Principles of banking and finance M. Buckle, E. Beccalli FN1024, 2790024 2011 Undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences This subject guide is for a Level 1 course (also known as a ‘100 course’) offered as part of the University of London International Programmes in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences. This is equivalent to Level 4 within the Framework for Higher Education Qualifications in England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ). For more information about the University of London International Programmes undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences, see: www.londoninternational.ac.uk/current_students/programme_resources/lse/index.shtml This guide was prepared for the University of London International Programmes by: M. Buckle, MSc, PhD, Senior Lecturer in Finance, European Business Management School, Department of Accounting, University of Wales, Swansea. E. Beccalli, Visiting Senior Fellow in Accounting, London School of Economics and Political Science. This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due to pressure of work the authors are unable to enter into any correspondence relating to, or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or unfavourable, please use the form at the back of this guide. University of London International Programmes Publications Office Stewart House 32 Russell Square London WC1B 5DN United Kingdom Website: www.londoninternational.ac.uk Published by: University of London © University of London 2008 Reprinted with minor revisions 2011 The University of London asserts copyright over all material in this subject guide except where otherwise indicated. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced in any form, or by any means, without permission in writing from the publisher. We make every effort to contact copyright holders. If you think we have inadvertently used your copyright material, please let us know. Contents Contents Chapter 1: Introduction........................................................................................... 1 General introduction to the subject................................................................................. 1 Learning outcomes......................................................................................................... 1 Essential reading............................................................................................................ 2 Further reading............................................................................................................... 3 References..................................................................................................................... 4 Online study resources.................................................................................................... 6 The structure of the subject guide .................................................................................. 7 How to use this subject guide......................................................................................... 8 Structure of each chapter................................................................................................ 9 Examination................................................................................................................... 9 Syllabus........................................................................................................................ 11 Part I: Financial systems........................................................................................ 13 Overview...................................................................................................................... 13 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems........................................................ 15 Aims............................................................................................................................ 15 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 15 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 15 Further reading ........................................................................................................... 15 Introduction................................................................................................................. 16 The structure of financial systems: financial markets, securities and financial intermediaries.............................................................................................................. 17 Taxonomy of financial intermediaries............................................................................ 18 Nature of financial instruments (securities).................................................................... 26 Structure of financial markets ...................................................................................... 32 Summary...................................................................................................................... 36 Key terms .................................................................................................................... 37 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 37 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 38 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems............................................................ 39 Aims ........................................................................................................................... 39 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 39 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 39 Further reading............................................................................................................. 39 References .................................................................................................................. 39 Introduction ................................................................................................................ 40 The evolution of financial systems................................................................................. 43 The emergence of market-based and bank-based systems............................................. 45 Market-based versus bank-based financial systems: implications................................... 50 Financial crises............................................................................................................. 53 Financial bubbles.......................................................................................................... 59 Summary...................................................................................................................... 61 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 62 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 62 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 62 i 24 Principles of banking and finance Part II: Principles of banking................................................................................. 63 Overview...................................................................................................................... 63 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation . ....................................................... 65 Aims............................................................................................................................ 65 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 65 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 65 Further reading............................................................................................................. 65 References .................................................................................................................. 65 Introduction................................................................................................................. 66 Some evidence on financial intermediation .................................................................. 67 Why do financial intermediaries exist?.......................................................................... 68 Asset transformation.................................................................................................... 69 Transaction costs.......................................................................................................... 71 Liquidity needs ........................................................................................................... 72 Asymmetric information: adverse selection and moral hazard........................................ 73 What is the future for financial intermediaries?............................................................. 82 Summary...................................................................................................................... 86 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 87 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 87 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 87 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks . .......................................................................... 89 Aims ........................................................................................................................... 89 Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 89 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 89 Further reading............................................................................................................. 89 References .................................................................................................................. 90 Introduction................................................................................................................. 90 Free banking................................................................................................................ 90 Why do banks need regulations?.................................................................................. 92 Arguments against regulation . .................................................................................... 95 Traditional regulation mechanisms ............................................................................... 96 Alternatives to traditional regulation: disclosure-based regulation of banking.............. 108 International banking regulation................................................................................. 110 Summary.................................................................................................................... 111 Key terms................................................................................................................... 112 A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 112 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 112 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking............................................................ 115 Aims ......................................................................................................................... 115 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 115 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 115 Further reading........................................................................................................... 115 References ................................................................................................................ 115 Introduction............................................................................................................... 116 Taxonomy of risk........................................................................................................ 116 Policies to reduce risk................................................................................................. 120 Credit risk management............................................................................................. 120 Interest rate risk management.................................................................................... 125 Summary.................................................................................................................... 134 Key terms................................................................................................................... 134 ii Contents A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 135 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 135 Part III: Principles of finance............................................................................... 137 Overview.................................................................................................................... 137 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation....................................................... 139 Aims.......................................................................................................................... 139 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 139 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 139 Further reading ......................................................................................................... 139 Introduction............................................................................................................... 140 The concept of present value...................................................................................... 140 Net present value (NPV) and the valuation of real assets............................................. 142 Other real asset appraisal techniques.......................................................................... 144 Valuation of financial assets (securities)...................................................................... 150 Common stocks (i.e. ordinary shares).......................................................................... 152 Summary.................................................................................................................... 155 Key terms................................................................................................................... 155 A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 155 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 156 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return........................................ 159 Aims ......................................................................................................................... 159 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 159 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 159 Further reading ......................................................................................................... 159 References................................................................................................................. 160 Introduction............................................................................................................... 160 Risk and return of a single financial security................................................................ 160 Risk and return of a portfolio: portfolio analysis........................................................... 164 Benefits of diversification............................................................................................ 165 Mean-standard deviation portfolio theory................................................................... 166 Asset pricing models................................................................................................... 171 Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)..................................................................................... 177 Summary.................................................................................................................... 180 Key terms................................................................................................................... 181 A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 181 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 181 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information.............................. 183 Aims ......................................................................................................................... 183 Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 183 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 183 Further reading ......................................................................................................... 183 References................................................................................................................. 184 Introduction............................................................................................................... 184 Informational efficient markets................................................................................... 185 Concept of excess returns........................................................................................... 187 Levels of informational market efficiency: weak, semi-strong and strong forms............. 188 Empirical evidence on efficient markets....................................................................... 190 Summary.................................................................................................................... 197 Key terms................................................................................................................... 197 iii 24 Principles of banking and finance A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 197 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 198 Appendix 1: Solutions to numerical activities..................................................... 199 Answers to ‘Activities’ marked with an asterisk............................................................ 199 Chapter 5................................................................................................................... 199 Chapter 6................................................................................................................... 199 Chapter 7................................................................................................................... 200 Chapter 8................................................................................................................... 201 Chapter 9................................................................................................................... 202 Appendix 2: Sample examination paper............................................................. 203 iv Chapter 1: Introduction Chapter 1: Introduction General introduction to the subject This subject guide provides an introduction to the principles of banking and finance. It covers a broad range of topics using an economic perspective, and aims to give a general background to any student interested in the subject of banking and finance. The contents of the subject guide can be broken down into three main parts: • In Part I, we investigate the structure and functions of financial systems. We focus on each of the three main entities that compose a financial system: financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets. We then investigate the difference in the relative importance of financial intermediaries and financial markets around the world, and thus propose a historical and economic investigation of the reasons behind the emergence of bank-based systems and market-based systems in different countries. • In Part II, we examine the issues that come under the broad heading of principles of banking. Here we examine the key economic reasons used to justify the existence of financial intermediaries (and specifically banks). We then investigate the special nature of banking regulation. Finally we outline the key risks in banking and the main methods used for risk management. Thus the areas covered include the role of financial intermediation, banking regulation and banking risk management. • In Part III, we move to the issues known as principles of finance. Here we will examine the techniques used by firms to value real investment projects, and the models used by investors to value bonds and stocks. We then investigate the issues related to the formation of an optimal portfolio by investors, and we derive the main equilibrium asset pricing models. Finally, we investigate the efficiency of the market in pricing securities, and thus we propose a theoretical and empirical validation of the efficient market hypothesis. The areas covered in this section therefore include capital budgeting, securities valuation, mean-standard deviation portfolio theory, asset pricing models and informational market efficiency. 24 Principles of banking and finance is a compulsory course for the BSc Banking and Finance. This is an important subject because it establishes many of the fundamental concepts in banking and finance that will be developed in later subjects in the degree, such as 92 Corporate finance, 29 Financial intermediation and 143 Valuation and securities analysis. Note that the guide uses mainly US references, takes a US view and uses US terminology. Learning outcomes By the end of this subject guide, and having done the relevant readings and activities, you should be able to: • discuss why financial systems exist, and how they are structured 1 24 Principles of banking and finance • explain why the relative importance of financial intermediaries and financial markets is different around the world, and how bank-based systems differ from market-based systems • understand why financial intermediaries exist, and discuss the role of transaction costs and information asymmetry theories in providing an economic justification • explain why banks need regulation, and illustrate the key reasons for and against the regulation of banking systems • discuss the main types of risks faced by banks, and use the main techniques employed by banks to manage their risks • explain how to value real assets and financial assets, and use the key capital budgeting techniques (Net Present Value and Internal Rate of Return) • explain how to value financial assets (bonds and stocks) • understand how risk affects the return of a risky asset, and hence how risk affects the value of the asset in equilibrium under the fundamental asset pricing paradigms (Capital Asset Pricing Model and Asset Pricing Theory) • discuss whether stock prices reflect all available information, and evaluate the empirical evidence on informational efficiency in financial markets. Essential reading The following text has been chosen as the core text for this subject guide, due to its extensive treatment of many (but not all) of the issues covered in the subject guide and its up-to-date discussions: Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) sixth edition [ISBN 978032155112]. However, this core text does not cover the material for the entire subject guide. To analyse comparative financial systems, the essential reading also includes: Allen, F. and D. Gale Comparing Financial Systems. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2001) [ISBN 9780262511254]. To investigate issues of principles of finance (capital budgeting and valuation of financial assets, risk and return of financial assets and portfolios), the following text is also essential reading: Brealey, R.A, S.C. Myers and F. Allen Principles of corporate finance. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2010) tenth (global) edition [ISBN 9780071314176] Chapters 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 8, 13 and 14. The subject guide must be used in conjunction with these three essential textbooks. At the head of each chapter of this guide, we indicate essential reading from Mishkin and Eakins. Alternatively, when no relevant readings are available in Mishkin and Eakins, we indicate reading from either Allen and Gale or Brealey, Myers and Allen. Several websites are indicated in the subject guide, mainly as references for activities you are required to do. Please visit these websites whenever indicated. The following articles from academic journals are also indicated as Essential reading in Chapters 5 and 6: 2 Chapter 1: Introduction Dow, S. ‘Why the banking system should be regulated’, Economic Journal 106 (436) 1996, pp.698–707. Dowd, K. ‘The Case for Financial Laissez-Faire’, Economic Journal 106 (436) 1996, pp.679–87. Gordy, M.B. ‘A comparative anatomy of credit risk models’, Journal of Banking and Finance 24 (1-2) 2000, pp.119–49. Detailed reading references in this subject guide refer to the editions of the set textbooks listed above. New editions of one or more of these textbooks may have been published by the time you study this course. You can use a more recent edition of any of the books; use the detailed chapter and section headings and the index to identify relevant readings. Also check the virtual learning environment (VLE) regularly for updated guidance on readings. Further reading Please note that as long as you read the Essential reading you are then free to read around the subject area in any text, paper or online resource. You will need to support your learning by reading as widely as possible and by thinking about how these principles apply in the real world. To help you read extensively, you have free access to the VLE and University of London Online Library (see below). Other useful texts for this course include: Bain, A.D. The Economics of the Financial Systems. (Oxford: Blackwell Publishers Ltd, 1992) [ISBN 9780631181972] Chapter 4. Brealey, R.A., S.C. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2008) tenth edition [ISBN 9780073368696] Chapter 8. Buckle, M. and J. Thompson The UK Financial System. (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2004) fourth edition [ISBN 9780719067723] Chapters 1, 2 and 17. Copeland, T.E., J.F. Weston and K. Shastri Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Boston, London: Pearson Addison Wesley, 2005) [ISBN 9780321223531] Chapters 2, 4, 5, 6 and 10. Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, S.J. Brown and W.N. Goetzmann Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2007) seventh edition [ISBN 9780470050828] Chapter 17, pp.59 and 61. Freixas, X. and J.C. Rochet Microeconomics of Banking. (Boston, Mass.: The MIT Press, 2008) [ISBN 9780262061933] Chapters 2, 8 and 9. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002) second edition [ISBN 9780072294330] Chapters 4, 5, 6, 9 and 10. Heffernan, S. Modern Banking in Theory and Practice. (Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, 2005) [ISBN 9780471962090] Chapters 2, 3, 4 and 5. Luenberger, D.G. Investment Science. