figure 20.6 Value of a protective put position at option expiration bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 690 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 691 Figure 20.7 compares the profits for the two strategies. The profit on the stock is zero Profits if the stock price remains unchanged and Profit on Stock ST 5 S0. It rises or falls by $1 for every dollar Profit on Protective Put swing in the ultimate stock price. The profit Portfolio on the protective put is negative and equal to the cost of the put if ST is below S0. The profit on the protective put increases one for one with increases in the stock price once ST ST exceeds S0. S0 = X Figure 20.7 makes it clear that the pro−P tective put offers some insurance against stock price declines in that it limits losses. Therefore, protective put strategies provide a form of portfolio insurance. The cost of −S0 the protection is that, in the case of stock price increases, your profit is reduced by the cost of the put, which turned out to be unneeded. This example also shows that despite Figure 20.7 Protective put versus stock investment the common perception that derivatives (at-the-money option) mean risk, derivative securities can be used effectively for risk management. In fact, such risk management is becoming accepted as part of the fiduciary responsibility of financial managers. Indeed, in one often-cited court case, Brane v. Roth, a company’s board of directors was successfully sued for failing to use derivatives to hedge the price risk of grain held in storage. Such hedging might have been accomplished using protective puts. The claim that derivatives are best viewed as risk management tools may seem surprising in light of the credit crisis of the last few years. The crisis was immediately precipitated when the highly risky positions that many financial institutions had established in credit derivatives blew up 2007–2008, resulting in large losses and government bailouts. Still, the same characteristics that make derivatives potent tools to increase risk also make them highly effective in managing risk, at least when used properly. Derivatives have aptly been compared to power tools: very useful in skilled hands, but also very dangerous when not handled with care. The nearby box makes the case for derivatives as central to risk management. Covered Calls A covered call position is the purchase of a share of stock with a simultaneous sale of a call option on that stock. The call is “covered” because the potential obligation to deliver the stock can be satisfied using the stock held in the portfolio. Writing an option without an offsetting stock position is called by contrast naked option writing. The value of a covered call position at expiration, presented in Table 20.2, equals the stock value minus the value of the call. The call value is subtracted because the covered call position involves writing a call to another investor who may exercise it at your expense. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 691 7/25/13 2:50 AM WORDS FROM THE STREET Final PDF to printer The Case for Derivatives They’ve been dubbed financial weapons of mass destruction, attacked for causing the financial turmoil sweeping the nation and identified as the kryptonite that brought down the global economy. Yet few Main Streeters really know what derivatives are—namely, financial contracts between a buyer and a seller that derive value from an underlying asset, such as a mortgage or a stock. There seems to be near consensus that derivatives were a source of undue risk. And then there’s Robert Shiller. The Yale economist believes just the opposite is true. A champion of financial innovation and an expert in management of risk, Shiller contends that derivatives, far from being a problem, are actually the solution. Derivatives, Shiller says, are merely a risk-management tool the same way insurance is. “You pay a premium and if an event happens, you get a payment.” That tool can be used well or, as happened recently, used badly. Shiller warns that banishing the tool gets us nowhere. For all the trillions in derivative trading, there were very few traders. Almost all the subprime mortgages that were bundled and turned into derivatives were sold by a handful of Wall Street institutions, working with a small number of large institutional buyers. It was a huge but illiquid and opaque market. Meanwhile, the system was built on the myriad decisions of individual homeowners and lenders around the world. None of them, however, could hedge their bets the way large institutions can. Those buying a condo in Miami had no way to protect themselves if the market went down. Derivatives, according to Shiller, could be used by homeowners—and, by extension, lenders—to insure themselves against falling prices. In Shiller’s scenario, you would be able to go to your broker and buy a new type of financial instrument, perhaps a derivative that is inversely related to a regional home-price index. If the value of houses in your area declined, the financial instrument would increase in value, offsetting the loss. Lenders could do the same thing, which would help them hedge against foreclosures. The idea is to make the housing market more liquid. More buyers and sellers mean that markets stay liquid and functional even under pressure. Some critics dismiss Shiller’s basic premise that more derivatives would make the housing market more liquid and more stable. They point out that futures contracts haven’t made equity markets or commodity markets immune from massive moves up and down. They add that a ballooning world of home-based derivatives wouldn’t lead to homeowners’ insurance: it would lead to a new playground for speculators. In essence, Shiller is laying the intellectual groundwork for the next financial revolution. We are now suffering through the first major crisis of the Information Age economy. Shiller’s answers may be counterintuitive, but no more so than those of doctors and scientists who centuries ago recognized that the cure for infectious diseases was not flight or quarantine, but purposely infecting more people through vaccinations. “We’ve had a major glitch in derivatives and securitization,” says Shiller. “The Titanic sank almost a century ago, but we didn’t stop sailing across the Atlantic.” Of course, people did think twice about getting on a ship, at least for a while. But if we listen only to our fears, we lose the very dynamism that has propelled us this far. That is the nub of Shiller’s call for more derivatives and more innovation. Shiller’s appeal is a tough sell at a time when derivatives have produced so much havoc. But he reminds us that the tools that got us here are not to blame; they can be used badly and they can be used well. And trying to stem the ineffable tide of human creativity is a fool’s errand. Source: Zachary Karabell, “The Case for Derivatives,” Newsweek, February 2, 2009. The solid line in Figure 20.8, panel C is the payoff. You see that the total position is worth ST when the stock price at time T is below X and rises to a maximum of X when ST exceeds X. In essence, the sale of the call options means the call writer has sold the claim to any stock value above X in return for the initial premium (the call price). Therefore, at expiration, the position is worth at most X. The dashed line of Figure 20.8, panel C is the net profit to the covered call. Writing covered call options has been a popular investment strategy among institutional investors. Consider the managers of a fund invested largely in stocks. They might find it appealing to write calls on some or all of the stock in order to boost income by the premiums collected. Although they thereby forfeit potential capital gains should the stock price rise above the exercise price, if they view X as the price at which they plan to sell the stock anyway, then the call may be viewed as a kind of “sell discipline.” The written call guarantees the stock sale will occur as planned. 692 bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 692 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 ST " X ST + X ST 20 ST ST 2(ST 2 X ) X Payoff of stock 1 Payoff of written call 5 TOTAL Options Markets: Introduction 693 Table 20.2 Value of a covered call position at option expiration Payoff of Stock A: Stock ST X Payoff of Written Call ST + B: Write Call Payoff of Covered Call = C: Covered Call X Payoff X Profit X ST − (S0 − C) Figure 20.8 Value of a covered call position at expiration bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 693 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer eXcel APPLICATIONS: Spreads and Straddles U sing spreadsheets to analyze combinations of options is very helpful. Once the basic models are built, it is easy to extend the analysis to different bundles of options. The Excel model “Spreads and Straddles” shown below can be used to evaluate the profitability of different strategies. You can find a link to this spreadsheet at www.mhhe.com/bkm. A B C D 1 2 3 Stock Prices 116.5 4 Beginning Market Price Ending Market Price 130 5 6 7 Buying Options: Call Options Strike Price Payoff Profit 8 110 −2.80 20.00 9 22.80 120 −6.80 10.00 10 16.80 130 −13.60 0.00 11 13.60 140 −10.30 0.00 12 10.30 13 Payoff Profit Put Options Strike Price 14 15 −12.60 110 12.60 0.00 16 −17.20 120 17.20 0.00 17 −23.60 130 23.60 0.00 18 −20.50 30.50 140 10.00 19 Payoff Straddle Price Profit 20 21 −15.40 35.40 110 20.00 22 −24.00 34.00 120 10.00 −37.20 23 37.20 130 0.00 −30.80 24 40.80 10.00 140 25 Example 20.4 Excel Question 1. Use the data in this spreadsheet to plot the profit on a bullish spread (see Figure 20.10) with X1 5 120 and X2 5 130. E F Spreads and Straddles Return % −12.28% −40.48% −100.00% −100.00% Return % −100.00% −100.00% −100.00% −67.21% Return % −43.50% −70.59% −100.00% −75.49% G H I X 110 Straddle Ending Profit Stock Price −15.40 50 24.60 60 14.60 70 4.60 80 −5.40 90 −15.40 100 −25.40 110 −35.40 120 −25.40 130 −15.40 140 −5.40 150 4.60 160 14.60 170 24.60 180 34.60 190 44.60 200 54.60 210 64.60 J K L X 120 Straddle Ending Profit Stock Price −24.00 36.00 50 26.00 60 16.00 70 6.00 80 −4.00 90 −14.00 100 −24.00 110 −34.00 120 −24.00 130 −14.00 140 −4.00 150 6.00 160 16.00 170 26.00 180 36.00 190 46.00 200 56.00 210 Covered Call Assume a pension fund holds 1,000 shares of stock, with a current price of $100 per share. Suppose the portfolio manager intends to sell all 1,000 shares if the share price hits $110, and a call expiring in 60 days with an exercise price of $110 currently sells for $5. By writing 10 call contracts (for 100 shares each) the fund can pick up $5,000 in extra income. The fund would lose its share of profits from any movement of the stock price above $110 per share, but given that it would have sold its shares at $110, it would not have realized those profits anyway. Straddle A long straddle is established by buying both a call and a put on a stock, each with the same exercise price, X, and the same expiration date, T. Straddles are useful strategies for investors who believe a stock will move a lot in price but are uncertain about the direction of the move. For example, suppose you believe an important court case that will make or break a company is about to be settled, and the market is not yet aware of the situation. The stock will either double in value if the case is settled favorably or will drop by half if the settlement goes against the company. The straddle position will do well regardless of the outcome because its value rises when the stock price makes extreme upward or downward moves from X. The worst-case scenario for a straddle is no movement in the stock price. If ST equals X, both the call and the put expire worthless, and the investor’s outlay for the purchase of both options is lost. Straddle positions, therefore, are bets on volatility. An investor who 694 bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 694 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 695 establishes a straddle must view the stock as more volatile than the market does. Conversely, investors who write straddles—selling both a call and a put—must believe the stock is less volatile. They accept the option premiums now, hoping the stock price will not change much before option expiration. The payoff to a straddle is presented in Table 20.3. The solid line of Figure 20.9, panel C illustrates this payoff. Notice the portfolio payoff is always positive, except at the one point where the portfolio has zero value, ST 5 X. You might wonder why all investors don’t pursue such a seemingly “no-lose” strategy. The reason is that the straddle requires that both the put and call be purchased. The value of the portfolio at expiration, while never negative, still must exceed the initial cash outlay for a straddle investor to clear a profit. The dashed line of Figure 20.9, panel C is the profit diagram. The profit line lies below the payoff line by the cost of purchasing the straddle, P 1 C. It is clear from the diagram that the straddle generates a loss unless the stock price deviates substantially from X. The stock price must depart from X by the total amount expended to purchase the call and the put for the straddle CONCEPT CHECK 20.4 to clear a profit. Strips and straps are variations of straddles. A strip is Graph the profit and payoff diagrams for strips two puts and one call on a security with the same exercise and straps. price and expiration date. A strap is two calls and one put. Spreads A spread is a combination of two or more call options (or two or more puts) on the same stock with differing exercise prices or times to maturity. Some options are bought, whereas others are sold, or written. A money spread involves the purchase of one option and the simultaneous sale of another with a different exercise price. A time spread refers to the sale and purchase of options with differing expiration dates. Consider a money spread in which one call option is bought at an exercise price X1, whereas another call with identical expiration date, but higher exercise price, X2, is written. The payoff will be the difference in the value of the call held and the value of the call written, as in Table 20.4. There are now three instead of two outcomes to distinguish: the lowest-price region where ST is below both exercise prices, a middle region where ST is between the two exercise prices, and a high-price region where ST exceeds both exercise prices. Figure 20.10 illustrates the payoff and profit to this strategy, which is called a bullish spread because the payoff either increases or is unaffected by stock price increases. Holders of bullish spreads benefit from stock price increases. One motivation for a bullish spread might be that the investor thinks one option is overpriced relative to another. For example, an investor who believes an X 5 $100 call is cheap compared to an X 5 $110 call might establish the spread, even without a strong desire to take a bullish position in the stock. Collars A collar is an options strategy that brackets the value of a portfolio between two bounds. Suppose that an investor currently is holding a large position in FinCorp stock, which is currently selling at $100 per share. A lower bound of $90 can be placed on the value of the portfolio by buying a protective put with exercise price $90. This protection, however, requires that the investor pay the put premium. To raise the money to pay for the put, the investor might write a call option, say, with exercise price $110. The call might sell for roughly the same price as the bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 695 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 696 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Table 20.3 Value of a straddle position at option expiration Payoff of call 1 Payoff of put 5 TOTAL ST * X ST # X 0 X 2 ST X 2 ST ST 2 X 0 ST 2 X Payoff of Call Payoff Profit A: Call 0 ST X −C Payoff of Put X X−P Payoff + B: Put X 0 −P ST Profit Payoff of Straddle X Payoff X−P−C Profit = C: Straddle P+C 0 X ST − (P + C) Figure 20.9 Value of a straddle at expiration bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 696 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction ST " X1 X1 * ST " X2 ST # X2 0 20 0 ST 2 X1 20 S T 2 X1 ST 2 X1 2(ST 2 X2) X 2 2 X1 Payoff of purchased call, exercise price 5 X1 1 Payoff of written call, exercise price 5 X2 5 TOTAL 697 Table 20.4 Value of a bullish spread position at expiration Payoff Payoff Profit A: Call Held (Strike price 5 X1) 0 − C1 X1 X2 ST Payoff B: Call Written (Strike price 5 X2) C2 0 X1 X2 ST Profit Payoff Payoff and Profit C: Bullish Spread X2 − X1 Payoff Profit 0 C2 − C1 X1 X2 ST Figure 20.10 Value of a bullish spread position at expiration bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 697 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 698 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives put, meaning that the net outlay for the two options positions is approximately zero. Writing the call limits the portfolio’s upside potential. Even if the stock price moves above $110, the investor will do no better than $110, because at a higher price the stock will be called away. Thus the investor obtains the downside protection represented by the exercise price of the put by selling her claim to any upside potential beyond the exercise price of the call. Example 20.5 Collars A collar would be appropriate for an investor who has a target wealth goal in mind but is unwilling to risk losses beyond a certain level. If you are contemplating buying a house for $220,000, for example, you might set this figure as your goal. Your current wealth may be $200,000, and you are unwilling to risk losing more than $20,000. A collar established by (1) purchasing 2,000 shares of stock currently selling at $100 per share, (2) purchasing 2,000 put options (20 options contracts) with exercise price $90, and (3) writing 2,000 calls with exercise price $110 would give you a good chance to realize the $20,000 capital gain without risking a loss of more than $20,000. CONCEPT CHECK 20.5 Graph the payoff diagram for the collar described in Example 20.5. 20.4 The Put-Call Parity Relationship We saw in the previous section that a protective put portfolio, comprising a stock position and a put option on that position, provides a payoff with a guaranteed minimum value, but with unlimited upside potential. This is not the only way to achieve such protection, however. A call-plus-bills portfolio also can provide limited downside risk with unlimited upside potential. Consider the strategy of buying a call option and, in addition, buying Treasury bills with face value equal to the exercise price of the call, and with maturity date equal to the expiration date of the option. For example, if the exercise price of the call option is $100, then each option contract (which is written on 100 shares) would require payment of $10,000 upon exercise. Therefore, you would purchase a T-bill with a maturity value of $10,000. More generally, for each option that you hold with exercise price X, you would purchase a risk-free zero-coupon bond with face value X. Examine the value of this position at time T, when the options expire and the zerocoupon bond matures: Value of call option Value of zero-coupon bond TOTAL ST " X ST + X 0 X X ST 2 X X ST If the stock price is below the exercise price, the call is worthless, but the bond matures to its face value, X. It therefore provides a floor value to the portfolio. If the stock price bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 698 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 699 exceeds X, then the payoff to the call, ST 2 X, is added to the face value of the bond to provide a total payoff of ST . The payoff to this portfolio is precisely identical to the payoff of the protective put that we derived in Table 20.1. If two portfolios always provide equal values, then they must cost the same amount to establish. Therefore, the call-plus-bond portfolio must cost the same as the stock-plus-put portfolio. Each call costs C. The riskless zero-coupon bond costs X/(1 1 rf )T. Therefore, the call-plus-bond portfolio costs C 1 X/(1 1 rf )T. The stock costs S0 to purchase now (at time zero), while the put costs P. Therefore, we conclude that C1 X 5 S0 1 P (1 1 rf )T (20.1) Equation 20.1 is called the put-call parity theorem because it represents the proper relationship between put and call prices. If the parity relation is ever violated, an arbitrage opportunity arises. For example, suppose you collect these data for a certain stock: Stock price Call price (1-year expiration, X 5 $105) Put price (1-year expiration, X 5 $105) Risk-free interest rate $110 $ 17 $ 5 5% per year We can use these data in Equation 20.1 to see if parity is violated: C1 ? X 5 S0 1 P T (1 1 r f ) 17 1 105 ? 5 110 1 5 1.05 117 2 115 This result, a violation of parity—117 does not equal 115—indicates mispricing. To exploit the mispricing, you buy the relatively cheap portfolio (the stock-plus-put position represented on the right-hand side of the equation) and sell the relatively expensive portfolio (the call-plus-bond position corresponding to the left-hand side). Therefore, if you buy the stock, buy the put, write the call, and borrow $100 for 1 year (because borrowing money is the opposite of buying a bond), you should earn arbitrage profits. Let’s examine the payoff to this strategy. In 1 year, the stock will be worth ST. The $100 borrowed will be paid back with interest, resulting in a cash outflow of $105. The written call will result in a cash outflow of ST 2 $105 if ST exceeds $105. The purchased put pays off $105 2 ST if the stock price is below $105. Table 20.5 summarizes the outcome. The immediate cash inflow is $2. In 1 year, the various positions provide exactly offsetting cash flows: The $2 inflow is realized without any offsetting outflows. This is an arbitrage opportunity that investors will pursue on a large scale until buying and selling pressure restores the parity condition expressed in Equation 20.1. Equation 20.1 actually applies only to options on stocks that pay no dividends before the expiration date of the option. The extension of the parity condition for European call options on dividend-paying stocks is, however, straightforward. Problem 12 at the end of bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 699 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 700 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Table 20.5 Arbitrage strategy Position Buy stock Borrow $105/1.05 5 $100 Sell call Buy put TOTAL Cash Flow in 1 Year Immediate Cash Flow ST * 105 ST # 105 2110 1100 117 25 2 ST 2105 0 105 2 ST 0 ST 2105 2(ST 2 105) 0 0 the chapter leads you through the demonstration. The more general formulation of the put-call parity condition is P 5 C 2 S0 1 PV(X) 1 PV(dividends) (20.2) where PV(dividends) is the present value of the dividends that will be paid by the stock during the life of the option. If the stock does not pay dividends, Equation 20.2 becomes identical to Equation 20.1. Notice that this generalization would apply as well to European options on assets other than stocks. Instead of using dividend income in Equation 20.2, we would let any income paid out by the underlying asset play the role of the stock dividends. For example, European put and call options on bonds would satisfy the same parity relationship, except that the bond’s coupon income would replace the stock’s dividend payments in the parity formula. Even this generalization, however, applies only to European options, as the cash flow streams from the two portfolios represented by the two sides of Equation 20.2 will match only if each position is held until expiration. If a call and a put may be optimally exercised at different times before their common expiration date, then the equality of payoffs cannot be assured, or even expected, and the portfolios will have different values. Example 20.6 Put-Call Parity Let’s see how well parity works using the data in Figure 20.1 on the IBM options. The February expiration call with exercise price $195 and time to expiration of 28 days cost $3.65 while the corresponding put option cost $5. IBM was selling for $194.47, and the annualized short-term interest rate on this date was 0.1%. IBM was expected to pay a dividend of $.85 with an ex-dividend date of February 8, 18 days hence. According to parity, we should find that P 5 C 1 PV(X) 2 S0 1 PV(Dividends) 5.00 5 3.65 1 195 28/365 (1.001) 2194.47 1 .85 (1.001)18/365 5.00 5 3.65 1 194.985 2 194.47 1 .85 5.00 5 5.015 So parity is violated by about $.015 per share. Is this a big enough difference to exploit? Almost certainly not. You have to weigh the potential profit against the trading costs of the call, put, and stock. More important, given the fact that options trade relatively infrequently, this deviation from parity might not be “real,” but may instead be attributable to “stale” (i.e., out-of-date) price quotes at which you cannot actually trade. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 700 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 701 20.5 Option-Like Securities Suppose you never traded an option directly. Why do you need to appreciate the properties of options in formulating an investment plan? Many financial instruments and agreements have features that convey implicit or explicit options to one or more parties. To value and use these securities correctly, you must understand their embedded option attributes. Callable Bonds You know from Chapter 14 that many corporate bonds are issued with call provisions entitling the issuer to buy bonds back from bondholders at some time in the future at a specified call price. The bond issuer holds a call option with exercise price equal to the price at which the bond can be repurchased. A callable bond arrangement therefore is essentially a sale of a straight bond (a bond with no option features such as callability or convertibility) to the investor and the concurrent issuance of a call option by the investor to the bond-issuing firm. There must be some compensation for the firm’s implicit call option. If the callable bond were issued with the same coupon rate as a straight bond, it would sell at a lower price than the straight bond: the price difference would equal the value of the call. To sell callable bonds at par, firms must issue them with coupon rates higher than the coupons on straight debt. The higher coupons are the investor’s compensation for the call option retained by the issuer. Figure 20.11 illustrates this optionlike property. The horizontal axis is the value of a straight bond with otherwise identical terms to the callable bond. The dashed 45-degree line represents the value of straight debt. The solid line is the value of the callable bond, and the dotted line is the value of the call option retained by the firm. A callable bond’s potential for capital gains is limited by the firm’s option to repurchase at the call price. CONCEPT CHECK 20.6 How is a callable bond similar to a covered call strategy on a straight bond? The option inherent in callable bonds actually is more complex than an ordinary call option, because usually it may be exercised only after some initial period of call protection. The price at which the bond is callable may change over time also. Unlike exchangelisted options, these features are defined in the initial bond covenant and will depend on the needs of the issuing firm and its perception of the market’s tastes. CONCEPT CHECK 20.7 Suppose the period of call protection is extended. How will the coupon rate the company needs to offer on its bonds change to enable the issuer to sell the bonds at par value? Convertible Securities Convertible bonds and convertible preferred stock convey options to the holder of the security rather than to the issuing firm. A convertible security typically gives its holder the bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 701 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 702 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives right to exchange each bond or share of preferred stock for a fixed number of shares of common stock, regardValue of Straight Debt less of the market prices of the securities at the time. For example, a bond with a conversion ratio of 10 allows its holder to Value of Callable Bond convert one bond of par value $1,000 into 10 shares of common stock. Alternatively, we say the conversion price in this case is $100: To receive 10 shares of stock, the investor sacrifices bonds with face value $1,000 or, put another way, $100 of face value Value of Firm’s Call Option per share. If the present value of the bond’s scheduled payments is less Value of than 10 times the value of one share Straight Debt Call Price of stock, it may pay to convert; that is, the conversion option is in the money. A bond worth $950 with a conversion Figure 20.11 Values of callable bonds compared with straight bonds ratio of 10 could be converted profitably if the stock were selling above $95, as the value of the 10 shares received for each bond surrendered would exceed $950. Most convertible bonds are issued “deep out of the money.” That is, the issuer sets the conversion ratio so that conversion will not be profitable unless there is a substantial increase in stock prices and/or decrease in bond prices from the time of issue. A bond’s conversion value equals the value it would have if you converted it into stock immediately. Clearly, a bond must sell for at least its conversion value. If it did not, you could purchase the bond, convert it, and clear an immediate profit. This condition could never persist, for all investors would pursue such a strategy and ultimately would bid up the price of the bond. The straight bond value, or “bond floor,” is the value the bond would have if it were not convertible into stock. The bond must sell for more than its straight bond value because a convertible bond has more value; it is in fact a straight bond plus a valuable call option. Therefore, the convertible bond has two lower bounds on its market price: the conversion value and the straight bond value. CONCEPT CHECK 20.8 Should a convertible bond issued at par value have a higher or lower coupon rate than a nonconvertible bond issued at par? Figure 20.12 illustrates the optionlike properties of the convertible bond. Figure 20.12, panel A shows the value of the straight debt as a function of the stock price of the issuing firm. For healthy firms, the straight debt value is almost independent of the value of the stock because default risk is small. However, if the firm is close to bankruptcy (stock prices are low), default risk increases, and the straight bond value falls. Panel B shows the conversion value of the bond. Panel C compares the value of the convertible bond to these two lower bounds. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 702 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 703 Straight Debt Value A Stock Price Conversion Value B Stock Price Convertible Bond Value Convertible Bond Value Conversion Value C Straight Debt Stock Price Figure 20.12 Value of a convertible bond as a function of stock price. Panel A, Straight debt value, or bond floor. Panel B, Conversion value of the bond. Panel C, Total value of convertible bond. When stock prices are low, the straight bond value is the effective lower bound, and the conversion option is nearly irrelevant. The convertible will trade like straight debt. When stock prices are high, the bond’s price is determined by its conversion value. With conversion all but guaranteed, the bond is essentially equity in disguise. We can illustrate with two examples: Annual coupon Maturity date Quality rating Conversion ratio Stock price Conversion value Market yield on 10-year Baa-rated bonds Value as straight debt Actual bond price Reported yield to maturity bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 703 Bond A Bond B $80 10 years Baa 20 $30 $600 8.5% $967 $972 8.42% $80 10 years Baa 25 $50 $1,250 8.5% $967 $1,255 4.76% 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 704 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Bond A has a conversion value of only $600. Its value as straight debt, in contrast, is $967. This is the present value of the coupon and principal payments at a market rate for straight debt of 8.5%. The bond’s price is $972, so the premium over straight bond value is only $5, reflecting the low probability of conversion. Its reported yield to maturity based on scheduled coupon payments and the market price of $972 is 8.42%, close to that of straight debt. The conversion option on bond B is in the money. Conversion value is $1,250, and the bond’s price, $1,255, reflects its value as equity (plus $5 for the protection the bond offers against stock price declines). The bond’s reported yield is 4.76%, far below the comparable yield on straight debt. The big yield sacrifice is attributable to the far greater value of the conversion option. In theory, we could value convertible bonds by treating them as straight debt plus call options. In practice, however, this approach is often impractical for several reasons: 1. The conversion price frequently increases over time, which means the exercise price of the option changes. 2. Stocks may pay several dividends over the life of the bond, further complicating the option-valuation analysis. 3. Most convertibles also are callable at the discretion of the firm. In essence, both the investor and the issuer hold options on each other. If the issuer exercises its call option to repurchase the bond, the bondholders typically have a month during which they still can convert. When issuers use a call option, knowing bondholders will choose to convert, the issuer is said to have forced a conversion. These conditions together mean the actual maturity of the bond is indeterminate. Warrants Warrants are essentially call options issued by a firm. One important difference between calls and warrants is that exercise of a warrant requires the firm to issue a new share of stock—the total number of shares outstanding increases. Exercise of a call option requires only that the writer of the call deliver an already-issued share of stock to discharge the obligation. In that case, the number of shares outstanding remains fixed. Also unlike call options, warrants result in a cash flow to the firm when the warrant holder pays the exercise price. These differences mean that warrant values will differ somewhat from the values of call options with identical terms. Like convertible debt, warrant terms may be tailored to meet the needs of the firm. Also like convertible debt, warrants generally are protected against stock splits and dividends in that the exercise price and the number of warrants held are adjusted to offset the effects of the split. Warrants are often issued in conjunction with another security. Bonds, for example, may be packaged together with a warrant “sweetener,” frequently a warrant that may be sold separately. This is called a detachable warrant. Issue of warrants and convertible securities creates the potential for an increase in outstanding shares of stock if exercise occurs. Exercise obviously would affect financial statistics that are computed on a per-share basis, so annual reports must provide earnings per share figures under the assumption that all convertible securities and warrants are exercised. These figures are called fully diluted earnings per share.3 3 We should note that the exercise of a convertible bond need not reduce EPS. Diluted EPS will be less than undiluted EPS only if interest saved (per share) on the convertible bonds is less than the prior EPS. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 704 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 705 The executive and employee stock options that became so popular in the 1990s actually were warrants. Some of these grants were huge, with payoffs to top executives in excess of $100 million. Yet firms almost uniformly chose not to acknowledge these grants as expenses on their income statements until new reporting rules that took effect in 2006 required such recognition. Collateralized Loans Many loan arrangements require that the borrower put up collateral to guarantee the loan will be paid back. In the event of default, the lender takes possession of the collateral. A nonrecourse loan gives the lender no recourse beyond the right to the collateral. That is, the lender may not sue the borrower for further payment if the collateral turns out not to be valuable enough to repay the loan. This arrangement gives an implicit call option to the borrower. Assume the borrower is obligated to pay back L dollars at the maturity of the loan. The collateral will be worth ST dollars at maturity. (Its value today is S0.) The borrower has the option to wait until loan maturity and repay the loan only if the collateral is worth more than the L dollars necessary to satisfy the loan. If the collateral is worth less than L, the borrower can default on the loan, discharging the obligation by forfeiting the collateral, which is worth only ST.4 Another way of describing such a loan is to view the borrower as turning over the collateral to the lender but retaining the right to reclaim it by paying off the loan. The transfer of the collateral with the right to reclaim it is equivalent to a payment of S0 dollars, less a simultaneous recovery of a sum that resembles a call option with exercise price L. In effect, the borrower turns over collateral but keeps an option to “repurchase” it for L dollars at the maturity of the loan if L turns out to be less than ST. This is a call option. A third way to look at a collateralized loan is to assume that the borrower will repay the L dollars with certainty but also retain the option to sell the collateral to the lender for L dollars, even if ST is less than L. In this case, the sale of the collateral would generate the cash necessary to satisfy the loan. The ability to “sell” the collateral for a price of L dollars represents a put option, which guarantees the borrower can raise enough money to satisfy the loan simply by turning over the collateral. It is perhaps surprising to realize that we can describe the same loan as involving either a put option or a call option, as the payoffs to calls and puts are so different. Yet the equivalence of the two approaches is nothing more than a reflection of the put-call parity relationship. In our call-option description of the loan, the value of the borrower’s liability is S0 2 C: The borrower turns over the asset, which is a transfer of S0 dollars, but retains a call worth C dollars. In the put-option description, the borrower is obligated to pay L dollars but retains the put, which is worth P: The present value of this net obligation is L/(1 1 rf )T 2 P. Because these alternative descriptions are equivalent ways of viewing the same loan, the value of the obligations must be equal: S0 2 C 5 L 2P (1 1 rf)T (20.3) Treating L as the exercise price of the option, Equation 20.3 is simply the put-call parity relationship. 4 In reality, of course, defaulting on a loan is not so simple. There are losses of reputation involved as well as considerations of ethical behavior. This is a description of a pure nonrecourse loan where both parties agree from the outset that only the collateral backs the loan and that default is not to be taken as a sign of bad faith if the collateral is insufficient to repay the loan. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 705 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 706 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Payoff A Payoff to lender L L When ST exceeds L, the loan is repaid and the collateral is reclaimed. Otherwise, the collateral is forfeited and the total loan repayment is worth only ST ST Payoff Payoff to call with exercise price L B L ST dollars minus the payoff to the implicit call option ST L Payoff C L Payoff to a put with exercise price L L dollars minus the payoff to the implicit put option ST L Figure 20.13 Collateralized loan. Panel A, Payoff to collateralized loan. Panel B, Lender can be viewed as collecting the collateral from the borrower, but issuing an option to the borrower to call back the collateral for the face value of the loan. Panel C, Lender can be viewed as collecting a risk-free loan from the borrower, but issuing a put to the borrower to sell the collateral for the face value of the loan. Figure 20.13 illustrates this fact. Figure 20.13, panel A is the value of the payment to be received by the lender, which equals the minimum of ST or L. Panel B shows that this amount can be expressed as ST minus the payoff of the call implicitly written by the lender and held by the borrower. Panel C shows it also can be viewed as a receipt of L dollars minus the proceeds of a put option. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 706 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 707 Levered Equity and Risky Debt Investors holding stock in incorporated firms are protected by limited liability, which means that if the firm cannot pay its debts, the firm’s creditors may attach only the firm’s assets, not sue the corporation’s equityholders for further payment. In effect, any time the corporation borrows money, the maximum possible collateral for the loan is the total of the firm’s assets. If the firm declares bankruptcy, we can interpret this as an admission that the assets of the firm are insufficient to satisfy the claims against it. The corporation may discharge its obligations by transferring ownership of the firm’s assets to the creditors. Just as is true for nonrecourse collateralized loans, the required payment to the creditors represents the exercise price of the implicit option, while the value of the firm is the underlying asset. The equityholders have a put option to transfer their ownership claims on the firm to the creditors in return for the face value of the firm’s debt. Alternatively, we may view the equityholders as retaining a call option. They have, in effect, already transferred their ownership claim to the firm to the creditors but have retained the right to reacquire that claim by paying off the loan. Hence the equityholders have the option to “buy back” the firm for a specified price: They have a call option. The significance of this observation is that analysts can value corporate bonds using option-pricing techniques. The default premium required of risky debt in principle can be estimated by using option-valuation models. We consider some of these models in the next chapter. 20.6 Financial Engineering One of the attractions of options is the ability they provide to create investment positions with payoffs that depend in a variety of ways on the values of other securities. We have seen evidence of this capability in the various options strategies examined in Section 20.4. Options also can be used to custom-design new securities Rate of Return on Index-Linked CD or portfolios with desired patterns of exposure to the price of an underlying security. In this sense, options (and futures contracts, to be discussed in Chapters 22 and 23) provide the ability to engage in financial engineering, the creation Slope = .7 of portfolios with specified payoff patterns. A simple example of a product engineered with options is the index-linked certificate of deposit. Index-linked CDs enable retail investors to take small positions in index options. Unlike conventional CDs, which pay a fixed rate of interest, these CDs pay deposiFigure 20.14 Return on index-linked CD tors a specified fraction of the bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 707 rM = Market Rate of Return 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 708 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives rate of return on a market index such as the S&P 500, while guaranteeing a minimum rate of return should the market fall. For example, the index-linked CD may offer 70% of any market increase, but protect its holder from any market decrease by guaranteeing at least no loss. The index-linked CD is clearly a type of call option. If the market rises, the depositor profits according to the participation rate or multiplier, in this case 70%; if the market falls, the investor is insured against loss. Just as clearly, the bank offering these CDs is in effect writing call options and can hedge its position by buying index calls in the options market. Figure 20.14 shows the nature of the bank’s obligation to its depositors. How might the bank set the appropriate multiplier? To answer this, note various features of the option: 1. The price the depositor is paying for the options is the forgone interest on the conventional CD that could be purchased. Because interest is received at the end of the period, the present value of the interest payment on each dollar invested is rf /(1 1 rf ). Therefore, the depositor trades a sure payment with present value per dollar invested of rf /(1 1 rf ) for a return that depends on the market’s performance. Conversely, the bank can fund its obligation using the interest that it would have paid on a conventional CD. 2. The option we have described is an at-the-money option, meaning that the exercise price equals the current value of the stock index. The option goes into the money as soon as the market index increases from its level at the inception of the contract. 3. We can analyze the option on a per-dollar-invested basis. For example, the option costs the depositor rf /(1 1 rf ) dollars per dollar placed in the index-linked CD. The market price of the option per dollar invested is C/S0: The at-the-money option costs C dollars and is written on one unit of the market index, currently at S0. Now it is easy to determine the multiplier that the bank can offer on the CDs. It receives from its depositors a “payment” of rf /(1 1 rf ) per dollar invested. It costs the bank C/S0 to purchase the call option on a $1 investment in the market index. Therefore, if rf /(1 1 rf ) is, for example, 70% of C/S0, the bank can purchase at most .7 call option on the $1 investment and the multiplier will be .7. More generally, the break-even multiplier on an index-linked CD is rf /(1 1 rf ) divided by C/S0. Example 20.7 Indexed-Linked CDs Suppose that rf 5 6% per year, and that 6-month maturity at-the-money calls on the market index currently cost $50. The index is at 1,000. Then the option costs 50/1,000 5 $.05 per dollar of market value. The CD rate is 3% per 6 months, meaning that rf /(1 1 rf) 5 .03/1.03 5 .0291. Therefore, the multiplier would be .0291/.05 5 .5825. The index-linked CD has several variants. Investors can purchase similar CDs that guarantee a positive minimum return if they are willing to settle for a smaller multiplier. In this case, the option is “purchased” by the depositor for (rf 2 rmin)/(1 1 rf ) dollars per dollar invested, where rmin is the guaranteed minimum return. Because the purchase price is lower, fewer options can be purchased, which results in a lower multiplier. Another variant of the “bullish” CD we have described is the bear CD, which pays depositors a fraction of any fall in the market index. For example, a bear CD might offer a rate of return of .6 times any percentage decline in the S&P 500. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 708 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 CONCEPT CHECK Options Markets: Introduction 709 20.9 Continue to assume that rf 5 3% per half-year, that at-the-money calls sell for $50, and that the market index is at 1,000. What would be the multiplier for 6-month bullish equity-linked CDs offering a guaranteed minimum return of .5% over the term of the CD? 20.7 Exotic Options Options markets have been tremendously successful. Investors clearly value the portfolio strategies made possible by trading options; this is reflected in the heavy trading volume in these markets. Success breeds imitation, and in recent years we have witnessed considerable innovation in the range of option instruments available to investors. Part of this innovation has occurred in the market for customized options, which now trade in active over-the-counter markets. Many of these options have terms that would have been highly unusual even a few years ago; they are therefore called exotic options. In this section we survey a few of the more interesting variants of these new instruments. Asian Options You already have been introduced to American- and European-style options. Asian-style options are options with payoffs that depend on the average price of the underlying asset during at least some portion of the life of the option. For example, an Asian call option may have a payoff equal to the average stock price over the last 3 months minus the strike price if that value is positive, and zero otherwise. These options may be of interest, for example, to firms that wish to hedge a profit stream that depends on the average price of a commodity over some period of time. Barrier Options Barrier options have payoffs that depend not only on some asset price at option expiration, but also on whether the underlying asset price has crossed through some “barrier.” For example, a down-and-out option is one type of barrier option that automatically expires worthless if and when the stock price falls below some barrier price. Similarly, down-and-in options will not provide a payoff unless the stock price does fall below some barrier at least once during the life of the option. These options also are referred to as knock-out and knock-in options. Lookback Options Lookback options have payoffs that depend in part on the minimum or maximum price of the underlying asset during the life of the option. For example, a lookback call option might provide a payoff equal to the maximum stock price during the life of the option minus the exercise price, instead of the final stock price minus the exercise price. Such an option provides (for a price, of course) a form of perfect market timing, providing the call holder with a payoff equal to the one that would accrue if the asset were purchased for X dollars and later sold at what turns out to be its high price. Currency-Translated Options Currency-translated options have either asset or exercise prices denominated in a foreign currency. For example, the quanto allows an investor to fix in advance the exchange rate at bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 709 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 710 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives which an investment in a foreign currency can be converted back into dollars. The right to translate a fixed amount of foreign currency into dollars at a given exchange rate is a simple foreign exchange option. Quantos are more interesting because the amount of currency that will be translated into dollars depends on the investment performance of the foreign security. Therefore, a quanto in effect provides a random number of options. Digital Options Digital options, also called binary or “bet” options, have fixed payoffs that depend on whether a condition is satisfied by the price of the underlying asset. For example, a digital call option might pay off a fixed amount of $100 if the stock price at maturity exceeds the exercise price. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm SUMMARY 1. A call option is the right to buy an asset at an agreed-upon exercise price. A put option is the right to sell an asset at a given exercise price. 2. American-style options allow exercise on or before the expiration date. European options allow exercise only on the expiration date. Most traded options are American in nature. 3. Options are traded on stocks, stock indexes, foreign currencies, fixed-income securities, and several futures contracts. 4. Options can be used either to lever up an investor’s exposure to an asset price or to provide insurance against volatility of asset prices. Popular option strategies include covered calls, protective puts, straddles, spreads, and collars. 5. The put-call parity theorem relates the prices of put and call options. If the relationship is violated, arbitrage opportunities will result. Specifically, the relationship that must be satisfied is P 5 C 2 S0 1 PV(X) 1 PV(dividends) where X is the exercise price of both the call and the put options, PV(X) is the present value of a claim to X dollars to be paid at the expiration date of the options, and PV(dividends) is the present value of dividends to be paid before option expiration. Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm 6. Many commonly traded securities embody option characteristics. Examples of these securities are callable bonds, convertible bonds, and warrants. Other arrangements such as collateralized loans and limited-liability borrowing can be analyzed as conveying implicit options to one or more parties. KEY TERMS call option exercise or strike price premium put option in the money out of the money KEY EQUATIONS 7. Trading in so-called exotic options now takes place in an active over-the-counter market. at the money American option European option protective put covered call ST 2 X 0 if ST . X if ST # X 0 X 2 ST if ST . X if ST # X Payoff to call investor 5 b Payoff to put investor 5 b straddle spread collar put-call parity theorem warrant Put-call parity: P 5 C 2 S0 1 PV(X ) 1 PV(Div) bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 710 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 1. We said that options can be used either to scale up or reduce overall portfolio risk. What are some examples of risk-increasing and risk-reducing options strategies? Explain each. 711 PROBLEM SETS 2. What are the trade-offs facing an investor who is considering buying a put option on an existing portfolio? 3. What are the trade-offs facing an investor who is considering writing a call option on an existing portfolio? Basic 4. Why do you think the most actively traded options tend to be the ones that are near the money? 5. Turn back to Figure 20.1, which lists prices of various IBM options. Use the data in the figure to calculate the payoff and the profits for investments in each of the following February expiration options, assuming that the stock price on the expiration date is $195. Call option, X 5 $190. Put option, X 5 $190. Call option, X 5 $195. Put option, X 5 $195. Call option, X 5 $200. Put option, X 5 $200. 6. Suppose you think FedEx stock is going to appreciate substantially in value in the next 6 months. Say the stock’s current price, S0, is $100, and the call option expiring in 6 months has an exercise price, X, of $100 and is selling at a price, C, of $10. With $10,000 to invest, you are considering three alternatives. a. Invest all $10,000 in the stock, buying 100 shares. b. Invest all $10,000 in 1,000 options (10 contracts). c. Buy 100 options (one contract) for $1,000, and invest the remaining $9,000 in a money market fund paying 4% in interest over 6 months (8% per year). What is your rate of return for each alternative for the following four stock prices 6 months from now? Summarize your results in the table and diagram below. Price of Stock 6 Months from Now $80 $100 $110 $120 a. All stocks (100 shares) b. All options (1,000 shares) c. Bills 1 100 options Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. b. c. d. e. f. Intermediate Rate of Return 0 ST 7. The common stock of the P.U.T.T. Corporation has been trading in a narrow price range for the past month, and you are convinced it is going to break far out of that range in the next 3 months. You do not know whether it will go up or down, however. The current price of the stock is $100 per share, and the price of a 3-month call option at an exercise price of $100 is $10. a. If the risk-free interest rate is 10% per year, what must be the price of a 3-month put option on P.U.T.T. stock at an exercise price of $100? (The stock pays no dividends.) bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 711 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 712 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives b. What would be a simple options strategy to exploit your conviction about the stock price’s future movements? How far would it have to move in either direction for you to make a profit on your initial investment? 8. The common stock of the C.A.L.L. Corporation has been trading in a narrow range around $50 per share for months, and you believe it is going to stay in that range for the next 3 months. The price of a 3-month put option with an exercise price of $50 is $4. a. If the risk-free interest rate is 10% per year, what must be the price of a 3-month call option on C.A.L.L. stock at an exercise price of $50 if it is at the money? (The stock pays no dividends.) b. What would be a simple options strategy using a put and a call to exploit your conviction about the stock price’s future movement? What is the most money you can make on this position? How far can the stock price move in either direction before you lose money? c. How can you create a position involving a put, a call, and riskless lending that would have the same payoff structure as the stock at expiration? What is the net cost of establishing that position now? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 9. You are a portfolio manager who uses options positions to customize the risk profile of your clients. In each case, what strategy is best given your client’s objective? a. • Performance to date: Up 16%. • Client objective: Earn at least 15%. • Your scenario: Good chance of large gains or large losses between now and end of year. i. Long straddle. ii. Long bullish spread. iii. Short straddle. b. • Performance to date: Up 16%. • Client objective: Earn at least 15%. • Your scenario: Good chance of large losses between now and end of year. i. Long put options. ii. Short call options. iii. Long call options. 10. An investor purchases a stock for $38 and a put for $.50 with a strike price of $35. The investor sells a call for $.50 with a strike price of $40. What is the maximum profit and loss for this position? Draw the profit and loss diagram for this strategy as a function of the stock price at expiration. 11. Imagine that you are holding 5,000 shares of stock, currently selling at $40 per share. You are ready to sell the shares but would prefer to put off the sale until next year for tax reasons. If you continue to hold the shares until January, however, you face the risk that the stock will drop in value before year-end. You decide to use a collar to limit downside risk without laying out a good deal of additional funds. January call options with a strike of $35 are selling at $2, and January puts with a strike price of $45 are selling at $3. What will be the value of your portfolio in January (net of the proceeds from the options) if the stock price ends up at: (a) $30, (b) $40, or (c) $50? Compare these proceeds to what you would realize if you simply continued to hold the shares. 12. In this problem, we derive the put-call parity relationship for European options on stocks that pay dividends before option expiration. For simplicity, assume that the stock makes one dividend payment of $D per share at the expiration date of the option. a. What is the value of a stock-plus-put position on the expiration date of the option? b. Now consider a portfolio comprising a call option and a zero-coupon bond with the same maturity date as the option and with face value (X 1 D). What is the value of this portfolio on the option expiration date? You should find that its value equals that of the stock-plus-put portfolio regardless of the stock price. c. What is the cost of establishing the two portfolios in parts (a) and (b)? Equate the costs of these portfolios, and you will derive the put-call parity relationship, Equation 20.2. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 712 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 713 13. a. A butterfly spread is the purchase of one call at exercise price X1, the sale of two calls at exercise price X2, and the purchase of one call at exercise price X3. X1 is less than X2, and X2 is less than X3 by equal amounts, and all calls have the same expiration date. Graph the payoff diagram to this strategy. b. A vertical combination is the purchase of a call with exercise price X2 and a put with exercise price X1, with X2 greater than X1. Graph the payoff to this strategy. 14. A bearish spread is the purchase of a call with exercise price X2 and the sale of a call with exercise price X1, with X2 greater than X1. Graph the payoff to this strategy and compare it to Figure 20.10. a. Strategy A is to write January call options on the CSI shares with strike price $45. These calls are currently selling for $3 each. b. Strategy B is to buy January put options on CSI with strike price $35. These options also sell for $3 each. c. Strategy C is to establish a zero-cost collar by writing the January calls and buying the January puts. Evaluate each of these strategies with respect to Joseph’s investment goals. What are the advantages and disadvantages of each? Which would you recommend? 16. Use the spreadsheet from the Excel Application boxes on spreads and straddles (available at www.mhhe.com/bkm; link to Chapter 20 material) to answer these questions. a. Plot the payoff and profit diagrams to a straddle position with an exercise (strike) price of $130. Assume the options are priced as they are in the Excel Application. b. Plot the payoff and profit diagrams to a bullish spread position with exercise (strike) prices of $120 and $130. Assume the options are priced as they are in the Excel Application. 17. Some agricultural price support systems have guaranteed farmers a minimum price for their output. Describe the program provisions as an option. What is the asset? The exercise price? eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 15. Joseph Jones, a manager at Computer Science, Inc. (CSI), received 10,000 shares of company stock as part of his compensation package. The stock currently sells at $40 a share. Joseph would like to defer selling the stock until the next tax year. In January, however, he will need to sell all his holdings to provide for a down payment on his new house. Joseph is worried about the price risk involved in keeping his shares. At current prices, he would receive $400,000 for the stock. If the value of his stock holdings falls below $350,000, his ability to come up with the necessary down payment would be jeopardized. On the other hand, if the stock value rises to $450,000, he would be able to maintain a small cash reserve even after making the down payment. Joseph considers three investment strategies: 18. In what ways is owning a corporate bond similar to writing a put option? A call option? 19. An executive compensation scheme might provide a manager a bonus of $1,000 for every dollar by which the company’s stock price exceeds some cutoff level. In what way is this arrangement equivalent to issuing the manager call options on the firm’s stock? 20. Consider the following options portfolio. You write a January expiration call option on IBM with exercise price $195. You write a January IBM put option with exercise price $190. a. Graph the payoff of this portfolio at option expiration as a function of IBM’s stock price at that time. b. What will be the profit/loss on this position if IBM is selling at $198 on the option expiration date? What if IBM is selling at $205? Use The Wall Street Journal listing from Figure 20.1 to answer this question. c. At what two stock prices will you just break even on your investment? d. What kind of “bet” is this investor making; that is, what must this investor believe about IBM’s stock price to justify this position? 21. Consider the following portfolio. You write a put option with exercise price 90 and buy a put option on the same stock with the same expiration date with exercise price 95. a. Plot the value of the portfolio at the expiration date of the options. b. On the same graph, plot the profit of the portfolio. Which option must cost more? bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 713 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 714 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 22. A FinCorp put option with strike price 60 trading on the Acme options exchange sells for $2. To your amazement, a FinCorp put with the same maturity selling on the Apex options exchange but with strike price 62 also sells for $2. If you plan to hold the options positions to expiration, devise a zero-net-investment arbitrage strategy to exploit the pricing anomaly. Draw the profit diagram at expiration for your position. 23. Assume a stock has a value of $100. The stock is expected to pay a dividend of $2 per share at year-end. An at-the-money European-style put option with one-year maturity sells for $7. If the annual interest rate is 5%, what must be the price of a 1-year at-the-money European call option on the stock? 24. You buy a share of stock, write a 1-year call option with X 5 $10, and buy a 1-year put option with X 5 $10. Your net outlay to establish the entire portfolio is $9.50. What is the risk-free interest rate? The stock pays no dividends. 25. You write a put option with X 5 100 and buy a put with X 5 110. The puts are on the same stock and have the same expiration date. a. Draw the payoff graph for this strategy. b. Draw the profit graph for this strategy. c. If the underlying stock has positive beta, does this portfolio have positive or negative beta? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 26. Joe Finance has just purchased a stock index fund, currently selling at $1,200 per share. To protect against losses, Joe also purchased an at-the-money European put option on the fund for $60, with exercise price $1,200, and 3-month time to expiration. Sally Calm, Joe’s financial adviser, points out that Joe is spending a lot of money on the put. She notes that 3-month puts with strike prices of $1,170 cost only $45, and suggests that Joe use the cheaper put. a. Analyze Joe’s and Sally’s strategies by drawing the profit diagrams for the stock-plus-put positions for various values of the stock fund in 3 months. b. When does Sally’s strategy do better? When does it do worse? c. Which strategy entails greater systematic risk? 27. You write a call option with X 5 50 and buy a call with X 5 60. The options are on the same stock and have the same expiration date. One of the calls sells for $3; the other sells for $9. a. Draw the payoff graph for this strategy at the option expiration date. b. Draw the profit graph for this strategy. c. What is the break-even point for this strategy? Is the investor bullish or bearish on the stock? 28. Devise a portfolio using only call options and shares of stock with the following value (payoff) at the option expiration date. If the stock price is currently 53, what kind of bet is the investor making? Payoff 50 50 Challenge bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 714 60 110 ST 29. You are attempting to formulate an investment strategy. On the one hand, you think there is great upward potential in the stock market and would like to participate in the upward move if it materializes. However, you are not able to afford substantial stock market losses and so cannot run the risk of a stock market collapse, which you think is also a possibility. Your investment adviser suggests a protective put position: Buy both shares in a market index stock fund and put options on those shares with 3-month expiration and exercise price of $1,170. The stock index fund is currently selling for $1,350. However, your uncle suggests 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 715 you instead buy a 3-month call option on the index fund with exercise price $1,260 and buy 3-month T-bills with face value $1,260. Stock fund $1,350 T-bill (face value $1,260) Call (exercise price $1,260) Put (exercise price $1,170) $1,215 $ 180 $ 9 Make a table of the profits realized for each portfolio for the following values of the stock price in 3 months: ST 5 $1,000, $1,260, $1,350, $1,440. Graph the profits to each portfolio as a function of ST on a single graph. d. Which strategy is riskier? Which should have a higher beta? e. Explain why the data for the securities given in part (c) do not violate the put-call parity relationship. 30. FedEx is selling for $100 a share. A FedEx call option with one month until expiration and an exercise price of $105 sells for $2 while a put with the same strike and expiration sells for $6.94. What is the market price of a zero-coupon bond with face value $105 and 1 month maturity? What is the risk-free interest rate expressed as an effective annual yield? 31. Demonstrate that an at-the-money call option on a given stock must cost more than an at-themoney put option on that stock with the same expiration. The stock will pay no dividends until after the expiration date. (Hint: Use put-call parity.) 1. Donna Donie, CFA, has a client who believes the common stock price of TRT Materials (currently $58 per share) could move substantially in either direction in reaction to an expected court decision involving the company. The client currently owns no TRT shares, but asks Donie for advice about implementing a strangle strategy to capitalize on the possible stock price movement. A strangle is a portfolio of a put and a call with a higher exercise price but the same expiration date. Donie gathers the TRT option-pricing data: Characteristic Price Strike price Time to expiration Call Option Put Option $ 5 $60 90 days from now $ 4 $55 90 days from now Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. On the same graph, draw the payoffs to each of these strategies as a function of the stock fund value in 3 months. (Hint: Think of the options as being on one “share” of the stock index fund, with the current price of each share of the fund equal to $1,350.) b. Which portfolio must require a greater initial outlay to establish? (Hint: Does either portfolio provide a final payout that is always at least as great as the payoff of the other portfolio?) c. Suppose the market prices of the securities are as follows: a. Recommend whether Donie should choose a long strangle strategy or a short strangle strategy to achieve the client’s objective. b. Calculate, at expiration for the appropriate strangle strategy in part (a), the: i. Maximum possible loss per share. ii. Maximum possible gain per share. iii. Break-even stock price(s). 2. Martin Bowman is preparing a report distinguishing traditional debt securities from structured note securities. Discuss how the following structured note securities differ from a traditional debt security with respect to coupon and principal payments: a. Equity index-linked notes. b. Commodity-linked bear bond. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 715 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 716 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 3. Suresh Singh, CFA, is analyzing a convertible bond. The characteristics of the bond and the underlying common stock are given in the following exhibit: Convertible Bond Characteristics Par value Annual coupon rate (annual pay) Conversion ratio Market price Straight value $1,000 6.5% 22 105% of par value 99% of par value Underlying Stock Characteristics Current market price Annual cash dividend $40 per share $1.20 per share Compute the bond’s: Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. Conversion value. b. Market conversion price. 4. Rich McDonald, CFA, is evaluating his investment alternatives in Ytel Incorporated by analyzing a Ytel convertible bond and Ytel common equity. Characteristics of the two securities are given in the following exhibit: Characteristics Convertible Bond Common Equity $1,000 4% $980 $925 25 At any time — $1,125 — — $35 per share — — — $0 $45 per share Par value Coupon (annual payment) Current market price Straight bond value Conversion ratio Conversion option Dividend Expected market price in 1 year a. Calculate, based on the exhibit, the: i. Current market conversion price for the Ytel convertible bond. ii. Expected 1-year rate of return for the Ytel convertible bond. iii. Expected 1-year rate of return for the Ytel common equity. One year has passed and Ytel’s common equity price has increased to $51 per share. Also, over the year, the interest rate on Ytel’s nonconvertible bonds of the same maturity increased, while credit spreads remained unchanged. b. Name the two components of the convertible bond’s value. Indicate whether the value of each component should decrease, stay the same, or increase in response to the: i. Increase in Ytel’s common equity price. ii. Increase in interest rates. 5. a. Consider a bullish spread option strategy using a call option with a $25 exercise price priced at $4 and a call option with a $40 exercise price priced at $2.50. If the price of the stock increases to $50 at expiration and each option is exercised on the expiration date, the net profit per share at expiration (ignoring transaction costs) is: i. ii. iii. iv. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 716 $8.50 $13.50 $16.50 $23.50 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 717 b. A put on XYZ stock with a strike price of $40 is priced at $2.00 per share, while a call with a strike price of $40 is priced at $3.50. What is the maximum per-share loss to the writer of the uncovered put and the maximum per-share gain to the writer of the uncovered call? Maximum Loss to Put Writer i. ii. iii. iv. Maximum Gain to Call Writer $38.00 $ 3.50 $38.00 $36.50 $40.00 $ 3.50 $40.00 $40.00 1. Go to www.nasdaq.com and select IBM in the quote section. Once you have the information quote, request the information on options. You will be able to access the prices for the calls and puts that are closest to the money. For example, if the price of IBM is $196.72, you will use the options with the $195 exercise price. Use near-term options. For example, in February, you would select April and July expirations. a. What are the prices for the put and call with the nearest expiration date? b. What would be the cost of a straddle using these options? c. At expiration, what would be the break-even stock prices for the straddle? d. What would be the percentage increase or decrease in the stock price required to break even? e. What are the prices for the put and call with a later expiration date? f. What would be the cost of a straddle using the later expiration date? At expiration, what would be the break-even stock prices for the straddle? g. What would be the percentage increase or decrease in the stock price required to break even? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. a. Denote the stock price at call option expiration by ST, and the exercise price by X. Value at expiration 5 ST 2 X 5 ST 2 $195 if this value is positive; otherwise the call expires worthless. Profit 5 Final value 2 Price of call option 5 Proceeds 2 $3.65. Proceeds Profits bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 717 ST 5 $185 ST 5 $205 $0 $10 $ 6.35 2$3.65 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 718 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives b. Value at expiration 5 X 2 ST 5 $195 2 ST if this value is positive; otherwise the put expires worthless. Profit 5 Final value 2 Price of put option 5 Proceeds 2 $5.00. ST 5 $185 Proceeds Profits ST 5 $205 $10 1$ 5.00 $0 2$5.00 2. Before the split, the final payoff would have been 100 3 ($200 2 $195) 5 $500. After the split, the payoff is 200 3 ($100 2 $97.50) 5 $500. The payoff is unaffected. 3. a. Write Put Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Buy Call Profit Payoff S Payoff S Profit Write Call Buy Put Profit S Payoff Payoff S Profit b. The payoffs and profits to both buying calls and writing puts generally are higher when the stock price is higher. In this sense, both positions are bullish. Both involve potentially taking delivery of the stock. However, the call holder will choose to take delivery when the stock price is high, while the put writer is obligated to take delivery when the stock price is low. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 718 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 719 c. The payoffs and profits to both writing calls and buying puts generally are higher when the stock price is lower. In this sense, both positions are bearish. Both involve potentially making delivery of the stock. However, the put holder will choose to make delivery when the stock price is low, while the call writer is obligated to make delivery when the stock price is high. 4. Payoff to a Strip ST " X ST + X 2 Puts 2(X 2 ST) 0 1 Call 0 ST 2 X Payoff and Profit 2X Payoff Slope = 1 2X − 2P − C Profit X − 2P − C ST Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Slope = −2 Payoff to a Strap ST " X 1 Put 2 Calls bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 719 ST + X X 2 ST 0 0 2(ST 2 X) 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer 720 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Payoff and Profit Payoff Slope = 2 Profit X Slope = −1 X − P − 2C ST Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm X − P − 2C 5. The payoff table on a per-share basis is as follows: Buy put (X 5 90) Share Write call (X 5 110) TOTAL ST " 90 90 " ST " 110 ST + 110 90 2 ST ST 0 0 0 ST 0 ST 2(ST 2 110) 90 ST 110 The graph of the payoff is as follows. If you multiply the per-share values by 2,000, you will see that the collar provides a minimum payoff of $180,000 (representing a maximum loss of $20,000) and a maximum payoff of $220,000 (which is the cost of the house). bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 720 7/25/13 2:50 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 20 Options Markets: Introduction 721 Payoff $110 Collar $90 $110 6. The covered call strategy would consist of a straight bond with a call written on the bond. The value of the strategy at option expiration as a function of the value of the straight bond is given by the solid colored payoff line in the following figure, which is virtually identical to Figure 20.11. Value of Straight Bond Payoff of Covered Call Value of Straight Bond X Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm ST $90 Call Written 7. The call option is worth less as call protection is expanded. Therefore, the coupon rate need not be as high. 8. Lower. Investors will accept a lower coupon rate in return for the conversion option. 9. The depositor’s implicit cost per dollar invested is now only ($.03 2 $.005)/1.03 5 $.02427 per 6-month period. Calls cost 50/1,000 5 $.05 per dollar invested in the index. The multiplier falls to .02427/.05 5 .4854. bod61671_ch20_678-721.indd 721 7/25/13 2:50 AM 221 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER TWENTY-ONE Option Valuation PART VI IN THE PREVIOUS chapter we examined option markets and strategies. We noted that many securities contain embedded options that affect both their values and their risk– return characteristics. In this chapter, we turn our attention to option-valuation issues. To understand most option-valuation models requires considerable mathematical and statistical background. Still, many of the ideas and insights of these models can be demonstrated in simple examples, and we will concentrate on these. We start with a discussion of the factors that ought to affect option prices. After this discussion, we present several bounds within which option prices must lie. Next we turn to quantitative models, starting with a simple “two-state” option-valuation model, and then showing how this approach can be generalized into a useful and accurate pricing tool. We then move on to one particular valuation formula, the famous Black-Scholes model, one of the most significant breakthroughs in finance theory in several decades. Finally, we look at some of the more important applications of option-pricing theory in portfolio management and control. Option-pricing models allow us to “back out” market estimates of stock-price volatility, and we will examine these measures of implied volatility. Next we turn to some of the more important applications of option-pricing theory in risk management. Finally, we take a brief look at some of the empirical evidence on option pricing, and the implications of that evidence concerning the limitations of the Black-Scholes model. 21.1 Option Valuation: Introduction bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 722 Intrinsic and Time Values Consider a call option that is out of the money at the moment, with the stock price below the exercise price. This does not mean the option is valueless. Even though immediate exercise today would be unprofitable, the call retains a positive value because there is always a chance the stock price will increase sufficiently by the expiration date to allow for profitable exercise. If not, the worst that can happen is that the option will expire with zero value. 