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1998) [ISBN 9780195108095] Chapters 6 and 7. Saunders, A. and M.M. Cornett Financial Institutions Management: a Risk Management Approach. (New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2007) sixth edition [ISBN 9780077211332] Chapters 2–6 and 8–12. Sinkey, J.F. Commercial Bank Financial Management in the Financial-Services Industry. (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education Inc., 2002) [ISBN 9780130984241] Chapter 16. Smart, S.B., W.L. Megginson and L.J. Gitman Corporate Finance. (Mason, Ohio: South-Western/Thomson Learning, 2004) [ISBN 9780324269604] Chapters 4, 7 and 10. 3 24 Principles of banking and finance References For certain topics, we will also list journal articles or texts as supplementary references to the additional reading. It is not essential that you read this material, but it may be helpful if you wish to better understand some of the topics in this subject guide. A full bibliography of the supplementary references is provided below: Akerlof, G. ‘The Market for “Lemons”: Quality, Uncertainty and the Market Mechanisms’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3) 1970, pp.488–500. Allen, F. and R. Karjalainen ‘Using Genetic Algorithms to Find Technical Trading Rules’, Journal of Financial Economics 51(2) 1999, pp.245–71. Altman, E.I. ‘Managing the commercial lending process’ in Aspinwall, R.C. and R.A. Eisenbeis Handbook of Banking Strategy. (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1985) [ISBN 9780471893141] pp.473–510. Ball, R. and P. Brown ‘An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers’, Journal of Accounting Research 6(2) 1968, pp.159–78. Bank of England Discussion Paper ‘The role of macroprudential policy’, November 2009. Available at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/ news/2009/111.htm Bank of England Financial Stability Report, no. 21 (London, 2007). Basel Committee on Bank Supervision Overview on the New Capital Accord. (Bank for International Settlements, January 2001) p.27. Benston G. and C. Smith ‘A Transaction Costs Approach to the Theory of Financial Intermediation’, Journal of Finance 31(2) 1976, pp.215–231. Bernard, V. and J. Thomas ‘Post-earnings announcement drift: Delayed price response or risk premium?’, Journal of Accounting Research 27(3) 1989 supplement, pp.1–36. Boyd, J.H. and M. Gertler ‘Are Banks Dead? Or Are the Reports Greatly Exaggerated?’ in The Declining(?) Role of Banking. (Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1994). Brock, W., J. Lakonishok and B. LeBaron ‘Simple Technical Trading Rules and the Stochastic Properties of Stock Returns’, Journal of Finance 47(5) 1992, pp.1731–764. Bullard. J, J. Neely and D. Wheelock ‘Systemic risk and the financial crisis: a primer’, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October 2009, pp.403-17. Carhart, M.M. ‘On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance’, Journal of Finance 52(1) 1997, pp.57–82. Chan, K.C., N. Chen and D. Hsieh ‘An Exploratory Investigation of the Firm Size Effect’, Journal of Financial Economics 14(3) 1985, pp.451–71. Chen, N. ‘Some Empirical Tests of the Theory of Arbitrage Pricing’, Journal of Finance 38(5) 1983, pp.1393–414. Chen, N., R. Roll and S. Ross ‘Economic Forces and Stock Market’, Journal of Business 59(3) 1986, pp.383–403. Cheng-few L., D.C. Porter and D.G. Weaver ‘Indirect tests of the HaugenLakonishok small-firm/January effect hypotheses: window dressing versus performance hedging’, The Financial Review (1998) 33, pp.177–94. Coase, R.H. ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics 3(1) 1960, pp.1–23. Corbett, J. and T. Jenkinson ‘How Is Investment Financed? A Study of Germany, Japan and the United States’, Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies 65 (1997) supplement, pp.69–93. DeBondt, F.M. and R. Thaler ‘Further Evidence on Investor Overreaction and Stock Market Seasonality’, Journal of Finance 42(3) 1987, pp.557–80. Diamond, D.W. ‘Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring’, Review of Economic Studies 51(166) 1984, pp.393–414. 4 Chapter 1: Introduction Diamond, D.W. ‘Financial Intermediation as Delegated Monitoring: A Simple Example’, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 82/3, 1996, pp.51-66. Diamond, D.W. and P.H. Dybvig ‘Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity’, Journal of Political Economy 91(3) 1983, pp.401–419. Dimson, E., P. Marsh, and M. Staunton ‘Global evidence on the equity risk premium’, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 15(4) 2003, pp.27–38. Dow, S., ‘Why the banking system should be regulated’, Economic Journal 106 (436) 1996, pp.698–707. Dowd, K., ‘The Case for Financial Laissez-Faire’, Economic Journal 96(106) 1996, pp.679–87. Fama, E. ‘Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work’, Journal of Finance 25(2) 1970, pp.383–417. Fama, E. ‘Banking in the theory of finance’, Journal of Monetary Economics 6(1) 1980, pp.39–57. Fama, E. and K.R. French ‘Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock Prices’, Journal of Political Economy 96(2) 1988, pp.246–73. Fama, E. ‘Efficient Capital Markets: II’, Journal of Finance 46(5) 1991, pp.1575– 618. Freixas, X, C. Giannini, G. Hoggart and F. Soussa ‘Lender of Last Resort: A Review of the Literature’, Bank of England Financial Stability Review, November 1999. Goddard, J.A., P. Molyneux and J.O.S. Wilson European Banking. Efficiency, Technology and Growth. (Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, 2001) [ISBN 9780471494492] pp.109–20. Gordy, M.B. ‘A comparative anatomy of credit risk models’, Journal of Banking and Finance 24(1–2) 2000, pp.119–49. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman ‘Mutual Fund Performance: an Analysis of Quarterly Portfolio Holdings’, Journal of Business 62(3) 1989, pp.393–416. Gurley, J.G. and E.S. Shaw Money in a Theory of Finance. (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institute, 1960) [ISBN 9780815733225]. Hackethal, A. and R.H. Schmidt ‘Financing Patterns: Measurement Concepts and Empirical Results’, Frankfurt Department of Finance Working Paper no. 125 (2004), p.30. Haugen, R. and J. Lakonishok The Incredible January Effect. (Dow Jones-Irwin, Homewood, Illinois, 1988) [ISBN 9781556238710]. Jacquier, E., A. Kane and A.J. Marcus ‘Geometric or Arithmetic Means: A Reconsideration’, Financial Analysts Journal 59(6) 2003, pp.46–53. Jegadeesh, N. and S. Titman ‘Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency’, Journal of Finance 48(1) 1993, pp.65–91. Jensen, M.C. ‘The performance of Mutual Funds in the Period 1945–64’, Journal of Finance 23(2) 1968, pp.389–416. Jensen, M.C., and W.H. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976, pp.305–60. Kay, J. ‘Narrow banking: the reform of banking regulation’, Centre for the study of Financial Innovation, publication no. 88, September 2009. Keim, D.B. ‘The CAPM and Equity Return Regularities’, Financial Analysts Journal 42(3) 1986, pp.19–34. Lacoste, P. ‘International capital flows in Argentina’, BIS Papers no. 23 (http:// www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap23e.pdf, 2004) Leland, H.E. and D.H. Pyle ‘Informational Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation’, Journal of Finance 32(2) 1977, pp.371–387. Lindgren, C., G. Garcia and M. Saal Bank Soundness and Macroeconomic Policy. (Washington DC: International Monetary Fund, 1996) [ISBN 9781557755995]. 5 24 Principles of banking and finance Lintner, J. ‘The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets’, Review of Economics and Statistics 47(1) 1965, pp.13–37. Lo, A. and C. MacKinlay ‘Stock Market Prices do not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test’, Review of Financial Studies 1(1) 1988, pp.41–66. Markowitz, H.M. ‘Portfolio Selection’, Journal of Finance 7(1) 1952, pp.77–91. Mayer, C. ‘Financial Systems, Corporate Finance, and Economic Development’ in Hubbard, R.G. (ed.) Asymmetric Information, Corporate Finance, and Investments. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990) [ISBN 9780226355856] pp.307–32. Mortlock, G. ‘New Zealand’s financial sector regulation’, Reserve Bank of New Zealand: Bulletin 66 (2003), pp.5–49. Patell, J.M. and M.A. Wolfson ‘The Intraday Speed of Adjustment of Stock Prices to Earnings and Dividend Announcements’, Journal of Financial Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.223–52. Poterba, J.M. and L.H. Summers ‘Mean Reversion in Stock Prices: Evidence and Implications’, Journal of Financial Economics 22(1) 1988, pp.27–59. Roll, R. ‘A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory’s Tests; Part 1: On Past and Potential Testability of the Theory’, Journal of Financial Economics 4(2) 1977, pp.129–76. Ross, S.A. ‘The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing’, Journal of Economic Theory 13(3) 1976, pp.341–60. Sharpe, W.F. ‘Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk’, Journal of Finance 19(3) 1964, pp.425–42. Trueman, B., M.H. Wong and X.J. Zhang ‘The Eyeballs Have it: Searching for the Value in Internet Stocks’, Working Paper, (University of California, April 2000). Turner, A ‘The Turner Review: A regulatory response to the global banking crisis’, Financial Services Authority, 2009. (download from www.fsa.gov.uk/ pubs/other/turner_review.pdf) Online study resources In addition to the subject guide and the Essential reading, it is crucial that you take advantage of the study resources that are available online for this course, including the VLE and the Online Library. You can access the VLE, the Online Library and your University of London email account via the Student Portal at: http://my.londoninternational.ac.uk You should receive your login details in your study pack. If you have not, or you have forgotten your login details, please email uolia.support@ london.ac.uk quoting your student number. The VLE The VLE, which complements this subject guide, has been designed to enhance your learning experience, providing additional support and a sense of community. It forms an important part of your study experience with the University of London and you should access it regularly. The VLE provides a range of resources for EMFSS courses: • Self-testing activities: Doing these allows you to test your own understanding of subject material. • Electronic study materials: The printed materials that you receive from the University of London are available to download, including updated reading lists and references. 6 Chapter 1: Introduction • Past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries: These provide advice on how each examination question might best be answered. • A student discussion forum: This is an open space for you to discuss interests and experiences, seek support from your peers, work collaboratively to solve problems and discuss subject material. • Videos: There are recorded academic introductions to the subject, interviews and debates and, for some courses, audio-visual tutorials and conclusions. • Recorded lectures: For some courses, where appropriate, the sessions from previous years’ Study Weekends have been recorded and made available. • Study skills: Expert advice on preparing for examinations and developing your digital literacy skills. • Feedback forms. Some of these resources are available for certain courses only, but we are expanding our provision all the time and you should check the VLE regularly for updates. Making use of the Online Library The Online Library contains a huge array of journal articles and other resources to help you read widely and extensively. To access the majority of resources via the Online Library you will either need to use your University of London Student Portal login details, or you will be required to register and use an Athens login: http://tinyurl.com/ollathens The easiest way to locate relevant content and journal articles in the Online Library is to use the Summon search engine. If you are having trouble finding an article listed in a reading list, try removing any punctuation from the title, such as single quotation marks, question marks and colons. For further advice, please see the online help pages: www.external.shl.lon.ac.uk/summon/about.php Unless otherwise stated, all websites in this subject guide were accessed in 2008. We cannot guarantee, however, that they will stay current and you may need to perform an internet search to find the relevant pages. The structure of the subject guide Part I of the subject guide focuses on financial systems, Part II addresses the key principles of banking and Part III investigates the principles of finance. The content of the subject guide is as follows. Part I: Financial systems • Chapter 2 serves as grounding to financial systems by investigating the functions and structure of financial systems. It thus focuses on each of the three main entities that compose financial systems (financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets). • Chapter 3 presents a discussion of the features of bank-based systems against market-based systems in different countries around the world. 7 24 Principles of banking and finance Part II: Principles of banking • Chapter 4 focuses specifically on the nature and process of financial intermediation by presenting a discussion of the key theories of financial intermediation (transformation of assets, uncertainty, reduction in transaction costs, reduction of problems arising out of asymmetric information). • Chapter 5 provides an investigation of the theoretical and practical aspects of regulation of banks, such as arguments for or against regulation, traditional regulation mechanisms and alternatives to traditional regulation. • Chapter 6 presents discussion of the key risks in banking (credit risk, interest rate risk, market risk and liquidity risk) and the main methods of risk management in banks (such as screening, monitoring, duration gap analysis, value-at-risk). Part III: Principles of finance • Chapter 7 outlines the concept and techniques of capital budgeting and securities valuation. It focuses first on the valuation of real investment projects using the Net Present Value (NPV), and provides a comparison of NPV with alternative techniques. Then it moves to the models used for the valuation of bonds and stocks. • Chapter 8 discusses the basics of risk and return of securities and mean-variance portfolio theory. It goes on to derive and discuss the equilibrium asset pricing models (Capital Asset Pricing Model and Arbitrage Pricing Model). • Chapter 9 focuses on the efficiency of financial markets by providing a theoretical derivation of the concepts of weak, semi-strong, and strong efficiency. It then moves to the discussion of the empirical evidence in favour of and against market efficiency. How to use this subject guide This subject guide is written for students studying 24 Principles of banking and finance. The aim is to help you to interpret the syllabus. It tells you what you are expected to know for each area of the syllabus and suggests the reading which will help you understand the material. It must be emphasised that this guide is intended to supplement the essential textbooks, not replace them. A different chapter is devoted to each major section of the syllabus and the chapter order of this guide follows the order of the topics as they appear in the syllabus. You need to appreciate that different topics are not self-contained. There is a degree of overlap between the topics and you are guided in this through cross-referencing between different chapters in the guide. However, in terms of studying this guide, the chapters are designed as self-contained units of study, but for examination purposes you need to have an understanding of the subject as a whole. We suggest that for each topic in the syllabus, you first read through the whole of the chapter in this guide to get an overview of the material to be covered. Then reread the chapter and follow up the suggestions for reading in the essential reading or further reading. After this you should work through the activities. 8 Chapter 1: Introduction Structure of each chapter At the beginning of each chapter, you will find a list of aims and learning outcomes. These tell you what you can expect to learn from that chapter of the subject guide and the relevant reading. You need to pay close attention to the learning outcomes and use them to check that you have fully understood the topics. You will then find the essential reading, further reading, and references. The list of essential reading indicates what you need to read as a minimum in order to cover the syllabus. Once you have read a chapter, check that you have covered all the essential reading. Each chapter contains ‘Activities’ which apply what you have just learnt in a practical way. Activities are heterogeneous: they include the analysis of institutional website material, numerical exercises and further readings on the texts. It is very important that you do these activities. For numerical activities (marked with an asterisk*) we provide answers in Appendix 1 at the end of the guide. Throughout the guide, there are a lot of key terms, all detailed in the ‘Key terms’ section at the end of each chapter. Compile your own glossary with full definitions and comments on each of these terms, and use it for revision. At the end of each chapter, look out for sample examination questions, similar to those asked in the final examination. We recommend that you try these sample examination questions during your revision. Examination Important: the information and advice given in the following section are based on the examination structure used at the time the guide was written. Please note that subject guides may be used for several years. Because of this we strongly advise you always to check both the current Regulations for relevant information about the examination, and the VLE where you should be advised of any forthcoming changes. You should also carefully check the rubric/instructions on the paper you actually sit and follow those instructions. Remember, it is important to check the VLE for: • up-to-date information on examination and assessment arrangements for this course • where available, past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries for the course which give advice on how each question might best be answered. The Principles of banking and finance examination paper is three hours in duration. You will be asked to answer four questions from a choice of eight. The examination paper is in two sections. You will be required to answer one question from Section A, one from Section B and two further questions from either section. The Examiners ensure that all the topics covered in the syllabus are examined. Section A of the exam essentially tests your understanding of concepts and theories from the syllabus. The questions in Section A are therefore discursive and generally split into two or three parts. In answering Section A questions Examiners will be looking for evidence of your understanding of the concept or theory being asked about. The subject guide sets out the essential points of theories/concepts that you can draw upon in 9 24 Principles of banking and finance answering the question. The essential reading and further reading texts go into further detail on these concepts and theories and you will generally be expected to go deeper into the subject matter than that set out in the subject guide if you want to get a very good mark. Please also note that evidence of understanding of a theory or concept may sometimes be demonstrated by the use of a relevant example. Examiners will also reward answers that show an up-to-date knowledge of a topic. For example, the regulation of banking is fast changing and the material in the subject guide may not be fully up-to-date when you read it. Keeping up-to-date with developments in relation to the topic areas of the syllabus will provide you with an opportunity to demonstrate to Examiners your understanding of the topic area. Section B of the exam essentially tests your understanding of the application of finance concepts and tools. As in Section A the questions in Section B are split into a number of parts with some parts requiring you to calculate something and other parts testing your understanding of the techniques being applied or your understanding of the answers you have calculated. Therefore to answer a Section B question fully requires you to understand how to apply techniques to the data given in the question in an appropriate way, to understand the assumptions and limitations of the technique you are using and to be able to interpret your calculated answer. Examples of section A type questions are provided at the end of Chapters 2, 3, 4, 5 and 9. Examples of section B type questions are provided at the end of Chapters 6, 7 and 8 and 9. You have to answer four questions, giving you 45 minutes to spend on each question. You should attempt all parts or aspects of a question. Pay attention to the breakdown of marks associated with the different parts of each question. Some questions may contain both numerical and essaybased parts. Examples of these types of questions (or question parts) are provided at the end of each chapter of this subject guide. • For essay-based questions, remember to plan your answer: list the main issue you want to discuss and the order of the discussion. • Begin the essay-based question with an introduction stating the aims of the essay, and conclude with a summary bringing together the main issues investigated in the essay. • Please use material only when relevant to the question. Answers including a large amount of irrelevant material are likely to be marked down. • Answers that simply repeat the subject guide material in a relevant way may be given a pass at best. • Answers with a clear structure, a good understanding of the material and originality in the approach are likely to achieve a good mark. A Sample examination paper is provided in Appendix 2 to this guide. 10 Chapter 1: Introduction Syllabus Part I: Financial systems 1. Introduction to financial systems: Role of financial systems (role of households, government and firms in terms of savings and investments). Financial intermediaries, securities and markets. Taxonomy of financial institutions. Nature of financial claims (debt versus equity, bonds and notes, fixed and floating interest rates, common and preferred stocks). Structure of financial markets (direct and indirect finance, dealers and brokers, banks, mutual funds, pension funds and insurance companies). 2. Comparative financial systems: Bank-based systems against marketbased systems. Legal aspects. Part II: Financial intermediaries 3. Role of financial intermediation: Nature and process of financial intermediation. Theories of financial intermediation (transformation of assets, uncertainty, reduction in transaction costs, reduction of problems arising out of symmetric information). Implications of financial intermediation (Hirshleifer model, effect on economic development). 4. Regulation of banks: Regulation of banks (free banking, arguments for and against regulation, traditional regulation mechanisms, alternatives to traditional regulation). 5. Risk management in banking: Market risks: liquidity risk, interest rate risk, foreign exchange risk. Credit risk: screening and monitoring, credit rationing, collateral. Part III: Principles of finance 6. Financial securities: Risk and return; Portfolio analysis: mean-variance portfolio theory. The portfolio selection process: the correlation of securities returns (single-index model and multi-index models). Asset pricing models: capital asset pricing models (CAPM) and arbitrage pricing theory (APT). 7. Capital budgeting: Pricing of bonds and stocks. Net pricing value. Project appraisal. 8. Financial markets: Transmission of information; Efficient markets. Theory and empirical evidence. Concepts of weak, semi-strong and strong efficiency. Concepts of excess return. Micro-structures. 11 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 12 Part I: Financial systems Part I: Financial systems Overview Before we introduce you to the Principles of banking (Part II) and to the Principles of finance (Part III), we begin our analysis by examining financial systems. Two main areas of interest are investigated: • What role does a financial system play in an economy? What is the structure of a financial system? (Chapter 2) • How does the structure of financial systems differ across countries worldwide? (Chapter 3) We answer these questions in Part I. 13 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 14 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems Aims The aim of this chapter is to investigate financial systems from both a functional and a structural perspective. We set out a taxonomy of financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets, and give an overview of the peculiarities of national financial systems. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you will be able to: • explain why financial systems exist (i.e. explain the functions of financial systems) • outline the structure of financial systems (i.e. describe the three main entities that compose financial systems: financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets) • describe which financial intermediaries operate in financial systems in the USA in particular and, more generally, around the world (e.g. depository institutions, contractual savings institutions and investment intermediaries) and explain their characteristics • explain which financial securities are traded on financial markets (bonds, notes, bills and stocks), and explain their nature • discuss the various theories that attempt to explain the shape of the yield curve • explain the structure of financial markets in the USA and around the world (primary versus secondary markets, money versus capital markets, organised versus over-the-counter markets, quote-driven dealer markets versus order-driven markets and brokered markets). Essential reading Allen, F. and D. Gale Comparing Financial Systems. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2001) Chapter 3. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapters 1, 2 and 10. Further reading Brealey, R.A., S.C. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2010) Chapter 14. Buckle, M. and J. Thompson The UK Financial System. (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2004) Chapter 1. Freixas, X. and J.C. Rochet Microeconomics of Banking. (Boston, Mass.: The MIT Press, 2008) Chapter 2. Saunders, A. and M.M. Cornett Financial Institutions Management: a Risk Management Approach. (New York, McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2007) Chapters 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6. 15 24 Principles of banking and finance Introduction We start the unit with an overview of financial systems, their functions and general structure. Then we investigate the nature and characteristics of the three major entities that compose financial systems. These are financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets. We will return to a more detailed investigation of each of these entities in later chapters. In our review of different countries, we restrict ourselves to large economies with well-developed financial systems, notably the USA, UK, France and Germany. Specifically, we take a US view and US terminology, therefore in Part I other countries are compared with the US system. Functions of financial systems Financial systems perform the essential economic function of channelling funds from units who have saved surplus funds to units who have a shortage of funds. The units who have saved can lend funds: they are known as lender-savers. The units with a shortage of funds must borrow funds to finance their spending: they are the borrower-spenders. The most important lender-savers are usually households; while the typical borrower-spenders are firms and the government. The channelling of funds from savers to spenders is very important for two reasons: • First, lender-savers (with excess of available funds) do not frequently have profitable investment opportunities, while borrower-spenders have investment opportunities but lack of funds. • Second, even for purposes other than investment opportunities in businesses, borrower-spenders may want to invest in excess of their current income or to adjust the composition of their wealth (reconciliation of the preferences for current versus future consumption). In direct finance, borrower-spenders borrow funds directly from lenders in the financial markets by selling them securities. In indirect finance, a financial intermediary stands between the lender-savers and the borrower-spenders: the intermediary helps to transfer funds from one to the other. This suggests that financial markets and intermediaries are alternatives that perform more or less the same function but in different ways (and perhaps with different degrees of success). Note, however, that the process of indirect finance, known as financial intermediation, is the most important way of transferring funds from lenders to borrowers. This contrasts with the attitude of the media to focus mainly on financial markets (as discussed in Chapter 4). Another important function of a financial system is the monetary function. The introduction of money into the economy enables savers and spenders to separate the act of sale from the act of purchase and allows them to overcome the main problem of barter, which is the ‘double coincidence of wants’ (each of the two parties involved in a transaction has to want simultaneously the good the other party is offering to exchange). The financial system provides a variety of payment mechanisms e.g. cheques, debit cards and credit cards to enable one party to pay another. Financial systems also provide mechanisms for risk to be transferred. For example insurance contracts allow a party such as a firm or household to transfer the risk of loss of wealth due to theft or fire to another party such as an insurance company. The firm or household will pay a fee (insurance premium) for this transfer. The insurance company, by providing a large 16 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems number of insurance contracts, is better able to manage the risk than an individual firm or household as they can obtain benefits of pooling and diversification. Thus a more efficient allocation of risk results. In short, the main functions of financial systems are to: • provide the mechanisms by which funds can be transferred from units in surplus to units with a shortage of funds in order to directly or indirectly facilitate lending and borrowing (as shown in Figure 2.1) • enable wealth holders to adjust the composition of their portfolios • provide payment mechanisms • provide mechanisms for risk transfer Activity 2.1 Throughout this guide, there are a lot of key terms, all collected in the ‘Key terms’ section at the end of each chapter. Compile your own glossary with full definitions and comments on each of these terms, and use it for revision. DIRECT Financial markets Securities Lenders Cash Cash Deposits Financial intermediaries INDIRECT Borrowers Cash Loans Figure 2.1: Direct and indirect lending performed by a financial system The structure of financial systems: financial markets, securities and financial intermediaries From a structural point of view a financial system can be seen in terms of the entities that compose the system. A financial system comprises financial markets, securities and financial intermediaries. Financial markets are markets in which funds are moved from people who have an excess of available funds (and lack of investment opportunities) to people who have investment opportunities (and lack of funds). They also have direct effects on personal wealth, and the behaviours of businesses and consumers. Therefore, they contribute to increase the production and the efficiency in the overall economy. Financial markets (such as bond and stock markets) are markets in which securities are traded. Securities (also called financial instruments) are financial claims on the issuer’s future income or assets. They represent financial liabilities for the individual or firm that sells them (borrower or issuer of the financial claim) in return for money, and financial assets for the buyer (lender or investor in the financial claim). By definition, therefore, the sum of financial assets in existence will exactly equal the sum of liabilities. 17 24 Principles of banking and finance Governments and corporations raise funds to finance their activities by issuing debt instruments (bonds) and equity instruments (shares, known in the USA as stocks). Bonds are securities that promise to make periodic payments of a sum of money for a specified period of time. Stocks are securities that represent a share of ownership in the firm. Financial intermediaries are economic agents who specialise in the activities of buying and selling (at the same time) financial contracts (loans and deposits) and securities (bonds and stocks). Note that financial securities are easily marketable, while financial contracts cannot be easily sold (marketed). Banks form the largest financial institution in our economy. They accept deposits (loans by individuals or firms to banks) and make loans (sums of money lent by banks to individuals or firms): therefore, they borrow deposits from people who have saved and in turn make loans to others. In recent years, other financial intermediaries, such as mutual funds, pension funds, insurance companies and investment banks, have been growing at the expense of banks. Taxonomy of financial intermediaries We begin by looking at the USA, the largest economy and financial system in the world. Later we will turn to other countries. In the USA the three major groups of financial intermediaries are: depository institutions, contractual savings institutions and investment intermediaries (for an overview of financial intermediaries around the world refer to the next section). Depository institutions Depository institutions: intermediaries with a significant proportion of their funds derived from customer deposits – include: commercial banks – savings institutions and credit unions. Commercial banks Commercial banks accept deposits (liabilities) to make loans (assets) and to buy government securities. Deposits are broad in range, including checkable deposits (deposits on which cheques can be written), savings deposits (deposits that are payable on demand, but do not allow depositors to write cheques), time deposits (deposits with a fixed term to maturity). Loans include consumer, commercial and mortgage loans. In the USA, commercial banks are the largest group of financial intermediary: in 2006 there were 7,402 with aggregate total assets of $10.1 trillion (according to the FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile). Note that the industry has experienced a recent consolidation as a result of mergers and acquisitions (simply consider that in 1984 there were 14,416 commercial banks). The performance of US banks improved throughout most of the 1990s, although it deteriorated slightly with the economic downturn in the early years of the twenty-first century. In 2006 the return on equity (ROE) of the US banking industry averaged 9.9 per cent. Activity 2.2 Consult the American Banker Online available (2-week trial subscription) at www.americanbanker.com/tools/ranking-the-banks.html. From the section on Banks, thrifts and holding companies locate the Top World Banking Companies by Assets and identify the 10 largest US depository institutions and compare their total assets value. Identify the largest depository institution in your own country. 18 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems The balance sheet structure of US commercial banks reflects the main assets and liabilities of their business. The aggregated balance sheet values for US banks in 2006 are reported in Table 2.1. As shown, loans constituted around 58 per cent of their assets (compared with 62 per cent in 1990), whereas investments in securities represented 16 per cent of their assets. Interest-bearing deposits instead constituted 54 per cent of their liabilities. Total assets 10,090,626 Total liabilities and capital Total loans & leases Less: Reserve for losses 10,090,626 5,980,915 Non-interest bearing deposits 1,216,695 69,071 Interest bearing deposits 5,514,667 Net loans and leases 5,911,844 Other borrowed funds Securities 1,665,743 Subordinated debt 149,795 4,721 All other liabilities 467,645 Other real estate owned Good will and other intangibles All other assets 1,711,411 358,472 Equity capital 2,149,832 Off-balance-sheet derivatives 1,030,413 132,162,947 Table 2.1: Aggregate balance sheet values for US commercial banks ($million, 2006) Source: Table created using data from FDIC website (www2.fdic.gov/hsob/) Savings and loan associations Historically savings and loan associations (S&Ls) and thrift institutions have concentrated mostly on residential mortgages by acquiring funds primarily through savings deposits. In terms of number of institutions, they are the second largest group of financial intermediaries (1,279 associations with $1.8 trillion of total assets in 2006 according to FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile). In the 1950s and 1960s, S&Ls grew much more rapidly than commercial banks. However, between 1979 and 1982 the change in the monetary policy of the Fed led to a dramatic surge in interest rates. (The Federal Reserve Bank, known as The Fed, is the central bank for the US banking system, as explained later in Chapters 3 and 5). This increase in the shortterm rates had two effects. • First, S&Ls had negative interest spreads (interest income minus interest expense) in funding the fixed-rate long-term residential mortgages. • Second, they had to pay more competitive interest rates on savings deposits. Note that The Federal Reserve Bank’s Regulation Q ceilings limited the interest rates payable on deposits by S&Ls. To overcome the effects of rising rates and disintermediation, in the early 1980s the Congress passed acts allowing S&Ls to expand their deposittaking (i.e. to offer checking accounts) and asset-investment powers (i.e. to make consumer and commercial loans). For many S&Ls the new powers created safer and more diversified institutions. However, for a small – but significant – group of S&Ls, they created an opportunity to take more risk in the attempt to improve profitability. For example, in Texas in the mid-1980s there had been a real estate and land prices crash, which led to the default of many borrowers with mortgage loans issued by S&Ls. As a result a large number of S&Ls failed at the end of the 1980s and as a consequence, new legislation – the FIRREA of 1989 – was adopted. 19 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 2.3 Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), section beginning on p.491, to investigate the recent reform of S&L. Then consult the section on Savings institutions in FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile available online at: http://www2.fdic.gov/qbp/2010sep/sav1.html. Draw a graph to show the trend in the number of institutions. Write a short explanation of why this variation has occurred. The evolution in the number and size (in terms of total assets) of both commercial banks and S&Ls is shown in Figures 2.2 and 2.3. 12.000.000 Total assets ('000 US$) 10.000.000 8.000.000 6.000.000 4.000.000 2.000.000 0 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 Commercial banks 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 S&L Figure 2.2: Trend in the size of US depository institutions 12.000 10.000 Number 8.000 6.000 4.000 2.000 0 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 Commercial banks 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 S&L Figure 2.3: Trend in the number of US depository institutions Source: Tables created using data from www2.fdic.gov/qbp/qbpSelect. asp?menuItem=STBL Credit unions Credit unions are non-profit institutions mutually organised and owned by their members (depositors). Their primary objective is to satisfy the depository and lending needs of their members, who have to belong to a particular group (identified by occupation, association, geographical location). The members’ deposits are used to provide loans to other members, and earnings from these loans are used to pay a higher rate of interest to member depositors. They are the most numerous among the institutions composing depository institutions, totalling about 8,535 in 2006 according to the Credit Union National Association. 20 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems Contractual savings institutions Contractual savings institutions acquire funds at periodic intervals on a contractual basis. The industry is classified into two major groups: insurance companies and pension funds. The liquidity of their assets is less important than for depository institutions because they can predict with reasonable accuracy the future payments due to their customers. As a consequence they invest their funds in long-term securities (such as corporate bonds, stocks and mortgages). Insurance companies The primary objective of insurance companies is to protect individuals and firms (known as policy-holders) from adverse events. Insurance companies receive premiums from policy-holders, and promise to pay compensation to policy-holders if particular events occur. There are two main segments in the industry: life insurance on the one hand, and property and causality insurance on the other. Life insurance protects against death, illness and retirement. Companies acquire premiums from the policy-holders, and use them mainly to buy corporate bonds, mortgages, and stocks (amount limited by legislation). In 2006 in the US, life insurance companies were the largest group among the contractual savings institutions with aggregate assets of $4.71 trillion as reported by the Insurance Information Institute. Note that traditional life insurance is no longer the primary business of many companies in the life/health insurance industry. Today, the emphasis has shifted to the underwriting of annuities. Annuities are contracts that accumulate funds and/or pay out a fixed or variable income stream, which can be for a fixed period of time or over the lifetimes of the contract holder and his or her beneficiaries. Property and causality insurance provides protection against personal injury and liabilities such as accidents, theft and fire. In comparison to life insurance companies, they hold more liquid assets because of a higher probability of loss of funds in case of major disasters. In the USA this segment is quite concentrated: the top 10 firms have a 51 per cent share of the market. Pension funds Pension funds provide retirement income (in the form of annuities) to employees covered by a pension plan. They receive contributions from employers or employees and invest these amounts in corporate bonds and stocks. There are private pension funds and public pension funds. The US government has promoted the establishment of pension funds, and the expectation is of further developments in pension funds in terms of number and variety of options. In some countries pensions funds are very important (e.g. USA and UK) whereas elsewhere they are not (e.g. France, Germany and Italy), because of the different importance of State pension schemes. Activity 2.4 What types of pensions are there? Visit the Financial Services Authority website (available at www.moneymadeclear.fsa.gov.uk/products/pensions/pensions.html) to find out more about the UK system. Do you now understand how a pension fund operates? Look in Mishkin and Eakins (2009), pp.561–62 to make sure. After reading Mishkin and Eakins (2009) do you think pension funds are financial intermediaries, i.e. do they channel funds from saver-lenders to spender-borrowers? 21 24 Principles of banking and finance Investment intermediaries Investment intermediaries comprise mutual funds, finance companies, investment banks and securities firms. Mutual funds Mutual funds pool resources from many individuals and companies and invest these resources in diversified portfolios of bonds, stocks and money market instruments. An open-ended mutual fund (the major type of mutual fund) continuously allows shareholders to sell (redeem) outstanding shares, and investors to buy new shares at any time. The value of these shares is determined by the value of the mutual fund’s holding assets. Two main advantages characterise mutual funds. First, mutual funds provide opportunities to small investors to invest in financial securities and diversify risk. Second, mutual funds take advantage of lower transaction costs when they buy larger blocks of financial securities. There are two segments in the mutual fund industry: long-term funds and short-term funds. Long-term funds comprise bond funds (funds that contain fixed-income debt securities), equity funds (funds that contain stock securities) and hybrid funds (funds that contain both debt and stock securities). Short-term funds are represented by money market mutual funds, funds that contain various mixes of money market securities and partially allow shareholders to write cheques against the value of their holdings: the presence of deposit-type accounts makes money market mutual funds to some extent similar to depository institutions. In the USA mutual funds are the second most important financial intermediary in terms of asset size. In fact, they are larger than the insurance industry, but smaller than the commercial bank industry. The combined assets of the nation’s mutual funds increased to $9.5 trillion in 2006, according to the Investment Company Institute’s official survey of the mutual fund industry. Activity 2.5 From the 2007 Investment Company Fact Book produced by the Investment Company Institute (available online at www.icifactbook.org/pdf/2010_factbook.pdf) read the summary on the significant events in the mutual fund industry (pp.210–12). Then write a short explanation of how you think these events have determined the historical trend of the industry as described in Table 1 ‘US Mutual Fund Industry Total Net Assets, Number of Funds, Number of Share Classes, and Number of Shareholder Accounts, (2010 Investment Company Fact Book, p.124). Total intermediated funds: US$ 25.17 trillions Insurance companies Commercial banks Mutual funds S&Ls Values in trillions of US dollars Figure 2.4: Intermediated funds by type of financial intermediary Source: Table created using data from FDIC website (http://www2.fdic.gov/hsob/) 22 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems Summing up, as shown in Figure 2.4, the total funds intermediated by US financial intermediaries are US$25.17 trillion in 2006. Commercial banks account for the highest proportion, followed by mutual funds, insurance companies and S&Ls. Finance companies Finance companies make loans to individuals and corporations by providing consumer lending, business lending and mortgage financing. Some of their loans are similar to those provided by commercial banks. However, finance companies differ from commercial banks because they do not accept deposits. They raise funds by selling commercial paper (a short-term debt instrument) and by issuing stocks and bonds. Moreover, finance companies often lend to customers perceived as too risky by commercial banks. There are three major types of finance companies: • Sales finance institutions that make loans to customers of a particular retailer or manufacturer (e.g. Ford Motor Credit). • Personal credit institutions that make loans to consumers perceived as too risky by commercial banks (e.g. Household Finance Corp). • Business credit institutions that provide financing to companies, especially through equipment leasing and factoring (purchase by the finance company of accounts receivable from corporate customers). Investment banks and securities firms Investment banks assist corporations or governments in the issue of new debt or equity securities. Investment banking includes: • the origination, underwriting and placement of securities in primary financial markets (primary and secondary markets are discussed later in this chapter). The process of underwriting a stock or bond issue requires the investment bank to purchase the entire issue at a predetermined price and then to resell it in the market. The investment bank then bears the risk that they are not able to resell the entire issue in which case it will hold the unsold stock on its own balance sheet. In return for taking on this risk the investment company receives an underwriting fee from the issuing company. • financial advisory on corporate finance activities (such as advising on mergers and acquisitions). Typically, investment banks earn their income from fees charged to clients. These fees are usually set as a fixed percentage of the size of the deal being worked. Securities firms assist in the trading of existing securities in the secondary markets. There are two main categories of securities firms: • brokers - agents of investors who match buyers with sellers of securities. They earn a commission for their service; • dealers - agents who link buyers and sellers by buying and selling securities. They hold inventories of securities, and sell these securities for a slightly higher price than they paid for them. They thus earn the bid-ask spread, the difference between the best ask (lowest price charged for immediate purchase of stock) and the best bid (highest price received for an immediate sale of a unit of stock). The main service offered by brokers is securities orders. Orders are trade instructions specifying what traders want to trade, whether to buy or sell, 23 24 Principles of banking and finance how much, when and how to trade, and on what terms. Traders issue orders when they cannot personally negotiate their trades. There are two primary types of orders: market orders and limit orders. Market orders are instructions to trade at the best price currently available in the market. Market order traders pay the bid-ask spread (they demand immediacy). It follows that there is price uncertainty. Large market orders can have substantial and unpredictable price impacts. Limit orders instead are instructions to trade at the best price available, but only if it is no worse that the limit price specified by the trader. For example, you submit a limit order to buy 100 shares of BP at (at most) 515p per share. The order will be executed if there is a seller willing to give you his shares for 515p or less. In such a case, there is no price uncertainty but there is execution uncertainty. Note that standing limit orders (i.e limit orders that are not immediately executed) provide the market with liquidity as they sit in the order book allowing traders who submit a market order to obtain immediate execution. In the USA, the securities firms and investment banking industry includes several types of firms: • National full-line firms acting both as broker-dealers and underwriters. The major US firms are Merrill Lynch and Morgan Stanley. • National full-line firms that specialise more in corporate finance and are highly active in trading securities; examples are Goldman Sachs and Smith Barney. • Specialised investment bank subsidiaries of commercial banks, such as J.P. Morgan Chase • Specialised discount brokers, stockbrokers that conduct trading activities for customers without offering any investment advice (such as Charles Schwab). • Specialised electronic trading securities firms (such as E*trade) enabling trades on a computer via the internet. • Regional securities firms concentrating in the service of customers of a particular geographical region. Retail and wholesale banks Commercial banking can also be separated into retail and wholesale banking. The difference between retail and wholesale banking is essentially one of size. Retail banks have traditionally provided intermediation and payment services to individuals and small businesses dealing with a large number of small value transactions. This is in contrast with the wholesale banks, which deal with a smaller number of larger value transactions. In practice it is difficult to identify purely retail banks. In the UK, USA and many other developed countries, large banks combine retail and wholesale activities. Wholesale banks consist mainly of investment banks. Financial intermediaries around the world In the United Kingdom the banking system comprises commercial banks, investment banks and building societies. Four big clearing banks currently dominate commercial banking: Barclays, Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS), HSBC, and Lloyds. They are essentially universal banks as they provide a wide range of services to individuals and corporations (from life insurance to underwriting). As London is an international financial