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 723 The value S0 2 X is sometimes called the intrinsic value of in-the-money call options because it gives the payoff that could be obtained by immediate exercise. Intrinsic value is set equal to zero for out-of-the-money or at-the-money options. The difference between the actual call price and the intrinsic value is commonly called the time value of the option. “Time value” is unfortunate terminology because it may confuse the option’s time value with the time value of money. Time value in the options context refers simply to the difference between the option’s price and the value the option would have if it were expiring immediately. It is the part of the option’s value that may be attributed to the fact that it still has positive time to expiration. Most of an option’s time value typically is a type of “volatility value.” Because the option holder can choose not to exercise, the payoff cannot be worse than zero. Even if a call option is out of the money now, it still will sell for a positive price because it offers the potential for a profit if the stock price increases, while imposing no risk of additional loss should the stock price fall. The volatility value lies in the value of the right not to exercise the call if that action would be unprofitable. The option to exercise, as opposed to the obligation to exercise, provides insurance against poor stock price performance. As the stock price increases substantially, it becomes likely that the call option will be exercised by expiration. Ultimately, with exercise all but assured, the volatility value becomes minimal. As the stock price gets ever larger, the option value approaches the “adjusted” intrinsic value, the stock price minus the present value of the exercise price, S0 2 PV(X ). Why should this be? If you are virtually certain the option will be exercised and the stock purchased for X dollars, it is as though you own the stock already. The stock certificate, with a value today of S0, might as well be sitting in your safe-deposit box now, as it will be there in only a few months. You just haven’t paid for it yet. The present value of your obligation is the present value of X, so the net value of the call option is S0 2 PV(X).1 Figure 21.1 illustrates the call option valuation function. The value curve shows that when the stock price is very low, the option is nearly worthless, because there is almost no chance that it will be exercised. When the stock price is very high, the option value approaches adjusted intrinsic value. In the midrange case, where the option is approximately at the money, the option curve diverges from the straight lines corresponding to adjusted intrinsic value. This is because although exercise today would have a negligible (or negative) payoff, the volatility value of the option is quite high in this region. The call always increases in value with the stock price. The slope is greatest, however, when the option is deep in the money. In this case, exercise is all but assured, and the option increases in price one-for-one with the stock price. Determinants of Option Values We can identify at least six factors that should affect the value of a call option: the stock price, the exercise price, the volatility of the stock price, the time to expiration, the interest rate, and the dividend rate of the stock. The call option should increase in value with the stock price and decrease in value with the exercise price because the payoff to a call, 1 This discussion presumes that the stock pays no dividends until after option expiration. If the stock does pay dividends before expiration, then there is a reason you would care about getting the stock now rather than at expiration—getting it now entitles you to the interim dividend payments. In this case, the adjusted intrinsic value of the option must subtract the value of the dividends the stock will pay out before the call is exercised. Adjusted intrinsic value would more generally be defined as S0 2 PV(X ) 2 PV(D), where D is the dividend to be paid before option expiration. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 723 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 724 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Option Value Value of Call Option S0 – PV(X) Value of Option if Now at Expiration = S – X = Intrinsic Value Time Value S0 PV(X) X Out of the Money In the Money Figure 21.1 Call option value before expiration if exercised, equals ST 2 X. The magnitude of the expected payoff increases with the difference S0 2 X. Call option values also increase with the volatility of the underlying stock price. To see why, consider circumstances where possible stock prices at expiration may range from $10 to $50 compared to a situation where they range only from $20 to $40. In both cases, the expected, or average, stock price will be $30. Suppose the exercise price on a call option is also $30. What are the option payoffs? High-Volatility Scenario Stock price Option payoff $10 0 $20 0 $30 0 $40 10 $50 20 $35 5 $40 10 Low-Volatility Scenario Stock price Option payoff $20 0 $25 0 $30 0 If each outcome is equally likely, with probability .2, the expected payoff to the option under high-volatility conditions will be $6, but under low-volatility conditions the expected payoff is half as much, only $3. Despite the fact that the average stock price in each scenario is $30, the average option payoff is greater in the high-volatility scenario. The source of this extra value is the limited loss an option holder can suffer, or the volatility value of the call. No matter how far below bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 724 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Table 21.1 Determinants of call option values If This Variable Increases . . . The Value of a Call Option Stock price, S Exercise price, X Volatility, s Time to expiration, T Interest rate, rf Dividend payouts Increases Decreases Increases Increases Increases Decreases Option Valuation 725 $30 the stock price drops, the option holder will get zero. Obviously, extremely poor stock price performance is no worse for the call option holder than moderately poor performance. In the case of good stock performance, however, the call will expire in the money, and it will be more profitable the higher the stock price. Thus extremely good stock outcomes can improve the option payoff without limit, but extremely poor outcomes cannot worsen the payoff below zero. This asymmetry means that volatility in the underlying stock price increases the expected payoff to the option, thereby enhancing its value.2 Similarly, longer time to expiration increases the value of a call option. For more distant expiration dates, there is more time for unpredictable future events to affect prices, and the range of likely stock prices increases. This has an effect similar to that of increased volatility. Moreover, as time to expiration lengthens, the present value of the exercise price falls, thereby benefiting the call option holder and increasing the option value. As a corollary to this issue, call option values are higher when interest rates rise (holding the stock price constant) because higher interest rates also reduce the present value of the exercise price. Finally, the dividend payout policy of the firm affects option values. A high-dividend payout policy puts a drag CONCEPT CHECK 21.1 on the rate of growth of the stock price. For any expected total rate of return on the stock, a higher dividend yield Prepare a table like Table 21.1 for the determust imply a lower expected rate of capital gain. This drag minants of put option values. How should on stock price appreciation decreases the potential pay- American put values respond to increases in off from the call option, thereby lowering the call value. S, X, s, T, rf, and dividend payouts? Table 21.1 summarizes these relationships. 21.2 Restrictions on Option Values Several quantitative models of option pricing have been devised, and we will examine some of them later in this chapter. All models, however, rely on simplifying assumptions. You might wonder which properties of option values are truly general and which depend on the particular simplifications. To start with, we will consider some of the more 2 You should be careful interpreting the relationship between volatility and option value. Neither the focus of this analysis on total (as opposed to systematic) volatility nor the conclusion that options buyers seem to like volatility contradicts modern portfolio theory. In conventional discounted cash flow analysis, we find the discount rate appropriate for a given distribution of future cash flows. Greater risk implies a higher discount rate and lower present value. Here, however, the cash flow from the option depends on the volatility of the stock. The option value increases not because traders like risk but because the expected cash flow to the option holder increases along with the volatility of the underlying asset. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 725 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 726 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives important general properties of option prices. Some of these properties have important implications for the effect of stock dividends on option values and the possible profitability of early exercise of an American option. Restrictions on the Value of a Call Option The most obvious restriction on the value of a call option is that its value cannot be negative. Because the option need not be exercised, it cannot impose any liability on its holder; moreover, as long as there is any possibility that at some point the option can be exercised profitably, it will command a positive price. Its payoff is zero at worst, and possibly positive, so it has some positive value. We can place another lower bound on the value of a call option. Suppose that the stock will pay a dividend of D dollars just before the expiration date of the option, denoted by T (where today is time 0). Now compare two portfolios, one consisting of a call option on one share of stock and the other a leveraged equity position consisting of that share and borrowing of (X 1 D)/(1 1 rf )T dollars. The loan repayment is X 1 D dollars, due on the expiration date of the option. For example, for a half-year maturity option with exercise price $70, dividends to be paid of $5, and effective annual interest of 10%, you would purchase one share of stock and borrow $75/(1.10)1/2 5 $71.51. In 6 months, when the loan matures, the payment due is $75. At that time, the payoff to the leveraged equity position would be Stock value 2 Payback of loan TOTAL In General Our Numbers ST 1 D 2(X 1 D) ST 2 X ST 1 5 275 ST 2 70 where ST denotes the stock price at the option expiration date. Notice that the payoff to the stock is the ex-dividend stock value plus dividends received. Whether the total payoff to the stock-plus-borrowing position is positive or negative depends on whether ST exceeds X. The net cash outlay required to establish this leveraged equity position is S0 2 $71.51, or, more generally, S0 2 (X 1 D)/(1 1 rf)T, that is, the current price of the stock, S0, less the initial cash inflow from the borrowing position. The payoff to the call option will be ST 2 X if the option expires in the money and zero otherwise. Thus the option payoff is equal to the leveraged equity payoff when that payoff is positive and is greater when the leveraged equity position has a negative payoff. Because the option payoff is always greater than or equal to that of the leveraged equity position, the option price must exceed the cost of establishing that position. Therefore, the value of the call must be greater than S0 2 (X 1 D)/(1 1 rf)T, or, more generally, C $ S0 2 PV(X ) 2 PV(D) where PV(X) denotes the present value of the exercise price and PV(D) is the present value of the dividends the stock will pay at the option’s expiration. More generally, we can interpret PV(D) as the present value of any and all dividends to be paid prior to the option expiration date. Because we know already that the value of a call option must be nonnegative, we may conclude that C is greater than the maximum of either 0 or S0 2 PV(X) 2 PV(D). We also can place an upper bound on the possible value of the call; this bound is simply the stock price. No one would pay more than S0 dollars for the right to purchase a stock currently worth S0 dollars. Thus C # S0. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 726 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 0 C $ St 2 PV(X) . St 2 X ge S Ra n 5 Al lo w ab le Bo un d Up Early Exercise and Dividends A call option holder who wants to close out that position has two choices: exercise the call or sell it. If the holder exercises at time t, the call will provide a payoff of St 2 X, assuming, of course, that the option is in the money. We have just seen that the option can be sold for at least St 2 PV(X ) 2 PV(D). Therefore, for an option on a non-dividendpaying stock, C is greater than St 2 PV(X ). Because the present value of X is less than X itself, it follows that Lower Bound 5 Adjusted Intrinsic Value 5 S0 2 PV(X) 2 PV(D) PV(X) 1 PV(D) S0 Figure 21.2 Range of possible call option values C Value of Call for The implication here is that the proGiven Stock Price ceeds from a sale of the option (at price C) must exceed the proceeds from an exercise (St 2 X). It is economically more attractive to sell the call, which keeps it alive, than to exercise and thereby end the option. In other words, calls on non-dividend-paying stocks are “worth more alive than dead.” If it never pays to exercise a call option before expiration, the right to exercise early actually must be valueless. We conclude that the values of otherwise identical American and European call options on stocks paying no dividends are equal. This simplifies matters, because any valuPV(X) 1 PV(D) ation formula that applies to the European call, for which only one exercise date need be considered, also must apply to an Figure 21.3 Call option value as a function of the American call. current stock price As most stocks do pay dividends, you may wonder whether this result is just a theoretical curiosity. It is not: Reconsider our argument and you will see that all that we really require is that the stock pay no dividends until the option expires. This condition will be true for many real-world options. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 727 727 Call Value pe r Figure 21.2 demonstrates graphically the range of prices that is ruled out by these upper and lower bounds for the value of a call option. Any option value outside the shaded area is not possible according to the restrictions we have derived. Before expiration, the call option value normally will be within the allowable range, touching neither the upper nor lower bound, as in Figure 21.3. Option Valuation S0 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 728 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives B: European Put Value A: American Put Value X X PV(X) Put Value Time Value S* X S0 PV(X) X S0 Figure 21.4 Put option values as a function of the current stock price Early Exercise of American Puts For American put options, the optimality of early exercise is most definitely a possibility. To see why, consider a simple example. Suppose that you purchase a put option on a stock. Soon the firm goes bankrupt, and the stock price falls to zero. Of course you want to exercise now, because the stock price can fall no lower. Immediate exercise gives you immediate receipt of the exercise price, which can be invested to start generating income. Delay in exercise means a time-value-of-money cost. The right to exercise a put option before expiration must have value. Now suppose instead that the firm is only nearly bankrupt, with the stock selling at just a few cents. Immediate exercise may still be optimal. After all, the stock price can fall by only a very small amount, meaning that the proceeds from future exercise cannot be more than a few cents greater than the proceeds from immediate exercise. Against this possibility of a tiny increase in proceeds must be weighed the time-value-of-money cost of deferring exercise. Clearly, there is some stock price below which early exercise is optimal. This argument also proves that the American put must be worth more than its European counterpart. The American put allows you to exercise anytime before expiration. Because the right to exercise early may be useful in some circumstances, it will command a premium in the capital market. The American put therefore will sell for a higher price than a European put with otherwise identical terms. Figure 21.4, panel A illustrates the value of an American put option as a function of the current stock price, S0. Once the stock price drops below a critical value, denoted S* in the figure, exercise becomes optimal. At that point the option-pricing curve is tangent to the straight line depicting the intrinsic value of the option. If and when the stock price reaches S*, the put option is exercised and its payoff equals its intrinsic value. In contrast, the value of the European put, which is graphed in Figure 21.4, panel B, is not asymptotic to the intrinsic value line. Because early exercise is prohibited, the maximum value of the European put is PV(X), which occurs at the point S0 5 0. Obviously, for a long enough horizon, PV(X) can be made arbitrarily small. CONCEPT CHECK 21.2 In light of this discussion, explain why the put-call parity relationship is valid only for European options on non-dividend-paying stocks. If the stock pays no dividends, what inequality for American options would correspond to the parity theorem? bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 728 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 729 21.3 Binomial Option Pricing Two-State Option Pricing A complete understanding of commonly used option-valuation formulas is difficult without a substantial mathematics background. Nevertheless, we can develop valuable insight into option valuation by considering a simple special case. Assume that a stock price can take only two possible values at option expiration: The stock will either increase to a given higher price or decrease to a given lower price. Although this may seem an extreme simplification, it allows us to come closer to understanding more complicated and realistic models. Moreover, we can extend this approach to describe far more reasonable specifications of stock price behavior. In fact, several major financial firms employ variants of this simple model to value options and securities with optionlike features. Suppose the stock now sells at S0 5 $100, and the price will either increase by a factor of u 5 1.20 to $120 (u stands for “up”) or fall by a factor of d 5 .9 to $90 (d stands for “down”) by year-end. A call option on the stock might specify an exercise price of $110 and a time to expiration of 1 year. The interest rate is 10%. At year-end, the payoff to the holder of the call option will be either zero, if the stock falls, or $10, if the stock price goes to $120. These possibilities are illustrated by the following value “trees”: 120 100 10 C 90 Stock price 0 Call option value Compare the payoff of the call to that of a portfolio consisting of one share of the stock and borrowing of $81.82 at the interest rate of 10%. The payoff of this portfolio also depends on the stock price at year-end: Value of stock at year-end 2 Repayment of loan with interest TOTAL $90 290 $ 0 $120 290 $ 30 We know the cash outlay to establish the portfolio is $18.18: $100 for the stock, less the $81.82 proceeds from borrowing. Therefore the portfolio’s value tree is 30 18.18 0 The payoff of this portfolio is exactly three times that of the call option for either value of the stock price. In other words, three call options will exactly replicate the payoff to the portfolio; it follows that three call options should have the same price as the cost of establishing the portfolio. Hence the three calls should sell for the same price as this replicating portfolio. Therefore, 3C 5 $18.18 or each call should sell at C 5 $6.06. Thus, given the stock price, exercise price, interest rate, and volatility of the stock price (as represented by the spread between the up or down movements), we can derive the fair value for the call option. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 729 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 730 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives This valuation approach relies heavily on the notion of replication. With only two possible end-of-year values of the stock, the payoffs to the levered stock portfolio replicate the payoffs to three call options and, therefore, command the same market price. Replication is behind most option-pricing formulas. For more complex price distributions for stocks, the replication technique is correspondingly more complex, but the principles remain the same. One way to view the role of replication is to note that, using the numbers assumed for this example, a portfolio made up of one share of stock and three call options written is perfectly hedged. Its year-end value is independent of the ultimate stock price: Stock value 2 Obligations from 3 calls written Net payoff $90 20 $90 $120 230 $ 90 The investor has formed a riskless portfolio, with a payout of $90. Its value must be the present value of $90, or $90/1.10 5 $81.82. The value of the portfolio, which equals $100 from the stock held long, minus 3C from the three calls written, should equal $81.82. Hence $100 2 3C 5 $81.82, or C 5 $6.06. The ability to create a perfect hedge is the key to this argument. The hedge locks in the end-of-year payout, which therefore can be discounted using the risk-free interest rate. To find the value of the option in terms of the value of the stock, we do not need to know either the option’s or the stock’s beta or expected rate of return. The perfect hedging, or replication, approach enables us to express the value of the option in terms of the current value of the stock without this information. With a hedged position, the final stock price does not affect the investor’s payoff, so the stock’s risk and return parameters have no bearing. The hedge ratio of this example is one share of stock to three calls, or one-third. This ratio has an easy interpretation in this context: It is the ratio of the range of the values of the option to those of the stock across the two possible outcomes. The stock, which originally sells for S0 5 100, will be worth either d 3 $100 5 $90 or u 3 $100 5 $120, for a range of $30. If the stock price increases, the call will be worth Cu 5 $10, whereas if the stock price decreases, the call will be worth Cd 5 0, for a range of $10. The ratio of ranges, 10/30, is one-third, which is the hedge ratio we have established. The hedge ratio equals the ratio of ranges because the option and stock are perfectly correlated in this two-state example. Because they are perfectly correlated, a perfect hedge requires that they be held in a fraction determined only by relative volatility. We can generalize the hedge ratio for other two-state option problems as H5 Cu 2 Cd uS0 2 dS0 where Cu or Cd refers to the call option’s value when the stock goes up or down, respectively, and uS0 and dS0 are the stock prices in the two states. The hedge ratio, H, is the ratio of the swings in the possible end-of-period values of the option and the stock. If the investor writes one option and holds H shares of stock, the value of the portfolio will be unaffected by the stock price. In this case, option pricing is easy: Simply set the value of the hedged portfolio equal to the present value of the known payoff. Using our example, the option-pricing technique would proceed as follows: 1. Given the possible end-of-year stock prices, uS0 5 120 and dS0 5 90, and the exercise price of 110, calculate that Cu 5 10 and Cd 5 0. The stock price range is 30, while the option price range is 10. 2. Find that the hedge ratio of 10/30 5 1⁄3. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 730 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 731 3. Find that a portfolio made up of 1⁄3 share with one written option would have an end-of-year value of $30 with certainty. 4. Show that the present value of $30 with a 1-year interest rate of 10% is $27.27. 5. Set the value of the hedged position to the present value of the certain payoff: 1 @3 S0 2 C0 5 $27.27 $33.33 2 C0 5 $27.27 6. Solve for the call’s value, C0 5 $6.06. What if the option is overpriced, perhaps selling for $6.50? Then you can make arbitrage profits. Here is how: Cash Flow in 1 Year for Each Possible Stock Price Initial Cash Flow S1 5 90 S1 5 120 $ 19.50 2100 80.50 $ 0 90 288.55 $230 120 288.55 $ 1.45 $ 1. Write 3 options 2. Purchase 1 share 3. Borrow $80.50 at 10% interest Repay in 1 year TOTAL $ 0 1.45 Although the net initial investment is zero, the payoff in 1 year is positive and riskless. If the option were underpriced, one would simply reverse this arbitrage strategy: Buy the option, and sell the stock short to eliminate price risk. Note, by the way, that the present value of the profit to the arbitrage strategy above exactly equals three times the amount by which the option is overpriced. The present value of the risk-free profit of $1.45 at a 10% interest rate is $1.318. With three options written in the strategy above, this translates to a profit of $.44 per option, exactly the amount by which the option was overpriced: $6.50 versus the “fair value” of $6.06. CONCEPT CHECK 21.3 Suppose the call option had been underpriced, selling at $5.50. Formulate the arbitrage strategy to exploit the mispricing, and show that it provides a riskless cash flow in 1 year of $.6167 per option purchased. Compare the present value of this cash flow to the option mispricing. Generalizing the Two-State Approach Although the two-state stock price model seems simplistic, we can generalize it to incorporate more realistic assumptions. To start, suppose we were to break up the year into two 6-month segments, and then assert that over each half-year segment the stock price could take on two values. In this example, we will say it can increase 10% (i.e., u 5 1.10) or decrease 5% (i.e., d 5 .95). A stock initially selling at 100 could follow these possible paths over the course of the year: 121 110 100 104.50 95 90.25 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 731 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 732 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives The midrange value of 104.50 can be attained by two paths: an increase of 10% followed by a decrease of 5%, or a decrease of 5% followed by a 10% increase. There are now three possible end-of-year values for the stock and three for the option: Cu C Cd Cuu Cud 5 Cdu Cdd Using methods similar to those we followed above, we could value Cu from knowledge of Cuu and Cud, then value Cd from knowledge of Cdu and Cdd, and finally value C from knowledge of Cu and Cd. And there is no reason to stop at 6-month intervals. We could next break the year into four 3-month units, or twelve 1-month units, or 365 1-day units, each of which would be posited to have a two-state process. Although the calculations become quite numerous and correspondingly tedious, they are easy to program into a computer, and such computer programs are used widely by participants in the options market. Example 21.1 Binomial Option Pricing Suppose that the risk-free interest rate is 5% per 6-month period and we wish to value a call option with exercise price $110 on the stock described in the two-period price tree just above. We start by finding the value of Cu. From this point, the call can rise to an expiration-date value of Cuu 5 $11 (because at this point the stock price is u 3 u 3 S0 5 $121) or fall to a final value of Cud 5 0 (because at this point, the stock price is u 3 d 3 S0 5 $104.50, which is less than the $110 exercise price). Therefore the hedge ratio at this point is H5 Cuu 2 Cud $11 2 0 2 5 5 uuS0 2 udS0 $121 2 104.50 3 Thus, the following portfolio will be worth $209 at option expiration regardless of the ultimate stock price: udS 5 $104.50 Buy 2 shares at price uS0 5 $110 Write 3 calls at price Cu TOTAL $209 0 $209 uuS0 5 $121 $242 233 $209 The portfolio must have a current market value equal to the present value of $209: 2 3 110 2 3Cu 5 $209/1.05 5 $199.047 Solve to find that Cu 5 $6.984. Next we find the value of Cd. It is easy to see that this value must be zero. If we reach this point (corresponding to a stock price of $95), the stock price at option expiration will be either $104.50 or $90.25; in either case, the option will expire out of the money. (More formally, we could note that with Cud 5 Cdd 5 0, the hedge ratio is zero, and a portfolio of zero shares will replicate the payoff of the call!) Finally, we solve for C using the values of Cu and Cd. Concept Check 4 leads you through the calculations that show the option value to be $4.434. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 732 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 CONCEPT CHECK Option Valuation 733 21.4 Show that the initial value of the call option in Example 21.1 is $4.434. a. Confirm that the spread in option values is Cu 2 Cd 5 $6.984. b. Confirm that the spread in stock values is uS0 2 dS0 5 $15. c. Confirm that the hedge ratio is .4656 shares purchased for each call written. d. Demonstrate that the value in one period of a portfolio comprised of .4656 shares and one call written is riskless. e. Calculate the present value of this payoff. f. Solve for the option value. Making the Valuation Model Practical As we break the year into progressively finer subintervals, the range of possible year-end stock prices expands. For example, when we increase the number of subperiods to three, the number of possible stock prices increases to four, as demonstrated in the following stock price tree: u2S0 S0 uS0 dS0 udS0 2 d S0 u3S0 u2dS0 ud2S0 d3S0 Thus, by allowing for an ever-greater number of subperiods, we can overcome one of the apparent limitations of the valuation model: that the number of possible end-of-period stock prices is small. Notice that extreme events such as u3S0 or d3S0 are relatively rare, as they require either three consecutive increases or decreases in the three subintervals. More moderate, or midrange, results such as u2dS0 can be arrived at by more than one path—any combination of two price increases and one decrease will result in stock price u2dS0. There are three of these paths: uud, udu, duu. In contrast, only one path, uuu, results in a stock price of u3S0. Thus midrange values are more likely. As we make the model more realistic and break up the option maturity into more and more subperiods, the probability distribution for the final stock price begins to resemble the familiar bell-shaped curve with highly unlikely extreme outcomes and far more likely midrange outcomes. The probability of each outcome is given by the binomial probability distribution, and this multiperiod approach to option pricing is therefore called the binomial model. But we still need to answer an important practical question. Before the binomial model can be used to value actual options, we need a way to choose reasonable values for u and d. The spread between up and down movements in the price of the stock reflects the volatility of its rate of return, so the choice for u and d should depend on that volatility. Call s your estimate of the standard deviation of the stock’s continuously compounded annualized rate of return, and ∆t the length of each subperiod. To make the standard deviation of the stock in the binomial model match your estimate of s, it turns out that you can set u 5 exp(s"Dt) and d 5 exp(2s"Dt).3 You can see that the 3 Notice that d 5 1/u. This is the most common, but not the only, way to calibrate the model to empirical volatility. For alternative methods, see Robert L. McDonald, Derivatives Markets, 3rd ed., Pearson/AddisonWesley, Boston: 2013, Ch. 10. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 733 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 734 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives proportional difference between u and d increases with both annualized volatility as well as the duration of the subperiod. This makes sense, as both higher s and longer holding periods make future stock prices more uncertain. The following example illustrates how to use this calibration. Example 21.2 Calibrating u and d to Stock Volatility Suppose you are using a 3-period model to value a 1-year option on a stock with volatility (i.e., annualized standard deviation) of s 5 .30. With a time to expiration of T 5 1 year, and three subperiods, you would calculate Dt 5 T/n 5 1/3, u 5 exp(s"Dt) 5 exp (.30"1/3) 5 1.189 and d 5 exp(2s"Dt) 5 exp(2.30"1/3) 5 .841. Given the probability of an up movement, you could then work out the probability of any final stock price. For example, suppose the probability that the stock price increases is .554 and the probability that it decreases is .446.4 Then the probability of stock prices at the end of the year would be as follows: Possible Paths Event 3 down movements 2 down and 1 up 1 down and 2 up 3 up movements Probability .4463 5 0.089 ddd ddu, dud, udd uud, udu, duu Final Stock Price 59.48 5 100 3 .8413 3 3 .4462 3 .554 5 0.330 84.10 5 100 3 1.189 3 .8412 3 3 .446 3 .5542 5 0.411 118.89 5 100 3 1.1892 3 .841 .5543 5 0.170 uuu 168.09 5 100 3 1.1893 We plot this probability distribution in Figure 21.5, panel A. Notice that the two middle end-of-period stock prices are, in fact, more likely than either extreme. Now we can extend Example 21.2 by breaking up the option maturity into ever-shorter subintervals. As we do, the stock price distribution becomes increasingly plausible, as we demonstrate in Example 21.3. Example 21.3 Increasing the Number of Subperiods In Example 21.2, we broke up the year into three subperiods. Let’s now look at the cases of six and 20 subperiods. Subperiods, n Dt 5 T/n u 5 exp ( s"Dt) d 5 exp (2s"Dt) 3 6 20 .333 .167 .015 exp(.173) 5 1.189 exp(.123) 5 1.130 exp(.067) 5 1.069 exp(2.173) 5 .841 exp(2.095) 5 .885 exp(2.067) 5 .935 4 Using this probability, the continuously compounded expected rate of return on the stock is .10. In general, the formula relating the probability of an upward movement with the annual expected rate of return, r, is exp(rDt) 2 d p5 . u2d bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 734 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 735 We plot the resulting probability distributions in panels B and C of Figure 21.5.5 Notice that the right tail of the distribution in panel C is noticeably longer than the left tail. In fact, as the number of intervals increases, the distribution progressively approaches the skewed log-normal (rather than the symmetric normal) distribution. Even if the stock price were to decline in each subinterval, it can never drop below zero. But there is no corresponding upper bound on its potential performance. This asymmetry gives rise to the skewness of the distribution. .45 .40 .35 .30 .25 .20 .15 .10 .05 .00 A B .35 .30 Probability Probability Eventually, as we divide the option maturity into an ever-greater number of subintervals, each node of the event tree would correspond to an infinitesimally small time interval. The possible stock price movement within that time interval would be correspondingly small. As those many intervals passed, the end-of-period stock price would more and more closely .25 .20 .15 .10 .05 .00 25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 Final Stock Price 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 Final Stock Price C .20 Probability 25 .15 .10 .05 .00 25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 Final Stock Price Figure 21.5 Probability distributions for final stock price. Possible outcomes and associated probabilities. In each panel, the stock’s annualized, continuously compounded expected rate of return is 10% and its standard deviation is 30%. Panel A. Three subintervals. In each subinterval, the stock can increase by 18.9% or fall by 15.9%. Panel B. Six subintervals. In each subinterval, the stock can increase by 13.0% or fall by 11.5%. Panel C. Twenty subintervals. In each subinterval, the stock can increase by 6.9% or fall by 6.5%. 5 We adjust the probabilities of up versus down movements using the formula in footnote 4 to make the distributions in Figure 21.5 comparable. In each panel, p is chosen so that the stock’s expected annualized, continuously compounded rate of return is 10%. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 735 7/27/13 1:45 AM WORDS FROM THE STREET Final PDF to printer A Risk-Neutral Shortcut We pointed out earlier in the chapter that the binomial model valuation approach is arbitrage-based. We can value the option by replicating it with shares of stock plus borrowing. The ability to replicate the option means that its price relative to the stock and the interest rate must be based only on the technology of replication and not on risk preferences. It cannot depend on risk aversion or the capital asset pricing model or any other model of equilibrium risk-return relationships. This insight—that the pricing model must be independent of risk aversion—leads to a very useful shortcut to valuing options. Imagine a risk-neutral economy, that is, an economy in which all investors are risk-neutral. This hypothetical economy must value options the same as our real one because risk aversion cannot affect the valuation formula. In a risk-neutral economy, investors would not demand risk premiums and would therefore value all assets by discounting expected payoffs at the risk-free rate of interest. Therefore, a security such as a call option would be valued by discounting its expected cash flow “E”(CF) at the risk-free rate: C 5 . We put the expectation 1 1 rf operator E in quotation marks to signify that this is not the true expectation, but the expectation that would prevail in the hypothetical risk-neutral economy. To be consistent, we must calculate this expected cash flow using the rate of return the stock would have in the riskneutral economy, not using its true rate of return. But if we successfully maintain consistency, the value derived for the hypothetical economy should match the one in our own. How do we compute the expected cash flow from the option in the risk-neutral economy? Because there are no risk premiums, the stock’s expected rate of return must equal the risk-free rate. Call p the probability that the stock price increases. Then p must be chosen to equate the expected rate of increase of the stock price to the risk-free rate (we ignore dividends here): “E”(S1) 5 p(uS) 1 (1 2 p)dS 5 (1 1 rf)S This implies that p 5 1 1 rf 2 d . We call p a risk-neutral u2d probability to distinguish it from the true, or “objective,” probability. To illustrate, in our two-state example at the beginning of Section 21.2, we had u 5 1.2, d 5 .9, and 1 1 .10 2 .9 2 5 . rf 5 .10. Given these values, p 5 1.2 2 .9 3 Now let’s see what happens if we use the discounted cash flow formula to value the option in the risk-neutral economy. We continue to use the two-state example from Section 21.2. We find the present value of the option payoff using the risk-neutral probability and discount at the risk-free interest rate: C5 “E”(CF) 1 1 rf 5 p Cu 1 (12p) Cd 1 1 rf 5 2/3 3 10 1 1/3 3 0 1.10 5 6.06 This answer exactly matches the value we found using our no-arbitrage approach! We repeat: This is not truly an expected discounted value. • The numerator is not the true expected cash flow from the option because we use the risk-neutral probability, p, rather than the true probability. • The denominator is not the proper discount rate for option cash flows because we do not account for the risk. • In a sense, these two “errors” cancel out. But this is not just luck: We are assured to get the correct result because the no-arbitrage approach implies that risk preferences cannot affect the option value. Therefore, the value computed for the risk-neutral economy must equal the value that we obtain in our economy. When we move to the more realistic multiperiod model, the calculations are more cumbersome, but the idea is the same. Footnote 4 shows how to relate p to any expected rate of return and volatility estimate. Simply set the expected rate of return on the stock equal to the riskfree rate, use the resulting probability to work out the expected payoff from the option, discount at the risk-free rate, and you will find the option value. These calculations are actually fairly easy to program in Excel. resemble a lognormal distribution.6 Thus the apparent oversimplification of the two-state model can be overcome by progressively subdividing any period into many subperiods. At any node, one still could set up a portfolio that would be perfectly hedged over the next tiny time interval. Then, at the end of that interval, on reaching the next node, a new hedge ratio could be computed and the portfolio composition could be revised to remain 6 Actually, more complex considerations enter here. The limit of this process is lognormal only if we assume also that stock prices move continuously, by which we mean that over small time intervals only small price movements can occur. This rules out rare events such as sudden, extreme price moves in response to dramatic information (like a takeover attempt). For a treatment of this type of “jump process,” see John C. Cox and Stephen A. Ross, “The Valuation of Options for Alternative Stochastic Processes,” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (January–March 1976), pp. 145–66, or Robert C. Merton, “Option Pricing When Underlying Stock Returns Are Discontinuous,” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (January–March 1976), pp. 125–44. 