centre, the role of foreign commercial banks is extremely important there: 24 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems they are roughly the same size as UK domestic banks. Investment banks are involved in traditional investment banking activities, like in the USA. Building societies, likeS&L’s in the USA, were originally devoted to providing mortgages. Deregulation has allowed them to expand their activities into traditional banking; as a result, they are now competitors of the big four. Among contractual savings institutions there are pension funds and insurance companies. They both constitute a large proportion of household assets, significantly larger than in other countries. Insurance services are provided by bank subsidiaries as well as insurance companies. The insurance industry, unlike banking, is not dominated by a few large players. The banking sector in Japan comprises shareholder-owned banks (ordinary banks, trust banks, and long-term credit banks) and cooperative banks (credit unions and credit association). Ordinary banks, the counterpart of commercial banks in other countries, provide mainly shortterm loans to individuals and corporations. Trust banks provide longterm loans to corporations, in addition to a range of services (ordinary banking services, asset management, investment advisory services). Long-term credit banks provide long- and medium-term loans (mainly to large corporations) by using the funds raised from medium- and shortterm bonds. Cooperative banks provide banking services to small corporations and are owned by their members. Among contractual savings institutions, life insurance companies are significantly more important in Japan than in other countries. These companies – that are mostly mutual – provide traditional life insurance products, make long-term loans to corporations and manage corporate pension funds. Property and causality insurance companies are also important, but not as important as life insurance companies. Pension funds in Japan are significantly more important than in France and Germany, but less than in the USA and UK. In France there are commercial banks, mutual and cooperative banks and savings banks. Commercial banks are the most important industry in the banking system, but mutual and cooperative banks are also significant. There are several types of mutual and cooperative banks with different specific purposes: Crédit Mutuel (to provide loans to individuals with modest income); Crédit Coopérative (to provide loans to their members, while receiving deposits from everybody); Crédit Agricole Mutuel (to provide loans to farmers); Crédit Populaire (to provide loans to the trade sector and medium-size industries). Savings banks can make loans only to non-industrial or non-commercial entities or individuals. Their unique feature is to offer accounts whose interest is tax-free up to a given amount. French contractual savings institutions are mostly insurance companies (similar to those in the Japanese financial system), whereas pension funds are rare. Insurance services can be provided by commercial banks as well as insurance companies. Commercial banks, savings banks and cooperative banks constitute the banking system in Germany. Commercial banks are universal banks that provide a full range of products and services: deposits, short- and long-term loans, life insurance, underwriting and even investing directly in equity securities. The big three commercial banks are: Deutsche, Dresdner and Commerzbank. Savings banks are non-profit maximising entities but are operated in the public interest. Cooperative banks are mutual organisations owned by their depositors. An interesting feature of the German banking system is that the majority of organisations (in terms of assets) are not profit-maximising entities. As in France, very few household assets are held by pension funds, whereas insurance companies 25 24 Principles of banking and finance hold a large proportion of assets. Insurance services are provided by universal banks as well as insurance companies and are usually organised by groups (because of the legal requirement to separate life insurance from other forms of insurance). USA Commercial banks S&L Credit Unions UK Commercial banks Building societies Japan Ordinary banks Co-operative banks (Credit Unions and Associations) France Commercial banks Mutual and Co-operative banks Savings banks Germany Commercial banks Co-operative banks Savings banks Institutions not found in USA Trust banks Long-term credit banks Your country Table 2.2: Equivalent names of depositary institutions Table 2.2 shows the different names used for the US institutions we looked at above. Add your country to the table in the last row. (Refer to Chapter 3 ‘Comparative financial systems’ to analyse the historical developments of national financial systems and to understand the reasons for the existence of bank-based and market-based financial systems across countries). Activity 2.6 In the following table, list the names of some major financial institutions and briefly note down the special features of the financial system in each country. Country Examples of important financial institutions Special features of their system USA UK Japan France Germany Nature of financial instruments (securities) Financial instruments (known as securities) can be classified into two broad groups: debt instruments and equity instruments. Note that there are also derivative instruments (such as futures, options and swaps), which are financial instruments that derive their value from the value of some other financial instruments or variables. (Although they are not analysed here, they will be developed in later subjects in the programme, such as 92 Corporate finance.) Remind yourself what a security is (see the Essential reading and see also p.17 earlier in this chapter). Debt and equity instruments Debt instruments are instruments that promise the payment of given sums to the investor. Examples of debt instruments are bills, notes and bonds (described below). Bonds represent debt owed by the issuer to the investor. They are claims that normally pay periodic interest (coupon payments) until the maturity date, and pay back the par value (face value) 26 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems to the investor at the maturity date. The coupon payments are usually based on a fixed interest rate. The interest rate is the cost of borrowing or the price paid for the rental of funds (usually expressed as a percentage). Equity represents claims to shares in the net income and assets of a firm, and they do not have a maturity date. In terms of economic rights, equity claims differ from debt instruments for several reasons. • First, firms are not contractually obliged to make periodic payments to equity holders: the payment of dividends is a discretionary decision of the firm. • Second, firms must pay all their debt holders before they make any payment to equity holders: therefore equity holders are residual claimants. As a result, equity claims are riskier than debt instruments. In addition to economic rights, equity claims confer ownership rights to equity holders. The presence of ownership rights is in contrast with bondholders, who have no ownership interest but are rather creditors of the firm. Ownership rights have two main implications. • First, equity holders can benefit from any increase in the income or asset value of the company. In the case of stock price increases (decreases) on the financial market, equity holders can obtain high capital gains (losses), whereas this is very unlikely by investing in bonds. • Second, equity holders have the right to vote for directors or on certain issues. The proportion of economic and ownership rights is different between common stocks and preferred stocks (as discussed below). Activity 2.7 If you expect a company to become bankrupt in a year’s time, would you rather hold bonds or equities issued by the company? Or nothing? Zero coupon bonds, coupon bonds and other types of bonds Debt instruments can be classified into two main categories: zero coupon bonds and coupon bonds. Zero coupon bonds are instruments under which a borrower promises, at the current time, to pay one specified nominal sum (face value) to the lender at one specified future date. In return, at the current date the borrower receives the bond price. Zeros are also known as discount bonds. Clearly, with positive interest rates, the price of a zero coupon bond must be lower than the face value. Let me give an example of a zero coupon bond: an 8-year zero issued today and with face value of $1,000 would require the borrower to repay this amount to the lender after this period of time. At the current date, the borrower receives an amount of cash which must be less than $1,000 given the positive time value of money. Coupon bonds are contractual agreements by the borrowers to make regular payments (known as coupons or interest) until a specified date (the maturity date), when the amount borrowed (principal) is repaid. The maturity is the time to the expiration date of the debt instrument. Coupon bonds deliver two different types of cash flow to the bondholder: • Face value: at the end of the bond’s lifetime, the issuer repays the face value of the bond to the holder. Face value is also known as par value or principal. 27 24 Principles of banking and finance • Coupon payments: regular (often semi-annual) payments of cash to the bondholder. These payments are generally a fixed fraction of the face value. The interest rate is the cost of borrowing or the price paid for the rental of funds (usually expressed as a percentage). Let me give an example of a coupon bond: assume that a company issues a three-year bond with a coupon rate of 5 per cent and face value of $1,000. The bondholder receives the following ($) cash flows (note the semiannual coupon payments which are each half the total annual coupon): Year 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 Cash flows ($) 25 25 25 25 25 1,025 Certain other popular bond types differ from standard coupon bonds along certain dimensions. These include: perpetual bonds, floating rate bonds and index-linked bonds. Perpetual bonds (also known as consols) never mature. They simply pay coupons of a specified amount forever. Floating rate bonds have coupon rates which vary over the bond’s lifetime. Generally, the floating coupon rate is set at a premium over some market interest rate (e.g LIBOR or the US T-bill rate) and is reset on a pre-specified basis. For index-linked bonds, coupons and principal grow in line with inflation (in the relevant country). First issued in the UK, they are now increasingly frequently issued by governments. As such, they can be thought of as real, risk-free securities (although in most cases indexation is not perfect). Certain bonds also have options embedded in them. These embedded options will provide the issuer or holder with extra rights over and above the usual. Examples include callable bonds, puttable bonds and convertible bonds. Callable bonds can be repaid early (i.e. before maturity) by the issuer if he/she so chooses. Early repayment might be restricted to a specified date (European) or may be allowed at any time prior to maturity (American). With puttable bonds the redemption date is under the control of the holder (i.e. the opposite to the callable bond case). Convertible bonds are debt instruments which can be converted into a share in the firm’s equity (either at a specific date or at any time). As such, this type of debt allows bondholders, as well as shareholders, to participate in upside gains of a corporation. On the basis of the country of sale in comparison to the issuer’s country of origin, there are two special types of bonds: foreign bonds and Eurobonds. A foreign bond is a bond issued by a borrower in a country different from that borrower’s country of origin (i.e. the borrower is selling debt abroad). The bond is denominated in the currency of the country in which it is sold. Hence, if a Russian firm sells Sterling denominated debt in the UK it has issued foreign bonds. Such Sterling denominated foreign bonds are colloquially known as bulldog bonds. Eurobonds are bonds denominated in the currency of one country but actually sold or traded in another, different country. So, for example, a Eurosterling bond will be denominated in Sterling but sold outside the UK. Coupons on these bonds are generally paid on an annual basis. Note that London is one of the major Eurobond markets. Activity 2.8 Identify whether the following bonds are foreign bonds or Eurobonds: 1. A US firm issues a dollar denominated bond in London. 2. A Japanese firm issues a dollar denominated bond in New York. 3. A UK company issues a dollar denominated bond in Singapore. 28 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems On the basis of the maturity, debt instruments can be divided into: shortterm (maturity less than one year), intermediate-term (maturity between one and ten years), and long-term (maturity of ten years or longer). Bonds are generally defined to have lifetimes exceeding one year. Debt securities with maturities less than a year are called money market securities. Bonds, notes and bills by issuer There are three main classes of institutions that issue bonds in the USA: national governments, local governments and corporations. (As we saw above, most US instruments and intermediaries have their parallels in other industrial countries). Government notes and bonds are issued in the USA by the US Treasury to finance national debt. Notes have an original maturity of one to ten years, while bonds have an original maturity of ten to twenty years. Government notes and bonds are normally seen to be free of default risk (risk that the issuer of the bond will default, that is, be unable to make interest payments and principal repayment, as discussed in Chapter 6). In fact, the issuer (the government) can always print money to pay off the debt if necessary. As a consequence, they pay lower interest rates than corporate bonds. Such bonds are known as gilts in the UK, Treasuries in the USA and Bunds in Germany. Note that among government debt instruments are Treasury bills. These are money market securities, with an original maturity of less than one year. They do not pay any interest, but they are issued at a discount from their par value and they are repaid at the par value at the maturity date. The difference between the issue value and the par value represents the yield to the investor. Municipal bonds are debt instruments issued by US local, county or state governments to finance public interest projects. Municipal bonds are not default-free and are not as liquid as Treasury bonds. In fact, such bonds are usually secured on their own revenues and not guaranteed by central government. However, they pay lower interest rates than Treasury bonds. The reason for this is that their interest payments are exempt from federal taxation, and thus this determines an implicit increase in the actual interest rates received by investors. Corporate bonds are issued by large corporations when they need long-term financing. They usually make interest payments twice a year (semi-annually). Clearly such debt is not risk-free and the level of risk will depend on the nature of the corporation’s activities (e.g. contrast utilities with biotech firms). The degree of risk, which depends on the default risk of the company, is higher than for government and municipal bonds. This determines the presence of higher interest rates. Moreover, this gives bondholders senior claims on corporate assets in the event of bankruptcy. Activity 2.9 Are each of the following statements true or false? 1. A bond only pays the holder a return if the company makes a profit. 2. Banks buy bonds and issue shares. They never buy shares or issue bonds. Default risk and bond rating A bond (generally) obliges a borrower to repay nominal cash flows at specified dates. However, circumstances may arise whereby the borrower is unable to meet the obligations. At such a time the borrower is said to be in default. After a default, the bondholder generally has a senior 29 24 Principles of banking and finance claim on the borrower’s assets. Obviously, the likelihood of a borrower defaulting will affect the terms on which individuals are willing to lend to a borrower: if I consider agent A to be more likely to default than agent B, I will charge agent A a higher rate of interest, a default risk premium. As discussed in Chapter 4, certain commercial organisations help characterise the default risk associated with bonds by providing credit ratings. The two main players in this market are Moody’s and Standard and Poor’s. They assign ratings to bonds such that highly rated bonds are projected to have low default risk while very low rated bonds (junk bonds) are believed to be quite likely to default. The term structure of interest rates The term to maturity influences the interest rate. Bonds with identical risk may have different yields (interest rates) because of the difference in the time remaining to maturity. A yield curve plots the yields (interest rates) of bonds with different maturity but the same risk. Usually the yield curve is constructed from government securities. These are often referred to as the benchmark yield curve, as they are the basis for evaluating other yields of similar maturity bonds. The yield curve can be: upward (the long-term rates are above the short-term rates); flat (short- and long-term interest rates are the same); and inverted (long-term interest rates are below short-term interest rates). There are a number of factors that influence the shape of the yield curve. (a) Expectations theory The expectations theory of the term structure of interest rates states that in equilibrium, the long-term rate is a geometric average of today’s shortterm rate and expected short-term rates in the future. This theory requires that there is an implicit relationship between current bond yields and forward rates. The forward rate of interest is the rate of interest that will be payable on funds beginning at some future date. For example, if: R represents the annual yield on a two-year bond, r1 represents the annual return from a one year bond, and r2 represents a one-year forward rate beginning in one year’s time then the following relationship will hold: (1 + R)2 = (1 + r1) x (1 + r2) With the expectations theory of the term structure, an investor who invests £1,000 in either a two-year bond, or a one-year bond subsequently reinvesting the proceeds from the first year into another one-year bond, will receive the same return from both strategies. According to the theory, the existence of arbitrageurs in bond markets ensures that this relationship holds. Suppose that the yield on a two-year government bond, R is 9% p.a. and the yield on an equivalent one year bond, r1 is 8% p.a. The yield implied on a one year bond held during year two of the two year bond’s life, r2, is given as: £1,000 x (1.09) x (1.09) = £1,188.10 = £1,000 x (1.08) x (1 + r2) r2 = 10.01% In this example, there is an upward sloping yield curve as the 1 year bond yield is lower than the two year yield. Usually we observe an upward 30 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems sloping yield curve, for example in 2008 the shape of the yield curve was the one shown in Figure 2.5. 4.48 4.19 3.50 Yield 3.21 2.52 2.24 1.55 1.26 0.57 0.28 0.00 3 Month 6 Month 2 Year 3 Year 5 Year 10 Year 30 Year Maturity Figure 2.5: US Treasury yield curve rates (8 February 2008) Source: Graph created using data from: http://bonds.yahoo.com/rates.html. In the yield curve example above, the current long rate (after three years) is higher than the current short rate, therefore short-term rates must be expected to rise in the future. Conversely, if the current long rate is lower than the current short rate then short-term rates are expected to decline in the future: in this instance, we will observe a downward sloping yield curve. Finally, if no change is expected in short rates, then the current long rate will equal the current short rate, and we will observe a flat yield curve. Hence, it should be clear that the shape of the yield curve will be determined by expectations of future interest rates. (b) Liquidity premium theory Liquidity premium theory asserts that, in a world of uncertainty, investors and lenders will want to hold assets which can be converted into cash quickly. Therefore they will demand a liquidity premium for holding longterm debt. Conversely, the same dislike for uncertainty causes borrowers (for example, firms and governments) to prefer to borrow for a longer period at a rate which is certain now – therefore they will be willing to pay a liquidity premium and, therefore, a higher rate of interest on their longer-term debt. This implies that the yield curve will normally be upward sloping, in the absence of any other influences. In reality, we need to consider the combined effect of expectations together with liquidity preference. A downward sloping yield curve will occur when expectations of an interest rate fall are sufficient to offset the liquidity premium. (c) Market segmentation As well as the investors’ expectations with respect to future interest rates and their preferences for liquidity, another theory, the market segmentation theory, suggests that the bond market is actually made up of a number of separate markets distinguished by time to maturity, each with their own supply and demand conditions. Different classes of investors and issuers will have a strong preference for certain segments of the yield curve and, therefore, the curve will not necessarily move up, or down, over its entire range. 31 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 2.10 Now read Mishkin and Eakins (2009) pp.107–109 and then try and answer the following questions: 1. According to the expectations theory, if the current short term rate is higher than the current long term rate, what is expected to happen to interest rates in the future? 2. Which of the three theories best explains why yield curves normally slope upwards? 3. Why can’t the market segmentation theory explain why yields on bonds of different maturities tend to move together? Activity 2.11 Consult http://bonds.yahoo.com/rates.html. This shows the interest rates paid on US Treasury bonds, municipal bonds and corporate bonds. Then try the following questions: 1. Why do 2-year Treasury bonds pay lower rates than 5-year Treasury bonds? 2. Why do 5-year municipal bonds pay lower rates than 5-year Treasury bonds? 3. Why do corporate bonds pay higher rates than government bonds? Common and preferred stocks Common stocks represent ownership interests in the firm. Common stockholders receive dividends (when distributed), take capital gains (or losses) when the stock price on the market increases (or decreases), and have the right to vote. Preferred stocks are equity claims with limited ownership rights in comparison to common stocks. They differ from common stocks in several ways. First, preferred stocks distribute a fixed constant dividend, which makes them more similar to bonds than to common stocks. Second, the price of preferred stocks is relatively stable, as the dividend is a constant amount. Third, preferred stocks do not usually carry voting rights. Finally, preferred stockholders have a residual claim on assets and income left over after creditors have been satisfied, but they have priority over common stockholders. Structure of financial markets Financial markets can be classified on the basis of several parameters: the nature of the financial securities traded (primary versus secondary markets), forms of organisation (organised exchanges versus over-thecounter markets), maturity of the financial instruments traded (capital markets versus money markets), and forms of trade intermediation (quotedriven dealer markets, order-driven markets and brokered markets). Primary and secondary markets A primary market is a financial market in which new issues of financial securities (both bonds and stocks) are sold to initial buyers. A secondary market is one in which securities that have been previously issued are resold. Primary markets facilitate new financing to corporations, but most of the trading of securities takes place in the secondary markets. Although some commentators have argued that secondary markets are less important to the economy than primary markets, they serve two important functions. First, they make financial securities more liquid. The improvement in liquidity makes securities more desirable to investors, and thus easier for the firm to sell them in the primary market. Second, they set the price of the securities the firm sells in the primary market. This means that the price of the securities’ issues on the primary markets is 32 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems partly determined by the price of similar securities traded in the secondary market. These two reasons explain why we focus our attention on secondary markets. In the USA the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and American Stock Exchange (AMEX) are the best known examples of secondary markets for the trading of previously issued stocks. (In April 2007 NYSE was combined with Euronext, as discussed below.) Note however that the US bond markets, where previously issued private or governmental bonds are traded, actually have a larger trading volume that the US stock markets. Activity 2.12 In the table below, tick the column that shows where each of the intermediaries operate. Operate in primary markets Operate in secondary markets Mutual funds Finance companies Investment banks Securities firms Exchanges and over-the-counter (OTC) markets Secondary markets can be organised as exchanges or over-the-counter (OTC) markets. • In exchanges, buyers and sellers (through their brokers) transact in one central location to conduct trades. Examples are the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) which recently acquired the American Stock Exchange (AMEX) and the London Stock Exchange (LSE). • In over-the-counter markets, dealers at different locations have an inventory of securities, and are ready to buy and sell these securities ‘over-the-counter’ to anyone willing to accept their price. Because of the technological links among dealers about prices, OTC markets are competitive and not very different from organised exchanges. OTC trading is most significant in the USA, where requirements for listing stocks on the exchanges are quite strict. Examples of OTC markets are: the US government bond market and the NASDAQ (National Association of Securities Dealers Automated Quotation System) stock exchange. The NASDAQ is the second largest US market. Traditionally, it used to be a pure dealer market. Following controversies about dealer collusion, since 1997 public limit orders are allowed to compete with dealers. Market and limit orders can be entered onto the Small Order Execution System (SOES), which automatically routes market orders to the dealer quoting the best price. (Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), pp.262–64 for more information on the NASDAQ.) Activity 2.13 Visit the Nasdaq website at www.nasdaqomx.com/whoweare/quickfacts/ and summarise the mission of Nasdaq. 33 24 Principles of banking and finance Money and capital markets On the basis of the maturity of the securities traded, a distinction between money and capital markets can be introduced. • Money markets are financial markets where only short-term debt instruments (maturity of less than one year) are traded. Money markets are mainly wholesale markets (large transactions) where firms and financial institutions manage their short-term liquidity needs (i.e. to earn interest on their temporary surplus funds). • Capital markets are markets in which long-term securities are traded. These long-term instruments include equity instruments (infinite life), government bonds and corporate bonds (original maturity of one year or greater). Capital markets’ securities are often held by financial intermediaries, such as mutual funds, pension funds and insurance companies. Quote-driven dealer markets, order-driven markets and brokered markets On the basis of how the trade intermediation occurs, a distinction between quote-driven dealer markets, order-driven markets and brokered markets can be made. • In quote-driven dealer markets, a dealer or market-maker is on one side of every trade. (Note that dealers are also known as market makers, as they quote prices and stand ready to buy and sell at these quotes, so that they provide liquidity). Dealers hold an inventory of the security, which fluctuates as they trade. They profit from charging a bid-ask spread and from speculating. • In order-driven markets, buyers and sellers trade directly without any intermediation. Most order-driven markets are auction markets. Trading rules formalise the process by which buyers seek the lowest available prices and sellers seek the highest available prices (price discovery process). • In brokered markets, brokers perform an active search role to match buyers and sellers. They do not provide liquidity but they find liquidity. They hold no inventory as they do not participate in the trade themselves. The most important brokered securities markets are those for large blocks of stocks and bonds. Most major equity markets are hybrid markets in that they are not purely order-driven or purely quote-driven, but a mixture of the two. For example the NYSE is an explicitly hybrid market. Each stock is assigned a single market-maker, known as a specialist. He must ensure that trade in the stock in question occurs in a fair and orderly fashion. He must provide quotes to everybody. However, the public can also submit limit orders to the specialist. The specialist then maintains (and has exclusive access to) the limit order book. When the specialist provides quotes to potential customers, they may be his own or (partially) composed from public limit orders. This implies that not all trades affect the specialist’s inventory. Secondary markets around the world In the United Kingdom, secondary financial markets are as sophisticated as in the USA. The London Stock Exchange, the major organised stock market in the UK, enables domestic and overseas companies to raise equity capital. (Note that in August 2007 the London Stock Exchange merged with Borsa Italiana, and nowadays the group leads the European equities business.) For frequently traded stocks (constituents of the FTSE-100, 34 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems the market index of the London Stock Exchange), the primary trading venue is the electronic, order-driven system called SETS (Stock Exchange Electronic Trading Services). Essentially, the London Stock exchange is a hybrid market: while the exchange itself regards SETS as the primary trading venue for FTSE-100 stocks, a lot of trade in these stocks is off the SETS order book. Dealers still exist who are voluntarily willing to provide liquidity in FTSE-100 stocks. Hence, the London Stock Exchange has some quote-driven features too (and is not fully transparent or centralised). As shown by Figure 2.6, in 2004 the total capitalisation of domestic listed companies on the London Stock Exchange was much lower than the one of NYSE. Note however that foreign companies, not included in the graph, constitute a high proportion of listed companies in the UK. Bond markets are important in the UK. The domestic bond market has been replaced by the Eurobond market (market for the trading of bonds denominated in a currency other than that of the country in which they are sold). The Eurobond market is based in London, and accounts for the trading of most (up to 80 per cent) of the new issues of international bonds. 12 Capitalisation domestic listed companies 10 8 6 4 2 0 NYSE Nasdaq Tokyo Stock Exchange London Stock Exchange Euronext Deutsche Borse AMEX Figure 2.6: Stock market capitalisation ($trillion), 2004 Source: Graph created using data from NYSE website (www.nyse.com). In Japan there are eight stock exchanges, with the Tokyo Stock Exchange by far the most important. The total capitalisation of domestic listed companies is similar to that of the London Stock Exchange. There is also an OTC market, which has become more important in recent years. The debt markets (for the debt of government, financial institutions and companies) are also well developed. In the Netherlands, France, Belgium and Portugal the stock exchange is Euronext, which was formed on 22 September 2000 when the exchanges of Amsterdam, Brussels and Paris merged. Euronext expanded at the beginning of 2002 with the acquisition of LIFFE (London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange) and the merger with the Portuguese exchange BVLP (Bolsa de Valores de Lisboa e Porto). Euronext represents a European cross-border exchange, integrating trading and clearing operations on regulated and non-regulated markets, and was formed in response to the globalisation of capital markets and to create a pan-European exchange offering its participants increased liquidity and lower transaction costs. In April 2007 NYSE Euronext (i.e. the holding company created by the combination of NYSE and Euronext) was established. NYSE Euronext operates the world’s largest and most liquid exchange group and offers the most diverse array of financial products and services. 35 24 Principles of banking and finance In Germany, the Deutsche Borse is composed of seven regional exchanges, with Frankfurt being the most important. These markets have been traditionally underdeveloped in Germany compared to most other countries. The bond markets are more important than the stock markets. Most of the debt traded is issued by the government and banks. Activity 2.14 In your own country, if you or a company want to launch (primary market) or buy and sell shares (secondary market), where do they do it? Note down what you’ve read about your country’s stock exchange(s) and look at their websites. Ask your own bank what they think of these and other financial markets and intermediaries. Summary In this chapter, we investigated financial systems by using a functional perspective (analysing the functions of financial systems in order to understand why they exist) and a structural perspective (to outline the structure of financial systems and describe the main entities that comprise financial systems). • From a functional perspective, financial systems perform two essential economic functions: the credit function and the monetary function. • From a structural perspective, financial systems comprise financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets. With reference to the US financial system, we provided a taxonomy of each of these three entities: • Financial intermediaries comprise depository institutions (commercial banks, savings and loan associations and credit unions), contractual savings institutions (insurance companies and pension funds), and investment intermediaries (mutual funds, finance companies, investment banks and securities firms). • Financial securities traded in financial markets are debt instruments (bonds, notes and bills), and equity instruments (common and preferred stocks). • Financial markets can be classified as primary versus secondary markets, organised exchanges versus over-the-counter markets, capital markets versus money markets, quote-driven dealer markets versus order-driven markets and brokered markets. Furthermore, the chapter provided an overview of the differences between national financial intermediaries and financial markets across the world. 36 Chapter 2: Introduction to financial systems Key terms Bi-ask spread Bonds Borrower-spenders Brokers Brokered markets Building societies Callable bonds Capital markets Commercial banks Common stocks Contractual savings institutions Convertible bonds Corporate bonds Coupon bonds Credit unions Dealers Debt instruments Default risk premium Depository institutions Direct finance Economic function of a financial system Equity Eurobonds Expectations theory Finance companies Financial intermediaries Financial markets Floating rate bonds Foreign bond Government bonds Government notes Index-linked bonds Indirect finance Insurance companies Interest rate term structure Investment banks Investment intermediaries Lender-savers Limit orders Liquidity premium theory Long-term credit banks Market makers Market segmentation theory Money markets Market orders Money market securities Municipal bonds Mutual/cooperative banks Mutual funds Order-driven markets Ordinary banks Organised exchanges Over-the-counter markets Pension funds Perpetual bonds Preferred stocks Primary markets Puttable bonds Retail banks Savings banks Savings institutions Secondary markets Securities Securities firms Shares Stocks Treasury bills Trust banks Wholesale banks Yield curve Zero coupon bonds A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you will be able to: • explain why financial systems exist (i.e. explain the functions of financial systems) • outline the structure of financial systems (i.e. describe the three main entities that compose financial systems: financial intermediaries, securities and financial markets) • describe which financial intermediaries operate in financial systems in the USA in particular and, more generally, around the world (e.g. depository institutions, contractual savings institutions and investment intermediaries) and explain their characteristics • explain which financial securities are traded on financial markets (bonds, notes, bills and stocks), and explain their nature • discuss the various theories that attempt to explain the shape of the yield curve • explain the structure of financial markets in the USA and around the world (primary versus secondary markets, money versus capital markets, organised versus over-the-counter markets, quote-driven dealer markets, order-driven markets and brokered markets). 37 24 Principles of banking and finance Sample examination questions 1. a. What is a financial system? Frame your answer both from a structural and a functional perspective. b. What is the primary function of depository institutions? How does this function compare with the primary function of insurance companies? c. What is a mutual fund? What are the differences between shortterm and long-term mutual funds? Where do mutual funds rank in terms of asset size among all financial intermediaries in the USA? 2. a. Explain how securities firms differ from investment banks. Which categories of firms are there in this industry? In what way are they financial intermediaries? b. What distinguishes stocks from bonds? What are the differences with reference to the risk/return relationship? c. ‘Because corporations do not actually raise any funds in secondary markets, they are less important to the economy than primary markets’. Comment. 3. a. With reference to examples, discuss globalisation of the financial markets around the world. b. Compare and contrast quote- and order-driven markets c. Explain the purpose of money markets and give examples of the types of money markets and their users. 38 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems Aims The aim of this chapter is first, to illustrate the main reasons for the existence of bank-based and market-based financial systems across countries, and to review the history of national financial systems and analyse why countries chose one way rather than another. Second, it aims to investigate the main causes of financial crises and their sequence of events. In particular we focus on the recent global financial crisis of 2007. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why the relative importance of banks and financial markets is different around the world • discuss how the historical evolution of financial systems helps to explain the existence of bank-based and market-based financial systems • outline the main similarities and differences between the financial systems of industrialised countries • discuss the implications (in terms of households’ asset allocation, role of indirect intermediation and firms’ financing) of the existence of bank-based and market-based financial systems • explain the main economic factors causing financial crises and the sequence of events of financial crises • discuss, with reference to examples from history, financial crises and bubbles. Essential reading Allen, F. and D. Gale Comparing Financial Systems. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2001) Chapters 1, 2 and 3. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapter 18. Further reading Heffernan, S. Modern Banking. (Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, 2005) Chapter 2. References Bank of England Financial Stability Report, no. 21 (London, 2007). Bullard. J, J. Neely and D. Wheelock ‘Systemic risk and the financial crisis: a primer’, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October 2009 pp.403-17 Corbett, J. and T. Jenkinson ‘How Is Investment Financed? A Study of Germany, Japan and the United States’, Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies (1997) 65 supplement, pp.69–93. Lacoste, P. ‘International capital flows in Argentina’, BIS Papers no. 23 (www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap23e.pdf, 2004). 39 24 Principles of banking and finance Lindgren, C., G. Garcia and M. Saal Bank Soundness and Macroeconomic Policy. (Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund, 1996). Mayer, C. ‘Financial Systems, Corporate Finance, and Economic Development’ in Hubbard, R.G. (ed.) Asymmetric Information, Corporate Finance, and Investments. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990) [ISBN 9780226355856] pp.307–32. Trueman, B., M.H. Wong and X.J. Zhang ‘The Eyeballs have it: Searching for the Value in Internet Stocks’, Working Paper. (University of California, April 2000). Turner, A ‘The Turner Review: A regulatory response to the global banking crisis’, Financial Services Authority, 2009. (download www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/turner_review.pdf) Introduction In Chapter 2 we suggested that financial markets and intermediaries are alternatives that perform more or less the same functions but in different ways (and perhaps with different degrees of success). Our objective in this chapter is to determine why we observe differences in financial systems with regard to the relative importance of financial intermediaries and financial markets, and hence why financial systems around the world can essentially be divided into bank-based and market-based systems. In terms of the relative importance of banks and markets, Figure 3.1 clearly indicates some important differences across countries. First, we can see that the USA is at one extreme and Germany at the other. The equity market capitalisation to GDP ratio for the USA was 107 per cent in 2009. In contrast, the corresponding ratio for Germany was 39 per cent. The US ratio of market capitalisation is almost three times that of Germany. Accordingly, the ratio of bank claims on the private sector to GDP was 48 per cent for the USA and 127 per cent for Germany: the German ratio is about 2.5 times that of the USA. Second, other financial systems fall in between these two extremes. On the one hand, in the UK, markets are more important than banks, but the relevance of banks is high (129 per cent versus 123 per cent). On the other hand, in Japan, banks are much more important than markets (127 per cent versus 70 per cent). Therefore, the UK and the USA are examples of market-based financial systems, where markets are more important than banks; while Japan and Germany are examples of bank-based financial systems, where the opposite situation occurs. Third, several other financial systems are interesting intermediate cases, where both markets and banks are important. In France, banks and markets are roughly equally important. In other European countries (Italy and Spain), banks are important, and markets are less so. However, there are differences in the irrespective relevance (Banks are much more important than markets in Italy). Why are there differences in the relative importance of financial markets and intermediaries in different countries? 40 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems 1,6 1,4 1,2 1 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 0 France Germany Italy Spain Bank claims/GDP United Kingdom USA Japan Market capitalisation/GDP Figure 3.1: International comparison of banks and markets, 2009 Sources: OECD Statistics (for GDP data); World Federation of Exchanges (for stock exchange data); European Banks Federation; Bank of England; Federal Reserve Bank of USA; Bank of Japan. The relative importance of different financial institutions is heterogeneous across countries. In terms of the different forms in which gross financial assets are held (directly by households, by pension funds, by insurance companies, by mutual funds), most assets are owned directly by households (except for the UK). In the USA and UK, pension funds are much more important than in other countries. In Germany, and to some extent in Japan, pension funds are relatively unimportant (please refer to Table 3.2 in Allen and Gale, 1998, p.48). Why are there differences in the relative importance of different financial intermediaries in different countries? What are the implications in terms of investment decisions of individuals in different countries? From the perspective of households, there is a clear difference between the assets held in the USA, UK, Germany and Japan. As regard to the total portfolio allocation of assets, households in the USA and UK hold a greater proportion of their assets as shares than is the case in the other countries we consider here (Germany, Japan and France). Overall (direct and indirect holdings via pension funds, insurance companies and mutual funds), equity constitutes 45 per cent of household assets in the USA, and 52 per cent in the UK (even more than in the USA). This contrasts sharply with Japan and Germany, where the corresponding values are 12 per cent and 13 per cent. For cash and cash equivalents (which include bank accounts) and bonds the reverse is true. In Japan 52 per cent of assets are held in cash and cash equivalents and 13 per cent in bonds, while in Germany the figure is 36 per cent in both (please refer to Table 3.3 in Allen and Gale, 1998, pp.50–51). In the USA only 19 per cent of assets are held in cash and cash equivalents, and 28 per cent in bonds. Activity 3.1 As you work throughout this section, fill in the table below on the household percentage of assets owned. USA UK Germany Japan Equity Cash and cash equivalents Bonds 41 24 Principles of banking and finance When you have completed the table in the Activity above you will see some sharp differences. The question is – why should these differences exist? Also, what are the implications in terms of risk for the investors of different countries? From the perspective of firms’ fund raising, the dominance of financial intermediaries over financial markets is clear in all countries. In all countries, except Japan, retained earnings are the most important source of finance. External finance is simply not very important. Loans represent the most important source of finance in terms of funds raised externally: they are the second source of finance in the USA, UK, Germany, Japan, France and Italy (Mayer, 1990; Corbett and Jenkinson, 1997). On the contrary, financial markets are not an important source of finance, as further discussed in Chapter 4. Even in the USA and the UK, which, as we saw above, have the highest financial market capitalisation to GDP, loans from financial intermediaries are far more important for corporate finance than are securities markets (bonds and stocks). In the countries with the lowest financial market capitalisation to GDP (Germany and Japan) financing from financial intermediaries has been almost ten times greater than that from securities markets. What makes financial intermediaries so important in the financing of firms? Summing up, the UK and the USA are examples of market-based financial systems, where: • Financial markets (organised markets for securities, such as stocks, bonds, futures and options) are more important than banks • The proportion of gross financial assets owned by pension funds is higher. • The proportion of equity in the total portfolio allocation of assets by householders is higher. • Loans from financial intermediaries are more important for corporate finance than marketable securities, but at a lower extent than in other financial systems. On the other hand, Germany and Japan are examples of bank-based financial systems. This chapter explains these points. Whether a country has a bank-based or market-based financial system is important. Each type of system facilitates the flow of funds from savers to borrowers, but each has different implications for dealing with potential asymmetric information problems that arise between those providing funds and those receiving them, as discussed in Chapter 4. Is the ideal financial system – in terms of linking savers and borrowers – one that relies heavily on banks through lending and stock ownership or control to resolve these potential informational problems, or one that relies heavily on financial markets? 