736 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 736 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 737 hedged over the coming small interval. By continuously revising the hedge position, the portfolio would remain hedged and would earn a riskless rate of return over each interval. This is called dynamic hedging, the continued updating of the hedge ratio as time passes. As the dynamic hedge becomes ever finer, the resulting option-valuation procedure becomes more precise. The nearby box offers further refinements on the use of the binomial model. CONCEPT CHECK 21.5 In the table in Example 21.3, u and d both get closer to 1 (u is smaller and d is larger) as the time interval ∆t shrinks. Why does this make sense? Does the fact that u and d are each closer to 1 mean that the total volatility of the stock over the remaining life of the option is lower? 21.4 Black-Scholes Option Valuation While the binomial model is extremely flexible, a computer is needed for it to be useful in actual trading. An option-pricing formula would be far easier to use than the tedious algorithm involved in the binomial model. It turns out that such a formula can be derived if one is willing to make just two more assumptions: that both the risk-free interest rate and stock price volatility are constant over the life of the option. In this case, as the time to expiration is divided into ever-more subperiods, the distribution of the stock price at expiration progressively approaches the lognormal distribution, as suggested by Figure 21.5. When the stock price distribution is actually lognormal, we can derive an exact option-pricing formula. The Black-Scholes Formula Financial economists searched for years for a workable option-pricing model before Black and Scholes7 and Merton8 derived a formula for the value of a call option. Scholes and Merton shared the 1997 Nobel Prize in Economics for their accomplishment.9 Now widely used by options market participants, the Black-Scholes pricing formula for a call option is C0 5 S0N(d1) 2 Xe2rTN(d2) (21.1) where d1 5 ln(S0 /X) 1 (r 1 s2 /2)T s"T d2 5 d1 2 s"T 7 Fischer Black and Myron Scholes, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy 81 (May–June 1973). 8 Robert C. Merton, “Theory of Rational Option Pricing,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (Spring 1973). 9 Fischer Black died in 1995. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 737 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 738 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives and C0 5 Current call option value. S0 5 Current stock price. N(d) 5 The probability that a random draw from a standard normal distribution will be less than d. This equals the area under the normal curve up to d, as in the shaded area of Figure 21.6. In Excel, this function is called NORMSDIST( ). X 5 Exercise price. e 5 The base of the natural log function, approximately 2.71828. In Excel, ex can be evaluated using the function EXP(x). r 5 Risk-free interest rate (the annualized continuously compounded rate on a safe asset with the same maturity as the expiration date of the option, which is to be distinguished from rf, the discrete period interest rate). T 5 Time to expiration of option, in years. ln 5 Natural logarithm function. In Excel, ln(x) can be calculated as LN(x). s 5 Standard deviation of the annualized continuously compounded rate of return of the stock. Notice a surprising feature of Equation 21.1: The option value does not depend on the expected rate of return on the stock. In a sense, this information is already built into the formula with the inclusion of the stock price, which itself depends on the stock’s risk and return characteristics. This version of the Black-Scholes formula is predicated on the assumption that the stock pays no dividends. Although you may find the Black-Scholes formula intimidating, we can explain it at a somewhat intuitive level. The trick is to view the N(d ) terms (loosely) as risk-adjusted probabilities that the call option will expire in the money. First, look at Equation 21.1 assuming both N(d ) terms are close to 1.0, that is, when there is a very high probability the option will be exercised. Then the call option value is equal to S0 2 Xe2rT, which is what we called earlier the adjusted intrinsic value, S0 2 PV(X). This makes sense; if exercise is certain, we have a claim on a stock with current value S0, and an obligation with present value PV(X ), or, with continuous compounding, Xe2rT. Now look at Equation 21.1 assuming the N(d) = Shaded area N(d ) terms are close to zero, meaning the option almost certainly will not be exercised. Then the equation confirms that the call is worth nothing. For middle-range values of N(d ) between 0 and 1, Equation 21.1 tells us that the call value can be viewed as the present value of the call’s potential payoff adjusting for the probability of in-the-money expiration. How do the N(d) terms serve as riskadjusted probabilities? This question quickly leads us into advanced statistics. Notice, d however, that ln(S0/X), which appears in the 0 numerator of d1 and d2, is approximately the percentage amount by which the option is currently in or out of the money. For example, if Figure 21.6 A standard normal curve S0 5 105 and X 5 100, the option is 5% in the bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 738 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 739 money, and ln(105/100) 5 .049. Similarly, if S0 5 95, the option is 5% out of the money, and ln(95/100) 5 2.051. The denominator, s"T, adjusts the amount by which the option is in or out of the money for the volatility of the stock price over the remaining life of the option. An option in the money by a given percent is more likely to stay in the money if both stock price volatility and time to expiration are low. Therefore, N(d1) and N(d2) increase with the probability that the option will expire in the money. Example 21.4 Black-Scholes Valuation You can use the Black-Scholes formula fairly easily. Suppose you want to value a call option under the following circumstances: Stock price: S0 5 100 Exercise price: X 5 95 Interest rate: r 5 .10 (10% per year) Time to expiration: T 5 .25 (3 months or one-quarter of a year) Standard deviation: s 5 .50 (50% per year) First calculate d1 5 ln(100 / 95) 1 (.10 1 .52 / 2).25 .5√.25 5 .43 d2 5 .43 2 .5".25 5 .18 Next find N(d1) and N(d2). The values of the normal distribution are tabulated and may be found in many statistics textbooks. A table of N(d ) is provided here as Table 21.2. The normal distribution function, N(d ), is also provided in any spreadsheet program. In Microsoft Excel, for example, the function name is NORMSDIST. Using either Excel or Table 21.2 we find that N(.43) 5 .6664 N(.18) 5 .5714 Thus the value of the call option is C 5 100 3 .6664 2 95e2.103.25 3 .5714 5 66.64 2 52.94 5 $13.70 CONCEPT CHECK 21.6 Recalculate the value of the call option in Example 21.4 using a standard deviation of .6 instead of .5. Confirm that the option is worth more using the higher stock-return volatility. What if the option price in Example 21.4 were $15 rather than $13.70? Is the option mispriced? Maybe, but before betting your fortune on that, you may want to reconsider the valuation analysis. First, like all models, the Black-Scholes formula is based on some simplifying abstractions that make the formula only approximately valid. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 739 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 740 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives d N(d ) d N(d ) d N(d ) d N(d ) d N(d ) d N(d ) 23.00 22.95 22.90 22.85 22.80 22.75 22.70 22.65 22.60 22.55 22.50 22.45 22.40 22.35 22.30 22.25 22.20 22.15 22.10 22.05 22.00 21.98 21.96 21.94 21.92 21.90 21.88 21.86 21.84 21.82 21.80 21.78 21.76 21.74 21.72 21.70 21.68 21.66 21.64 21.62 21.60 .0013 .0016 .0019 .0022 .0026 .0030 .0035 .0040 .0047 .0054 .0062 .0071 .0082 .0094 .0107 .0122 .0139 .0158 .0179 .0202 .0228 .0239 .0250 .0262 .0274 .0287 .0301 .0314 .0329 .0344 .0359 .0375 .0392 .0409 .0427 .0446 .0465 .0485 .0505 .0526 .0548 21.58 21.56 21.54 21.52 21.50 21.48 21.46 21.44 21.42 21.40 21.38 21.36 21.34 21.32 21.30 21.28 21.26 21.24 21.22 21.20 21.18 21.16 21.14 21.12 21.10 21.08 21.06 21.04 21.02 21.00 20.98 20.96 20.94 20.92 20.90 20.88 20.86 20.84 20.82 20.80 20.78 .0571 .0594 .0618 .0643 .0668 .0694 .0721 .0749 .0778 .0808 .0838 .0869 .0901 .0934 .0968 .1003 .1038 .1075 .1112 .1151 .1190 .1230 .1271 .1314 .1357 .1401 .1446 .1492 .1539 .1587 .1635 .1685 .1736 .1788 .1841 .1894 .1949 .2005 .2061 .2119 .2177 20.76 20.74 20.72 20.70 20.68 20.66 20.64 20.62 20.60 20.58 20.56 20.54 20.52 20.50 20.48 20.46 20.44 20.42 20.40 20.38 20.36 20.34 20.32 20.30 20.28 20.26 20.24 20.22 20.20 20.18 20.16 20.14 20.12 20.10 20.08 20.06 20.04 20.02 0.00 0.02 0.04 .2236 .2297 .2358 .2420 .2483 .2546 .2611 .2676 .2743 .2810 .2877 .2946 .3015 .3085 .3156 .3228 .3300 .3373 .3446 .3520 .3594 .3669 .3745 .3821 .3897 .3974 .4052 .4129 .4207 .4286 .4365 .4443 .4523 .4602 .4681 .4761 .4841 .4920 .5000 .5080 .5160 0.06 0.08 0.10 0.12 0.14 0.16 0.18 0.20 0.22 0.24 0.26 0.28 0.30 0.32 0.34 0.36 0.38 0.40 0.42 0.44 0.46 0.48 0.50 0.52 0.54 0.56 0.58 0.60 0.62 0.64 0.66 0.68 0.70 0.72 0.74 0.76 0.78 0.80 0.82 0.84 .5239 .5319 .5398 .5478 .5557 .5636 .5714 .5793 .5871 .5948 .6026 .6103 .6179 .6255 .6331 .6406 .6480 .6554 .6628 .6700 .6773 .6844 .6915 .6985 .7054 .7123 .7191 .7258 .7324 .7389 .7454 .7518 .7580 .7642 .7704 .7764 .7823 .7882 .7939 .7996 0.86 0.88 0.90 0.92 0.94 0.96 0.98 1.00 1.02 1.04 1.06 1.08 1.10 1.12 1.14 1.16 1.18 1.20 1.22 1.24 1.26 1.28 1.30 1.32 1.34 1.36 1.38 1.40 1.42 1.44 1.46 1.48 1.50 1.52 1.54 1.56 1.58 1.60 1.62 1.64 .8051 .8106 .8159 .8212 .8264 .8315 .8365 .8414 .8461 .8508 .8554 .8599 .8643 .8686 .8729 .8770 .8810 .8849 .8888 .8925 .8962 .8997 .9032 .9066 .9099 .9131 .9162 .9192 .9222 .9251 .9279 .9306 .9332 .9357 .9382 .9406 .9429 .9452 .9474 .9495 1.66 1.68 1.70 1.72 1.74 1.76 1.78 1.80 1.82 1.84 1.86 1.88 1.90 1.92 1.94 1.96 1.98 2.00 2.05 2.10 2.15 2.20 2.25 2.30 2.35 2.40 2.45 2.50 2.55 2.60 2.65 2.70 2.75 2.80 2.85 2.90 2.95 3.00 3.05 .9515 .9535 .9554 .9573 .9591 .9608 .9625 .9641 .9656 .9671 .9686 .9699 .9713 .9726 .9738 .9750 .9761 .9772 .9798 .9821 .9842 .9861 .9878 .9893 .9906 .9918 .9929 .9938 .9946 .9953 .9960 .9965 .9970 .9974 .9978 .9981 .9984 .9986 .9989 Table 21.2 Cumulative normal distribution bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 740 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 741 Some of the important assumptions underlying the formula are the following: 1. The stock will pay no dividends until after the option expiration date. 2. Both the interest rate, r, and variance rate, s2, of the stock are constant (or in slightly more general versions of the formula, both are known functions of time— any changes are perfectly predictable). 3. Stock prices are continuous, meaning that sudden extreme jumps such as those in the aftermath of an announcement of a takeover attempt are ruled out. Variants of the Black-Scholes formula have been developed to deal with many of these limitations. Second, even within the context of the Black-Scholes model, you must be sure of the accuracy of the parameters used in the formula. Four of these—S0, X, T, and r—are straightforward. The stock price, exercise price, and time to expiration are readily determined. The interest rate used is the money market rate for a maturity equal to that of the option, and the dividend payout is reasonably predictable, at least over short horizons. The last input, though, the standard deviation of the stock return, is not directly observable. It must be estimated from historical data, from scenario analysis, or from the prices of other options, as we will describe momentarily. We saw in Chapter 5 that the historical variance of stock market returns can be calculated from n observations as follows: s2 5 n (r 2 r)2 n t a n n 2 1 t51 where r is the average return over the sample period. The rate of return on day t is defined to be consistent with continuous compounding as rt 5 ln(St/St21). [We note again that the natural logarithm of a ratio is approximately the percentage difference between the numerator and denominator so that ln(St/St21) is a measure of the rate of return of the stock from time t 2 1 to time t.] Historical variance commonly is computed using daily returns over periods of several months. Because the volatility of stock returns must be estimated, however, it is always possible that discrepancies between an option price and its Black-Scholes value are simply artifacts of error in the estimation of the stock’s volatility. In fact, market participants often give the option-valuation problem a different twist. Rather than calculating a Black-Scholes option value for a given stock’s standard deviation, they ask instead: What standard deviation would be necessary for the option price that I observe to be consistent with the Black-Scholes formula? This is called the implied volatility of the option, the volatility level for the stock implied by the option price.10 Investors can then judge whether they think the actual stock standard deviation exceeds the implied volatility. If it does, the option is considered a good buy; if actual volatility seems greater than the implied volatility, its fair price would exceed the observed price. Another variation is to compare two options on the same stock with equal expiration dates but different exercise prices. The option with the higher implied volatility would be considered relatively expensive, because a higher standard deviation is required to justify its price. The analyst might consider buying the option with the lower implied volatility and writing the option with the higher implied volatility. The Black-Scholes valuation formula, as well as the implied volatility, is easily calculated using an Excel spreadsheet like Spreadsheet 21.1. The model inputs are provided in 10 This concept was introduced in Richard E. Schmalensee and Robert R. Trippi, “Common Stock Volatility Expectations Implied by Option Premia,” Journal of Finance 33 (March 1978), pp. 129–47. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 741 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 742 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives A B C 1 INPUTS 2 Standard deviation (annual) 3 Maturity (in years) 4 Risk-free rate (annual) 0.06 5 Stock price 6 Exercise price 7 Dividend yield (annual) D E F OUTPUTS G H I J FORMULA FOR OUTPUT IN COLUMN E 0.2783 d1 0.0029 0.5 d2 –0.1939 E2–B2*SQRT(B3) N(d1) 0.5012 NORMSDIST(E2) 100 N(d2) 0.4231 NORMSDIST(E3) 105 B/S call value 7.0000 B5*EXP(–B7*B3)*E4–B6*EXP(–B4*B3)*E5 0 B/S put value 8.8968 B6*EXP(–B4*B3)*(1–E5)–B5*EXP(–B7*B3)*(1–E4) (LN(B5/B6)+(B4–B7+.5*B2^2)*B3)/(B2*SQRT(B3)) Spreadsheet 21.1 eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Spreadsheet to calculate Black-Scholes call option values column B, and the outputs are given in column E. The formulas for d1 and d2 are provided in the spreadsheet, and the Excel formula NORMSDIST(d1) is used to calculate N(d1).11 Cell E6 contains the Black-Scholes formula. (The formula in the spreadsheet actually includes an adjustment for dividends, as described in the next section.) To compute an implied volatility, we can use the Goal Seek command from the What-If Analysis menu (which can be found under the Data tab) in Excel. See Figure 21.7 for an illustration. Goal Seek asks us to change the value of one cell to make the value of another cell (called the target cell) equal to a specific value. For example, if we observe a call option selling for $7 with other inputs as given in the spreadsheet, we can use Goal Seek to change the value in cell B2 (the standard deviation of the stock) to set the option value in cell E6 equal to $7. The target cell, E6, is the call price, and the spreadsheet manipulates cell B2. When you click OK, the spreadsheet finds that a standard deviation equal to .2783 is consistent with a call price of $7; this would be the option’s implied volatility if it were selling at $7. A C B D E OUTPUTS F G H I J 1 INPUTS 2 Standard deviation (annual) 3 Maturity (in years) 4 Risk-free rate (annual) 0.06 N(d1) 0.5012 NORMSDIST(E2) 5 Stock price 100 N(d2) 0.4231 NORMSDIST(E3) 6 Exercise price 105 B/S call value 7.0000 B5*EXP(2B7*B3)*E42B6*EXP(2B4*B3)*E5 7 Dividend yield (annual) 0 B/S put value 8.8968 B6*EXP(2B4*B3)*(12E5) 2 B5*EXP(2B7*B3)*(12E4) K FORMULA FOR OUTPUT IN COLUMN E 0.2783 d1 0.0029 0.5 d2 20.1939 (LN(B5/B6)1(B42B71.5*B2^2)*B3)/(B2*SQRT(B3)) E22B2*SQRT(B3) 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 Figure 21.7 Using Goal Seek to find implied volatility eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 11 In some versions of Excel, the function is NORM.S.DIST(d,TRUE). bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 742 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 743 Jan-90 Jan-91 Jan-92 Jan-93 Jan-94 Jan-95 Jan-96 Jan-97 Jan-98 Jan-99 Jan-00 Jan-01 Jan-02 Jan-03 Jan-04 Jan-05 Jan-06 Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10 Jan-11 Jan-12 Jan-13 Implied Volatility (%) The Chicago Board Options Exchange 70 regularly computes the implied volatilSubprime and Credit Crises 60 ity of major stock indexes. Figure 21.8 is U.S. Debt a graph of the implied (30-day) volatility 50 LTCM Downgrade Iraq of the S&P 500 since 1990. During peri40 9/11 Gulf War ods of turmoil, implied volatility can spike 30 quickly. Notice the peaks in January 1991 20 (Gulf War), August 1998 (collapse of Long10 Term Capital Management), September 11, 0 2001, 2002 (build-up to invasion of Iraq), and, most dramatically, during the credit crisis of 2008. Because implied volatility correlates with crisis, it is sometimes called an “investor fear gauge.” Figure 21.8 Implied volatility of the S&P 500 (VIX index) A futures contract on the 30-day implied Source: Chicago Board Options Exchange, www.cboe.com. volatility of the S&P 500 has traded on the CBOE Futures Exchange since 2004. The payoff of the contract depends on market implied volatility at the expiration of the contract. The ticker symbol of the contract is VIX. As the nearby box makes clear, observers use it to infer the market’s assessment of possible stock price swings in coming months. In this case, the article questioned the relatively low level of the VIX in light of tense political negotiations at the end of 2012 over the so-called fiscal cliff. The question was whether the price of the VIX contract indicated that investors were being too complacent about the potential for market disruption if those negotiations were to fail. Figure 21.8 reveals an awkward empirical fact. While the Black-Scholes formula is derived assuming that stock volatility is constant, the time series of implied volatilities derived from that formula is in fact far from constant. This contradiction reminds us that the Black-Scholes model (like all models) is a simplification that does not capture all aspects of real markets. In this particular context, extensions of the pricing model that allow stock volatility to evolve randomly over time would be desirable, and, in fact, many extensions of the model along these lines have been developed.12 The fact that volatility changes unpredictably means that it can be difficult to choose the proper volatility input to use in any option-pricing model. A considerable amount of recent research has been devoted to techniques to predict changes in volatility. These techniques, known as ARCH and stochastic volatility models, posit that changes in volatility are partially predictable and that by analyzing recent levels and trends in volatility, one can improve predictions of future volatility.13 CONCEPT CHECK 21.7 Suppose the call option in Spreadsheet 21.1 actually is selling for $8. Is its implied volatility more or less than 27.83%? Use the spreadsheet (available at the Online Learning Center) and Goal Seek to find its implied volatility at this price. 12 Influential articles on this topic are J. Hull and A. White, “The Pricing of Options on Assets with Stochastic Volatilities,” Journal of Finance (June 1987), pp. 281–300; J. Wiggins, “Option Values under Stochastic Volatility,” Journal of Financial Economics (December 1987), pp. 351–72; and S. Heston, “A Closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic Volatility with Applications to Bonds and Currency Options,” Review of Financial Studies 6 (1993), pp. 327–43. For a more recent review, see E. Ghysels, A. Harvey, and E. Renault, “Stochastic Volatility,” in Handbook of Statistics, Vol. 14: Statistical Methods in Finance, ed. G. S. Maddala (Amsterdam: North Holland, 1996). 13 For an introduction to these models see C. Alexander, Market Models (Chichester, England: Wiley, 2001). bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 743 7/27/13 1:45 AM WORDS FROM THE STREET Final PDF to printer “Fear” Gauge Showing Little of It On the floor of the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE), those who trade in fear have seen little but calm. Measures of volatility in U.S. markets are pointing to relative calm, but some investors say the low readings are a sign of complacency. Unlike the rocky ride in the stock market since the U.S. presidential election, the CBOE’s Volatility Index, or VIX, has registered tranquility. For four months, the so-called fear gauge of financial markets has traded below its two-decade historical average of 20, its longest such streak in more than 5 years. Some investors worry that the low readings are a sign of complacency, and that the potential for further declines in response to unexpected bad news isn’t reflected in stock prices. These investors say various barometers of skittishness could tick higher as the year-end deadline nears for an agreement on taxes and spending. That anxiety also would likely be reflected in increased volatility in the stock and commodities markets. The VIX is an index calculated from the prices investors are willing to pay for options tied to the Standard & Poor’s 500-stock index. As investors become nervous, they are willing to pay more for options, driving up the value of the VIX. As market watchers search for clues about whether the relative calm can last, some of them are looking back to the early summer of 2011. Back then, the VIX was trading at levels close to today’s, even though market pundits worried that lawmakers wouldn’t agree to raise the debt ceiling. That scenario could have led the U.S. government to default on its debt. Within a few weeks, as the debt-ceiling wrangling was going down to the wire, Standard & Poor’s cut the U.S.’s long-term triple-A credit rating. The VIX nearly tripled to 48 in a span of two weeks. “The whole situation leads me to believe that this lack of a cushion in the market will lead to wilder shocks” to markets if negative events happen, says Michael Palmer of Group One Trading who trades the VIX on the floor of the CBOE. Source: Steven Russolillo and Kaitlyn Kiernan, The Wall Street Journal, November 26, 2012. Reprinted with permission. © 2012 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. Dividends and Call Option Valuation We noted earlier that the Black-Scholes call option formula applies to stocks that do not pay dividends. When dividends are to be paid before the option expires, we need to adjust the formula. The payment of dividends raises the possibility of early exercise, and for most realistic dividend payout schemes the valuation formula becomes significantly more complex than the Black-Scholes equation. We can apply some simple rules of thumb to approximate the option value, however. One popular approach, originally suggested by Black, calls for adjusting the stock price downward by the present value of any dividends that are to be paid before option expiration.14 Therefore, we would simply replace S0 with S0 2 PV(dividends) in the BlackScholes formula. Such an adjustment will take dividends into account by reflecting their eventual impact on the stock price. The option value then may be computed as before, assuming that the option will be held to expiration. In one special case, the dividend adjustment takes a simple form. Suppose the underlying asset pays a continuous flow of income. This might be a reasonable assumption for options on a stock index, where different stocks in the index pay dividends on different days, so that dividend income arrives in a more or less continuous flow. If the dividend yield, denoted d, is constant, one can show that the present value of that dividend flow accruing until the option expiration date is S0 (1 2 e2dT). (For intuition, notice that e2dT approximately equals 1 2 dT, so the value of the dividend is approximately dTS0.) In this case, S0 2 PV(Div) 5 S0 e2dT, and we can derive a Black-Scholes call option formula on the dividend-paying asset simply by substituting S0 e2dT for S0 in the original formula. This approach is used in Spreadsheet 21.1. These procedures yield a very good approximation of option value for European call options that must be held until expiration, but they do not allow for the fact that the holder of an American call option might choose to exercise the option just before a dividend. The current value of a call option, assuming that it will be exercised just before the ex-dividend date, might be greater than the value of the option assuming it will be held until expiration. Although holding the option until expiration allows greater effective time to expiration, 14 Fischer Black, “Fact and Fantasy in the Use of Options,” Financial Analysts Journal 31 (July–August 1975). 744 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 744 8/1/13 8:11 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 745 which increases the option value, it also entails more dividend payments, lowering the expected stock price at expiration and thereby lowering the current option value. For example, suppose that a stock selling at $20 will pay a $1 dividend in 4 months, whereas the call option on the stock does not expire for 6 months. The effective annual interest rate is 10%, so that the present value of the dividend is $1/(1.10)1/3 5 $0.97. Black suggests that we can compute the option value in one of two ways: 1. Apply the Black-Scholes formula assuming early exercise, thus using the actual stock price of $20 and a time to expiration of 4 months (the time until the dividend payment). 2. Apply the Black-Scholes formula assuming no early exercise, using the dividendadjusted stock price of $20 2 $.97 5 $19.03 and a time to expiration of 6 months. The greater of the two values is the estimate of the option value, recognizing that early exercise might be optimal. In other words, the so-called pseudo-American call option value is the maximum of the value derived by assuming that the option will be held until expiration and the value derived by assuming that the option will be exercised just before an ex-dividend date. Even this technique is not exact, however, for it assumes that the option holder makes an irrevocable decision now on when to exercise, when in fact the decision is not binding until exercise notice is given.15 Put Option Valuation We have concentrated so far on call option valuation. We can derive Black-Scholes European put option values from call option values using the put-call parity theorem. To value the put option, we simply calculate the value of the corresponding call option in Equation 21.1 from the Black-Scholes formula, and solve for the put option value as P 5 C 1 PV(X ) 2 S0 5 C 1 Xe2rT 2 S0 (21.2) We calculate the present value of the exercise price using continuous compounding to be consistent with the Black-Scholes formula. Sometimes, it is easier to work with a put option valuation formula directly. If we substitute the Black-Scholes formula for a call in Equation 21.2, we obtain the value of a European put option as P 5 Xe2rT 3 1 2 N(d2) 4 2 S0 3 1 2 N(d1) 4 Example 21.5 (21.3) Black-Scholes Put Valuation Using data from Example 21.4 (C 5 $13.70, X 5 $95, S 5 $100, r 5 .10, s 5 .50, and T 5 .25), Equation 21.3 implies that a European put option on that stock with identical exercise price and time to expiration is worth $95e2.10 3 .25(1 2 .5714) 2 $100(1 2 .6664) 5 $6.35 15 An exact formula for American call valuation on dividend-paying stocks has been developed in Richard Roll, “An Analytic Valuation Formula for Unprotected American Call Options on Stocks with Known Dividends,” Journal of Financial Economics 5 (November 1977). The technique has been discussed and revised in Robert Geske, “A Note on an Analytical Formula for Unprotected American Call Options on Stocks with Known Dividends,” Journal of Financial Economics 7 (December 1979), and Robert E. Whaley, “On the Valuation of American Call Options on Stocks with Known Dividends,” Journal of Financial Economics 9 (June 1981). bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 745 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 746 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Notice that this value is consistent with put-call parity: P 5 C 1 PV(X ) 2 S0 5 13.70 1 95e2.10 3 .25 2 100 5 6.35 As we noted traders can do, we might then compare this formula value to the actual put price as one step in formulating a trading strategy. Dividends and Put Option Valuation Equation 21.2 or 21.3 is valid for European puts on non-dividend-paying stocks. As we did for call options, if the underlying asset pays a dividend, we can find European put values by substituting S0 2 PV(Div) for S0. Cell E7 in Spreadsheet 21.1 allows for a continuous dividend flow with a dividend yield of d. In that case S0 2 PV(Div) 5 S0e2dT. However, listed put options on stocks are American options that offer the opportunity of early exercise, and we have seen that the right to exercise puts early can turn out to be valuable. This means that an American put option must be worth more than the corresponding European option. Therefore, Equation 21.2 or 21.3 describes only the lower bound on the true value of the American put. However, in many applications the approximation is very accurate.16 21.5 Using the Black-Scholes Formula Hedge Ratios and the Black-Scholes Formula In the last chapter, we considered two investments in FinCorp stock: 100 shares or 1,000 call options. We saw that the call option position was more sensitive to swings in the stock price than was the all-stock position. To analyze the overall exposure to a stock price more precisely, however, it is necessary to quantify these relative sensitivities. We can summarize the overall exposure of portfolios of options with various exercise prices and times to expiration using the hedge ratio, the change in option price for a $1 increase in the stock price. A call option, therefore, has a positive hedge ratio and a put option a negative hedge ratio. The hedge ratio is commonly called the option’s delta. If you were to graph the option value as a function of the stock value, as we have done for a call option in Figure 21.9, the hedge ratio is simply the slope of the curve evaluated at the current stock price. For example, suppose the slope of the curve at S0 5 $120 equals .60. As the stock increases in value by $1, the option increases by approximately $.60, as the figure shows. For every call option written, .60 share of stock would be needed to hedge the investor’s portfolio. If one writes 10 options and holds six shares of stock, according to the hedge ratio of .6, a $1 increase in stock price will result in a gain of $6 on the stock holdings, whereas the loss on the 10 options written will be 10 3 $.60, an equivalent $6. The stock price movement leaves total wealth unaltered, which is what a hedged position is intended to do. Black-Scholes hedge ratios are particularly easy to compute. The hedge ratio for a call is N(d1), whereas the hedge ratio for a put is N(d1) 2 1. We defined N(d1) as part of the BlackScholes formula in Equation 21.1. Recall that N(d) stands for the area under the standard normal curve up to d. Therefore, the call option hedge ratio must be positive and less than 1.0, whereas the put option hedge ratio is negative and of smaller absolute value than 1.0. 16 For a more complete treatment of American put valuation, see R. Geske and H. E. Johnson, “The American Put Valued Analytically,” Journal of Finance 39 (December 1984), pp. 1511–24. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 746 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation Figure 21.9 verifies that the slope of the call option valuation function is less than Value of a Call (C) 1.0, approaching 1.0 only as the stock price becomes much greater than the exercise price. This tells us that option values change less 40 than one-for-one with changes in stock prices. Why should this be? Suppose an option is so far in the money that you are absolutely certain it will be exercised. In that case, every 20 dollar increase in the stock price would Slope 5 .6 increase the option value by $1. But if there is a reasonable chance the call option will expire out of the money, even after a moderate stock 0 price gain, a $1 increase in the stock price will not necessarily increase the ultimate payoff 120 to the call; therefore, the call price will not respond by a full dollar. The fact that hedge ratios are less than 1.0 Figure 21.9 Call option value and hedge ratio does not contradict our earlier observation that options offer leverage and disproportionate sensitivity to stock price movements. Although dollar movements in option prices are less than dollar movements in the stock price, the rate of return volatility of options remains greater than stock return volatility because options sell at lower prices. In our example, with the stock selling at $120, and a hedge ratio of .6, an option with exercise price $120 may sell for $5. If the stock price increases to $121, the call price would be expected to increase by only $.60 to $5.60. The percentage increase in the option value is $.60/$5.00 5 12%, however, whereas the stock price increase is only $1/$120 5 .83%. The ratio of the percentage changes is 12%/.83% 5 14.4. For every 1% increase in the stock price, the option price increases by 14.4%. This ratio, the percentage change in option price per percentage change in stock price, is called the option elasticity. The hedge ratio is an essential tool in portfolio management and control. An example will show why. Example 21.6 747 S0 Hedge Ratios Consider two portfolios, one holding 750 FinCorp calls and 200 shares of FinCorp and the other holding 800 shares of FinCorp. Which portfolio has greater dollar exposure to FinCorp price movements? You can answer this question easily by using the hedge ratio. Each option changes in value by H dollars for each dollar change in stock price, where H stands for the hedge ratio. Thus, if H equals .6, the 750 options are equivalent to .6 3 750 5 450 shares in terms of the response of their market value to FinCorp stock price movements. The first portfolio has less dollar sensitivity to stock price change because the 450 share-equivalents of the options plus the 200 shares actually held are less than the 800 shares held in the second portfolio. This is not to say, however, that the first portfolio is less sensitive to the stock’s rate of return. As we noted in discussing option elasticities, the first portfolio may have lower total value than the second, so despite its lower sensitivity in terms of total market value, it might have greater rate of return sensitivity. Because a call option has a lower market value than the stock, its price changes more than proportionally with stock price changes, even though its hedge ratio is less than 1.0. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 747 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer eXcel APPLICATIONS: Black-Scholes Option Valuation T analysis of calls while the second workbook presents similar analysis for puts. You can find these spreadsheets at the Online Learning Center at www.mhhe.com/bkm. he spreadsheet below can be used to determine option values using the Black-Scholes model. The inputs are the stock price, standard deviation, expiration of the option, exercise price, risk-free rate, and dividend yield. The call option is valued using Equation 21.1 and the put is valued using Equation 21.3. For both calls and puts, the dividend-adjusted Black-Scholes formula substitutes Se2dT for S, as outlined on page 744. The model also calculates the intrinsic and time value for both puts and calls. Further, the model presents sensitivity analysis using the one-way data table. The first workbook presents the 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 A B Chapter 21- Black-Scholes Option Pricing Call Valuation & Call Time Premiums Standard deviation (σ) Variance (annual, σ2) Time to expiration (years, T) Risk-free rate (annual, r) Current stock price (S0) Exercise price (X) Dividend yield (annual, δ) d1 d2 N(d1) N(d2) Black-Scholes call value Black-Scholes put value 0.27830 0.07745 0.50 6.00% $100.00 $105.00 0.00% 0.0029095 −0.193878 0.50116 0.42314 $6.99992 $8.89670 Intrinsic value of call Time value of call $0.00000 6.99992 Intrinsic value of put Time value of put $5.00000 3.89670 CONCEPT CHECK 21.8 C D E Call Standard Option Deviation Value 7.000 0.15 3.388 0.18 4.089 0.20 4.792 0.23 5.497 0.25 6.202 0.28 6.907 0.30 7.612 0.33 8.317 0.35 9.022 0.38 9.726 0.40 10.429 0.43 11.132 0.45 11.834 0.48 12.536 0.50 13.236 Excel Questions 1. Find the value of the call and put options using the parameters given in this box but changing the standard deviation to .25. What happens to the value of each option? 