42 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems Activity 3.2 Plot the different countries shown in Figure 3.1 on a graph like this. High ratio of bank claims High % of market capitalisation The evolution of financial systems A basic knowledge of the historical development of financial systems is essential if you are to understand the reasons for the existence of market-based and bank-based systems. The stages that characterise the development of financial systems are briefly described below. You can find a full account of these in Allen and Gale (see Essential reading). We only summarise the main points here. Ancient practices In the first phase, which started with the Mesopotanian financial system (third millennium BC) and ended with the Roman empire (first century AD), the main characteristics of the system can be stylised as follows. • Financial instruments were initially limited to precious metals or metallic (gold and silver) coins, but were then extended to loans and mortgages. Loans were made to individuals for consumption needs and for agricultural financing (from landlords to tenants). Mortgages were a combination of a loan and an insurance contract, and they were mainly used for foreign trade financing. The provider supplied funds to finance a voyager; however in the event of a catastrophe, repayment was not required (note the similarities with the equity instruments). • Financial intermediaries were limited to money changers and banks. Money changers emerged because of the existence of many different types of coins. Banks began to operate in Athens in the late fifth century BC. Their main functions were to accept deposits and make loans. Italian bankers After the Romans, monetary systems did not develop in Europe until the next period of progress, starting in 1200. This came again from Italy, this time north of Rome in Tuscany and further north. These developments led eventually to the Renaissance in the 1300s. You can find some of the reasons explained in Allen and Gale – look out for the following factors: the role of the pre-Reformation Church; the aristocracy, nation states and taxation; the rise of Islam; trade routes between Asia and Europe (via the Silk Road). As a result, several characteristics of the modern financial system developed: 43 24 Principles of banking and finance • Financial instruments became more varied. They included, in addition to trade credit and mortgages, bills of exchange, government and corporate securities and insurance contracts. The innovation of bills of exchange has been very important and opened up the way to banks in a modern sense. Bills of exchange were debt instruments drawn on the buyer of goods, which promised the payment of a specified amount in the buyer’s hometown at some date in the future. Due to the prohibition on usury imposed by the Roman Catholic Church, bills of exchange could not be discounted. To overcome this prohibition, the exchange rate specified in the transaction was such that there was a de facto discount. Other new financial instruments appeared: (1) Debt claims against amount borrowed by governments (such as that of the Florentine Republic); (2) Corporate claims (equity-like instruments) issued by partnerships and companies. Finally, maritime insurance became important and life insurance was introduced. • Financial intermediaries included early types of banks and insurance companies. Banks were first established in Florence, Siena and Lucca after the Middle Ages, then spread to Venice and Genoa. In the fourteenth century Bardi and Peruzzi in Florence grew to a substantial size: just to give a measure of their size, consider that they financed the English side of the Hundred Years’ War. In the fifteenth century, Medici banks in Florence achieved a sophistication that remained unbeaten until the nineteenth century. The main activities of banks were: (1) transferring money associated with international trade and the Roman Catholic Church; (2) establishing networks in Europe. • Informal markets appeared. To a limited extent, government and corporate securities were transferable and traded. It is worth mentioning that Jewish people were more important than the Italians in northern Europe and went on to play important financial roles in Spain and Poland. The Church’s rules against usury gave the Jewish bankers their competitive advantage. Dutch finance The third phase of financial development took place mainly in Amsterdam in the early 1600s. The Netherlands finally ejected their colonial masters – the Spanish – after a long, costly war and their new-found independence allowed a blossoming of trade and finance. The period is known to the Dutch as their ‘Golden Era’ and the wealth that flowed down the River Rhine from Germany, France and Switzerland led to new financial systems. Other signs of increased wealth were the rise of Dutch painting, empirebuilding and successful wars against the English, culminating in a Dutch king of England in 1689. As we see below, the Dutch also gave the English a model for a ‘central bank’ as well as a new king. • Financial markets became more formalised. The first formal stock exchange developed as part of the Amsterdam Bourse, which was established in 1608 as a market for commodities and also for securities (although these were less important). The market soon developed sophisticated trading practices. The reason for the development of the Amsterdam Bourse was the tulip mania of 1636–37, the first main financial bubble (please refer to the last section of this chapter): the price of tulips rose quickly to very high levels, before collapsing dramatically and causing the bankruptcy of many speculators. • Financial instruments: options and futures contracts were traded on the Amsterdam Bourse; 44 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems • Central banks appeared as the institutions through which governments were involved in financial systems. The Bank of Amsterdam, established in 1609, became a model for public banks set up by governments. Its main purpose was to facilitate payments. Commercial banks took deposits and made exchanges, but in general did not provide credit. The emergence of market-based and bank-based systems In the fourth phase, starting in the years 1719–20, when the South Sea Bubble occurred in England and the Mississippi Bubble in France, two distinctly different types of financial systems developed: the stock marketoriented US/UK model and the bank-oriented continental European model. Whereas the UK repealed the heavy regulation of the stock market (the so-called Bubble Act, which was a reaction to the South Sea Bubble) at the beginning of the nineteenth century, France did not ease restriction on the stock market until the 1980s. The French experience has substantially affected the development of financial systems in continental Europe, among them the German system. The historical development in each of these main countries is analysed below. United States of America The National Bank Acts of 1863 and 1864 set up a national banking system as a reaction to the chaos of the US Civil War. Fears of excessive centralisation led to the banks in each state being granted limited powers: each bank was confined to a single state; and banks were prohibited from holding equity or paying interest on demand deposits. After a series of panics in the system (1873, 1884, 1893, 1907), the Federal Reserve System was established – with a regional structure – in 1913. In 1933 another major banking panic led to the closing of banks for an extended period. This led to the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933, which introduced deposit insurance and required the separation of commercial and investment banking operations (and thus prohibited universal banking and prevented banks from underwriting securities). As a result, throughout the nineteenth century, the US banking system was highly fragmented, without a nationwide system with extensive branch networks. On the other hand, capital markets are more important than banks in the USA. Several reasons explain the strength of the role of the USA’s financial markets: 1. The Civil War helped to develop New York’s financial market (as wars between England and France did in the eighteenth century with regard to the London capital markets), and the First World War helped the New York market to supplant London markets (as New York’s markets were financing all parties). 2. The prohibition on banks’ holding equity and the fragmentation of the banking system (particularly with regard to providing services to the corporate sector). 3. The Great Crash of 1929, which led to the creation of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). This aimed to ensure the integrity of the markets and the regulation of financial markets. 4. Financial innovation, by the introduction of new financial instruments such as various derivative instruments (swap and complex options). At the same time, new exchanges for options and financial futures have appeared and become major markets. 45 24 Principles of banking and finance Recently, three restrictions on the banking system have been relaxed. First, the erosion of the Glass-Steagall Act prohibitions. In 1987 the Federal Reserve allowed affiliates of approved commercial banks to engage in underwriting activities as long as the revenue did not exceed a specified amount – which started at 10 per cent, but was raised to 25 per cent – of the affiliates’ total revenues. In 1988 the Federal Reserve used a loophole in Section 20 of the Glass-Steagall Act to allow three commercial banks (Bankers’ Trust, Citicorp and J.P. Morgan) to underwrite corporate debt securities and to underwrite stocks. Two competitive reasons determined this legislative change. On the one hand, brokerage firms began to engage in the traditional banking business of issuing deposits. On the other hand, foreign banks’ activities in the USA eroded the position of national US banks. Second, the elimination of the Glass-Steagall Act. The Gramm-Leach-Bliley Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999 allows securities firms and insurance companies to purchase banks, and allows banks to underwrite insurance and securities and engage in real estate activities. Third, the relaxation of the historical restriction on banks crossing state boundaries. The Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994 stated that after 1997 banks would be essentially unrestricted with regard to interstate banking, except in states that opted out or imposed other restrictions. Nationwide banks are now beginning to emerge. Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), pp.450–79 for more detail on the historical development of the US banking system. In particular focus on why the regulators decided to separate banking and other financial services companies (through Glass-Steagall) and then why they reversed this when Glass Steagall was repealed. You will notice that one of the consequences of the repeal of Glass-Steagall has been greater consolidation of the industry through large mergers. This has created a problem called the ‘too-big-to-fail problem’ which we will examine in Chapter 5 of this subject guide. The financial assets of households are mostly equity (45 per cent of the total). Over a long period there has been a shift away from individuals’ holding equity directly to intermediaries (mainly pension funds and mutual funds) holding it. We analysed this earlier: see pp.21. United Kingdom The financial system in the UK resembles that in the USA in that markets play an important role. However, differences in the size and structure of the banking sector are evident. Moreover, the UK system is characterised by much less regulation than the US system. The speculation on the stocks of the South Sea Company, a company set up in 1711 to fund a portion of the government debt in exchange for a payment to the company, determined a dramatic rise in its price. This led to a large number of other stock issues by promoters who hoped to profit from price appreciation. To prevent these other stocks from diverting resources away from the South Sea Company, the Bubble Act was passed in 1720. However, the Act did not prevent a dramatic fall in the price of the South Sea Company, and many speculators went bankrupt (note the similarities with the tulip mania that occurred in the Amsterdam Bourse). The Act, not repealed until 1824, imposed the need to obtain a royal charter to form a joint stock company. The effect of the Act was to create barriers to company formation. This explains why the London capital market did not become a source of funds for companies. 46 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems However, it did become important for government financing. During the nineteenth century, the London Stock Exchange, established in 1802, steadily increased its importance as a source of funds for firms because of several events: • the repeal of the Bubble Act in 1824 • the freedom to form companies without specific parliamentary approval, introduced in 1856 • the development of railways in Britain and abroad, which resulted in a large demand for capital. New York replaced London as the world’s major financial centre after 1918. To this day the UK remains a stock market-based financial system. The UK banking system also developed strongly in the nineteenth century due to several other events: • The Bank of England, founded in 1694 as a private institution, was initially intended to help the government market debt to finance the Nine Years’ War with France. Its role became more important in 1742, when it was granted a monopoly over note issues in England except for private banks. Note that the growth of central banking activities in England laid the foundation for the development of central banks in other countries. • Banks consolidated into nationwide networks: country banks needed to have London branches because of the Bank of England’s role, and London banks needed to have branches outside London. • A visible concentration process took place (in contrast to the United States). As noted earlier, commercial banking was traditionally dominated by four clearing banks: Barclays, National Westminster, Midland and Lloyds (now Barclays, Royal Bank of Scotland, HSBC and Lloyds). Note that although there is no equivalent to the GlassSteagall Act and universal banking is allowed, commercial and investment banking (merchant banking or securities firms in UK terminology) were, until recently, traditionally separate because of restrictive practices. However, in 1986, the ‘Big Bang’ brought important structural changes in the London Stock Exchange, and as a consequence all the securities firms became part of integrated financial institutions. • The foreign and domestic sectors of the banking industry are roughly equal in size. This large foreign presence may in part explain the high ratio of bank claims on the private sector to GDP. However, with a few exceptions, foreign banks are not involved with the domestic sector. Traditionally, one important characteristic of the banking system is that banks did not engage in long-term lending to industry. This explains why firms rely greatly on internal finance and markets for raising funds. Germany Germany is very different from the US/UK financial system because banks play a far more important role and markets are less relevant, as shown in the opening section by the banks’ claims and market capitalisation to GDP. The historical development of the financial system explains its present characteristics. Prior to 1850, German financial markets were undeveloped relative to those in the UK, and joint stock companies were rare. The markets (Frankfurt and Berlin) were mostly for government debt and loans to 47 24 Principles of banking and finance princes, towns and foreign estate. During the same period, banks provided the initial finance for industrialisation and subsequently managed the issue of shares and bonds to repay the loans. Links between banks and industry grew substantially during this period. Banks were represented on the boards of companies, and industrialists held seats on the boards of banks. This led to the development of the Hausbank system, where firms have a long-term relationship with a given bank and use it for most of their financing needs. This qualifies as a universal banking system, where banks offer a full range of services to commercial customers and are formally linked to their commercial customers through equity holdings. Even today, the three major universal banks – Deutsche, Dresdner and Commerzbank – dominate the allocation of resources in the corporate sector. This explains why the most important sources of funds for firms were bank financing and internal finance. There are several reasons why financial markets in Germany remain relatively undeveloped: • The reliance on bank finance and the close relationship between banks and industrial firms. This explains why bank loans are very important, although retentions (funds internally generated by firms) are the single most important source of finance. • Few households participate directly in the financial market, because of the lack of prohibitions on insider trading, which make participation by unsophisticated investors unattractive. • Limited availability of mutual funds. Overall this implies that German investors have a limited range of equity instruments to invest in. This explains why the allocation across assets is mostly in cash and cash equivalents (36 per cent) and bonds (36 per cent), while equity is fairly unimportant (13 per cent). It is interesting to note the recent developments towards the creation of a single market in banking in the countries of the European Union (EU). In order to remove barriers to trade across European banking systems, a single market in banking has been created by harmonising regulation throughout the countries of the EU. The Second Banking directive of 1993 created the so-called EU passport, which entitles a bank in one member country to provide core banking services throughout the EU on the basis of the authorisation of their own member country. Moreover, complementary directives are aimed at providing harmonisation of solvency regulation across the EU (Basel Capital Requirements Directives). The original Basel Accord (now referred to as Basel 1) was agreed in 1988 by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. It helped to strengthen the soundness and stability of the international banking system as a result of the higher capital ratios that it required. Basel 2, a revision of the existing framework taking effect from the end of 2006, had the effect of making the framework more risk sensitive and representative of modern banks’ risk management practices (as discussed in Chapter 5). Japan The Japanese financial system is often seen as similar to the German bank-based financial system. However, Japan has experienced a different historical development in the role of the government. In Germany, the Hausbank system developed in the private sector, whereas in Japan the government was instrumental in the development of the main banking system. The supervision by the Ministry of Finance and the Bank of Japan extends over areas as diverse as the opening of new branches, opening hours, credit volumes, interest rates and accounting rules. 48 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems From the time of the abolition of feudalism and the Meiji Restoration towards the end of the nineteenth century, the Japanese authorities played a leading role in the growth of the modern industrial economy and the establishment of a financial system. During wartime, from 1937 to 1941, the government introduced a system of central control of financial resources, the so-called system of credit allocation. This determined a close relationship between banks and companies in the keiretsu, which is a group of industrial firms with a core group of banks. This led to the development of the main characteristics of the banking system: 1. Long-term relationships between a bank and its client firm. 2. Holding of both debt and equity of non-financial firms by the bank. 3. Active intervention of the bank in case of financial problems in the firm. This explains why in Japan loans (and not retentions) are the most important source of financing. Traditionally Japanese banks have shown a high degree of segmentation and specialisation, along functional lines. The reform of 1992 reduced the amount of segmentation: different types of financial firms are now allowed to enter new financial activities through separate subsidiaries. The Japanese banking system experienced a major crisis between 1997 and 1998, when seven large financial institutions went bankrupt (as explained in Chapter 4). Private financial institutions still have not fully recovered from this crisis: in July 2007 only one Japanese bank (Mitsubishi UFJ Financial Group) still maintains a global presence and occupies the seventh position in The Banker’s ranking of the top 1,000 banks, whereas in 1994 six of the 10 top places were occupied by Japanese banks. For most of the past fifty years, the weakness of the securities market has, to some extent, been self-perpetuating. On the one hand, the bank system experienced an abundance of funds. This abundance has been mainly determined by the large financial surplus of the personal sector, which in turn has been determined by two facts: Japanese households are heavy savers and they have limited investment opportunities in housing. This explains the pattern of Japanese households’ asset allocation, which is mainly cash and cash equivalents (52 per cent including bank accounts). On the other hand, the equity market tends to be volatile and speculative because of the dependence of companies on banks’ financing, which has determined their very high leverage ratios (the amount of capital divided by total assets, as explained in Chapter 5). However, in recent years, financial markets have steadily become more important. In order to gain international recognition, the Japanese government relaxed several regulatory restrictions, such as the restriction on issuing bonds. At the same time, large firms are able increasingly to rely on financial markets to raise funds. Overall, this has resulted in the development of fairly sophisticated financial markets. Nevertheless, the historical development of the Japanese financial market has determined the relative unimportance of equity and bonds in the asset allocation of Japanese households (13 and 12 per cent respectively). Note that in the 1990s the fall in individual ownerships has mainly been offset by an increase in the holdings of banks, insurance companies and business corporations. 49 24 Principles of banking and finance France The Mississippi Bubble (see p.40) profoundly affected the subsequent development of the stock market and banks in France. After the collapse, an official Bourse was set up. However, markets for company securities did not develop significantly during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. Similarly, the Mississippi Bubble retarded the development of banks for many years. Two main institutions were founded in the 1938–62 period with the aim of providing long-term loans for the industry. However, they ended up providing short-term commercial loans and speculating in foreign bonds. This suggests that the system of banks lending to industry developed in a deeper way only in Germany. Overall, the French financial system has traditionally been a bank-based system (even if less pronounced than the German system), and markets have played a less relevant role. However, in the 1980s, the government made a strong effort to reform the financial system and bolster financial markets. As a consequence, French financial markets have developed greatly since the beginning of the 1980s because of: 1. Two main reforms. First, the creation of a single national market, so that stocks from any of the seven exchanges could be traded at any exchange. Second, the completion of a computerised trading system (so-called CAC, Cotation Assistée et Continu). 2. The immediate success of derivatives markets (and MATIF in particular), set up in the mid-1980s. 3. The substantial presence of collective investment scheme (such as mutual funds), holding 19 per cent of financial assets, much higher than in any other country. Note, however, that a high proportion of assets (62 per cent) are held directly by households, and the main categories of assets held are cash and cash equivalents (38 per cent) and bonds (33 per cent). This explains why the French system is now an intermediate case, where both markets and banks are equally important. Activity 3.3 Investigate the following financial crises on the internet: Tulip mania, South Sea Bubble, Mississippi Bubble, Stock Market Crash of 1929. Then answer the following question: How have financial crises influenced the development of the financial system in the UK, USA and France? (Don’t forget to do the Essential reading: Allen and Gale (2001) Chapter 2 to analyse in more detail the historical development of financial systems across countries.) Market-based versus bank-based financial systems: implications The presence of market-based and bank-based financial systems emerges by comparing national banking structures on the basis of: 1. Integration of banking and commerce, which can operate either by banks’ ownership of commercial firms or by commercial firms’ ownership of banks. In the USA and the UK there is virtually no integration of banking and commerce. However in both Germany and Japan there is a close relationship between banks and firms. The higher amount of information available to banks operating in Germany and 50 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems Japan – in comparison to US/UK banks – helps in monitoring the firms and thus reducing the moral hazard problem. Moral hazard is one of the problems intermediaries face in lending (as described in detail in the next chapter) and represents the risk (hazard) that the borrower engages in activities that are undesirable (immoral) for the lender after the transaction is made. 2. Integration of the provision of bank and non-bank financial services. Bank financial services refer to traditional deposit-based lending, while non-bank financial services are those such as investment, underwriting, insurance, trust and property services. A high level of integration characterises universal banks of Germany, against the traditionally low integration in the USA and UK. Note, however, that the regulations of USA/UK have recently been reformed, and higher degrees of integration are now possible. Other countries, such as France and Italy, have limited forms of universal banking. In other words, there is a clear distinction between market-based (USA and UK) and bank-based systems (Germany, Japan and France). However, several peculiarities make the picture more complex: 1. The USA, unlike the UK and other European countries, did not develop a nationwide banking system with few banks. 2. In Germany and France, financial markets for company shares did not develop until recent years. Instead banks have had a primary role in providing funds to firms. 3. In Germany the ties between banks and firms are strong and intimate, but in France the banking relationship developed in a less successful way. 4. In Japan the government played an important role in the development of the banking system, whereas in Germany the Hausbank system developed without government intervention. What is the economic reason for the existence of two broad types of financial systems, one market-based and the other bank-based? The answer is the different reactions to the instability associated with financial markets. As a consequence of the South Sea Bubble in England, and the Mississippi Bubble in France, two distinctly different types of financial systems developed. This occurred because the UK repealed the heavy regulation of the stock market (Bubble Act) at the beginning of the nineteenth century, whereas France did not ease the restriction on the stock market until the 1980s. Many other financial crises and speculative bubbles (Tulip mania, Great Crash of 1929) affected the development of financial systems. This suggests that financial systems are fragile and crises are endemic. (The next section investigates the economic reasons for financial crises.) Financial markets did not develop spontaneously. As we have already seen, various kinds of financial institutions were responsible for the first financial transactions, mainly involving loans and transfers. Only at the beginning of the seventeenth century, with the foundation of the Amsterdam Bourse, was a formal market established. The presence of market imperfections – transaction costs and asymmetric information, as discussed in the next chapter, see p.64 – explains why for a long time most financial systems have been much closer to the extreme where no financial markets exist. Financial intermediaries are needed to overcome market imperfections, and thus enable firms and investors to exploit the market effectively. 