2. What is implied volatility if the call option is selling for $9? F H G LEGEND: Enter data Value calculated See comment Standard Deviation 0.150 0.175 0.200 0.225 0.250 0.275 0.300 0.325 0.350 0.375 0.400 0.425 0.450 0.475 0.500 Call Time Value 7.000 3.388 4.089 4.792 5.497 6.202 6.907 7.612 8.317 9.022 9.726 10.429 11.132 11.834 12.536 13.236 I J Stock Price $60 $65 $70 $75 $80 $85 $90 $95 $100 $105 $110 $115 $120 $125 $130 $135.00 K Call Option Value 7.000 0.017 0.061 0.179 0.440 0.935 1.763 3.014 4.750 7.000 9.754 12.974 16.602 20.572 24.817 29.275 33.893 L M Stock Price $60 $65 $70 $75 $80 $85 $90 $95 $100 $105 $110 $115 $120 $125 $130 $135 N Call Time Value 7.000 0.017 0.061 0.179 0.440 0.935 1.763 3.014 4.750 7.000 9.754 7.974 6.602 5.572 4.817 4.275 3.893 Portfolio Insurance In Chapter 20, we showed that protective put strategies offer a sort of insurance policy on an asset. The What is the elasticity of a put option currently protective put has proven to be extremely popular with selling for $4 with exercise price $120 and hedge investors. Even if the asset price falls, the put conveys ratio 2.4 if the stock price is currently $122? the right to sell the asset for the exercise price, which is a way to lock in a minimum portfolio value. With an at-the-money put (X 5 S0), the maximum loss that can be realized is the cost of the put. The asset can be sold for X, which equals its original value, so even if the asset price falls, the investor’s net loss over the period is just the cost of the put. If the asset value increases, however, upside potential is unlimited. Figure 21.10 graphs the profit or loss on a protective put position as a function of the change in the value of the underlying asset, P. 748 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 748 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 749 While the protective put is a simple and convenient way Change in Value of Protected Position to achieve portfolio insurance, that is, to limit the worst-case portfolio rate of return, there are practical difficulties in trying to insure a portfolio of stocks. First, unless the investor’s portfolio corresponds to a standard 0 Change in Value market index for which puts are 0 of Underlying Asset traded, a put option on the portCost of Put folio will not be available for 2P purchase. And if index puts are used to protect a non-indexed portfolio, tracking error can result. For example, if the portfolio falls in value while the market index rises, the put will Figure 21.10 Profit on a protective put strategy fail to provide the intended protection. Moreover, the maturities of traded options may not match the investor’s horizon. Therefore, rather than using option strategies, investors may use trading strategies that mimic the payoff to a protective put option. Here is the general idea. Even if a put option on the desired portfolio does not exist, a theoretical option-pricing model (such as the Black-Scholes model) can be used to determine how that option’s price would respond to the portfolio’s value if it did trade. For example, if stock prices were to fall, the put option would increase in value. The option model could quantify this relationship. The net exposure of the (hypothetical) protective put portfolio to swings in stock prices is the sum of the exposures of the two components of the portfolio, the stock and the put. The net exposure of the portfolio equals the equity exposure less the (offsetting) put option exposure. We can create “synthetic” protective put positions by holding a quantity of stocks with the same net exposure to market swings as the hypothetical protective put position. The key to this strategy is the option delta, or hedge ratio, that is, the change in the price of the protective put option per change in the value of the underlying stock portfolio. Example 21.7 Synthetic Protective Put Options Suppose a portfolio is currently valued at $100 million. An at-the-money put option on the portfolio might have a hedge ratio or delta of 2.6, meaning the option’s value swings $.60 for every dollar change in portfolio value, but in an opposite direction. Suppose the stock portfolio falls in value by 2%. The profit on a hypothetical protective put position (if the put existed) would be as follows (in millions of dollars): Loss on stocks: Gain on put: Net loss bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 749 2% of $100 5 $2.00 .6 3 $2.00 5 1.20 5 $ .80 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 750 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives We create the synthetic option position by selling a proportion of shares equal to the put option’s delta (i.e., selling 60% of the shares) and placing the proceeds in risk-free T-bills. The rationale is that the hypothetical put option would have offset 60% of any change in the stock portfolio’s value, so one must reduce portfolio risk directly by selling 60% of the equity and putting the proceeds into a risk-free asset. Total return on a synthetic protective put position with $60 million in risk-free investments such as T-bills and $40 million in equity is Loss on stocks: 1 Loss on bills: Net loss 2% of $40 5 $.80 5 0 5 $.80 The synthetic and actual protective put positions have equal returns. We conclude that if you sell a proportion of shares equal to the put option’s delta and place the proceeds in cash equivalents, your exposure to the stock market will equal that of the desired protective put position. The challenge with this procedure is that deltas constantly change. Figure 21.11 shows that as the stock price falls, the magnitude of the appropriate hedge ratio increases. Therefore, market declines require extra hedging, that is, additional conversion of equity into cash. This constant updating of the hedge ratio is called dynamic hedging (alternatively, delta hedging). Dynamic hedging is one reason portfolio insurance has been said to contribute to market volatility. Market declines trigger additional sales of stock as portfolio insurers strive to increase their hedging. These additional sales are seen as reinforcing or exaggerating marValue of a Put (P) ket downturns. In practice, portfolio insurers often do Higher Slope 5 not actually buy or sell stocks directly when High Hedge Ratio they update their hedge positions. Instead, they minimize trading costs by buying or selling stock index futures as a substitute for sale of the stocks themselves. As you will see in the next chapter, stock prices and index futures prices usually are very tightly linked by cross-market arbitrageurs so that futures transactions can be used as reliable Low Slope 5 proxies for stock transactions. Instead of Low Hedge Ratio selling equities based on the put option’s S0 delta, insurers will sell an equivalent number 0 of futures contracts.17 Several portfolio insurers suffered great setbacks during the market crash of October 19, Figure 21.11 Hedge ratios change as the stock price 1987, when the market suffered an unprecefluctuates dented 1-day loss of about 20%. A description 17 Notice, however, that the use of index futures reintroduces the problem of tracking error between the portfolio and the market index. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 750 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 751 of what happened then should let you appreciate the complexities of applying a seemingly straightforward hedging concept. 1. Market volatility at the crash was much greater than ever encountered before. Put option deltas based on historical experience were too low; insurers underhedged, held too much equity, and suffered excessive losses. 2. Prices moved so fast that insurers could not keep up with the necessary rebalancing. They were “chasing deltas” that kept getting away from them. The futures market also saw a “gap” opening, where the opening price was nearly 10% below the previous day’s close. The price dropped before insurers could update their hedge ratios. 3. Execution problems were severe. First, current market prices were unavailable, with trade execution and the price quotation system hours behind, which made computation of correct hedge ratios impossible. Moreover, trading in stocks and stock futures ceased during some periods. The continuous rebalancing capability that is essential for a viable insurance program vanished during the precipitous market collapse. 4. Futures prices traded at steep discounts to their proper levels compared to reported stock prices, thereby making the sale of futures (as a proxy for equity sales) seem expensive. Although you will see in the next chapter that stock index futures prices normally exceed the value of the stock index, Figure 21.12 shows that on October 19, futures sold far below the stock index level. When some insurers gambled that the futures price would recover to its usual premium over the stock index, and chose to defer sales, they remained underhedged. As the market fell farther, their portfolios experienced substantial losses. Although most observers at the time believed that the portfolio insurance industry would never recover from the market crash, delta hedging is still alive and well on Wall Street. Dynamic hedges are widely used by large firms to hedge potential losses from options positions. For example, the nearby box notes that when Microsoft ended its employee stock option program and J. P. Morgan purchased many already-issued options 10 0 210 220 230 240 10 11 12 October 19 1 2 3 4 10 11 12 October 20 1 2 3 4 Figure 21.12 S&P 500 cash-to-futures spread in points at 15-minute intervals Note: Trading in futures contracts halted between 12:15 and 1:05. Source: The Wall Street Journal. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal, © 1987 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All rights reserved worldwide. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 751 7/27/13 1:45 AM WORDS FROM THE STREET Final PDF to printer J. P. Morgan Rolls Dice on Microsoft Options Microsoft, in a shift that could be copied throughout the technology business, said yesterday that it plans to stop issuing stock options to its employees, and instead will provide them with restricted stock. Though details of the plan still aren’t clear, J. P. Morgan effectively plans to buy the options from Microsoft employees who opt for restricted stock instead. Employee stock options are granted as a form of compensation and allow employees the right to exchange the options for shares of company stock. The price offered to employees for the options presumably will be lower than the current value, giving J. P. Morgan a chance to make a profit on the deal. Rather than holding the options, and thus betting Microsoft’s stock will rise, people familiar with the bank’s strategy say J. P. Morgan probably will match each option it buys from the company’s employees with a separate trade in the stock market that both hedges the bet and gives itself a margin of profit. For Wall Street’s so-called rocket scientists who do complicated financial transactions such as this one, the strategy behind J. P. Morgan’s deal with Microsoft isn’t particularly unique or sophisticated. They add that the bank has several ways to deal with the millions of Microsoft options that could come its way. The bank, for instance, could hedge the options by shorting, or betting against, Microsoft stock. Microsoft has the largest market capitalization of any stock in the market, and its shares are among the most liquid, meaning it would be easy to hedge the risk of holding those options. J. P. Morgan also could sell the options to investors, much as they would do with a syndicated loan, thereby spreading the risk. Source: Jathon Sapsford and Ken Brown, The Wall Street Journal, July 9, 2003. Reprinted with permission. © 2003 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All rights reserved. of Microsoft employees, it was widely expected that Morgan would protect its options position by selling shares in Microsoft in accord with a delta hedging strategy. Option Pricing and the Crisis of 2008–2009 Merton18 shows how option pricing models can provide insight into the financial crisis of 2008–2009. The key to understanding his argument is to remember that when banks lend to or buy the debt of firms with limited liability, they implicitly write a put option to the borrower (see Chapter 20, Section 20.5). If the borrower has sufficient assets to pay off the loan when it comes due, it will do so, and the lender will be fully repaid. But if the borrower has insufficient assets, it can declare bankruptcy and discharge its obligations by transferring ownership of the firm to its creditors. The borrower’s ability to satisfy the loan by transferring ownership is equivalent to the right to “sell” itself to the creditor for the face value of the loan. This arrangement is therefore just like a put option on the firm with exercise price equal to the stipulated loan repayment. Consider the payoff to the lender at loan maturity (time T) as a function of the value of the borrowing firm, VT, when the loan, with face value L, comes due. If VT $ L, the lender is paid off in full. But if VT , L, the lender gets the firm, which is worth less than the promised payment L. We can write the payoff in a way that emphasizes the implicit put option: Payoff 5 b L 0 5L2 b VT L 2 VT if VT $ L if VT , L (21.4) Equation 21.4 shows that the payoff on the loan equals L (when the firm has sufficient assets to pay off the debt), minus the payoff of a put option on the value of the firm (VT) with an exercise price of L. Therefore, we may view risky lending as a combination of safe lending, with a guaranteed payoff of L, combined with a short position in a put option on the borrower. 18 This material is based on a lecture given by Robert Merton at MIT in March 2009. You can find the lecture online at http://mitworld.mit.edu/video/659. 752 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 752 8/1/13 8:11 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 753 Value of Put as % of Face Value of Debt When firms sell credit default swaps 50 (see Chapter 14, Section 14.5), the implicit put option is even clearer. Here, 40 the CDS seller agrees to make up any losses due to the insolvency of a bond 30 issuer. If the issuer goes bankrupt, leav20 ing assets of only VT for the creditors, the CDS seller is obligated to make up the 10 difference, L 2 VT. This is in essence a pure put option. 0 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 225 250 Now think about the exposure of these 210 implicit put writers to changes in the Firm Value as Percent of Face Value of Debt financial health of the underlying firm. The value of a put option on VT appears in Figure 21.13. When the firm is finanFigure 21.13 Value of implicit put option on a loan guarantee as cially strong (i.e., V is far greater than L), a percentage of the face value of debt (Debt maturity 5 1 year; the slope of the curve is nearly zero, Standard deviation of value of firm 5 40%; Risk free rate 5 6%) implying that there is little exposure of the implicit put writer (either the bank or the CDS writer) to the value of the borrowing firm. For example, when firm value is 1.75 times the value of the debt, the dashed line drawn tangent to the put value curve has a slope of only 2.040. But if there is a big shock to the economy, and firm value falls, not only does the value of the implicit put rise, but its slope is now steeper, implying that exposure to further shocks is now far greater. When firm value is only 75% of the value of the loan, the slope of the line tangent to the put value valuation curve is far steeper, 2.644. You can see how as you get closer to the edge of the cliff, it gets easier and easier to slide right off. We often hear people say that a shock to asset values of the magnitude of the financial crisis was a 10-sigma event, by which they mean that such an event was so extreme that it would be 10 standard deviations away from an expected outcome, making it virtually inconceivable. But this analysis shows that standard deviation may be a moving target, increasing dramatically as the firm weakens. As the economy falters and put options go further into the money, their sensitivity to further shocks increases, increasing the risk that even worse losses may be around the corner. The built-in instability of risk exposures makes a scenario like the crisis more plausible and should give us pause when we discount an extreme scenario as “almost impossible.” Option Pricing and Portfolio Theory We’ve just seen that the option pricing model predicts that security risk characteristics can be unstable. For example, as the firm weakens, the risk of its debt can quickly accelerate. So, too, can equity risk change dramatically as the firm’s financial condition deteriorates. We know from the last chapter (Section 20.5) that equity in a levered firm is like a call option on the value of the firm. If firm value exceeds the value of the firm’s maturing debt, the firm can choose to pay off the debt, retaining the difference between firm value and the face value of its debt. If not, the firm can default on the loan, turning the firm over to its creditors, and the equity holders get nothing. In this sense, equity is a call option, and the firm’s total value is the underlying asset. In Section 21.5, we saw that the elasticity of an option measures the sensitivity of its rate of return to the rate of return on the underlying asset. For example, if a call option’s elasticity is five, its rate of return will swing five times as widely as the rate of return on the underlying asset. This would imply that both the option’s beta and its standard deviation are five times the bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 753 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 754 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives beta and standard deviation of the underlying asset. Therefore, when compil30 ing the “input list” for creating an efficient portfolio, we may 25 wish to think of equity as an implicit call option and com20 pute its elasticity with respect 15 to the total value of the firm. For example, if the covariance 10 of the firm’s assets with other securities is stable, then we 5 can use elasticity to find the covariance of the firm’s equity 0 25 50 75 100 125 150 175 200 with those securities. This will Stock Price allow us to calculate beta and standard deviation. Unfortunately, elasticity can Figure 21.14 Call option elasticity as a function of stock price itself be a moving target. As (Parameters: s 5 .25; T 5 .5, r 5 .06; X 5 100) the firm gets weaker, its elasticity will increase, potentially very quickly. Figure 21.14 uses the Black-Scholes model to plot call option elasticity as a function of the value of the underlying stock. Notice that as the option goes out of the money (the stock price falls below 100), elasticity increases rapidly and without limit. Similarly, as the firm gets closer to insolvency (the value of firm assets falls below the face value of debt), equity elasticity shoots up, and even small changes in financial condition can lead to major changes in risk. Elasticity is far more stable (and closer to 1) when the firm is healthy, i.e., the implicit call option is deep in the money. Similarly, equity risk characteristics will be far more stable for healthy firms than for precarious ones. Elasticity 35 Hedging Bets on Mispriced Options Suppose you believe that the standard deviation of IBM stock returns will be 35% over the next few weeks, but IBM put options are selling at a price consistent with a volatility of 33%. Because the put’s implied volatility is less than your forecast of the stock volatility, you believe the option is underpriced. Using your assessment of volatility in an optionpricing model like the Black-Scholes formula, you would estimate that the fair price for the puts exceeds the actual price. Does this mean that you ought to buy put options? Perhaps it does, but by doing so, you risk losses if IBM stock performs well, even if you are correct about the volatility. You would like to separate your bet on volatility from the “attached” bet inherent in purchasing a put that IBM’s stock price will fall. In other words, you would like to speculate on the option mispricing by purchasing the put option, but hedge the resulting exposure to the performance of IBM stock. The option delta can be interpreted as a hedge ratio that can be used for this purpose. The delta was defined as Delta 5 Change in value of option Change in value of stock (21.5) Therefore, delta is the slope of the option-pricing curve. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 754 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 755 This ratio tells us precisely how many shares of stock we must hold to offset our exposure to IBM. For example, if the delta is 2.6, then the put will fall by $.60 in value for every one-point increase in IBM stock, and we need to hold .6 share of stock to hedge each put. If we purchase 10 option contracts, each for 100 shares, we would need to buy 600 shares of stock. If the stock price rises by $1, each put option will decrease in value by $.60, resulting in a loss of $600. However, the loss on the puts will be offset by a gain on the stock holdings of $1 per share 3 600 shares. To see how the profits on this strategy might develop, let’s use the following example. Example 21.8 Speculating on Mispriced Options Suppose option expiration T is 60 days; put price P is $4.495; exercise price X is $90; stock price S is $90; and the risk-free rate r is 4%. We assume that the stock will not pay a dividend in the next 60 days. Given these data, the implied volatility on the option is 33%, as we posited. However, you believe the true volatility is 35%, implying that the fair put price is $4.785. Therefore, if the market assessment of volatility is revised to the value you believe is correct, your profit will be $.29 per put purchased. Recall that the hedge ratio, or delta, of a put option equals N(d1) 2 1, where N (•) is the cumulative normal distribution function and d1 5 ln(S/X ) 1 (r 1 s2 / 2)T s√T Using your estimate of s 5 .35, you find that the hedge ratio N(d1) 2 1 5 2.453. Suppose, therefore, that you purchase 10 option contracts (1,000 puts) and purchase 453 shares of stock. Once the market “catches up” to your presumably better volatility estimate, the put options purchased will increase in value. If the market assessment of volatility changes as soon as you purchase the options, your profits should equal 1,000 3 $.29 5 $290. The option price will be affected as well by any change in the stock price, but this part of your exposure will be eliminated if the hedge ratio is chosen properly. Your profit should be based solely on the effect of the change in the implied volatility of the put, with the impact of the stock price hedged away. Table 21.3 illustrates your profits as a function of the stock price assuming that the put price changes to reflect your estimate of volatility. Panel B shows that the put option alone can provide profits or losses depending on whether the stock price falls or rises. We see in panel C, however, that each hedged put option provides profits nearly equal to the original mispricing, regardless of the change in the stock price. CONCEPT CHECK 21.9 Suppose you bet on volatility by purchasing calls instead of puts. How would you hedge your exposure to stock-price fluctuations? What is the hedge ratio? Notice in Example 21.8 that the profit is not exactly independent of the stock price. This is because as the stock price changes, so do the deltas used to calculate the hedge ratio. The hedge ratio in principle would need to be continually adjusted as deltas evolve. The sensitivity of the delta to the stock price is called the gamma of the option. Option gammas are analogous to bond convexity. In both cases, the curvature of the value function means that hedge ratios or durations change with market conditions, making rebalancing a necessary part of hedging strategies. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 755 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 756 PART VI Table 21.3 Profit on hedged put portfolio Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives A. Cost to establish hedged position 1,000 put options @ $4.495/option 453 shares @ $90/share TOTAL outlay $ 4,495 40,770 $45,265 B. Value of put option as a function of the stock price at implied volatility of 35% Stock Price: Put price Profit (loss) on each put 89 $ 5.254 0.759 90 $ 4.785 0.290 91 $ 4.347 (0.148) Stock Price: Value of 1,000 put options Value of 453 shares 89 $ 5,254 40,317 90 $ 4,785 40,770 91 $ 4,347 41,223 TOTAL Profit (5 Value 2 Cost from panel A) $45,571 306 $45,555 290 $45,570 305 C. Value of and profit on hedged put portfolio A variant of the strategy in Example 21.8 involves cross-option speculation. Suppose you observe a 45-day expiration call option on IBM with strike price 95 selling at a price consistent with a volatility of s 5 33% while another 45-day call with strike price 90 has an implied volatility of only 27%. Because the underlying asset and expiration date are identical, you conclude that the call with the higher implied volatility is relatively overpriced. To exploit the mispricing, you might buy the cheap calls (with strike price 90 and implied volatility of 27%) and write the expensive calls (with strike price 95 and implied volatility 33%). If the risk-free rate is 4% and IBM is selling at $90 per share, the calls purchased will be priced at $3.6202 and the calls written will be priced at $2.3735. Despite the fact that you are long one call and short another, your exposure to IBM stock-price uncertainty will not be hedged using this strategy. This is because calls with different strike prices have different sensitivities to the price of the underlying asset. The lower-strike-price call has a higher delta and therefore greater exposure to the price of IBM. If you take an equal number of positions in these two options, you will inadvertently establish a bullish position in IBM, as the calls you purchase have higher deltas than the calls you write. In fact, you may recall from Chapter 20 that this portfolio (long call with low exercise price and short call with high exercise price) is called a bullish spread. To establish a hedged position, we can use the hedge ratio approach as follows. Consider the 95-strike-price options you write as the asset that hedges your exposure to the 90-strike-price options you purchase. Then the hedge ratio is H5 5 Change in value of 90-strike-price call for $1 change in IBM Change in value of 95-strike-price call for $1 change in IBM Delta of 90-strike-price call .1 Delta of 95-strike-price call You need to write more than one call with the higher strike price to hedge the purchase of each call with the lower strike price. Because the prices of higher-strike-price calls are less sensitive to IBM prices, more of them are required to offset the exposure. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 756 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 757 Suppose the true annual volatility of the stock is midway between the two implied volatilities, so s 5 30%. We know that the delta of a call option is N(d1). Therefore, the deltas of the two options and the hedge ratio are computed as follows: Option with strike price 90: d1 5 ln(90/90) 1 (.04 1 .302 /2) 3 45/365 .30"45/365 5 .0995 N(d1) 5 .5396 Option with strike price 95: d1 5 ln(90/95) 1 (.04 1 .302 /2) 3 45/365 .30"45/365 5 2.4138 N(d1) 5 .3395 Hedge ratio: .5396 5 1.589 .3395 Therefore, for every 1,000 call options purchased with strike price 90, we need to write 1,589 call options with strike price 95. Following this strategy enables us to bet on the relative mispricing of the two options without taking a position on IBM. Panel A of Table 21.4 shows that the position will result in a cash inflow of $151.30. The premium income on the calls written exceeds the cost of the calls purchased. When you establish a position in stocks and options that is hedged with respect to fluctuations in the price of the underlying asset, your portfolio is said to be delta neutral, meaning that the portfolio has no tendency to either increase or decrease in value when the stock price fluctuates. Let’s check that our options position is in fact delta neutral. Suppose that the implied volatilities of the two options come back into alignment just after you establish your Table 21.4 A. Cost flow when portfolio is established Purchase 1,000 calls (X 5 90) @ $3.6202 (option priced at implied volatility of 27%) Write 1,589 calls (X 5 95) @ $2.3735 (option priced at implied volatility of 33%) TOTAL Profits on deltaneutral options portfolio $ 3,620.20 cash outflow 3,771.50 cash inflow $ 151.30 net cash inflow B. Option prices at implied volatility of 30% Stock Price: 90-strike-price calls 95-strike-price calls 89 90 91 $3.478 1.703 $3.997 2.023 $4.557 2.382 C. Value of portfolio after implied volatilities converge to 30% Stock Price: Value of 1,000 calls held 2 Value of 1,589 calls written TOTAL bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 757 89 $3,478 2,705 $ 773 90 $3,997 3,214 $ 782 91 $4,557 3,785 $ 772 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 758 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives position, so that both options are priced at implied volatilities of 30%. You expect to profit from the increase in the value of the call purchased as well as from the decrease in the value of the call written. The option prices at 30% volatility are given in panel B of Table 21.4 and the values of your position for various stock prices are presented in panel C. Although the profit or loss on each option is affected by the stock price, the value of the delta-neutral option portfolio is positive and essentially independent of the price of IBM. Moreover, we saw in panel A that the portfolio would have been established without ever requiring a cash outlay. You would have cash inflows both when you establish the portfolio and when you liquidate it after the implied volatilities converge to 30%. This unusual profit opportunity arises because you have identified prices out of alignment. Such opportunities could not arise if prices were at equilibrium levels. By exploiting the pricing discrepancy using a delta-neutral strategy, you should earn profits regardless of the price movement in IBM stock. Delta-neutral hedging strategies are also subject to practical problems, the most important of which is the difficulty in assessing the proper volatility for the coming period. If the volatility estimate is incorrect, so will be the deltas, and the overall position will not truly be hedged. Moreover, option or option-plus-stock positions generally will not be neutral with respect to changes in volatility. For example, a put option hedged by a stock might be delta neutral, but it is not volatility neutral. Changes in the market assessments of volatility will affect the option price even if the stock price is unchanged. These problems can be serious, because volatility estimates are never fully reliable. First, volatility cannot be observed directly and must be estimated from past data which imparts measurement error to the forecast. Second, we’ve seen that both historical and implied volatilities fluctuate over time. Therefore, we are always shooting at a moving target. Although delta-neutral positions are hedged against changes in the price of the underlying asset, they still are subject to volatility risk, the risk incurred from unpredictable changes in volatility. The sensitivity of an option price to changes in volatility is called the option’s vega. Thus, although delta-neutral option hedges might eliminate exposure to risk from fluctuations in the value of the underlying asset, they do not eliminate volatility risk. 21.6 Empirical Evidence on Option Pricing The Black-Scholes option-pricing model has been subject to an enormous number of empirical tests. For the most part, the results of the studies have been positive in that the Black-Scholes model generates option values fairly close to the actual prices at which options trade. At the same time, some regular empirical failures of the model have been noted. The biggest problem concerns volatility. If the model were accurate, the implied volatility of all options on a particular stock with the same expiration date would be equal—after all, the underlying asset and expiration date are the same for each option, so the volatility inferred from each also ought to be the same. But in fact, when one actually plots implied volatility as a function of exercise price, the typical results appear as in Figure 21.15, which treats S&P 500 index options as the underlying asset. Implied volatility steadily falls as the exercise price rises. Clearly, the Black-Scholes model is missing something. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 758 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 759 19 Mark Rubinstein, “Implied Binomial Trees,” Journal of Finance 49 (July 1994), pp. 771–818. For an extensive discussion of these more general models, see R. L. McDonald, Derivatives Markets, 3rd ed. (Boston: Pearson Education [Addison-Wesley], 2013). 20 1. Option values may be viewed as the sum of intrinsic value plus time or “volatility” value. The volatility value is the right to choose not to exercise if the stock price moves against the holder. Thus the option holder cannot lose more than the cost of the option regardless of stock price performance. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Implied Volatility (%) Rubinstein19 suggests that the problem with the model has to do with fears of 25 a market crash like that of October 1987. The idea is that deep out-of-the-money puts 20 would be nearly worthless if stock prices 15 evolve smoothly, because the probability of the stock falling by a large amount 10 (and the put option thereby moving into the money) in a short time would be very 5 small. But a possibility of a sudden large downward jump that could move the puts 0 into the money, as in a market crash, would 0.84 0.89 0.94 0.99 1.04 1.09 impart greater value to these options. Thus, Ratio of Exercise Price to Current Value of Index the market might price these options as though there is a bigger chance of a large drop in the stock price than would be suggested by the Black-Scholes assumptions. Figure 21.15 Implied volatility of the S&P 500 index as a The result of the higher option price is a function of exercise price greater implied volatility derived from the Source: Mark Rubinstein, “Implied Binomial Trees,” Journal of Finance (July 1994), pp. 771–818. Black-Scholes model. Interestingly, Rubinstein points out that prior to the 1987 market crash, plots of implied volatility like the one in Figure 21.15 were relatively flat, consistent with the notion that the market was then less attuned to fears of a crash. However, postcrash plots have been consistently downward sloping, exhibiting a shape often called the option smirk. When we use option-pricing models that allow for more general stock price distributions, including crash risk and random changes in volatility, they generate downward-sloping implied volatility curves similar to the one observed in Figure 21.15.20 SUMMARY 2. Call options are more valuable when the exercise price is lower, when the stock price is higher, when the interest rate is higher, when the time to expiration is greater, when the stock’s volatility is greater, and when dividends are lower. 3. Call options must sell for at least the stock price less the present value of the exercise price and dividends to be paid before expiration. This implies that a call option on a non-dividend-paying stock may be sold for more than the proceeds from immediate exercise. Thus European calls are worth as much as American calls on stocks that pay no dividends, because the right to exercise the American call early has no value. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 759 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 760 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 4. Options may be priced relative to the underlying stock price using a simple two-period, twostate pricing model. As the number of periods increases, the binomial model can approximate more realistic stock price distributions. The Black-Scholes formula may be seen as a limiting case of the binomial option model, as the holding period is divided into progressively smaller subperiods when the interest rate and stock volatility are constant. 5. The Black-Scholes formula applies to options on stocks that pay no dividends. Dividend adjustments may be adequate to price European calls on dividend-paying stocks, but the proper treatment of American calls on dividend-paying stocks requires more complex formulas. 6. Put options may be exercised early, whether the stock pays dividends or not. Therefore, American puts generally are worth more than European puts. 7. European put values can be derived from the call value and the put-call parity relationship. This technique cannot be applied to American puts for which early exercise is a possibility. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 8. The implied volatility of an option is the standard deviation of stock returns consistent with an option’s market price. It can be backed out of an option-pricing model by finding the stock volatility that makes the option’s value equal to its observed price. 9. The hedge ratio is the number of shares of stock required to hedge the price risk involved in writing one option. Hedge ratios are near zero for deep out-of-the-money call options and approach 1.0 for deep in-the-money calls. 10. Although their hedge ratios are less than 1.0, call options have elasticities greater than 1.0. The rate of return on a call (as opposed to the dollar return) responds more than one-for-one with stock price movements. 11. Portfolio insurance can be obtained by purchasing a protective put option on an equity position. When the appropriate put is not traded, portfolio insurance entails a dynamic hedge strategy where a fraction of the equity portfolio equal to the desired put option’s delta is sold and placed in risk-free securities. 12. The option delta is used to determine the hedge ratio for options positions. Delta-neutral portfolios are independent of price changes in the underlying asset. Even delta-neutral option portfolios are subject to volatility risk, however. Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm 13. Empirically, implied volatilities derived from the Black-Scholes formula tend to be lower on options with higher exercise prices. This may be evidence that the option prices reflect the possibility of a sudden dramatic decline in stock prices. Such “crashes” are inconsistent with the Black-Scholes assumptions. KEY TERMS intrinsic value time value binomial model Black-Scholes pricing formula implied volatility KEY EQUATIONS pseudo-American call option value hedge ratio delta option elasticity Binomial model: u 5 exp(s"Dt); d 5 exp(2s"Dt); p 5 portfolio insurance dynamic hedging gamma delta neutral vega exp(rDt) 2 d u2d Put-call parity: P 5 C 1 PV(X) 2 S0 1 PV(Dividends) Black-Scholes formula (no dividend case): SN(d1) 2 Xe2rTN(d2) where d1 5 ln(S/X) 1 (r 1 ½ s2)T s"T Delta (or hedge ratio): H 5 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 760 ; d2 5 d1 2 s"T Change in option value Change in stock value 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 761 1. We showed in the text that the value of a call option increases with the volatility of the stock. Is this also true of put option values? Use the put-call parity theorem as well as a numerical example to prove your answer. PROBLEM SETS 2. Would you expect a $1 increase in a call option’s exercise price to lead to a decrease in the option’s value of more or less than $1? Basic 3. Is a put option on a high-beta stock worth more than one on a low-beta stock? The stocks have identical firm-specific risk. 4. All else equal, is a call option on a stock with a lot of firm-specific risk worth more than one on a stock with little firm-specific risk? The betas of the two stocks are equal. 5. All else equal, will a call option with a high exercise price have a higher or lower hedge ratio than one with a low exercise price? 6. In each of the following questions, you are asked to compare two options with parameters as given. The risk-free interest rate for all cases should be assumed to be 6%. Assume the stocks on which these options are written pay no dividends. A B T X s .5 .5 50 50 .20 .25 Price of Option $10 $10 Which put option is written on the stock with the lower price? i. A. ii. B. iii. Not enough information. b. Put T X s A B .5 .5 50 50 .2 .2 Price of Option $10 $12 Which put option must be written on the stock with the lower price? i. A. ii. B. iii. Not enough information. c. Call S X s Price of Option A 50 50 .20 $12 B 55 50 .20 $10 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. Put Intermediate Which call option must have the lower time to expiration? i. A. ii. B. iii. Not enough information. d. Call T X S Price of Option A B .5 .5 50 50 55 55 $10 $12 Which call option is written on the stock with higher volatility? i. A. ii. B. iii. Not enough information. e. Call T X S Price of Option A B .5 .5 50 50 55 55 $10 $ 7 bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 761 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 762 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Which call option is written on the stock with higher volatility? i. A. ii. B. iii. Not enough information. 7. Reconsider the determination of the hedge ratio in the two-state model (see page 730), where we showed that one-third share of stock would hedge one option. What would be the hedge ratio for the following exercise prices: 120, 110, 100, 90? What do you conclude about the hedge ratio as the option becomes progressively more in the money? 8. Show that Black-Scholes call option hedge ratios also increase as the stock price increases. Consider a 1-year option with exercise price $50, on a stock with annual standard deviation 20%. The T-bill rate is 3% per year. Find N(d1) for stock prices $45, $50, and $55. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 9. We will derive a two-state put option value in this problem. Data: S0 5 100; X 5 110; 1 1 r 5 1.10. The two possibilities for ST are 130 and 80. a. Show that the range of S is 50, whereas that of P is 30 across the two states. What is the hedge ratio of the put? b. Form a portfolio of three shares of stock and five puts. What is the (nonrandom) payoff to this portfolio? What is the present value of the portfolio? c. Given that the stock currently is selling at 100, solve for the value of the put. 10. Calculate the value of a call option on the stock in the previous problem with an exercise price of 110. Verify that the put-call parity theorem is satisfied by your answers to Problems 9 and 10. (Do not use continuous compounding to calculate the present value of X in this example because we are using a two-state model here, not a continuous-time Black-Scholes model.) 11. Use the Black-Scholes formula to find the value of a call option on the following stock: Time to expiration Standard deviation Exercise price Stock price Interest rate 6 months 50% per year $50 $50 3% 12. Find the Black-Scholes value of a put option on the stock in the previous problem with the same exercise price and expiration as the call option. eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 13. Recalculate the value of the call option in Problem 11, successively substituting one of the changes below while keeping the other parameters as in Problem 11: a. b. c. d. e. Time to expiration 5 3 months. Standard deviation 5 25% per year. Exercise price 5 $55. Stock price 5 $55. Interest rate 5 5%. Consider each scenario independently. Confirm that the option value changes in accordance with the prediction of Table 21.1. 14. A call option with X 5 $50 on a stock currently priced at S 5 $55 is selling for $10. Using a volatility estimate of s 5 .30, you find that N(d1) 5 .6 and N(d2) 5 .5. The risk-free interest rate is zero. Is the implied volatility based on the option price more or less than .30? Explain. 15. What would be the Excel formula in Spreadsheet 21.1 for the Black-Scholes value of a straddle position? Use the following case in answering Problems 16–21: Mark Washington, CFA, is an analyst with BIC. One year ago, BIC analysts predicted that the U.S. equity market would most likely experience a slight downturn and suggested delta-hedging the BIC portfolio. As predicted, the U.S. equity markets did indeed experience a downturn of approximately 4% over a 12-month period. However, portfolio performance for BIC was disappointing, lagging its peer group by nearly 10%. Washington has been told to review the options strategy to determine why the hedged portfolio did not perform as expected. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 762 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 763 16. Which of the following best explains a delta-neutral portfolio? A delta-neutral portfolio is perfectly hedged against: a. Small price changes in the underlying asset. b. Small price decreases in the underlying asset. c. All price changes in the underlying asset. 17. After discussing the concept of a delta-neutral portfolio, Washington determines that he needs to further explain the concept of delta. Washington draws the value of an option as a function of the underlying stock price. Using this diagram, indicate how delta is interpreted. Delta is the: a. Slope in the option price diagram. b. Curvature of the option price graph. c. Level in the option price diagram. 18. Washington considers a put option that has a delta of 20.65. If the price of the underlying asset decreases by $6, then what is the best estimate of the change in option price? 19. BIC owns 51,750 shares of Smith & Oates. The shares are currently priced at $69. A call option on Smith & Oates with a strike price of $70 is selling at $3.50 and has a delta of .69. What is the number of call options necessary to create a delta-neutral hedge? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 20. Return to the previous problem. Will the number of call options written for a delta-neutral hedge increase or decrease if the stock price falls? 21. Which of the following statements regarding the goal of a delta-neutral portfolio is most accurate? One example of a delta-neutral portfolio is to combine a: a. Long position in a stock with a short position in call options so that the value of the portfolio does not change with changes in the value of the stock. b. Long position in a stock with a short position in a call option so that the value of the portfolio changes with changes in the value of the stock. c. Long position in a stock with a long position in call options so that the value of the portfolio does not change with changes in the value of the stock. 22. Should the rate of return of a call option on a long-term Treasury bond be more or less sensitive to changes in interest rates than is the rate of return of the underlying bond? 23. If the stock price falls and the call price rises, then what has happened to the call option’s implied volatility? 24. If the time to expiration falls and the put price rises, then what has happened to the put option’s implied volatility? 25. According to the Black-Scholes formula, what will be the value of the hedge ratio of a call option as the stock price becomes infinitely large? Explain briefly. 26. According to the Black-Scholes formula, what will be the value of the hedge ratio of a put option for a very small exercise price? 27. The hedge ratio of an at-the-money call option on IBM is .4. The hedge ratio of an at-the-money put option is 2.6. What is the hedge ratio of an at-the-money straddle position on IBM? 28. Consider a 6-month expiration European call option with exercise price $105. The underlying stock sells for $100 a share and pays no dividends. The risk-free rate is 5%. What is the implied volatility of the option if the option currently sells for $8? Use Spreadsheet 21.1 (available at www.mhhe.com/bkm; link to Chapter 21 material) to answer this question. eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm a. Go to the Data tab of the spreadsheet and select Goal Seek from the What-If menu. The dialog box will ask you for three pieces of information. In that dialog box, you should set cell E6 to value 8 by changing cell B2. In other words, you ask the spreadsheet to find the value of standard deviation (which appears in cell B2) that forces the value of the option (in cell E6) equal to $8. Then click OK, and you should find that the call is now worth $8, and the entry for standard deviation has been changed to a level consistent with this value. This is the call’s implied standard deviation at a price of $8. b. What happens to implied volatility if the option is selling at $9? Why has implied volatility increased? bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 763 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 764 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives c. What happens to implied volatility if the option price is unchanged at $8, but option expiration is lower, say, only 4 months? Why? d. What happens to implied volatility if the option price is unchanged at $8, but the exercise price is lower, say, only $100? Why? e. What happens to implied volatility if the option price is unchanged at $8, but the stock price is lower, say, only $98? Why? 29. A collar is established by buying a share of stock for $50, buying a 6-month put option with exercise price $45, and writing a 6-month call option with exercise price $55. On the basis of the volatility of the stock, you calculate that for a strike price of $45 and expiration of 6 months, N(d1) 5 .60, whereas for the exercise price of $55, N(d1) 5 .35. a. What will be the gain or loss on the collar if the stock price increases by $1? b. What happens to the delta of the portfolio if the stock price becomes very large? Very small? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 30. These three put options are all written on the same stock. One has a delta of 2.9, one a delta of 2.5, and one a delta of 2.1. Assign deltas to the three puts by filling in this table. Put X A B C 10 20 30 Delta 31. You are very bullish (optimistic) on stock EFG, much more so than the rest of the market. In each question, choose the portfolio strategy that will give you the biggest dollar profit if your bullish forecast turns out to be correct. Explain your answer. a. Choice A: $10,000 invested in calls with X 5 50. Choice B: $10,000 invested in EFG stock. b. Choice A: 10 call option contracts (for 100 shares each), with X 5 50. Choice B: 1,000 shares of EFG stock. 32. You would like to be holding a protective put position on the stock of XYZ Co. to lock in a guaranteed minimum value of $100 at year-end. XYZ currently sells for $100. Over the next year the stock price will increase by 10% or decrease by 10%. The T-bill rate is 5%. Unfortunately, no put options are traded on XYZ Co. a. Suppose the desired put option were traded. How much would it cost to purchase? b. What would have been the cost of the protective put portfolio? c. What portfolio position in stock and T-bills will ensure you a payoff equal to the payoff that would be provided by a protective put with X 5 100? Show that the payoff to this portfolio and the cost of establishing the portfolio matches that of the desired protective put. 33. Return to Example 21.1. Use the binomial model to value a 1-year European put option with exercise price $110 on the stock in that example. Does your solution for the put price satisfy put-call parity? 34. Suppose that the risk-free interest rate is zero. Would an American put option ever be exercised early? Explain. 35. Let p(S, T, X) denote the value of a European put on a stock selling at S dollars, with time to maturity T, and with exercise price X, and let P(S, T, X) be the value of an American put. a. b. c. d. e. Evaluate p(0, T, X). Evaluate P(0, T, X). Evaluate p(S, T, 0). Evaluate P(S, T, 0). What does your answer to (b) tell you about the possibility that American puts may be exercised early? 36. You are attempting to value a call option with an exercise price of $100 and 1 year to expiration. The underlying stock pays no dividends, its current price is $100, and you believe it has a 50% chance of increasing to $120 and a 50% chance of decreasing to $80. The risk-free rate of interest is 10%. Calculate the call option’s value using the two-state stock price model. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 764 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 765 37. Consider an increase in the volatility of the stock in the previous problem. Suppose that if the stock increases in price, it will increase to $130, and that if it falls, it will fall to $70. Show that the value of the call option is now higher than the value derived in the previous problem. 38. Calculate the value of a put option with exercise price $100 using the data in Problem 36. Show that put-call parity is satisfied by your solution. 39. XYZ Corp. will pay a $2 per share dividend in 2 months. Its stock price currently is $60 per share. A call option on XYZ has an exercise price of $55 and 3-month time to expiration. The risk-free interest rate is .5% per month, and the stock’s volatility (standard deviation) 5 7% per month. Find the pseudo-American option value. (Hint: Try defining one “period” as a month, rather than as a year.) 40. “The beta of a call option on General Electric is greater than the beta of a share of General Electric.” True or false? 41. “The beta of a call option on the S&P 500 index with an exercise price of 1,330 is greater than the beta of a call on the index with an exercise price of 1,340.” True or false? 43. Goldman Sachs believes that market volatility will be 20% annually for the next 3 years. Threeyear at-the-money call and put options on the market index sell at an implied volatility of 22%. What options portfolio can Goldman establish to speculate on its volatility belief without taking a bullish or bearish position on the market? Using Goldman’s estimate of volatility, 3-year atthe-money options have N(d1) 5 .6. 44. You are holding call options on a stock. The stock’s beta is .75, and you are concerned that the stock market is about to fall. The stock is currently selling for $5 and you hold 1 million options on the stock (i.e., you hold 10,000 contracts for 100 shares each). The option delta is .8. How much of the market-index portfolio must you buy or sell to hedge your market exposure? 45. Imagine you are a provider of portfolio insurance. You are establishing a 4-year program. The portfolio you manage is currently worth $100 million, and you hope to provide a minimum return of 0%. The equity portfolio has a standard deviation of 25% per year, and T-bills pay 5% per year. Assume for simplicity that the portfolio pays no dividends (or that all dividends are reinvested). a. How much should be placed in bills? How much in equity? b. What should the manager do if the stock portfolio falls by 3% on the first day of trading? 46. Suppose that call options on ExxonMobil stock with time to expiration 3 months and strike price $90 are selling at an implied volatility of 30%. ExxonMobil stock currently is $90 per share, and the risk-free rate is 4%. If you believe the true volatility of the stock is 32%, how can you trade on your belief without taking on exposure to the performance of ExxonMobil? How many shares of stock will you hold for each option contract purchased or sold? Challenge eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 42. What will happen to the hedge ratio of a convertible bond as the stock price becomes very large? 47. Using the data in the previous problem, suppose that 3-month put options with a strike price of $90 are selling at an implied volatility of 34%. Construct a delta-neutral portfolio comprising positions in calls and puts that will profit when the option prices come back into alignment. 48. Suppose that JPMorgan Chase sells call options on $1.25 million worth of a stock portfolio with beta 5 1.5. The option delta is .8. It wishes to hedge out its resultant exposure to a market advance by buying a market-index portfolio. a. How many dollars’ worth of the market-index portfolio should it purchase to hedge its position? b. What if it instead uses market index puts to hedge its exposure? Should it buy or sell puts? Each put option is on 100 units of the index, and the index at current prices represents $1,000 worth of stock. 49. Suppose you are attempting to value a 1-year maturity option on a stock with volatility (i.e., annualized standard deviation) of s 5 .40. What would be the appropriate values for u and d if your binomial model is set up using: a. 1 period of 1 year. b. 4 subperiods, each 3 months. c. 12 subperiods, each 1 month. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 765 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 766 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 50. You build a binomial model with one period and assert that over the course of a year, the stock price will either rise by a factor of 1.5 or fall by a factor of 2/3. What is your implicit assumption about the volatility of the stock’s rate of return over the next year? 51. Use the put-call parity relationship to demonstrate that an at-the-money call option on a nondividend-paying stock must cost more than an at-the-money put option. Show that the prices of the put and call will be equal if S 5 (1 1 r)T. 52. Return to Problem 36. Value the call option using the risk-neutral shortcut described in the box on page 736. Confirm that your answer matches the value you get using the two-state approach. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 53. Return to Problem 38. What will be the payoff to the put, Pu, if the stock goes up? What will be the payoff, Pd, if the stock price falls? Value the put option using the risk-neutral shortcut described in the box on page 736. Confirm that your answer matches the value you get using the two-state approach. 1. The board of directors of Abco Company is concerned about the downside risk of a $100 million equity portfolio in its pension plan. The board’s consultant has proposed temporarily (for 1 month) hedging the portfolio with either futures or options. Referring to the following table, the consultant states: a. “The $100 million equity portfolio can be fully protected on the downside by selling (shorting) 4,000 futures contracts.” b. “The cost of this protection is that the portfolio’s expected rate of return will be zero percent.” Market, Portfolio, and Contract Data Equity index level Equity futures price Futures contract multiplier Portfolio beta Contract expiration (months) 99.00 100.00 $250 1.20 3 Critique the accuracy of each of the consultant’s two statements. 2. Michael Weber, CFA, is analyzing several aspects of option valuation, including the determinants of the value of an option, the characteristics of various models used to value options, and the potential for divergence of calculated option values from observed market prices. a. What is the expected effect on the value of a call option on common stock if the volatility of the underlying stock price decreases? If the time to expiration of the option increases? b. Using the Black-Scholes option-pricing model, Weber calculates the price of a 3-month call option and notices the option’s calculated value is different from its market price. With respect to Weber’s use of the Black-Scholes option-pricing model, i. Discuss why the calculated value of an out-of-the-money European option may differ from its market price. ii. Discuss why the calculated value of an American option may differ from its market price. 3. Joel Franklin is a portfolio manager responsible for derivatives. Franklin observes an Americanstyle option and a European-style option with the same strike price, expiration, and underlying stock. Franklin believes that the European-style option will have a higher premium than the American-style option. a. Critique Franklin’s belief that the European-style option will have a higher premium. Franklin is asked to value a 1-year European-style call option for Abaco Ltd. common stock, which last traded at $43.00. He has collected the information in the following table. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 766 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Closing stock price Call and put option exercise price 1-year put option price $43.00 45.00 4.00 1-year Treasury bill rate Time to expiration 5.50% One year Option Valuation 767 b. Calculate, using put-call parity and the information provided in the table, the European-style call option value. c. State the effect, if any, of each of the following three variables on the value of a call option. (No calculations required.) i. An increase in short-term interest rate. ii. An increase in stock price volatility. iii. A decrease in time to option expiration. a. b. c. d. Construct a two-period binomial tree for the value of the stock index. Calculate the value of a European call option on the index with an exercise price of 60. Calculate the value of a European put option on the index with an exercise price of 60. Confirm that your solutions for the values of the call and the put satisfy put-call parity. 5. Ken Webster manages a $200 million equity portfolio benchmarked to the S&P 500 index. Webster believes the market is overvalued when measured by several traditional fundamental/ economic indicators. He is concerned about potential losses but recognizes that the S&P 500 index could nevertheless move above its current 1136 level. Webster is considering the following option collar strategy: • Protection for the portfolio can be attained by purchasing an S&P 500 index put with a strike price of 1130 (just out of the money). • The put can be financed by selling two 1150 calls (farther out-of-the-money) for every put purchased. • Because the combined delta of the two calls (see following table) is less than 1 (that is, 2 3 .36 5 .72), the options will not lose more than the underlying portfolio will gain if the market advances. The information in the following table describes the two options used to create the collar. Characteristics Option price Option implied volatility Option’s delta Contracts needed for collar 1150 Call 1130 Put $8.60 22% 0.36 602 $16.10 24% 20.44 301 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 4. A stock index is currently trading at 50. Paul Tripp, CFA, wants to value 2-year index options using the binomial model. The stock will either increase in value by 20% or fall in value by 20%. The annual risk-free interest rate is 6%. No dividends are paid on any of the underlying securities in the index. Notes: • Ignore transaction costs. • S&P 500 historical 30-day volatility 5 23%. • Time to option expiration 5 30 days. a. Describe the potential returns of the combined portfolio (the underlying portfolio plus the option collar) if after 30 days the S&P 500 index has: i. risen approximately 5% to 1193. ii. remained at 1136 (no change). iii. declined by approximately 5% to 1080. (No calculations are necessary.) b. Discuss the effect on the hedge ratio (delta) of each option as the S&P 500 approaches the level for each of the potential outcomes listed in part (a). c. Evaluate the pricing of each of the following in relation to the volatility data provided: i. the put ii. the call bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 767 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer 768 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Select a stock for which options are listed on the CBOE Web site (www.cboe.com). The price data for captions can be found on the “delayed quotes” menu option. Enter a ticker symbol for a stock of your choice and pull up its option price data. Using daily price data from finance.yahoo.com calculate the annualized standard deviation of the daily percentage change in the stock price. Create a Black-Scholes option-pricing model in a spreadsheet, or use our Spreadsheet 21.1, available at www. mhhe.com/bkm (link to the Chapter 21 material). Using the standard deviation and a risk-free rate found at www.bloomberg.com/markets/rates/index.html, calculate the value of the call options. How do the calculated values compare to the market prices of the options? On the basis of the difference between the price you calculated using historical volatility and the actual price of the option, what do you conclude about expected trends in market volatility? SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. If This Variable Increases . . . The Value of a Put Option S X Decreases Increases Increases s T rf Dividend payouts Increases* Decreases Increases *For American puts, increase in time to expiration must increase value. One can always choose to exercise early if this is optimal; the longer expiration date simply expands the range of alternatives open to the option holder which must make the option more valuable. For a European put, where early exercise is not allowed, longer time to expiration can have an indeterminate effect. Longer expiration increases volatility value because the final stock price is more uncertain, but it reduces the present value of the exercise price that will be received if the put is exercised. The net effect on put value can be positive or negative. To understand the impact of higher volatility, consider the same scenarios as for the call. The lowvolatility scenario yields a lower expected payoff. High volatility Low volatility Stock price Put payoff Stock price Put payoff $10 $20 $20 $10 $20 $10 $25 $ 5 $30 $ 0 $30 $ 0 $40 $ 0 $35 $ 0 $50 $ 0 $40 $ 0 2. The parity relationship assumes that all options are held until expiration and that there are no cash flows until expiration. These assumptions are valid only in the special case of European options on non-dividend-paying stocks. If the stock pays no dividends, the American and European calls are equally valuable, whereas the American put is worth more than the European put. Therefore, although the parity theorem for European options states that P 5 C 2 S0 1 PV(X) in fact, P will be greater than this value if the put is American. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 768 7/27/13 1:45 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 21 Option Valuation 769 3. Because the option now is underpriced, we want to reverse our previous strategy. Cash Flow in 1 Year for Each Possible Stock Price Initial Cash Flow Buy 3 options Short-sell 1 share; repay in 1 year Lend $83.50 at 10% interest rate TOTAL S 5 90 0 290 91.85 1.85 216.50 100 283.50 0 S 5 120 30 2120 91.85 1.85 The riskless cash flow in 1 year per option is $1.85/3 5 $.6167, and the present value is $.6167/1.10 5 $.56, precisely the amount by which the option is underpriced. 4. a. Cu 2 Cd 5 $6.984 2 0 b. uS0 2 dS0 5 $110 2 $95 5 $15 c. 6.984/15 5 .4656 Action Today (time 0) dS0 5 $95 uS0 5 $110 Buy .4656 shares at price S0 5 $100 Write 1 call at price C0 $44.232 $51.216 0 TOTAL $44.232 26.984 $44.232 The portfolio must have a market value equal to the present value of $44.232. e. $44.232/1.05 5 $42.126 f. .4656 3 $100 2 C0 5 $42.126 C0 5 $46.56 2 $42.126 5 $4.434 5. When ∆t shrinks, there should be lower possible dispersion in the stock price by the end of the subperiod because each shorter subperiod offers less time in which new information can move stock prices. However, as the time interval shrinks, there will be a correspondingly greater number of these subperiods until option expiration. Thus, total volatility over the remaining life of the option will be unaffected. In fact, take another look at Figure 21.2. There, despite the fact that u and d each get closer to 1 as the number of subintervals increases and the length of each subinterval falls, the total volatility of the stock return until option expiration is unaffected. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Value in Next Period as Function of Stock Price d. 6. Because s 5 .6, s2 5 .36. d1 5 ln(100/95) 1 (.10 1 .36/2).25 .6".25 5 .4043 d2 5 d1 2 .6".25 5 .1043 Using Table 21.2 and interpolation, or from a spreadsheet function: N(d1) 5 .6570 N(d2) 5 .5415 C 5 100 3 .6570 2 95e2.103.25 3 .5415 5 15.53 7. Implied volatility exceeds .2783. Given a standard deviation of .2783, the option value is $7. A higher volatility is needed to justify an $8 price. Using Spreadsheet 21.1 and Goal Seek, you can confirm that implied volatility at an option price of $8 is .3138. 8. A $1 increase in stock price is a percentage increase of 1/122 5 .82%. The put option will fall by (.4 3 $1) 5 $.40, a percentage decrease of $.40/$4 5 10%. Elasticity is 210/.82 5 212.2. 9. The delta for a call option is N(d1), which is positive, and in this case is .547. Therefore, for every 10 option contracts purchased, you would need to short 547 shares of stock. bod61671_ch21_722-769.indd 769 7/27/13 1:45 AM 222 Final PDF to printer CHAPTER TWENTY-TWO PART VI Futures Markets FUTURES AND FORWARD contracts are like options in that they specify purchase or sale of some underlying security at some future date. The key difference is that the holder of an option is not compelled to buy or sell, and will not do so if the trade is unprofitable. A futures or forward contract, however, carries the obligation to go through with the agreed-upon transaction. A forward contract is not an investment in the strict sense that funds are paid for an asset. It is only a commitment today to transact in the future. Forward arrangements are part of our study of investments, however, because they offer powerful means to hedge other investments and generally modify portfolio characteristics. Forward markets for future delivery of various commodities go back at least to ancient Greece. Organized futures markets, though, are a relatively modern development, dating only to the 19th century. Futures markets replace informal forward contracts bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 770 with highly standardized, exchange-traded securities. While futures markets have their roots in agricultural products and commodities, the markets today are dominated by trading in financial futures such as those on stock indexes, interest-rate-dependent securities such as government bonds, and foreign exchange. The markets themselves also have changed, with trading today largely taking place in electronic markets. This chapter describes the workings of futures markets and the mechanics of trading in these markets. We show how futures contracts are useful investment vehicles for both hedgers and speculators and how the futures price relates to the spot price of an asset. We also show how futures can be used in several risk-management applications. This chapter deals with general principles of future markets. Chapter 23 describes specific futures markets in greater detail. 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 771 22.1 The Futures Contract To see how futures and forwards work and how they might be useful, consider the portfolio diversification problem facing a farmer growing a single crop, let us say wheat. The entire planting season’s revenue depends critically on the highly volatile crop price. The farmer can’t easily diversify his position because virtually his entire wealth is tied up in the crop. The miller who must purchase wheat for processing faces a risk management problem that is the mirror image of the farmer’s. He is subject to profit uncertainty because of the unpredictable cost of the wheat. Both parties can hedge their risk by entering into a forward contract requiring the farmer to deliver the wheat when harvested at a price agreed upon now, regardless of the market price at harvest time. No money need change hands at this time. A forward contract is simply a deferred-delivery sale of some asset with the sales price agreed on now. All that is required is that each party be willing to lock in the ultimate delivery price. The contract protects each party from future price fluctuations. Futures markets formalize and standardize forward contracting. Buyers and sellers trade in a centralized futures exchange. The exchange standardizes the types of contracts that may be traded: It establishes contract size, the acceptable grade of commodity, contract delivery dates, and so forth. Although standardization eliminates much of the flexibility available in forward contracting, it has the offsetting advantage of liquidity because many traders will concentrate on the same small set of contracts. Futures contracts also differ from forward contracts in that they call for a daily settling up of any gains or losses on the contract. By contrast, no money changes hands in forward contracts until the delivery date. The centralized market, standardization of contracts, and depth of trading in each contract allows futures positions to be liquidated easily rather than renegotiated with the other party to the contract. Because the exchange guarantees the performance of each party, costly credit checks on other traders are not necessary. Instead, each trader simply posts a good-faith deposit, called the margin, to guarantee contract performance. The Basics of Futures Contracts The futures contract calls for delivery of a commodity at a specified delivery or maturity date, for an agreed-upon price, called the futures price, to be paid at contract maturity. The contract specifies precise requirements for the commodity. For agricultural commodities, the exchange sets allowable grades (e.g., No. 2 hard winter wheat or No. 1 soft red wheat). The place or means of delivery of the commodity is specified as well. Delivery of agricultural commodities is made by transfer of warehouse receipts issued by approved warehouses. For financial futures, delivery may be made by wire transfer; for index futures, delivery may be accomplished by a cash settlement procedure such as those for index options. Although the futures contract technically calls for delivery of an asset, delivery rarely occurs. Instead, parties to the contract much more commonly close out their positions before contract maturity, taking gains or losses in cash. Because the futures exchange specifies all the terms of the contract, the traders need bargain only over the futures price. The trader taking the long position commits to purchasing the commodity on the delivery date. The trader who takes the short position commits to delivering the commodity at contract maturity. The trader in the long position is said to “buy” a contract; the short-side trader “sells” a contract. The words buy and sell bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 771 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 772 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives are figurative only, because a contract is not really bought or sold like a stock or bond; it is entered into by mutual agreement. At the time the contract is entered into, no money changes hands. Figure 22.1 shows prices for several futures contracts as they appear in The Wall Street Journal. The boldface heading lists in each case the commodity, the exchange where the futures contract is traded, the contract size, and the pricing unit. The first agricultural contract listed is for corn, traded on the Chicago Board of Trade (CBT). (The CBT merged with the Chicago Mercantile Exchange in 2007 but, for now, maintains a separate identity.) Each contract calls for delivery of 5,000 bushels, and prices in the entry are quoted in cents per bushel. The next several rows detail price data for contracts expiring on various dates. The March 2013 maturity corn contract, for example, opened during the day at a futures price of 720.25 cents per bushel. The highest futures price during the day was 726, the lowest was 714.50, and the settlement price (a representative trading price during the last few minutes of trading) was 724.25. The settlement price increased by 3.50 cents from the previous trading day. Finally, open interest, or the number of outstanding contracts, was 494,588. Similar information is given for each maturity date. The trader holding the long position, that is, the person who will purchase the good, profits from price increases. Suppose that when the contract matures in March, the price of corn turns out to be 729.25 cents per bushel. The long-position trader who entered the contract at the futures price of 724.25 cents therefore earns a profit of 5 cents per bushel. As each contract calls for delivery of 5,000 bushels, the profit to the long position equals 5,000 3 $.05 5 $250 per contract. Conversely, the short position loses 5 cents per bushel. The short position’s loss equals the long position’s gain. To summarize, at maturity: Profit to long 5 Spot price at maturity 2 Original futures price Profit to short 5 Original futures price 2 Spot price at maturity where the spot price is the actual market price of the commodity at the time of the delivery. The futures contract, therefore, is a zero-sum game, with losses and gains netting out to zero. Every long position is offset by a short position. The aggregate profits to futures trading, summing over all investors, also must be zero, as is the net exposure to changes in the commodity price. For this reason, the establishment of a futures market in a commodity should not have a major impact on prices in the spot market for that commodity. Figure 22.2, panel A is a plot of the profits realized by an investor who enters the long side of a futures contract as a function of the price of the asset on the maturity date. Notice that profit is zero when the ultimate spot price, PT, equals the initial futures price, F0. Profit per unit of the underlying asset rises or falls one-for-one with changes in the final spot price. Unlike the payoff of a call option, the payoff of the long futures position can be negative: This will be the case if the spot price falls below the original futures price. Unlike the holder of a call, who has an option to buy, the long futures position trader cannot simply walk away from the contract. Also unlike options, in the case of futures there is no need to distinguish gross payoffs from net profits. This is because the futures contract is not purchased; it is simply a contract that is agreed to by two parties. The futures price adjusts to make the present value of entering into a new contract equal to zero. The distinction between futures and options is highlighted by comparing panel A of Figure 22.2 to the payoff and profit diagrams for an investor in a call option with exercise price, X, chosen equal to the futures price F0 (see panel C). The futures investor is exposed to considerable losses if the asset price falls. In contrast, the investor in the call cannot lose more than the cost of the option. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 772 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer Futures Contracts | WSJ.com/commodities Open Contract High hi lo low Settle Copper-High (CMX)-25,000 Ibs.; $ per Ib. Jan March 3.6580 3.6725 3.6760 3.6965 Gold (CMX)-100 troy oz.; $ per troy oz. Chg 3.6645 20.0065 3.6765 20.0080 3.6520 3.6610 Feb April June Aug Oct Dec 1683.80 1685.80 1664.20 1669.90 1686.40 1688.10 1666.40 1672.10 1688.10 1689.60 1669.50 1674.20 1689.00 1689.00 1670.60 1676.00 1689.50 1690.20 1673.10 1677.70 1694.70 1694.70 1674.40 1679.60 miNY Gold (CMX) -50 troy oz.; $ per troy oz. Feb 1684.25 1684.50 1664.75 1670.00 April 1683.50 1684.00 1667.75 1672.00 June 1684.00 1684.00 1674.50 1674.25 Palladium (NYM)-50 troy oz.; $ per troy oz. Feb 718.80 718.80 718.70 726.30 March 725.20 728.80 716.60 726.70 June 725.55 729.90 719.20 728.15 Platinum (NYM)-50 troy oz.; $ per troy oz. Jan 1681.80 1681.80 1674.00 1682.80 Feb 1673.00 1680.40 1673.00 1680.80 Silver (CMX)-5,000 troy oz.; $ per troy oz. Jan 31.735 31.750 31.735 31.695 March 32.240 32.245 31.605 31.722 miNY Silver (CMX)-2500 troy oz.; $ per troy oz. March 32.138 32.438 31.613 31.725 May 31.863 31.900 31.838 31.775 Sept 32.038 32.038 32.038 31.875 Crude Oil, Light Sweet (NYM)-1,000 bbls.; $ per bbl. March 95.50 96.68 95.12 95.95 April 95.89 97.16 95.60 96.45 May 96.38 97.58 96.00 96.90 Aug 96.42 97.57 96.32 97.31 Sept 96.08 97.58 96.07 97.07 Oct 96.10 96.96 96.04 96.77 Heating Oil No.2 (NYM)-42,000 gal.; $ per gal. Feb 3.0795 3.0958 3.0693 3.0864 March 3.0674 3.0848 3.0561 3.0764 Gasoline-NY RBOB (NYM)-42,000 gal.; $ per gal. Feb 2.8335 2.8762 2.8171 2.8629 March 2.8495 2.8882 2.8316 2.8767 Natural Gas (NYM)-10,000 MMBtu.; $ per MMBtu. Feb 3.570 3.592 3.441 3.446 March 3.569 3.588 3.447 3.454 April 3.597 3.613 3.482 3.490 May 3.653 3.667 3.540 3.549 Oct 3.804 3.826 3.703 3.715 Jan’14 4.218 4.219 4.123 4.135 Open interest 411 103,266 216.80 216.80 216.80 216.80 216.90 216.90 160,918 149,804 38,688 24,841 11,949 26,055 216.70 216.90 216.75 2,282 96 12 0.50 0.50 0.65 4 30,654 1,480 28.90 28.00 47 13 20.714 20.717 17 78,766 20.714 20.722 20.717 295 11 1 0.72 0.70 0.69 0.73 0.71 0.69 295,685 102,709 86,130 38,272 51,513 41,212 .0083 .0112 46,296 83,625 .0291 .0278 39,099 121,519 2.108 2.099 2.091 2.088 2.080 2.068 47,921 320,563 159,548 94,821 104,406 78,522 Agriculture Futures Corn (CBT)-5,000 bu.; cents per bu. March Dec 720.25 589.75 726.00 591.00 Ethanol (CBT)-29,000 gal.; $ per gal. 724.25 585.50 714.50 583.75 Feb 2.367 2.383 2.367 March 2.378 2.397 2.374 Oats (CBT)-5,000 bu.; cents per bu. March 360.00 361.25 355.50 May 365.50 367.75 362.75 Soybeans (CBT)-5,000 bu.; cents per bu. March 1437.00 1439.00 1415.00 May 1426.75 1428.25 1404.50 Soybean Meal (CBT)-100 tons.; $ per ton. March 416.50 417.00 408.00 MAy 412.10 412.50 404.20 Soybean Oil (CBT)-60,000 lbs.; cents per lb. March 52.04 52.20 51.50 May 52.40 52.60 51.87 Rough Rice (CBT)-2,000 cwt.; cents per cwt. March 1530.50 1537.00 1523.00 May 1562.00 1562.00 1554.50 Wheat (CBT)-5,000 bu.; cents per bu. March 775.50 775.75 763.00 July 788.25 788.75 777.00 Wheat (KC)-5,000 bu.; cents per bu. March 819.00 820.00 816.75 July n.a. n.a. 835.25 Wheat (MPLS)-5,000 bu.; cents per bu. March 860.00 860.75 852.25 May 872.25 872.25 864.50 Cattle-Feeder (CME)-50,000 lbs.; cents per lb. Jan 144.425 145.000 144.100 March 147.300 148.575 146.725 Cattle-Live (CME)-40,000 lbs.; cents per lb. Feb 126.100 126.875 125.625 April 130.650 131.425 130.175 Contract High hi lo low Chg Open interest 146.55 149.50 23.85 23.85 90,658 29,315 18.49 18.46 2.01 2.07 341,806 167,304 20.88 21.23 2.67 2.43 958 4,057 82.89 82.20 2.41 1.53 132,025 34,978 113.20 114.30 22.40 22.20 14,247 4,127 146-050 146-150 145-090 145-270 144-170 144-300 143-300 144-120 Treasury Notes (CBT)-$100,000; pts 32nds of 100% March 132-120 132-175 131-315 132-075 June 131-125 131-130 131-000 131-060 5 Yr. Treasury Notes (CBT)-$100,000; pts 32nds of 100% March 124-082 124-102 124-020 124-060 June 123-255 123-267 123-207 123-245 2 Yr. Treasury Notes (CBT)-$200,000; pts 32nds of 100% March 110-077 110-080 110-070 110-075 June 110-070 110-075 110-065 110-067 30 Day Federal Funds (CBT)-$5,00,000; 100-daily avg. Jan 99.858 99.858 99.855 99.858 March ... 