51 24 Principles of banking and finance The implications of the existence of the two broad types of financial systems affects households’ asset allocation, the role of indirect intermediation (pension funds, insurance companies, mutual funds) and firms’ financing. With regard to households’ asset allocation, as shown in Figure 3.2, in the UK/USA equity is a much more important component of household assets than in Japan, France and Germany. Equity constitutes 45 per cent of household assets in the USA and 52 per cent in the UK (even more than in the USA), whereas it constitutes only 12 per cent and 13 per cent in Japan and Germany. For cash and cash equivalents (which include bank accounts) and bonds, the reverse is true. In Japan 52 per cent of assets are held in cash and cash equivalents and 13 per cent in bonds, while in Germany the figure is 36 per cent for both. In the USA only 19 per cent of assets are held in cash and cash equivalents and 28 per cent in bonds. Bonds are fairly unimportant in the UK and Japan. This implies that in the USA and the UK households bear significant risk, while in Germany, France and Japan they bear relatively little risk. 100% Other Real estate Loan and mortgages Foreign equity Foreign bonds Domestic equity Domestic bonds Cash and cash equivalents 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% US UK Japan France Germany Figure 3.2: Portfolio allocation of total financial assets owned by the household sector (%) Source: Figure created using data from Miles (1999), p.22. In terms of the different forms in which gross financial assets are held (directly by households, by pension funds, by insurance companies, by mutual funds), as shown in Figure 3.3, most assets are owned directly by households (except for the UK). In particular, individuals’ indirect investments through intermediaries (pension funds and mutual funds) are dominant in Germany, France and Japan. On the other hand, the individual’s participation in the stock market (through direct transactions) is high in the USA, although it has been falling. This implies that the decisions individuals must take are of a different nature. However, the general trend is that individuals are becoming less involved in making transactions directly in financial markets, whereas pension funds and mutual funds are increasing their share of the market. Specifically, in the UK and USA, pension funds and insurance companies are much more important than in other countries. In Germany, and to some extent in Japan, pension funds are relatively unimportant. 52 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% % held in mutual funds % held by insurance companies % held by pension fund (public and private) % held directly by household US UK Japan France Germany Figure 3.3: Financial assets ultimately owned by the household sector Source: Figure created using data from Miles (1999), p.21. In terms of firms’ financing, the distinction between market-based and bank-based systems is less clear. However there are differences in how firms obtain funds from external sources. In the countries with the lowest financial market capitalisation to GDP (Germany and Japan), firms’ financing from financial intermediaries has been almost ten times greater than that from securities markets. However, even in market-based systems, financial markets are not an important source of finance (as discussed in the next chapter). The current trend is towards market-based systems. Several government policies support this argument. • The European Union is moving towards a single financial market in the countries of the European Union (EU) through harmonising regulation throughout EU countries. • France has chosen to increase the importance of financial markets since the mid-1980s. • Japan introduced various reforms of its financial system (known as the ‘Big Bang’) between 1998 and 1999. Why are market-based systems suddenly so popular? There are two reasons. First, government intervention has become discredited. Second, economic theory emphasises the effectiveness of financial markets in allocating resources. However, market imperfections, such as transaction costs and asymmetric information, represent important limitations of financial markets, as discussed in the next chapter. Activity 3.4 Describe in two pages the historical development of the financial system in your country. Does it represent a market-based or bank-based system? Financial crises Financial crises are defined as major disruptions in financial markets that are characterised by sharp falls in asset prices and the failure of many financial institutions (including banks). Financial crises have been common in most countries throughout modern history in Europe and the USA and have had a deep impact on the development of financial systems, as described in the previous section. Moreover, many emerging countries have had several banking problems in recent years: about three-quarters of the member countries of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) suffered 53 24 Principles of banking and finance some form of financial crises between 1980 and 1996 (Lindgren, Garcia, Saal, 1996). Given the historical importance of crises and their relevance in emerging countries and more recently (following the global financial crisis of 2007-09) in developed countries, it is important to understand why they occur. Financial crises occur where there is a large increase in asymmetric information in financial markets. Asymmetric information occurs when one party to a transaction has less information than the other party, and thus is unable to make an accurate decision. (We discuss the asymmetric information issue further in the next chapter; however, we also need to introduce it here as part of our investigation into what causes a country to have a market- or a bank-based system). An increase in information asymmetries means a market becomes less efficient as a channel for moving funds from savers to investors, and therefore the market-based system becomes less attractive relative to the banking system. A financial crisis can lead to economic activity contracting sharply. To understand why financial crises occur, let us examine four main factors. 1. Problems in the banking sector. Banks play a major role in the financing of productive investments because of their ability to produce information. Because banks have a mismatch between the maturities of liquid liabilities and illiquid assets (as explained in the next chapter), they are vulnerable to liquidity shocks. Deterioration in their balance sheets implies that fewer resources are available to lend. This leads to a decline in investment spending, which slows economic activities. In the case of a severe crisis, the banks might fail. Fear can spread from one bank to another. A panic at one bank can very quickly spread to other banks as depositors rush to withdraw their deposits simultaneously. In the absence of deposit insurance and being ignorant of the quality of each bank’s loan portfolios, depositors at both good and bad banks attempt to withdraw their funds simultaneously. However, the banks will have insufficient funds to meet all these requests. Because banks operate on a sequential service constraint (a first come, first served basis), depositors have a strong incentive to run on the bank first. Uncertainty about the health of the banking system can lead to runs on banks both good and bad, and the failure of one bank can provoke the failure of others (known as the contagion effect or systemic risk). These multiple bank failures are known as bank panics. There are two consequences of a bank panic. First, a loss of information in financial markets and a loss of financial intermediation by the banking sector. Second, a decrease in the supply of funds to borrowers (because of the absence of lending), which leads to higher interest rates. 2. An increase in interest rates. A sharp increase in interest rates, caused by either a decrease in the money supply or an increase in the demand (you do not have to know this process to study this unit), means that individuals and firms with the riskiest investment projects are the only ones willing to pay the higher interest. Bad credit risks are the only ones still willing to borrow (because of the adverse selection problem – see Chapter 4 for details). In other words, the only customers who still want to borrow when interest rates are high are those who are likely to have weak, risky uses for the money. The consequence is that lenders no longer want to make loans. This decrease in lending leads to a decline in investment and aggregate economic activity. 54 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems 3. Stock market decline. A sharp decline in the stock market is another possible reason for a serious deterioration in firms’ balance sheets, which in turn can provoke a financial crisis. Given that share prices are the valuation of a firm’s net worth, a stock market decline implies a reduction in the firm’s net worth. The lower value of net worth implies a lower value of the collateral, which is property promised to the lender if the borrower defaults. The decline in the net worth makes banks less willing to lend because they are less protected by this collateral, and this causes a reduction in investments and aggregate economic activities. In addition, the decline in net worth induces firms to take on more risky investments, as they lose less if they have to default. As a consequence, lending is less attractive for banks, and thus there is a reduction in investments and aggregate economic activities. 4. An increase in uncertainty. The failure of prominent financial institutions, a recession or a stock market crash create increased uncertainty in the financial markets. Lenders become unable to screen good and bad credit risks (again due to the adverse selection problem). Once again, the decrease in lending results in a decline in investments and aggregate economic activity. Financial crises in the USA The following sequence of events characterises many US financial crises: • The four factors causing financial crises (described above) lead to an increase in adverse selection and moral hazard problems. • Lending, investment spending and aggregate economic activity decline. • Depositors begin to withdraw their funds from banks, which can result in a full-scale bank panic. The determinants of the depositors’ behaviour are the economic slowdown and the uncertainty about the banking system. • Interest rates increase even further and financial intermediation by banks decreases because of the reduced number of banks. • Adverse selection and moral hazard problems worsen. • There is further economic contraction. • In case of a sharp decline in prices, the recovery process is shortcircuited due to a further deterioration of firms’ net worth. This phenomenon is known as debt deflation, or rather increased burden of indebtedness for firms. Activity 3.5 Refer to Figure 15.2 in Mishkin and Eakins (2009), p.390 to better investigate the sequence of events in US financial crises. Many of the concepts such as adverse selection and moral hazard will be examined in more detail in Chapter 4 of this subject guide. Now study the features of the Great Depression, a description of which follows. The Great Depression The financial crisis in the Great Depression was the worst ever experienced by the USA. In 1928–29, the stock market experienced a boom, during which stock prices doubled. To curb it, the Federal Reserve pursued a tight monetary policy, mainly through an increase in interest rates. The stock market then crashed in 1929. By the middle of 1930, more than half of the stock market decline had been reversed. However, after the middle of 1930, the adverse shocks extended to the agricultural industry 55 24 Principles of banking and finance and the stock market continued to decline. This increased uncertainty and economic contraction determined a worsening of adverse selection and moral hazard in credit markets. From October 1930 to March 1933, a sequence of banks collapsed (over one-third of the US banks went out of business). This determined a reduction in the amount of financial intermediation and a decline in the ability of financial markets to channel funds to firms with productive investment opportunities. In the same period (1930–33), the price level fell by 25 per cent. This triggered a debt deflation (i.e. net worth fell because of the increased burden of indebtedness borne by firms). The decline in net worth and the resulting increase in adverse selection and moral hazard problems in the credit market led to a prolonged economic contraction in which the unemployment rate rose to 25 per cent. The global financial crisis 2007–09 The global financial crisis of 2007–09 was caused by a number of factors, but two general developments lay at its core. First, the growth of global macro-imbalances and second, financial market innovations. Large current account surpluses developed in Asian economies such as China and Japan as well as in oil exporting economies. The counterpart to this was the growing current account deficits of economies such as the US and some European economies such as the UK. The surpluses had been used to buy large amounts of government debt in the US and Europe. The consequence of this was to drive down interest rates in these countries. Low interest rates in the US and Europe have also been a consequence of low inflation as a result of low cost imports coming from fast growing developing nations such as China. Low inflation has allowed central banks to keep interest rates low. One consequence of low interest rates has been a massive expansion of debt – particularly mortgage debt. A rapid expansion of mortgage lending by banks fuelled a property price bubble as house prices grew at very fast rates. This in turn led lenders to relax credit standards leading to a rapid expansion of sub-prime mortgage lending in the US (and in other European countries). (The term sub-prime generally refers to borrowers who do not qualify for prime interest rates because they have weakened credit histories, low credit scores, high debt-burden ratios or high loan-to-value ratios.) Another contributing factor has been the desire of investors to obtain higher yields to offset the lower interest rates available in credit markets. This desire for higher yields was satisfied by financial innovation, in particular the process of securitisation whereby debt is packaged then transferred off the balance sheets of banks and new securities issued. Figure 3.4 illustrates the process. In Figure 3.4 the bank transfers the pool of mortgages to a separate entity called a special purpose vehicle (SPV). This should be independent of the bank and is normally set up as a trust. 56 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems First transaction: 1 2 SPV Originator 3 1 2 3 Market 3 The originator (here a bank) sells the mortgages, or assigns the income, to the SPV. The SPV issues bonds to the market. The SPV receives cash from the market and passes it to the bank. Subsequent transaction: SPV Income 4 4 5 Market 5 Payments from customers (originally to the bank) now go to the SPV. The SPV uses these to repay bonds (both interest and principal). Figure 3.4 The securitisation process The securities created from packages of residential mortgages were called Residential Mortgage Backed Securities (RMBS). Sometimes additional securities, known as collateralised debt obligations–CDOs), were created by combining multiple RMBSs (or parts of RMBSs) and then selling portions of the income streams derived from the mortgage pool or RMBSs to investors with different appetites for risk. One of the original ideas behind securitisation was to allow banks to transfer risk off their balance sheet, thereby allowing them to diversify. The hope was that much of this debt would be transferred to other parts of the financial system. However, the majority of investors in the securitised debt were other banks that held the securities in their trading books. The ratings agencies also assigned high credit ratings to much of the securitised debt products, thus creating the perception that the default risk on these securities was very low. Problems occurred in 2006–07 when house prices in economies such as the US fell. Many borrowers found that they owed more on their house than it was worth. Many borrowers chose to default – particularly subprime borrowers who were more sensitive to the fall in house prices. Rising loan defaults caused many RMBSs and CDOs that were backed by residential mortgages to experience substantial losses. In late 2007, banks such as Northern Rock in the UK, that depended heavily on securitisation to fund expansion of its business, found that this source of funding dried up as investors began to shun new issues of securitised mortgages. At the same time banks holding securitised debt in their trading books began to experience severe mark-to market losses. This led to concerns about liquidity in markets as banks reduced lending to each other through the inter-bank market as fears of insolvency increased. These strains continued into 2008 as large institutions such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac became reliant on government support in the US. A large drop in confidence occurred in September 2008 as Lehman Brothers investment bank failed, thus signalling that major institutions were not too big to fail. The collapse in confidence in the banking sector in many economies around the world led central banks and governments to intervene to provide exceptional liquidity support, then recapitalisation of major banks, to prevent further failures. The severely impaired state of the banking system led to a large reduction in credit extension by banks thus resulting in a severe economic recession in most economies in the world. 57 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 3.9 Read Turner (2009), Chapter 1 and Bullard, Neely and Wheelock (2009) for a more detailed discussion of the causes and consequences of the financial crisis of 2007–09. You should focus on the following questions in your reading: 1. What were the macro-economic factors that contributed to the crisis? 2. What caused interest rates to be kept low in Western economies in the years before the crisis? 3. Why did banks relax lending conditions in the years before the crisis? 4. How does the process of securitisation allow banks to fund new lending? 5. Why did the crisis in the banking sector lead to a contraction of economic activity (recession) for most economies? Note that we will follow up many of the problems revealed by the banking crisis in Chapter 5 when we consider regulation of the banking system. Financial crises in emerging market countries In recent years, many emerging market countries have experienced financial crises, as documented in Table 3.1. The sequence of events characterising these financial crises is different from what occurred in the USA in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries mainly due to differences in the institutional features of debt markets in emerging market countries. Beginning Mexico Ending Change in Change in Fiscal deposits net worth costs (%) (%) (%) Net IMF disbursement ($million) Dec 1994 1996 –15 –64 19.3 10.67 1994 1995 –43 –6 15 –0.66 South Korea July 1997 1999 –6 15 31.3 6.07 Indonesia July 1997 1999 13 –183 56.8 10.35 Venezuela Thailand July 1997 1999 –2 58 43.8 3.21 Ecuador 1998 2001 –24 –59 21.7 0.3 Turkey 2000 2002 –27 97 30.5 13.42 Dec 2001 2003 –4.8 –37 11.4 –16 Argentina Table 3.1: Financial crises in emerging market countries Source: Adapted from Lacoste (2004), p.97. The following factors have caused financial crises in emerging countries: 1. Deterioration in banks’ balance sheets due to the increase in loan losses, which, in turn, was due to weak supervision by bank regulators and lack of expertise in screening/monitoring borrowers at banks. This factor affected Mexican and East Asian crises and determined an erosion of banks’ capital. Note that Argentina, instead, had a wellsupervised banking system and no lending boom occurred before the crisis; nevertheless in 1998 Argentina entered a recession that led to some loan losses. 2. Increase in interest rates abroad and internally, which amplified adverse selection (i.e. it was more likely that the parties willing to take on the most risk would seek loans). This factor, consistent with the US experience, affected Mexican and Argentine but not East Asian crises. 58 3. Stock market decline and increase in uncertainty. This factor, once again consistent with the US experience, affected Mexico, Thailand, South Korea and Argentina. Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems 4. Fiscal problems of the government. As government budget deficits could not be financed by foreign borrowing, the government forced banks to absorb large amounts of government debt. As a consequence, investors lost confidence in the ability of the government to repay its debt. The price of government debt decreased and determined big losses in banks’ balance sheets. This factor was typical of the Argentine crisis, but not of the US, Mexican and East Asian crises. 5. Rise of interest rates abroad. The US Fed began to increase the government rate to head off inflationary pressures. Although this monetary policy was successful in the USA, it put upward pressures in foreign countries (particularly in Mexico and Argentina). These factors worsened adverse selection and moral hazard problems. On the one hand, financial intermediaries experienced more difficulties in screening out good and bad borrowers. On the other hand, the decline in capital determined a decrease in the value of firms’ collateral and an increase in firms’ incentives to make risky investments (because of less equity to lose if the investments were unsuccessful). At this point, speculative attacks developed in the foreign exchange markets, plunging the economies into a full-scale crisis. Moreover, the interaction of the institutional structure of debt markets with the currency devaluations played an important role: as large proportions of firms’ debts were denominated in foreign currencies, the depreciation of domestic currencies implied an increase in indebtedness. The collapse of currencies led to a rise in actual and expected inflation rates, and consequently in market interest rates. The increased interest payments caused reductions in the cash flows of households and firms. The very short duration of debt contracts (typical of emerging market countries) provoked a substantial effect on cash flows. The sharp decline in lending led to an economic activity decline and to a deterioration in balance sheets, which in turn led to a worsening banking crisis. This materialised in substantial losses for banks because many firms and households were no longer able to pay off their debts. Even more problematic for the banks was the deterioration in their balance sheet because of the large amount of short-term liabilities denominated in foreign currencies, which experienced a sharp increase in their value after the devaluation. The banking system would have collapsed in the absence of a government safety net (e.g. the assistance of the IMF). Activity 3.10 Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), pp.391–95 to get further details on the financial crises in emerging-market countries: Mexico (1994–95) and East Asia (1997–98). Try to identify the common causes and consequences of the crises in Mexico and South East Asia. Financial bubbles Financial crises often follow what appear to be bubbles in asset prices. A bubble occurs when an asset or commodity becomes overinflated in value. These bubbles in asset prices typically have three distinct phases: • Financial liberalisation results in an expansion in credit, which is accompanied by an increase in asset prices such as real estates and shares. They rise as the bubble inflates. • The bubble bursts and asset prices collapse (often within a short period of time). 