99.875 99.865 99,870 10 Yr. Int. Rate Swaps (CBT)-$100,000; pts 32nds of 100% March 118.922 118.922 118.422 118.609 1 Month Libor (CME)-$3,000,000; pts of 100% Feb ... ... ... 99.7975 Eurodollar (CME)-$1,000,000; pts of 100% Feb 99.7025 99.7050 99.7000 99.7025 March 99.7000 99.7050 99.7000 99.7000 June 99.6850 99.6850 99.6800 99.6800 Dec 99.6400 99.6400 99.6250 99.6300 24.0 24.0 548,615 747 22.0 22.0 1,865,707 24,269 21.0 21.0 1,527,948 3,958 ... ... 1,007,447 1,956 ... ... 57,169 36,813 2.078 9,349 ... 3,622 .0025 ... ... 2.0050 53,143 835,707 706,194 728,161 Open Metal & Petroleum Futures 3.50 24.75 494,588 223,643 2.382 2.396 .01 .01 1,131 1,605 361.00 367.75 1.25 ... 7,404 2,438 1435.25 1423.75 21.75 23.00 226,757 140,830 414.70 410.60 21.80 21.50 127,823 56,552 52.11 52.49 .08 .00 155,915 59,010 1528.50 1560.50 22.00 22.00 12,472 1,490 768.50 782.25 26.25 26.50 226.800 83,615 821.50 840.50 28.75 28.00 91,904 35,595 855.50 867.50 25.00 24.75 20,338 9,776 144.600 147.950 .400 .800 2,205 14,972 125.875 130.350 .100 2.100 47,761 155,046 Coffee (ICE-US)-37,500 lbs.; cents per Ib. March May 150.65 151.30 146.10 153.75 154.20 149.10 Sugar-World (ICE-US)-112,000 lbs.; cents per Ib. March 18.54 18.59 18.31 May 18.59 18.59 18.30 Sugar-Domestic (ICE-US)-112,000 lbs.; cents per Ib. March 21.00 21.00 20.55 May 21.45 21.45 21.10 Cotton (ICE-US)-50,000 Ibs.; cents per Ib. March 80.10 84.00 80.00 May 80.35 82.95 80.15 Orange Juice (ICE-US)-15,000 Ibs.; cents per Ib. March 115.60 116.80 113.00 May 116.55 117.40 114.30 Settle Interest Rate Futures Treasury Bonds (CBT)-$100,000; pts 32nds of 100% March June Currency Futures Japanese Yen (CME)-¥12,500,000; $ per 100¥ March June 1.1296 1.1310 1.1313 1.1310 1.1045 1.1056 1.1119 1.1127 2.0163 2.0164 204,630 991 March June .9992 .9970 .9997 .9978 .9952 .9934 .9958 .9938 2.0036 2.0036 139,041 2,204 March June 1.5828 1.5830 1.5848 1.5837 1.5752 1.5750 1.5787 1.5781 2.0049 2.0049 158,952 236 March 1.0758 1.0782 1.0730 1.0779 .0016 40,548 1.0495 1.0509 1.0405 1.0433 1.0405 1.0441 1.0355 1.0366 1.0320 1.0320 1.0310 1.0303 Mexican Peso (CME)-MXN 500,000; $ per 10MXN March .07830 .07893 .07820 .07865 June .07758 .07783 .07758 .07798 Euro (CME)-€125,000; $ per € March 1.3317 1.3398 1.3291 1.3378 June 1.3329 1.3400 1.3300 1.3385 Euro/Japanese Yen (ICE-US)-€125,000; ¥ per € March 117.675 11.6750 11.6750 120.3200 Euro/British Pound (ICE-US)-€125,000; £ per € March ... ... ... 0.8474 Euro/Swiss France (ICE-US)-€125,000; CHF per € March 1.2376 1.2445 1.2360 1.2411 2.0074 2.0073 2.0073 204,989 331 1 .00015 .00015 187,352 122 .0053 .0052 216,667 1,777 2.2100 4,186 .0060 2,992 .0031 8,588 Canadian Dollar (CME)-CAD 100,000; $ per CAD British Pound (CME)-£62,500; $ per £ Swiss Franc (CME)-CHF 125,000; $ per CHF Australian Dollar (CME)-AUD 100,000; $ per AUD March June Sept Index Futures DJ Industrial Average (CBT)-$10 3 index March 13703 13781 62 10,749 13702 13818 13701 S&P 500 Index (CME)-$250 3 index March 1483.80 1497.50 1483.30 June 1482.90 1491.60 1480.60 Mini S&P 500 (CME)-$50 3 index March 1483.25 1497.75 1482.75 June 1477.25 1491.25 1476.25 Mini S&P Midcap 400 (CME)-$100 3 index March 1077.50 1089.20 1075.70 Nasdaq 100 (CME)-$100 3 index March 2716.75 2743.50 2709.75 13781 62 112,004 1491.80 1485.10 1.50 1.50 194,350 4,188 1491.75 1485.00 1.50 1.50 2,972,476 18,475 1086.30 4.70 116,953 2718.25 240.75 10,891 13706 13815 Mini DJ Industrial Average (CBT)-$5 3 index March Figure 22.1 Futures listings Source: The Wall Street Journal, January 25, 2013. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal, © 2013 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 773 773 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 774 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Profit Profit Payoff Profit PT F0 F0 A: Long Futures Profit = PT – F0 PT B: Short Futures Profit = F0 – PT X PT C: Buy a Call Option Figure 22.2 Profits to buyers and sellers of futures and options contracts Figure 22.2, panel B is a plot of the profits realized by an investor who enters the short side of a futures contract. It is the mirror image of the profit diagram for the long position. CONCEPT CHECK 22.1 a. Compare the profit diagram in Figure 22.2, panel B to the payoff diagram for a long position in a put option. Assume the exercise price of the option equals the initial futures price. b. Compare the profit diagram in Figure 22.2, panel B to the payoff diagram for an investor who writes a call option. Existing Contracts Futures and forward contracts are traded on a wide variety of goods in four broad categories: agricultural commodities, metals and minerals (including energy commodities), foreign currencies, and financial futures (fixed-income securities and stock market indexes). In addition to indexes on broad stock indexes, one can now trade single-stock futures on individual stocks and narrowly based indexes. OneChicago has operated an entirely electronic market in single-stock futures since 2002. The exchange maintains futures markets in actively traded stocks with the most liquidity as well as in some popular ETFs such as those on the S&P 500 (ticker SPY), the NASDAQ-100 (QQQ), and the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DIA). However, trading volume in single-stock futures has to date been somewhat disappointing. Table 22.1 offers a sample of the various contracts trading in 2013. Contracts now trade on items that would not have been considered possible only a few years ago, such as electricity as well as weather futures and options contracts. Weather derivatives (which trade on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange) have payoffs that depend on average weather conditions, for example, the number of degree-days by which the temperature in a region exceeds or falls short of 65 degrees Fahrenheit. The potential use of these derivatives in managing the risk surrounding electricity or oil and natural gas use should be evident. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 774 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Foreign Currencies British pound Canadian dollar Japanese yen Euro Swiss franc Australian dollar Mexican peso Brazilian real Agricultural Corn Oats Soybeans Soybean meal Soybean oil Wheat Barley Flaxseed Canola Rye Cattle Hogs Pork bellies Cocoa Coffee Cotton Milk Orange juice Sugar Lumber Rice Metals and Energy Copper Aluminum Gold Platinum Palladium Silver Crude oil Heating oil Gas oil Natural gas Gasoline Propane Commodity index Electricity Weather Futures Markets Interest Rate Futures Equity Indexes Eurodollars Euroyen Euro-denominated bond Euroswiss Sterling British government bond German government bond Italian government bond Canadian government bond Treasury bonds Treasury notes Treasury bills LIBOR EURIBOR Municipal bond index Federal funds rate Bankers’ acceptance Interest rate swaps S&P 500 index Dow Jones Industrials S&P Midcap 400 NASDAQ 100 NYSE index Russell 2000 index Nikkei 225 (Japanese) FTSE index (British) CAC-40 (French) DAX-30 (German) All ordinary (Australian) Toronto 35 (Canadian) Dow Jones Euro STOXX 50 Industry indexes, e.g., Banking Telecom Utilities Health care Technology 775 Table 22.1 Sample of futures contracts While Table 22.1 includes many contracts, the large and ever-growing array of markets makes this list necessarily incomplete. The nearby box discusses some comparatively fanciful futures markets, sometimes called prediction markets, in which payoffs may be tied to the winner of presidential elections, the box office receipts of a particular movie, or anything else in which participants are willing to take positions. Outside the futures markets, a well-developed network of banks and brokers has established a forward market in foreign exchange. This forward market is not a formal exchange in the sense that the exchange specifies the terms of the traded contract. Instead, participants in a forward contract may negotiate for delivery of any quantity of goods, whereas in the formal futures markets contract size and delivery dates are set by the exchange. In forward arrangements, banks and brokers simply negotiate contracts for clients (or themselves) as needed. This market is huge. In London alone, the largest currency market, around $2 trillion of currency trades each day. 22.2 Trading Mechanics The Clearinghouse and Open Interest Until about 10 years ago, most futures trades in the United States occurred among floor traders in the “trading pit” for each contract. Today, however, trading is overwhelmingly conducted through electronic networks, particularly for financial futures. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 775 7/30/13 9:29 PM WORDS FROM THE STREET Final PDF to printer Prediction Markets If you find S&P 500 or T-bond contracts a bit dry, perhaps you’d be interested in futures contracts with payoffs that depend on the winner of the next presidential election, or the severity of the next influenza season, or the host city of the 2024 Olympics. You can now find “futures markets” in these events and many others. For example, both Intrade (www.intrade.com) and Iowa Electronic Markets (www.biz.uiowa.edu/iem) maintain presidential futures markets. In July 2011, you could have purchased a contract that would pay off $1 in November 2012 if the Republican candidate won the presidential race but nothing if he lost. The contract price (expressed as a percentage of face value) therefore may be viewed as the probability of a Republican victory, at least according to the consensus view of market participants at the time. If you believed in July that the probability of a Republican victory was 55%, you would have been prepared to pay up to $.55 for the contract. Alternatively, if you had wished to bet against the Republicans, you could have sold the contract. Similarly, you could bet on (or against) a Democrat victory using the Democrat contract. (When there are only two relevant parties, betting on one is equivalent to betting against the other, but in other elections, such as primaries where there are several viable candidates, selling one candidate’s contract is not the same as buying another’s.) The accompanying figure shows the price of each contract from July 2011 through Election Day 2012. The price clearly tracks each candidate’s perceived prospects. You can see Obama’s price rise dramatically in the days shortly before the election as it became ever clearer that he would win the election. Interpreting prediction market prices as probabilities actually requires a caveat. Because the contract payoff is risky, the price of the contract may reflect a risk premium. Therefore, to be precise, these probabilities are actually risk-neutral probabilities (see Chapter 21). In practice, however, it seems unlikely that the risk premium associated with these contracts is substantial. Prediction markets for the 2012 presidential election. the election. Price is in cents. Contract on each party pays $1 if the party wins 100 Democrat 90 Republican 80 70 Price 60 50 40 30 20 10 08-Nov-12 11-Oct-12 23-Sep-12 05-Sep-12 18-Aug-12 31-Jul-12 13-Jul-12 25-Jun-12 07-Jun-12 20-May-12 02-May-12 14-Apr-12 27-Mar-12 20-Feb-12 09-Mar-12 15-Jan-12 02-Feb-12 28-Dec-11 10-Dec-11 22-Nov-11 04-Nov-11 17-Oct-11 29-Sep-11 11-Sep-11 24-Aug-11 19-Jul-11 06-Aug-11 01-Jul-11 0 Date Source: Iowa Electronic Markets, downloaded January 25, 2013. The impetus for this shift originated in Europe, where electronic trading is the norm. Eurex, which is jointly owned by the Deutsche Börse and Swiss exchange, is among the world’s largest derivatives exchanges. It operates a fully electronic trading and clearing platform and, in 2004, received clearance from regulators to list contracts in the U.S. In response, the Chicago Board of Trade adopted an electronic platform provided by Eurex’s 776 bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 776 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 777 European rival Euronext.liffe,1 and the CBOT’s Treasury contracts are now traded electronically. The Chicago Mercantile Exchange maintains another electronic trading system called Globex. The electronic markets enable trading around the clock. The CBOT and CME merged in 2007 into one combined company, named the CME Group, with all electronic trading from both exchanges moving onto Globex. It seems inevitable that electronic trading will continue to displace floor trading. Once a trade is agreed to, the clearinghouse enters the picture. Rather than having the long and short traders hold contracts with each other, the clearinghouse becomes the seller of the contract for the long position and the buyer of the contract for the short position. The clearinghouse is obligated to deliver the commodity to the long position and to pay for delivery from the short; consequently, the clearinghouse’s position nets to zero. This arrangement makes the clearinghouse the trading partner of each trader, both long and short. The clearinghouse, bound to perform on its side of each contract, is the only party that can be hurt by the failure of any trader to observe the obligations of the futures contract. This arrangement is necessary because a futures contract calls for future performance, which cannot be as easily guaranteed as an immediate stock transaction. Figure 22.3 illustrates the role of the clearinghouse. Panel A shows what would happen in the absence of the clearinghouse. The trader in the long position would be obligated to pay the futures price to the short-position trader, and the trader in the short position would be obligated to deliver the commodity. Panel B shows how the clearinghouse becomes an intermediary, acting as the trading partner for each side of the contract. The clearinghouse’s position is neutral, as it takes a long and a short position for each transaction. The clearinghouse makes it possible for traders to liquidate positions easily. If you are currently long in a contract and want to undo your position, you simply instruct your broker to enter the short side of a contract to close out your position. This is called a reversing trade. The exchange nets out your long and short positions, reducing your net position to zero. Your zero net position with the clearinghouse eliminates the need to fulfill at maturity either the original long or reversing short position. The open interest on the conA Money tract is the number of contracts outShort Long standing. (Long and short positions Position Position are not counted separately, meaning that open interest can be defined Commodity either as the number of long or short contracts outstanding.) The clearB inghouse’s position nets out to zero, Money Money and so is not counted in the compuLong Short Clearinghouse tation of open interest. When conPosition Position tracts begin trading, open interest is zero. As time passes, open interCommodity Commodity est increases as progressively more contracts are entered. There are many apocryphal stoFigure 22.3 Panel A, Trading without a clearinghouse. Panel B, ries about futures traders who wake Trading with a clearinghouse. up to discover a small mountain of 1 Euronext.liffe is the international derivatives market of Euronext. It resulted from Euronext’s purchase of LIFFE (the London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange) and a merger with the Lisbon exchange in 2002. Euronext was itself the result of a 2000 merger of the exchanges of Amsterdam, Brussels, and Paris. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 777 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 778 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives wheat or corn on their front lawn. But the truth is that futures contracts rarely result in actual delivery of the underlying asset. Traders establish long or short positions in contracts that will benefit from a rise or fall in the futures price and almost always close out, or reverse, those positions before the contract expires. The fraction of contracts that result in actual delivery is estimated to range from less than 1% to 3%, depending on the commodity and activity in the contract. In the unusual case of actual deliveries of commodities, they occur via regular channels of supply, most often warehouse receipts. You can see the typical pattern of open interest in Figure 22.1. In the copper contract, for example, the January delivery contract is approaching maturity, and open interest is small; most contracts have been reversed already. The greatest open interest is in the March contract. For other contracts, for example, gold, for which the nearest maturity date isn’t until February, open interest is typically highest in the nearest contract. The Margin Account and Marking to Market The total profit or loss realized by the long trader who buys a contract at time 0 and closes, or reverses, it at time t is just the change in the futures price over the period, Ft 2 F0. Symmetrically, the short trader earns F0 2 Ft. The process by which profits or losses accrue to traders is called marking to market. At initial execution of a trade, each trader establishes a margin account. The margin is a security account consisting of cash or near-cash securities, such as Treasury bills, that ensures the trader is able to satisfy the obligations of the futures contract. Because both parties to a futures contract are exposed to losses, both must post margin. To illustrate, return to the first corn contract listed in Figure 22.1. If the initial required margin on corn, for example, is 10%, then the trader must post $3,620 per contract of the margin account. This is 10% of the value of the contract, $7.24 per bushel 3 5,000 bushels per contract. Because the initial margin may be satisfied by posting interest-earning securities, the requirement does not impose a significant opportunity cost of funds on the trader. The initial margin is usually set between 5% and 15% of the total value of the contract. Contracts written on assets with more volatile prices require higher margins. On any day that futures contracts trade, futures prices may rise or may fall. Instead of waiting until the maturity date for traders to realize all gains and losses, the clearinghouse requires all positions to recognize profits as they accrue daily. If the futures price of corn rises from 724 to 726 cents per bushel, the clearinghouse credits the margin account of the long position for 5,000 bushels times 2 cents per bushel, or $100 per contract. Conversely, for the short position, the clearinghouse takes this amount from the margin account for each contract held. This daily settling is called marking to market. It means the maturity date of the contract does not govern realization of profit or loss. Instead, as futures prices change, the proceeds accrue to the trader’s margin account immediately. We will provide a more detailed example of this process shortly. Marking to market is the major way in which futures and forward contracts differ, besides contract standardCONCEPT CHECK 22.2 ization. Futures follow this pay-(or receive-)as-you-go method. Forward contracts are simply held until maturity, What must be the net inflow or outlay from and no funds are transferred until that date, although the marking to market for the clearinghouse? contracts may be traded. If a trader accrues sustained losses from daily marking to market, the margin account may fall below a critical value called the maintenance margin. If the value of the account falls below this value, the trader receives a margin call, requiring that the margin account be replenished or the position be reduced to a size commensurate with the remaining funds. Margins and bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 778 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 779 margin calls safeguard the position of the clearinghouse. Positions are closed out before the margin account is exhausted—the trader’s losses are covered, and the clearinghouse is not put at risk. Example 22.1 Maintenance Margin Suppose the maintenance margin is 5% while the initial margin was 10% of the value of the corn, or $3,620. Then a margin call will go out when the original margin account has fallen in half, by about $1,810. Each 1-cent decline in the corn price results in a $50 loss to the long position. Therefore, the futures price need only fall by 37 cents (or 5% of its current value) to trigger a margin call. On the contract maturity date, the futures price will equal the spot price of the commodity. As a maturing contract calls for immediate delivery, the futures price on that day must equal the spot price—the cost of the commodity from the two competing sources is equalized in a competitive market.2 You may obtain delivery of the commodity either by purchasing it directly in the spot market or by entering the long side of a futures contract. A commodity available from two sources (spot or futures market) must be priced identically, or else investors will rush to purchase it from the cheap source in order to sell it in the high-priced market. Such arbitrage activity could not persist without prices adjusting to eliminate the arbitrage opportunity. Therefore, the futures price and the spot price must converge at maturity. This is called the convergence property. For an investor who establishes a long position in a contract now (time 0) and holds that position until maturity (time T), the sum of all daily settlements will equal FT 2 F0, where FT stands for the futures price at contract maturity. Because of convergence, however, the futures price at maturity, FT, equals the spot price, PT, so total futures profits also may be expressed as PT 2 F0. Thus we see that profits on a futures contract held to maturity perfectly track changes in the value of the underlying asset. Example 22.2 Marking to Market Assume the current futures price for silver for delivery 5 days from today is $30.10 per ounce. Suppose that over the next 5 days, the futures price evolves as follows: Day 0 (today) 1 2 3 4 5 (delivery) Futures Price $30.10 30.20 30.25 30.18 30.18 30.21 2 Small differences between the spot and futures price at maturity may persist because of transportation costs, but this is a minor factor. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 779 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 780 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives The daily mark-to-market settlements for each contract held by the long position will be as follows: Day 1 2 3 4 5 Profit (Loss) per Ounce 3 5,000 Ounces/Contract 5 Daily Proceeds 30.20 2 30.10 5 .10 30.25 2 30.20 5 .05 30.18 2 30.25 5 2.07 30.18 2 30.18 5 0 30.21 2 30.18 5 .03 $500 250 2350 0 150 Sum 5 $550 The profit on Day 1 is the increase in the futures price from the previous day, or ($30.20 2 $30.10) per ounce. Because each silver contract on the Commodity Exchange (CMX) calls for purchase and delivery of 5,000 ounces, the total profit per contract is 5,000 times $.10, or $500. On Day 3, when the futures price falls, the long position’s margin account will be debited by $350. By Day 5, the sum of all daily proceeds is $550. This is exactly equal to 5,000 times the difference between the final futures price of $30.21 and original futures price of $30.10. Because the final futures price equals the spot price on that date, the sum of all the daily proceeds (per ounce of silver held long) also equals PT 2 F0. Cash versus Actual Delivery Most futures contracts call for delivery of an actual commodity such as a particular grade of wheat or a specified amount of foreign currency if the contract is not reversed before maturity. For agricultural commodities, where quality of the delivered good may vary, the exchange sets quality standards as part of the futures contract. In some cases, contracts may be settled with higher- or lower-grade commodities. In these cases, a premium or discount is applied to the delivered commodity to adjust for the quality difference. Some futures contracts call for cash settlement. An example is a stock index futures contract where the underlying asset is an index such as the Standard & Poor’s 500 or the New York Stock Exchange Index. Delivery of every stock in the index clearly would be impractical. Hence the contract calls for “delivery” of a cash amount equal to the value that the index attains on the maturity date of the contract. The sum of all the daily settlements from marking to market results in the long position realizing total profits or losses of ST 2 F0, where ST is the value of the stock index on the maturity date T and F0 is the original futures price. Cash settlement closely mimics actual delivery, except the cash value of the asset rather than the asset itself is delivered. More concretely, the S&P 500 index contract calls for delivery of $250 times the value of the index. At maturity, the index might list at 1,200, the market-value-weighted index of the prices of all 500 stocks in the index. The cash settlement contract calls for delivery of $250 3 1,200, or $300,000 cash in return for $250 times the futures price. This yields exactly the same profit as would result from directly purchasing 250 units of the index for $300,000 and then delivering it for $250 times the original futures price. Regulations Futures markets are regulated by the federal Commodities Futures Trading Commission. The CFTC sets capital requirements for member firms of the futures exchanges, authorizes trading in new contracts, and oversees maintenance of daily trading records. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 780 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 781 The futures exchange may set limits on the amount by which futures prices may change from one day to the next. For example, if the price limit on silver contracts were set at $1 and silver futures close today at $22.10 per ounce, then trades in silver tomorrow may vary only between $21.10 and $23.10 per ounce. The exchanges may increase or reduce price limits in response to perceived changes in price volatility of the contract. Price limits are often eliminated as contracts approach maturity, usually in the last month of trading. Price limits traditionally are viewed as a means to limit violent price fluctuations. This reasoning seems dubious. Suppose an international monetary crisis overnight drives up the spot price of silver to $30. No one would sell silver futures at prices for future delivery as low as $22.10. Instead, the futures price would rise each day by the $1 limit, although the quoted price would represent only an unfilled bid order—no contracts would trade at the low quoted price. After several days of limit moves of $1 per day, the futures price would finally reach its equilibrium level, and trading would occur again. This process means no one could unload a position until the price reached its equilibrium level. We conclude that price limits offer no real protection against fluctuations in equilibrium prices. Taxation Because of the mark-to-market procedure, investors do not have control over the tax year in which they realize gains or losses. Instead, price changes are realized gradually, with each daily settlement. Therefore, taxes are paid at year-end on cumulated profits or losses regardless of whether the position has been closed out. As a general rule, 60% of futures gains or losses are treated as long term, and 40% as short term. 22.3 Futures Markets Strategies Hedging and Speculation Hedging and speculating are two polar uses of futures markets. A speculator uses a futures contract to profit from movements in futures prices, a hedger to protect against price movement. If speculators believe prices will increase, they will take a long position for expected profits. Conversely, they exploit expected price declines by taking a short position. Example 22.3 Speculating with Oil Futures Suppose you believe that crude oil prices are going to increase and therefore decide to purchase crude oil futures. Each contract calls for delivery of 1,000 barrels of oil, so for every dollar increase in the futures price of crude, the long position gains $1,000 and the short position loses that amount. Conversely, suppose you think that prices are heading lower and therefore sell a contract. If crude oil prices do in fact fall, then you will gain $1,000 per contract for every dollar that prices decline. If the futures price for delivery in February is $91.86 and crude oil is selling at the contract maturity date for $93.86, the long side will profit by $2,000 per contract purchased. The short side will lose an identical amount on each contract sold. On the other hand, if oil has fallen to $89.86, the long side will lose, and the short side will gain, $2,000 per contract. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 781 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 782 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Why does a speculator buy a futures contract? Why not buy the underlying asset directly? One reason lies in transaction costs, which are far smaller in futures markets. Another important reason is the leverage that futures trading provides. Recall that futures contracts require traders to post margin considerably less than the value of the asset underlying the contract. Therefore, they allow speculators to achieve much greater leverage than is available from direct trading in a commodity. Example 22.4 Futures and Leverage Suppose the initial margin requirement for the oil contract is 10%. At a current futures price of $91.86, and contract size of 1,000 barrels, this would require margin of .10 3 91.86 3 1,000 5 $9,186. A $2 jump in oil prices represents an increase of 2.18%, and results in a $2,000 gain on the contract for the long position. This is a percentage gain of 21.8% in the $9,186 posted as margin, precisely 10 times the percentage increase in the oil price. The 10-to-1 ratio of percentage changes reflects the leverage inherent in the futures position, because the contract was established with an initial margin of one-tenth the value of the underlying asset. Hedgers, by contrast, use futures to insulate themselves against price movements. A firm planning to sell oil, for example, might anticipate a period of market volatility and wish to protect its revenue against price fluctuations. To hedge the total revenue derived from the sale, the firm enters a short position in oil futures. As the following example illustrates, this locks in its total proceeds (i.e., revenue from the sale of the oil plus proceeds from its futures position). Example 22.5 Hedging with Oil Futures Consider an oil distributor planning to sell 100,000 barrels of oil in February that wishes to hedge against a possible decline in oil prices. Because each contract calls for delivery of 1,000 barrels, it would sell 100 contracts that mature in February. Any decrease in prices would then generate a profit on the contracts that would offset the lower sales revenue from the oil. To illustrate, suppose that the only three possible prices for oil in February are $89.86, $91.86, and $93.86 per barrel. The revenue from the oil sale will be 100,000 times the price per barrel. The profit on each contract sold will be 1,000 times any decline in the futures price. At maturity, the convergence property ensures that the final futures price will equal the spot price of oil. Therefore, the profit on the 100 contracts sold will equal 100,000 3 (F 0 2 PT), where PT is the oil price on the delivery date, and F 0 is the original futures price, $91.86. Now consider the firm’s overall position. The total revenue in February can be computed as follows: Oil Price in February, PT Revenue from oil sale: 100,000 3 PT 1 Profit on futures: 100,000 3 (F0 2 PT) TOTAL PROCEEDS bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 782 $89.86 $91.86 $93.86 $8,986,000 200,000 $9,186,000 $9,186,000 0 $9,186,000 $9,386,000 2200,000 $9,186,000 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 783 The revenue from the oil sale plus the proceeds from the contracts equals the current futures price, $91.86 per barrel. The variation in the price of the oil is precisely offset by the profits or losses on the futures position. For example, if oil falls to $89.86 a barrel, the short futures position generates $200,000 profit, just enough to bring total revenues to $9,186,000. The total is the same as if one were to arrange today to sell the oil in February at the futures price. Figure 22.4 illustrates the nature of the hedge in Example 22.5. The upward-sloping line is the revenue from the sale of oil. The downward-sloping line is the profit on the futures contract. The horizontal line is the sum of sales revenue plus futures profits. This line is flat, as the hedged position is independent of oil prices. To generalize Example 22.5, note that oil will sell for PT per barrel at the maturity of the contract. The profit per barrel on the futures will be F0 2 PT. Therefore, total revenue is PT 1 (F0 2 PT) 5 F0, which is independent of the eventual oil price. The oil distributor in Example 22.5 engaged in a short hedge, taking a short futures position to offset risk in the sales price of a particular asset. A long hedge is the analogous hedge for someone who wishes to eliminate the risk of an uncertain purchase price. For example, a power supplier planning to purchase oil may be afraid that prices might rise by the time of the purchase. As the following Concept Check illustrates, the supplier might buy oil futures to lock in the net purchase price at the time of the transaction. CONCEPT CHECK 22.3 Suppose as in Example 22.5 that oil will be selling in February for $89.86, $91.86, or $93.86 per barrel. Consider a firm that plans to buy 100,000 barrels of oil in February. Show that if the firm buys 100 oil contracts today, its net expenditures in February will be hedged and equal to $9,186,000. 120 Hedged revenues are constant at $91.86 per barrel, equal to the futures price Proceeds (per Barrel) 100 80 Sales revenue increases with oil price 60 40 Profit on short futures position falls with oil price 20 0 85 –20 90 91.86 95 100 105 Oil Price Sales Revenue per Barrel Futures Profits per Barrel Total Proceeds Figure 22.4 Hedging revenues using futures, Example 22.5 (Futures price 5 $91.86) bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 783 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 784 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Exact futures hedging may be impossible for some goods because the necessary futures contract is not traded. For example, a portfolio manager might want to hedge the value of a diversified, actively managed portfolio for a period of time. However, futures contracts are listed only on CONCEPT CHECK 22.4 indexed portfolios. Nevertheless, because returns on the manager’s diversified portfolio will have a high correWhat are the sources of risk to an investor who lation with returns on broad-based indexed portfolios, uses stock index futures to hedge an actively an effective hedge may be established by selling index managed stock portfolio? How might you estifutures contracts. Hedging a position using futures on mate the magnitude of that risk? another asset is called cross-hedging. Basis Risk and Hedging The basis is the difference between the futures price and the spot price.3 As we have noted, on the maturity date of a contract, the basis must be zero: The convergence property implies that FT 2 PT 5 0. Before maturity, however, the futures price for later delivery may differ substantially from the current spot price. In Example 22.5 we discussed the case of a short hedger who manages risk by entering a short position to deliver oil in the future. If the asset and futures contract are held until maturity, the hedger bears no risk. Risk is eliminated because the futures price and spot price at contract maturity must be equal: Gains and losses on the futures and the commodity position will exactly cancel. However, if the contract and asset are to be liquidated early, before contract maturity, the hedger bears basis risk, because the futures price and spot price need not move in perfect lockstep at all times before the delivery date. In this case, gains and losses on the contract and the asset may not exactly offset each other. Some speculators try to profit from movements in the basis. Rather than betting on the direction of the futures or spot prices per se, they bet on the changes in the difference between the two. A long spot–short futures position will profit when the basis narrows. Example 22.6 Speculating on the Basis Consider an investor holding 100 ounces of gold, who is short one gold-futures contract. Suppose that gold today sells for $1,591 an ounce, and the futures price for June delivery is $1,596 an ounce. Therefore, the basis is currently $5. Tomorrow, the spot price might increase to $1,595, while the futures price increases to $1,599, so the basis narrows to $4. The investor’s gains and losses are as follows: Gain on holdings of gold (per ounce): $1,595 2 $1,591 5 $4 Loss on gold futures position (per ounce): $1,599 2 $1,596 5 $3 The net gain is the decrease in the basis, or $1 per ounce. A related strategy is a calendar spread position, where the investor takes a long position in a futures contract of one maturity and a short position in a contract on the same commodity, but with a different maturity.4 Profits accrue if the difference in futures prices 3 Usage of the word basis is somewhat loose. It sometimes is used to refer to the futures-spot difference F 2 P, and sometimes to the spot-futures difference P 2 F. We will consistently call the basis F 2 P. 4 Yet another strategy is an intercommodity spread, in which the investor buys a contract on one commodity and sells a contract on a different commodity. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 784 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 785 between the two contracts changes in the hoped-for direction, that is, if the futures price on the contract held long increases by more (or decreases by less) than the futures price on the contract held short. Example 22.7 Speculating on the Spread Consider an investor who holds a September maturity contract long and a June contract short. If the September futures price increases by 5 cents while the June futures price increases by 4 cents, the net gain will be 5 cents 2 4 cents, or 1 cent. Like basis strategies, spread positions aim to exploit movements in relative price structures rather than to profit from movements in the general level of prices. 22.4 Futures Prices The Spot-Futures Parity Theorem We have seen that a futures contract can be used to hedge changes in the value of the underlying asset. If the hedge is perfect, meaning that the asset-plus-futures portfolio has no risk, then the hedged position must provide a rate of return equal to the rate on other risk-free investments. Otherwise, there will be arbitrage opportunities that investors will exploit until prices are brought back into line. This insight can be used to derive the theoretical relationship between a futures price and the price of its underlying asset. Suppose for simplicity that the S&P 500 index currently is at 1,000 and an investor who holds $1,000 in a mutual fund indexed to the S&P 500 wishes to temporarily hedge her exposure to market risk. Assume that the indexed portfolio pays dividends totaling $20 over the course of the year, and for simplicity, that all dividends are paid at year-end. Finally, assume that the futures price for year-end delivery of the S&P 500 contract is 1,010.5 Let’s examine the end-of-year proceeds for various values of the stock index if the investor hedges her portfolio by entering the short side of the futures contract. Final value of stock portfolio, ST Payoff from short futures position (equals F0 2 FT 5 $1,010 2 ST) Dividend income TOTAL $ 970 40 $ 990 20 $1,010 0 $1,030 220 $1,050 240 $1,070 260 20 $1,030 20 $1,030 20 $1,030 20 $1,030 20 $1,030 20 $1,030 The payoff from the short futures position equals the difference between the original futures price, $1,010, and the year-end stock price. This is because of convergence: The futures price at contract maturity will equal the stock price at that time. Notice that the overall position is perfectly hedged. Any increase in the value of the indexed stock portfolio is offset by an equal decrease in the payoff of the short futures position, resulting in a final value independent of the stock price. The $1,030 total payoff is 5 Actually, the futures contract calls for delivery of $250 times the value of the S&P 500 index, so that each contract would be settled for $250 times the index. With the index at 1,000, each contract would hedge about $250 3 1,000 5 $250,000 worth of stock. Of course, institutional investors would consider a stock portfolio of this size to be quite small. We will simplify by assuming that you can buy a contract for one unit rather than 250 units of the index. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 785 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 786 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives the sum of the current futures price, F0 5 $1,010, and the $20 dividend. It is as though the investor arranged to sell the stock at year-end for the current futures price, thereby eliminating price risk and locking in total proceeds equal to the futures price plus dividends paid before the sale. What rate of return is earned on this riskless position? The stock investment requires an initial outlay of $1,000, whereas the futures position is established without an initial cash outflow. Therefore, the $1,000 portfolio grows to a year-end value of $1,030, providing a rate of return of 3%. More generally, a total investment of S0, the current stock price, grows to a final value of F0 1 D, where D is the dividend payout on the portfolio. The rate of return is therefore Rate of return on hedged stock portfolio 5 (F0 1 D) 2 S0 S0 This return is essentially riskless. We observe F0 at the beginning of the period when we enter the futures contract. While dividend payouts are not perfectly riskless, they are highly predictable over short periods, especially for diversified portfolios. Any uncertainty is extremely small compared to the uncertainty in stock prices. Presumably, 3% must be the rate of return available on other riskless investments. If not, then investors would face two competing risk-free strategies with different rates of return, a situation that could not last. Therefore, we conclude that (F0 1 D) 2 S0 5 rf S0 Rearranging, we find that the futures price must be F0 5 S0(1 1 rf) 2 D 5 S0(1 1 rf 2 d) (22.1) where d is the dividend yield on the stock portfolio, defined as D/S0. This result is called the spot-futures parity theorem. It gives the normal or theoretically correct relationship between spot and futures prices. Any deviation from parity would give rise to risk-free arbitrage opportunities. Example 22.8 Futures Market Arbitrage Suppose that parity were violated. For example, suppose the risk-free interest rate were only 1% so that according to Equation 22.1, the futures price should be $1,000(1.01) 2 $20 5 $990. The actual futures price, F0 5 $1,010, is $20 higher than its “appropriate” value. This implies that an investor can make arbitrage profits by shorting the relatively overpriced futures contract and buying the relatively underpriced stock portfolio using money borrowed at the 1% market interest rate. The proceeds from this strategy would be as follows: Action Borrow $1,000, repay with interest in 1 year Buy stock for $1,000 Enter short futures position (F0 5 $1,010) TOTAL bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 786 Initial Cash Flow Cash Flow in 1 Year 11,000 21,000 0 0 21,000(1.01) 5 2$1,010 ST 1 $20 dividend $1,010 2 ST $20 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 787 The net initial investment of the strategy is zero. But its cash flow in 1 year is $20 regardless of the stock price. In other words, it is riskless. This payoff is precisely equal to the mispricing of the futures contract relative to its parity value, 1,010 2 990. When parity is violated, the strategy to exploit the mispricing produces an arbitrage profit—a riskless profit requiring no initial net investment. If such an opportunity existed, all market participants would rush to take advantage of it. The results? The stock price would be bid up, and/or the futures price offered down until Equation 22.1 is satisfied. A similar analysis applies to the possibility that F0 is less than $990. In this case, you simply reverse the strategy above to earn riskless profits. We conclude, therefore, that in a well-functioning market in which arbitrage opportunities are competed away, F0 5 S0(1 1 rf) 2 D. CONCEPT CHECK 22.5 Return to the arbitrage strategy laid out in Example 22.8. What would be the three steps of the strategy if F0 were too low, say, $980? Work out the cash flows of the strategy now and in 1 year in a table like the one in the example. Confirm that your profits equal the mispricing of the contract. The arbitrage strategy of Example 22.8 can be represented more generally as follows: Action 1. Borrow S0 dollars 2. Buy stock for S0 3. Enter short futures position TOTAL Initial Cash Flow Cash Flow in 1 Year S0 2S0 0 0 2S0 (1 1 rf) ST 1 D F0 2 ST F0 2 S0(1 1 rf) 1 D The initial cash flow is zero by construction: The money necessary to purchase the stock in step 2 is borrowed in step 1, and the futures position in step 3, which is used to hedge the value of the stock position, does not require an initial outlay. Moreover, the total cash flow at year-end is riskless because it involves only terms that are already known when the contract is entered. If the final cash flow were not zero, all investors would try to cash in on the arbitrage opportunity. Ultimately prices would change until the year-end cash flow is reduced to zero, at which point F0 would equal S0(1 1 rf) 2 D. The parity relationship also is called the cost-of-carry relationship because it asserts that the futures price is determined by the relative costs of buying a stock with deferred delivery in the futures market versus buying it in the spot market with immediate delivery and “carrying” it in inventory. If you buy stock now, you tie up your funds and incur a time-value-of-money cost of rf per period. On the other hand, you receive dividend payments with a current yield of d. The net carrying cost advantage of deferring delivery of the stock is therefore rf 2 d per period. This advantage must be offset by a differential between the futures price and the spot price. The price differential just offsets the cost-of-carry advantage when F0 5 S0(1 1 rf 2 d). The parity relationship is easily generalized to multiperiod applications. We simply recognize that the difference between the futures and spot price will be larger as the maturity of the contract is longer. This reflects the longer period to which we apply the net cost of carry. For contract maturity of T periods, the parity relationship is F0 5 S0(1 1 rf 2 d)T bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 787 (22.2) 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 788 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Dividend Yield (Annualized, %) 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Jul-12 Jan-13 Jul-11 Jan-12 Jul-10 Jan-11 Jan-10 Jul-09 Jul-08 Jan-09 Jul-07 Jan-08 Jul-06 Jan-07 Jul-05 Jan-06 Jul-04 Jan-05 Jul-03 Jan-04 Jul-02 Jan-03 Jul-01 Jan-02 Jan-01 0 Figure 22.5 S&P 500 monthly dividend yield Notice that when the dividend yield is less than the risk-free rate, Equation 22.2 implies that futures prices will exceed spot prices, and by greater amounts for longer times to contract maturity. But when d > rf, as is the case today, the income yield on the stock exceeds the forgone (risk-free) interest that could be earned on the money invested; in this event, the futures price will be less than the current stock price, again by greater amounts for longer maturities. You can confirm that this is so by examining the S&P 500 contract listings in Figure 22.1. Although dividends of individual securities may fluctuate unpredictably, the annualized dividend yield of a broad-based index such as the S&P 500 is fairly stable, recently in the neighborhood of a bit more than 2% per year. The yield is seasonal, however, with regular peaks and troughs, so the dividend yield for the relevant months must be the one used. Figure 22.5 illustrates the yield pattern for the S&P 500. Some months, such as January or April, have consistently low yields, while others, such as May, have consistently high ones.6 We have described parity in terms of stocks and stock index futures, but it should be clear that the logic applies as well to any financial futures contract. For gold futures, for example, we would simply set the dividend yield to zero. For bond contracts, we would let the coupon income on the bond play the role of dividend payments. In both cases, the parity relationship would be essentially the same as Equation 22.2. The arbitrage strategy described above should convince you that these parity relationships are more than just theoretical results. Any violations of the parity relationship give rise to arbitrage opportunities that can provide large profits to traders. We will see in the next chapter that index arbitrage in the stock market is a tool to exploit violations of the parity relationship for stock index futures contracts. Spreads Just as we can predict the relationship between spot and futures prices, there are similar ways to determine the proper relationships among futures prices for contracts of different 6 The very high dividend yield in November 2004 was due to Microsoft’s special one-time dividend of $3 per share. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 788 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 789 maturity dates. Equation 22.2 shows that the futures price is in part determined by time to maturity. If the risk-free rate is greater than the dividend yield (i.e., rf > d), then the futures price will be higher on longer-maturity contracts and if rf < d, longer-maturity futures prices will be lower. You can confirm from Figure 22.1 that in 2013, when the risk-free rate was below the dividend yield, the longer-maturity S&P 500 contract did have a lower futures price than the shorter term contract. For futures on assets like gold, which pay no “dividend yield,” we can set d 5 0 and conclude that F must increase as time to maturity increases. To be more precise about spread pricing, call F(T1) the current futures price for delivery at date T1, and F(T2) the futures price for delivery at T2. Let d be the dividend yield of the stock. We know from the parity Equation 22.2 that F(T1) 5 S0(1 1 rf 2 d)T1 F(T2) 5 S0(1 1 rf 2 d)T2 As a result, F(T2) /F(T1) 5 (1 1 rf 2 d)(T2 2T1) Therefore, the basic parity relationship for spreads is F(T2) 5 F(T1)(1 1 rf 2 d)(T2 2T1) (22.3) Equation 22.3 should remind you of the spot-futures parity relationship. The major difference is in the substitution of F(T1) for the current spot price. The intuition is also similar. Delaying delivery from T1 to T2 assures the long position that the stock will be purchased for F(T2) dollars at T2 but does not require that money be tied up in the stock until T2. The savings realized are the net cost of carry between T1 and T2. Delaying delivery from T1 until T2 frees up F(T1) dollars, which earn risk-free interest at rf. The delayed delivery of the stock also results in the lost dividend yield between T1 and T2. The net cost of carry saved by delaying the delivery is thus rf 2 d. This gives the proportional increase in the futures price that is required to compensate market participants for the delayed delivery of the stock and postponement of the payment of the futures price. If the parity condition for spreads is violated, arbitrage opportunities will arise. (Problem 19 at the end of the chapter explores this possibility.) Example 22.9 Spread Pricing To see how to use Equation 22.3, consider the following data for a hypothetical contract: Contract Maturity Data January 15 March 15 Futures Price $105.00 104.75 Suppose that the effective annual T-bill rate is 1% and that the dividend yield is 2% per year. The “correct” March futures price relative to the January price is, according to Equation 22.3, 105(1 1 .01 2 .02)1/6 5 104.82 The actual March futures price is 104.75, meaning that the March futures price is slightly underpriced compared to the January futures and that, aside from transaction costs, an arbitrage opportunity seems to be present. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 789 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer eXcel APPLICATIONS: Parity and Spreads T he parity spreadsheet allows you to calculate futures prices corresponding to a spot price for different maturities, interest rates, and income yields. You can use the spreadsheet to see how prices of more distant contracts will fluctuate with spot prices and the cost of carry. You can learn more about this spreadsheet by using the version available on our Web site at www.mhhe.com/bkm. (the difference in futures prices for the long versus short maturity contracts) if the interest rate increases by 2%? 2. What happens to the time spread if the income yield increases by 2%? 3. What happens to the spread if the income yield equals the interest rate? Excel Questions 1. Experiment with different values for both income yield and interest rate. What happens to the size of the time spread A B C D E 1 Spot Futures Parity and Time Spreads 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Spot price Income yield (%) Interest rate (%) Today’s date Maturity date 1 Maturity date 2 Maturity date 3 100 2 4.5 5/14/09 11/17/09 1/2/10 6/7/10 Futures prices versus maturity 100.00 101.26 101.58 102.66 Spot price Futures 1 Futures 2 Futures 3 11 12 13 14 Time to maturity 1 Time to maturity 2 Time to maturity 3 0.51 0.63 1.06 Equation 22.3 shows that futures prices with different maturities should all move together. This is not surprising because all are linked to the same spot price through the parity relationship. Figure 22.6 plots futures prices on gold for three maturity dates. It is apparent that the prices move in virtual lockstep and that the more distant delivery dates command higher futures prices, as Equation 22.3 predicts. Futures Price, $/ounce 1660 1640 1620 1600 1580 1560 Dec ‘12 delivery June ‘13 delivery Dec ‘13 delivery 1540 1520 1500 1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 Date in July 2012 Figure 22.6 Gold futures prices 790 bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 790 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 791 Forward versus Futures Pricing Until now we have paid little attention to the differing time profile of returns of futures and forward contracts. Instead, we have taken the sum of daily mark-to-market proceeds to the long position as PT 2 F0 and assumed for convenience that the entire profit accrues on the delivery date. Our parity theorems apply only to forward pricing because they assume that contract proceeds are in fact realized only on delivery. In contrast, the actual timing of cash flows conceivably might affect the futures price. Futures prices will deviate from parity when marking to market gives a systematic advantage to either the long or short position. If marking to market tends to favor the long position, for example, the futures price should exceed the forward price, because the long position will be willing to pay a premium for the advantage of marking to market. When will marking to market favor either a long or short trader? A trader will benefit if daily settlements are received (and can be invested) when the interest rate is high and are paid (and can be financed) when the interest rate is low. Because long positions will benefit if futures prices tend to rise when interest rates are high, they will be willing to accept a higher futures price. Therefore, a positive correlation between interest rates and changes in futures prices implies that the “fair” futures price will exceed the forward price. Conversely, a negative correlation means that marking to market favors the short position and implies that the equilibrium futures price should be below the forward price. For most contracts, the covariance between futures prices and interest rates is so low that the difference between futures and forward prices will be negligible. However, contracts on long-term fixed-income securities are an important exception to this rule. In this case, because prices have a high correlation with interest rates, the covariance can be large enough to generate a meaningful spread between forward and future prices. 22.5 Futures Prices versus Expected Spot Prices So far we have considered the relationship between futures prices and the current spot price. What about the relationship between the futures price and the expected value of the spot price? In other words, how well does the futures price forecast the ultimate spot price? Three traditional theories have been put forth: the expectations hypothesis, normal backwardation, and contango. Today’s consensus is that all of these traditional hypotheses are subsumed by modern portfolio theory. Figure 22.7 shows the expected path of futures under the three traditional hypotheses. Expectations Hypothesis The expectations hypothesis is the simplest theory of futures pricing. It states that the futures price equals the expected value of the future spot price: F0 5 E(PT). Under this theory the expected profit to either position of a futures contract would equal zero: The short position’s expected profit is F0 2 E(PT), whereas the long’s is E(PT) 2 F0. With F0 5 E(PT), the expected profit to either side is zero. This hypothesis relies on a notion of risk neutrality. If all market participants are risk neutral, they should agree on a futures price that provides an expected profit of zero to all parties. The expectations hypothesis resembles market equilibrium in a world with no uncertainty; that is, if prices of goods at all future dates were currently known, then the futures price for delivery at any particular date would equal the currently known future spot price for that date. It is a tempting but incorrect leap to then assert that under uncertainty the futures price should equal the currently expected spot price. This view ignores the risk premiums that must be built into futures prices when ultimate spot prices are uncertain. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 791 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 792 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives Normal Backwardation Future Prices This theory is associated with the famous British economists John Maynard Keynes and John Hicks. Contango They argued that for most commodities there are natural hedgers who wish to shed risk. For examExpectations Hypothesis E(PT) ple, wheat farmers desire to shed the risk of uncertain wheat prices. These farmers will take short posiNormal Backwardation tions to deliver wheat at a guaranteed price; they will short hedge. To induce speculators to take the corresponding long positions, the farmers need to offer them an Time expectation of profit. They will Delivery enter the long side of the contract Date only if the futures price is below the expected spot price of wheat, for an expected profit of E(PT) 2 F0. Figure 22.7 Futures price over time, in the special case that the The speculators’ expected profit expected spot price remains unchanged is the farmers’ expected loss, but farmers are willing to bear this expected loss to avoid the risk of uncertain wheat prices. The theory of normal backwardation thus suggests that the futures price will be bid down to a level below the expected spot price and will rise over the life of the contract until the maturity date, at which point FT 5 PT. Although this theory recognizes the important role of risk premiums in futures markets, it is based on total variability rather than on systematic risk. (This is not surprising, as Keynes wrote almost 40 years before the development of modern portfolio theory.) The modern view refines the measure of risk used to determine appropriate risk premiums. Contango The polar hypothesis to backwardation holds that the natural hedgers are the purchasers of a commodity, rather than the suppliers. In the case of wheat, for example, we would view grain processors as willing to pay a premium to lock in the price that they must pay for wheat. These processors hedge by taking a long position in the futures market; therefore, they are called long hedgers, whereas farmers are short hedgers. Because long hedgers will agree to pay high futures prices to shed risk, and because speculators must be paid a premium to enter the short position, the contango theory holds that F0 must exceed E(PT). It is clear that any commodity will have both natural long hedgers and short hedgers. The compromise traditional view, called the “net hedging hypothesis,” is that F0 will be less than E(PT) when short hedgers outnumber long hedgers and vice versa. The strong side of the market will be the side (short or long) that has more natural hedgers. The strong side must pay a premium to induce speculators to enter into enough contracts to balance the “natural” supply of long and short hedgers. Modern Portfolio Theory The three traditional hypotheses all envision a mass of speculators willing to enter either side of the futures market if they are sufficiently compensated for the risk they incur. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 792 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 793 Modern portfolio theory fine-tunes this approach by refining the notion of risk used in the determination of risk premiums. Simply put, if commodity prices pose positive systematic risk, futures prices must be lower than expected spot prices. To illustrate this approach, consider once again a stock paying no dividends. If E(PT) denotes the expected time-T stock price and k denotes the required rate of return on the stock, then the price of the stock today must equal the present value of its expected future payoff as follows: E(PT) P0 5 (22.4) (1 1 k)T We also know from the spot-futures parity relationship that F0 P0 5 (22.5) (1 1 rf)T Therefore, the right-hand sides of Equations 22.4 and 22.5 must be equal. Equating these terms allows us to solve for F0: 1 1 rf 11k ≤ T (22.6) You can see immediately from Equation 22.6 that F0 will be less than the expectation of PT whenever k is greater than rf, which will be the case for any positive-beta asset. This means that the long side of the contract will make an expected profit [F0 will be lower than E(PT)] when the commodity exhibits positive systematic risk (k is greater than rf). Why should this be? A long futures position will provide a profit (or loss) of PT 2 F0. If the ultimate value of PT entails positive systematic risk, so will the profit to the long position. Speculators with well-diversified portfolios will be willing to enter long futures positions only if they receive compensation for bearing that risk in the form of positive expected profits. Their expected profits will be positive only if E(PT) is greater than F0. The short position’s profit is the negative of the long’s and will have negative systematic risk. Diversified investors in the short CONCEPT CHECK 22.6 position will be willing to suffer that expected loss to lower portfolio risk and will be willing to enter the conWhat must be true of the risk of the spot price of tract even when F0 is less than E(PT). Therefore, if PT has an asset if the futures price is an unbiased estimate of the ultimate spot price? positive beta, F0 must be less than the expectation of PT. The analysis is reversed for negative-beta commodities. 1. Forward contracts call for future delivery of an asset at a currently agreed-on price. The long trader purchases the good, and the short trader delivers it. If the price of the asset at the maturity of the contract exceeds the forward price, the long side benefits by virtue of acquiring the good at the contract price. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm F0 5 E(PT) ¢ SUMMARY 2. A futures contract is similar to a forward contract, differing most importantly in the aspects of standardization and marking to market, which is the process by which gains and losses on futures contract positions are settled daily. In contrast, forward contracts call for no cash transfers until contract maturity. 3. Futures contracts are traded on organized exchanges that standardize the size of the contract, the grade of the deliverable asset, the delivery date, and the delivery location. Traders negotiate only over the contract price. This standardization increases liquidity and means that buyers and sellers can easily find many traders for a desired purchase or sale. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 793 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 794 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 4. The clearinghouse steps in between each pair of traders, acting as the short position for each long and as the long position for each short. In this way traders need not be concerned about the performance of the trader on the opposite side of the contract. In turn, traders post margins to guarantee their own performance. 5. The long position’s gain or loss between time 0 and time t is Ft 2 F0. Because FT 5 PT, the long’s profit if the contract is held until maturity is PT 2 F0, where PT is the spot price at time T and F0 is the original futures price. The gain or loss to the short position is F0 2 PT. 6. Futures contracts may be used for hedging or speculating. Speculators use the contracts to take a stand on the ultimate price of an asset. Short hedgers take short positions in contracts to offset any gains or losses on the value of an asset already held in inventory. Long hedgers take long positions to offset gains or losses in the purchase price of a good. 7. The spot-futures parity relationship states that the equilibrium futures price on an asset providing no service or payments (such as dividends) is F0 5 P0(1 1 rf)T. If the futures price deviates from this value, then market participants can earn arbitrage profits. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 8. If the asset provides services or payments with yield d, the parity relationship becomes F0 5 P0(1 1 rf 2 d)T. This model is also called the cost-of-carry model, because it states that futures price must exceed the spot price by the net cost of carrying the asset until maturity date T. Related Web sites for this chapter are available at www. mhhe.com/bkm 9. The equilibrium futures price will be less than the currently expected time T spot price if the spot price exhibits systematic risk. This provides an expected profit for the long position who bears the risk and imposes an expected loss on the short position who is willing to accept that expected loss as a means to shed systematic risk. KEY TERMS forward contract futures price long position short position single-stock futures clearinghouse KEY EQUATIONS Spot-futures parity: F0(T ) 5 S0 (1 1 r 2 d )T open interest marking to market maintenance margin convergence property cash settlement basis basis risk calendar spread spot-futures parity theorem cost-of-carry relationship Futures spread parity: F0(T2) 5 F0(T1) (1 1 r 2 d)(T2 2T1) Futures vs. expected spot prices: F0 5 E(PT) ¢ PROBLEM SETS 1 1 rf 11k T ≤ 1. Why is there no futures market in cement? 2. Why might individuals purchase futures contracts rather than the underlying asset? Basic 3. What is the difference in cash flow between short-selling an asset and entering a short futures position? 4. Are the following statements true or false? Why? a. All else equal, the futures price on a stock index with a high dividend yield should be higher than the futures price on an index with a low dividend yield. b. All else equal, the futures price on a high-beta stock should be higher than the futures price on a low-beta stock. c. The beta of a short position in the S&P 500 futures contract is negative. 5. What is the difference between the futures price and the value of the futures contract? bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 794 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 795 6. Evaluate the criticism that futures markets siphon off capital from more productive uses. 7. a. Turn to the S&P 500 contract in Figure 22.1. If the margin requirement is 10% of the futures price times the multiplier of $250, how much must you deposit with your broker to trade the March maturity contract? b. If the March futures price were to increase to 1,498, what percentage return would you earn on your net investment if you entered the long side of the contract at the price shown in the figure? c. If the March futures price falls by 1%, what is your percentage return? Intermediate 8. a. A single-stock futures contract on a non-dividend-paying stock with current price $150 has a maturity of 1 year. If the T-bill rate is 3%, what should the futures price be? b. What should the futures price be if the maturity of the contract is 3 years? c. What if the interest rate is 6% and the maturity of the contract is 3 years? a. You own a large position in a relatively illiquid bond that you want to sell. b. You have a large gain on one of your Treasuries and want to sell it, but you would like to defer the gain until the next tax year. c. You will receive your annual bonus next month that you hope to invest in long-term corporate bonds. You believe that bonds today are selling at quite attractive yields, and you are concerned that bond prices will rise over the next few weeks. 10. Suppose the value of the S&P 500 stock index is currently 1,400. If the 1-year T-bill rate is 3% and the expected dividend yield on the S&P 500 is 2%, what should the 1-year maturity futures price be? What if the T-bill rate is less than the dividend yield, for example, 1%? 11. Consider a stock that pays no dividends on which a futures contract, a call option, and a put option trade. The maturity date for all three contracts is T, the exercise price of both the put and the call is X, and the futures price is F. Show that if X 5 F, then the call price equals the put price. Use parity conditions to guide your demonstration. 12. It is now January. The current interest rate is 2%. The June futures price for gold is $1,500, whereas the December futures price is $1,510. Is there an arbitrage opportunity here? If so, how would you exploit it? 13. OneChicago has just introduced a single-stock futures contract on Brandex stock, a company that currently pays no dividends. Each contract calls for delivery of 1,000 shares of stock in 1 year. The T-bill rate is 6% per year. Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 9. How might a portfolio manager use financial futures to hedge risk in each of the following circumstances: a. If Brandex stock now sells at $120 per share, what should the futures price be? b. If the Brandex price drops by 3%, what will be the change in the futures price and the change in the investor’s margin account? c. If the margin on the contract is $12,000, what is the percentage return on the investor’s position? 14. The multiplier for a futures contract on a stock market index is $250. The maturity of the contract is 1 year, the current level of the index is 1,300, and the risk-free interest rate is .5% per month. The dividend yield on the index is .2% per month. Suppose that after 1 month, the stock index is at 1,320. a. Find the cash flow from the mark-to-market proceeds on the contract. Assume that the parity condition always holds exactly. b. Find the holding-period return if the initial margin on the contract is $13,000. 15. You are a corporate treasurer who will purchase $1 million of bonds for the sinking fund in 3 months. You believe rates will soon fall, and you would like to repurchase the company’s sinking fund bonds (which currently are selling below par) in advance of requirements. Unfortunately, you must obtain approval from the board of directors for such a purchase, and this can take up to 2 months. What action can you take in the futures market to hedge any adverse movements in bond yields and prices until you can actually buy the bonds? Will you be long or short? Why? A qualitative answer is fine. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 795 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 796 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 16. The S&P portfolio pays a dividend yield of 1% annually. Its current value is 1,500. The T-bill rate is 4%. Suppose the S&P futures price for delivery in 1 year is 1,550. Construct an arbitrage strategy to exploit the mispricing and show that your profits 1 year hence will equal the mispricing in the futures market. eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 17. The Excel Application box in the chapter (available at www.mhhe.com/bkm; link to Chapter 22 material) shows how to use the spot-futures parity relationship to find a “term structure of futures prices,” that is, futures prices for various maturity dates. a. Suppose that today is January 1, 2013. Assume the interest rate is 3% per year and a stock index currently at 1,500 pays a dividend yield of 1.5%. Find the futures price for contract maturity dates of February 14, 2013, May 21, 2013, and November 18, 2013. b. What happens to the term structure of futures prices if the dividend yield is higher than the risk-free rate? For example, what if the dividend yield is 4%? Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Challenge 18. a. How should the parity condition (Equation 22.2) for stocks be modified for futures contracts on Treasury bonds? What should play the role of the dividend yield in that equation? b. In an environment with an upward-sloping yield curve, should T-bond futures prices on more-distant contracts be higher or lower than those on near-term contracts? c. Confirm your intuition by examining Figure 22.1. 19. Consider this arbitrage strategy to derive the parity relationship for spreads: (1) enter a long futures position with maturity date T1 and futures price F(T1); (2) enter a short position with maturity T2 and futures price F(T2); (3) at T1, when the first contract expires, buy the asset and borrow F(T1) dollars at rate rf; (4) pay back the loan with interest at time T2. a. What are the total cash flows to this strategy at times 0, T1, and T2? b. Why must profits at time T2 be zero if no arbitrage opportunities are present? c. What must the relationship between F(T1) and F(T2) be for the profits at T2 to be equal to zero? This relationship is the parity relationship for spreads. 1. Joan Tam, CFA, believes she has identified an arbitrage opportunity for a commodity as indicated by the following information: Spot price for commodity Futures price for commodity expiring in 1 year Interest rate for 1 year $120 $125 8% a. Describe the transactions necessary to take advantage of this specific arbitrage opportunity. b. Calculate the arbitrage profit. 2. Michelle Industries issued a Swiss franc–denominated 5-year discount note for SFr200 million. The proceeds were converted to U.S. dollars to purchase capital equipment in the United States. The company wants to hedge this currency exposure and is considering the following alternatives: • At-the-money Swiss franc call options. • Swiss franc forwards. • Swiss franc futures. a. Contrast the essential characteristics of each of these three derivative instruments. b. Evaluate the suitability of each in relation to Michelle’s hedging objective, including both advantages and disadvantages. 3. Identify the fundamental distinction between a futures contract and an option contract, and briefly explain the difference in the manner that futures and options modify portfolio risk. 4. Maria VanHusen, CFA, suggests that using forward contracts on fixed-income securities can be used to protect the value of the Star Hospital Pension Plan’s bond portfolio against the possibility of rising interest rates. VanHusen prepares the following example to illustrate how such protection would work: • A 10-year bond with a face value of $1,000 is issued today at par value. The bond pays an annual coupon. • An investor intends to buy this bond today and sell it in 6 months. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 796 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer CHAPTER 22 Futures Markets 797 • The 6-month risk-free interest rate today is 5% (annualized). • A 6-month forward contract on this bond is available, with a forward price of $1,024.70. • In 6 months, the price of the bond, including accrued interest, is forecast to fall to $978.40 as a result of a rise in interest rates. a. Should the investor buy or sell the forward contract to protect the value of the bond against rising interest rates during the holding period? b. Calculate the value of the forward contract for the investor at the maturity of the forward contract if VanHusen’s bond-price forecast turns out to be accurate. c. Calculate the change in value of the combined portfolio (the underlying bond and the appropriate forward contract position) 6 months after contract initiation. 5. Sandra Kapple asks Maria VanHusen about using futures contracts to protect the value of the Star Hospital Pension Plan’s bond portfolio if interest rates rise. VanHusen states: a. “Selling a bond futures contract will generate positive cash flow in a rising interest rate environment prior to the maturity of the futures contract.” b. “The cost of carry causes bond futures contracts to trade for a higher price than the spot price of the underlying bond prior to the maturity of the futures contract.” Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm Comment on the accuracy of each of VanHusen’s two statements. E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES Go to the Chicago Mercantile Exchange site at www.cme.com. From the Products & Trading tab, select the link to Equity Index, and then link to the NASDAQ-100 E-mini contract. Now find the tab for Contract Specifications. 1. What is the contract size for the futures contract? 2. What is the settlement method for the futures contract? 3. For what months are the futures contracts available? 4. Click the link to View Price Limits and then U.S. Equity Price Limits. What is the current value of the 10% price limit for this contract? 5. Click on View Calendar. What is the settlement date of the shortest-maturity outstanding contract? The longest-maturity contract? SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS 1. Short Futures F0 Write (Sell) Call Buy (Long) Put Payoff, Profit Payoff Payoff PT X PT X PT 2. The clearinghouse has a zero net position in all contracts. Its long and short positions are offsetting, so that net cash flow from marking to market must be zero. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 797 7/27/13 1:48 AM Final PDF to printer 798 PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 3. Oil Price in February, PT Cash flow to purchase oil: 2100,000 3 PT 1 Profit on long futures: 100,000 3 (PT 2 F0) TOTAL CASH FLOW $89.86 $91.86 $93.86 2$8,986,000 2$9,186,000 0 2$9,386,000 2200,000 2$9,186,000 2$9,186,000 2$9,186,000 1200,000 Visit us at www.mhhe.com/bkm 4. The risk would be that the index and the portfolio do not move perfectly together. Thus basis risk involving the spread between the futures price and the portfolio value could persist even if the index futures price were set perfectly relative to the index itself. You can measure this risk using the index model. If you regress the return of the active portfolio on the return of the index portfolio, the regression R-square will equal the proportion of the variance of the active portfolio’s return that could have been hedged using the index futures contract. You can also measure the risk of the imperfectly hedged position using the standard error of the regression, which tells you the standard deviation of the residuals in the index model. Because these are the components of the risky returns that are independent of the market index, this standard deviation measures the variability of the portion of the active portfolio’s return that cannot be hedged using the index futures contract. bod61671_ch22_770-798.indd 798 5. The futures price, $980, is $10 below the parity value of $990. The cash flow to the following strategy is riskless and equal to this mispricing. Action Initial Cash Flow Cash Flow in 1 Year Lend S0 dollars 21,000 1,000(1.01) 5 1,010 Sell stock short 11,000 0 Long futures TOTAL 0 2ST 2 20 ST 2 980 $10 risklessly 6. It must have zero beta. If the futures price is an unbiased estimator, then we infer that it has a zero risk premium, which means that beta must be zero. 7/27/13 1:48 AM