59 24 Principles of banking and finance • Default of many firms and other agents that have borrowed to buy assets at inflated prices. A banking crisis may follow, causing problems in real sectors of the economy such as industry. Historic examples of this type of crisis are the Dutch tulip mania (described in the next section), the South Sea Bubble in England and the Mississippi Bubble in France (discussed in the previous section). More recent examples are bubbles in Japan (late 1980s), Mexico (1994–95) and East Asia (1997– 98) and housing market bubbles in the US, UK, Spain etc. prior to the 200709 crisis described above. Another recent case, the internet bubble of the late 1990s, is described below. Dutch tulip mania The tulip mania (1636–37) was the first serious financial bubble. The prices of tulip bulbs rose quickly to very high levels, before collapsing dramatically and causing the bankruptcy of many speculators. The following sequence of events characterised the tulip mania. The tulip, introduced to Europe in the middle of the sixteenth century, experienced a strong growth in popularity in the Netherlands, boosted by competition for possession of the rarest tulips. The competition escalated until prices reached very high levels. The flower rapidly became a luxury item and a status symbol. In 1623, a single bulb of a famous tulip variety could cost as much as a thousand florins (vs. the average yearly income of 150 florins). Tulips were also exchanged for land and houses. By 1636, tulips were traded on the stock exchanges of numerous Dutch towns and cities. People started to trade their other possessions in order to speculate in the tulip market. Some traders sold tulip bulbs that had only just been planted or those they intended to plant (i.e. tulip future contracts, a type of derivative instrument). After some time, the Dutch government started to introduce regulation to help control the tulip mania. Consequently, a few informed speculators started liquidating their tulip bulbs and contracts. Moreover, more tulip bulbs were added to the supply due to people harvesting new tulip bulbs. Suddenly tulip bulbs were not quite as rare as before. People began to suspect that the demand for tulips could not last. The tulip market began a slight downward trend. In February 1637 the market experienced a widespread panic: everyone realised that tulips were not worth the prices people were paying for them, and began to sell. The bubble burst: in less than six weeks, tulip prices crashed by over 90 per cent. Attempts were made to resolve the situation, but these were unsuccessful. Ultimately, individuals were stuck with the bulbs they held at the end of the crash. Note that lesser versions of the tulip mania also occurred in other parts of Europe (e.g. England), although matters never reached the state they had in the Netherlands. The internet bubble of the late 1990s During the internet bubble of the late 1990s, the remarkable market values assigned to internet and related high-tech companies seemed inconsistent with rational valuation. Equity valuations were based on uncertain future forecasts. Even if all market participants rationally priced common stocks as the present value of all future cash flows expected (which will be explained in Chapter 7), it was still possible for inflated prices to develop. There were two main reasons for the internet bubble of the late 1990s: 1. Outlandish and unsupportable claims were being made regarding the growth of the internet (and the related telecommunications structure needed to support it); 60 Chapter 3: Comparative financial systems 2. Unsustainable projections for the rates and duration of growth of these ‘new economy’ companies. As an example of how difficult it is to value these companies, we recall the following story about analyst recommendations. At the time when Amazon.com stock was trading for $130 a share, a prominent analyst issued a buy stock recommendation, even though official projections led him to a valuation of only $30. Admitting that he could justify any valuation between $1 and $200, the analyst stated his recommendation was based on the company, its opportunities and its management. During those years, professional investors argued that the valuations of high-tech companies were proper, and professional pension fund and mutual fund managers overweighted their portfolios with high-tech stocks. Although it is now clear in retrospect that these professionals were wrong, there were certainly no obvious arbitrage opportunities available. While there were no profitable and predictable arbitrage opportunities available during the internet bubble, and although stock prices eventually did adjust to levels that more reasonably reflected the likely present value of their cash flows, an argument can be maintained that asset prices did remain ‘incorrect’ for a period of time. In the USA, the market index of the internet stock industry went above 1,000 in February 2000, and fell to 200 in October 2000. Moreover, although internet firms represented 6 per cent of the public equity market during February 2000, the pure internet sector represented 19 per cent of the daily volume. The above stylised facts about returns and volumes provide evidence of the irrationality of financial markets. The result was that too much new capital was allocated to internet and related telecommunications companies. Therefore, the stock market may well have temporarily failed in its role of efficiently allocating equity capital. Summary We showed in this chapter that differences in reactions to the instability of financial markets explain the existence of market-based financial systems (where financial markets are more important than banks) and bank-based financial systems. Overall, there is a clear distinction between marketbased (USA and UK) and bank-based systems (Germany, Japan and France), although the current trend is towards market-based systems. The two types of financial systems have different implications for: • Households’ asset allocation: in the market-based systems, equity (in the sense of stocks and shares) is a much more important component of household assets than in the bank-based systems; the reverse is true for cash, cash equivalents (which include bank accounts) and bonds. • The role of indirect intermediation (pension funds, insurance companies, mutual funds): individuals’ indirect investments through intermediaries are dominant in the bank-based systems, whereas individuals’ direct participation to the stock market is high in the market-based systems, especially the USA (although even there it is in decline). • Firms’ financing: in the market-based systems, loans from financial intermediaries are more important for corporate finance than marketable securities, but at a lesser extent than in the bank-based financial systems. The final issue concerns financial crises, which are major disruptions caused by a marked increase in the asymmetric information problem in 61 24 Principles of banking and finance financial markets. The four types of factors that lead to financial crises are bank panics, increase in interest rates, stock market decline and increase in uncertainty. Key terms asymmetric information bank-based systems Bubble Act financial bubble financial crises firms’ fund raising Glass-Steagall Act Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act gross financial assets households internet bubble market-based systems market capitalisation to GNP Mississippi Bubble tulip mania universal banks A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why the relative importance of banks and financial markets is different around the world • discuss how the historical evolution of financial systems helps to explain the existence of bank-based and market-based financial systems • outline the main similarities and differences between the financial systems of industrialised countries • discuss the implications (in terms of households’ asset allocation, role of indirect intermediation and firms’ financing) of the existence of bank-based and market-based financial systems • explain the main economic factors causing financial crises and the sequence of events of financial crises • discuss, with reference to examples from history, financial crises and bubbles. Sample examination questions 1. Analyse the historical evolution of financial systems in order to explain the reasons for the existence of market-based and bank-based systems. 2. a. Compare and contrast the German and Japanese banking systems. b. Explain the main implications of the presence of market-based versus bank-based financial systems. 3. a. How did competitive forces lead to the repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act’s separation of the banking and securities industries? What are the recent changes in US regulation on the separation of the banking and securities industries? b. In the light of the global financial crisis of 2007–09 discuss the case for a new Glass-Steagall Act. 4. a. How can a stock market crash provoke a financial crisis? b. Analyse the main events of financial bubbles. Refer to the internet bubble of the late 1990s as a case study. 5. a. Analyse the causes of the global financial crisis of 2007–09. b. What lessons can regulators learn from this crisis? 62 Part II: Principles of banking Part II: Principles of banking Overview In Part II, the focus is on one of the three pillars of a financial system: financial intermediaries. The aim is to introduce you to the principles of banking. In Chapter 2 we proposed a taxonomy of financial intermediaries, one of the three entities comprising a financial system. In Chapter 3 we investigated the reasons for the differences in the relative importance of financial intermediaries and financial markets in financial systems around the world. But we still have to answer several important questions: 1. Why do financial intermediaries exist? What are the key economic theories that enable us to justify the existence of financial intermediaries? (Chapter 4) 2. Why do banks need to be regulated? What are the key economic reasons for and against banking regulation? How does regulation operate in practice? (Chapter 5) 3. What are the main risks faced by banks? How do banks manage these risks? In particular, what are the techniques and models used by banks to manage risk? (Chapter 6) In the following chapters of Part II, we will answer each of these questions. 63 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 64 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation Aims The aim of this chapter is to illustrate the main reasons for the existence of financial intermediaries and to introduce the key economic theories required to analyse this issue. Furthermore, it illustrates how these economic theories can be applied to understand the existence (and relevance) of financial intermediaries. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why financial intermediaries exist • discuss how the presence of market imperfections explains the importance of financial intermediaries (and the relative unimportance of financial markets) in the financing of corporations • explain how financial intermediaries are able to reduce the transaction cost problem • explain how financial intermediaries are able to reduce/solve the problems arising from adverse selection and moral hazard • discuss the expected developments affecting the role of the different types of financial intermediaries (especially banks) in the future. Essential reading Allen, F. and D. Gale Comparing Financial Systems. (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2001) pp.47–52. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapters 15 and 18. Further reading Bain, A.D. The Economics of the Financial Systems. (Oxford: Blackwell Publishers Ltd, 1992) Chapter 4. Buckle, M. and J. Thompson The UK Financial System. (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2004) Chapter 2. Freixas, X. and J.C. Rochet Microeconomics of Banking. (Boston, Mass.: The MIT Press, 2008) Chapter 2. References Akerlof, G. ‘The Market for “Lemons”: Quality, Uncertainty and the Market Mechanisms’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 84(3) 1970, pp.488–500. Benston, G. and C. Smith ‘A Transaction Costs Approach to the Theory of Financial Intermediation’, Journal of Finance 31(2) 1976, pp.215–31. Boyd, J.H. and M. Gertler ‘Are Banks Dead? Or Are the Reports Greatly Exaggerated?’ in The Declining (?) Role of Banking. (Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1994). Coase, R.H. ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics 3(1) 1960, pp.1–23. 65 24 Principles of banking and finance Diamond, D.W. ‘Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring’, Review of Economic Studies 51(166) 1984, pp.393–414. Diamond, D.W. ‘Financial Intermediation as Delegated Monitoring: A simple example’, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 82(3) 1996, pp 51–66. Diamond, D.W. and P.H. Dybvig ‘Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity’, Journal of Political Economy 91(3) 1983, pp.401–19. Fama, E. ‘Banking in the theory of finance’, Journal of Monetary Economics 6(1) 1980, pp.39–57. Goddard, J.A., P. Molyneux and J.O.S. Wilson European Banking. Efficiency, Technology and Growth. (Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, 2001) [ISBN 9780471494492] pp.109–20. Gurley, J.G. and E.S. Shaw Money in a Theory of Finance. (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institute, 1960) [ISBN 9780815733225]. Hackethal, A. and R.H. Schmidt ‘Financing Patterns: Measurement Concepts and Empirical Results’, Frankfurt Department of Finance Working Paper no. 125 (2004), p.30. Jensen, M.C. and W.H. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976, pp.305–60. Leland, H.E. and D.H. Pyle ‘Informational Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation’, The Journal of Finance 32(2) 1977, pp.371–87. Introduction Several facts about financial intermediation deserve your attention. First, bank loans – and not stocks – are the most important source of funds raised externally by firms, despite the fact that so much media attention is focused on the stock market. Second, bonds are more important than stocks in financing firms. Third, direct lending from people who save to people who borrow to finance investment opportunities is less important than indirect lending through a financial intermediary such as a bank. This is despite the fact that it would seem more logical for the units with surplus funds to lend these funds directly to units in deficit. This chapter attempts to explain why most financing is indirect through intermediaries and thus considers the following questions: • What makes banks so important in the financing of businesses? • What are the reasons for the lesser importance of the stock markets in comparison to other external sources? • Why are financial intermediaries more important than securities markets for getting funds from savers to investors? These empirical facts (or puzzles) need to be understood in order to appreciate why financial intermediaries exist and how financial intermediation works. The analysis focuses on the main reasons for the existence of financial intermediaries and illustrates how a few (but powerful) economic theories can be applied to understand their existence, relevance and functioning. The analysis also investigates the future for traditional intermediation services provided by banks, given the decline observed in many countries in recent years. 66 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation Some evidence on financial intermediation Figure 4.1 shows the source of external funds used to finance firms over the period 1970–2000 in the USA, Germany and Japan. The categories of external funds are: bank loans, non-bank loans (loans by other intermediaries), bonds (marketable debt securities) and stocks (issue of new equity). 80 70 60 50 % 40 30 20 10 0 Bank loans Non-bank loans USA Germany Bonds Stocks Japan Figure 4.1: Sources of external funds for non-financial businesses in the United States, Germany and Japan (1970–2000) (Note: definitions of the categories of external funds are given in Mishkin and Eakins (2009), p.367.) Source: Graph created using data from Hackethal, A. and R.H. Schmidt ‘Financing Patterns: Measurement Concepts and Empirical Results’, Frankfurt Department of Finance Working Paper no. 125 (2004), p.30. Pause and note down what you think Figure 4.1 shows. First, loans are the most important source of funds raised externally in the USA, Germany and Japan. Buckle and Thompson (2004) report a similar finding for the UK. Although most funds raised by firms are internally generated (i.e. retained profits) with the exception of Japan, banks have the most important role in the external financing of businesses (56 per cent in the USA and 86 per cent in Japan and Germany). Specifically, the importance of banks is especially high in countries such as Germany (76 per cent) and Japan (78 per cent), the so-called bank-oriented systems as discussed in Chapter 3. However, it has to be noted that the share of banks in the financing of businesses has been declining in recent years. Figure 4.1 leads us to ask this question: what makes banks so important in the financing of businesses? A second equally important question is: what is driving the recent decline in their relevance? Activity 4.1 Find out the relative importance of sources of external funds for non-financial firms in your country. See if you can relate what you find to the importance of bank-oriented versus market-oriented systems. Second, Figure 4.1 shows that stocks are the least important source of external financing for firms. In an average year, US firms raise funds over five times more through loans than with stocks. The issue of new equity is even less important than bank loans in the rest of the world: about 10 67 24 Principles of banking and finance times less relevant in Germany, and about 20 times in Japan. Why are stock markets less important than other external sources? Third, bonds are more important than stocks in financing firms (32 per cent versus 11 per cent in the USA). The difference in the relative share, however, is less remarkable in Japan (9 per cent bonds versus 5 per cent stocks). Nevertheless, the combined amount of stocks and bonds, which constitutes marketable securities, represents 43 per cent in the USA, and only 15 per cent in Germany and 14 per cent in Japan. What are the reasons limiting the use of marketable securities by businesses to finance their activities? Fourth, only a small proportion of marketable securities (stocks and bonds) were sold directly to households (direct finance); the majority of these securities were bought primarily by non-bank financial intermediaries (pension funds, mutual funds and insurance companies). In this way, indirect finance, which involves the activities of financial intermediaries, is many times more important than direct finance, in which firms raise funds directly from lenders in the financial markets. This seems odd on the face of it. Units with surplus funds can lend these funds directly to units in deficit. On the one hand, the surplus units can obtain a return. On the other hand, the units in deficit can finance their investment opportunities. Why have indirect finance and financial intermediaries been so important in financial markets? Read about these four points in Mishkin and Eakins (2009) Chapter 15, which contains a fuller treatment of the relative importance of financial intermediaries and the relative unimportance of securities markets for the financing of businesses. Activity 4.2 Now read pages 47–52 in Allen and Gale (2001) and answer the following questions: 1. What is the percentage of direct finance versus indirect finance in the United States, Germany and Japan? (Refer to Figure 3.3 to find out the percentage values of marketable securities). 2. On the basis of your answer to the question above, discuss the relative importance of financial intermediaries versus financial markets. In order to answer the set of questions arising from the above empirical evidence, we need to answer the question of why financial intermediaries exist. The next section identifies and illustrates each of the possible reasons for this, and the corresponding theories of financial intermediation. Why do financial intermediaries exist? We described financial intermediaries in Chapter 2 and their place in the financial system (see p.15). Now we will look deeper into their role. Why do they exist? To answer this question we need to appreciate each of the reasons for the existence of financial intermediaries, and the relevant theories of financial intermediation. Financial intermediaries exist to solve or reduce market imperfections, such as: differences in the preferences of lenders and borrowers (in terms of size, maturity, liquidity, risk), presence of transaction costs, shocks in consumers’ consumption and asymmetric information (which gives rise to both adverse selection and moral hazard). Several theories have been developed to explain how financial 68 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation intermediaries reduce/solve these market imperfections. They are the theories of: • asset transformation • transaction costs reduction • liquidity insurance • informational economies of scale and delegated monitoring. Together they account for the existence of financial intermediaries and they provide a framework for the analysis, as summarised in Table 4.1. Market imperfection Theory of financial intermediation Differences in the preferences of lenders and borrowers (in terms of size, maturity, liquidity, risk) Theory of asset transformation Presence of transaction costs Theory of transaction cost reduction Shocks in consumers’ consumption Liquidity insurance theory Adverse selection Informational economies of scale theory Moral hazard Delegated monitoring theory Table 4.1: Framework for the analysis of the existence of financial intermediation The framework based on transaction costs and asymmetric information has been developed by Professor Charles Goodhart, a member of the Financial Markets Group (FMG) Research Centre at LSE. The FMG is directed by David Webb, an LSE Professor in Finance, and is now one of the leading centres in Europe for academic research into financial markets. In the following sections we will investigate each of the above theories. Asset transformation The simplest way to explain the existence of financial intermediaries is to emphasise their role in transforming particular types of assets into others, the process of asset transformation. Financial intermediaries simultaneously satisfy both borrowers’ needs for permanent or long-term capital and the desires of many lenders for a high degree of liquidity in their asset holdings (assets may be turned into cash at short notice). To reconcile the conflicting requirements of lenders and borrowers, financial intermediaries transform the primary securities issued by firms into the indirect securities required by lenders (Gurley and Shaw, 1960; Fama, 1980). Specifically, they issue liabilities (deposit claims) with the characteristics of low risk, short-term, high liquidity, and use a proportion of these funds to acquire the larger size, high-risk and illiquid claims issued by firms. Therefore, financial intermediaries undertake four main transformations: 1. Maturity transformation: the liabilities of financial intermediaries generally mature more quickly than their assets. The traditional role of banks is to make long-term loans and fund them by issuing shortterm deposits, a process commonly referred to as ‘borrowing short and lending long’. Financial intermediaries are said to be mismatching the maturity of the assets they hold with the maturity of the liabilities they issue. 69 24 Principles of banking and finance 2. Size transformation: the amounts lenders make available are on average smaller than the amounts required by borrowers. Financial intermediaries collect the small amounts made available by lenders and parcel them into the larger amounts required by borrowers. 3. Liquidity transformation: financial intermediaries provide financial or secondary claims to depositors (e.g. bank accounts) that often have superior liquidity features than direct claims (e.g. bonds and stocks). Specifically, deposits are contracts that offer high liquidity and low risk (and they are held in the liabilities side of banks’ balance sheets). Loans instead are illiquid and a higher risk asset than deposits (and they are held in the assets side of banks’ balance sheets). Financial intermediaries (and banks in particular) can hold liabilities and assets of different liquidity features in their balance sheet through diversification of their portfolios. The more diversification, the lower the default probability. 4. Risk transformation: financial intermediaries transform risks to reconcile the preferences of borrowers and lenders. The lenders who hold the liability of the financial intermediaries must be able to regard them as absolutely safe. The intermediaries’ loans, however, inevitably bear some default risk (the risk that the borrower will default on his or her obligations, that he or she will fail to pay interest or repay the loan itself when it is due). The degree (and range) of risk transformation qualifies the type of intermediary. Banks assume on their own the widest degree (and range) of risks. What determines the ability of banks to transform risky loans (assets) into virtually riskless deposits (liabilities)? Try to answer this before reading on. Banks do this in three ways: a. Screening loan applications: this enables the risk of loss on each individual loan to be minimised: the use of credit scoring is one technique banks can use to select only the good borrowers (i.e. good income/earnings or good record on repaying debt). b. Diversifying risk: the spread of risks is achieved by lending to different types of borrowers. Banks try to avoid a heavy concentration in any single branch of economic activity or any single area of the country, and to restrict the maximum size of any single loan. There are many examples of the problems arising from interdependent risks. The failure of 400 Texan banks over the period 1985–89, as a result of the turmoil in the oil economy, was due to the heavy concentration of their loan portfolio in real estate dependent on the oil business. c. Pooling risks: the presence of a large number of loans, as a consequence of the law of large numbers, reduces the variability of losses. The large number of loans does not reduce the expected loss in the portfolio of loans overall, but it is does give considerably improved predictability and limits the maximum loss for which the intermediary has to allow. (Techniques that banks can use to evaluate and manage default risks are discussed in Chapter 6.) This pragmatic perspective highlights the existence of units in surplus (lenders) and units in deficit (borrowers) with heterogeneous preferences as regards the characteristics of financial resources lent and borrowed. Therefore it enables us to move beyond the classical (ideal) world of frictionless and complete financial markets, and introduces some (small) market imperfections. These imperfections obstruct the conclusion of 70 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation financial transactions: lenders and borrowers are not able to diversify perfectly and obtain optimal risk sharing. As a consequence, financial intermediaries are needed to reconcile the conflicting requirements of lenders and borrowers. Although this perspective offers a useful preliminary justification of the existence of financial intermediaries, it is has three main limitations. It does not explain: • why borrowers do not undertake their own asset transformation • why there are different types of financial intermediaries • how different types of intermediaries perform their monetary, credit and allocation functions. In the following sections, we illustrate the main theories about financial intermediation, and we see that these theories provide answers to these three questions. They are the theories of transaction costs, liquidity insurance and asymmetric information. Transaction costs In financial intermediation, transaction costs are incurred because of the time and money spent in performing financial transactions (Coase, 1960). The presence of transaction costs causes difficulties for a potential lender in finding an appropriate borrower. There are four main types of transaction costs: 1. Search costs: costs of searching out, and finding information about, a suitable counterpart (incurred both by lenders and borrowers). 2. Verification costs: lenders incur costs to verify the accuracy of the information provided by borrowers. 3. Monitoring and auditing costs: once a loan is made, lenders incur costs to monitor the activities of borrowers, and their adherence to the conditions of the contract. 4. Enforcement costs: in case the borrower is unable to meet the conditions of the contract, the lender will need to ensure their enforcement. How financial intermediaries reduce transaction costs Financial intermediaries reduce transaction costs by internalising them. Benston and Smith (1976, p.215) state ‘The raison d’être for this industry is the existence of transaction costs.’ Specifically, financial intermediaries reduce transaction costs in a number of ways. First, they develop branch networks and information systems, which enable lenders and borrowers to avoid the need to seek out a suitable counterpart on each occasion. Second, they provide standardised products, thereby cutting the information costs associated with scrutinising individual financial instruments. Third, they use tested procedures and routines. According to the theory of transaction costs, financial institutions are able to reduce transaction costs by taking advantage of the following: • Economies of scale refer to the reduction in transaction costs per dollar of output as the size (scale) of the financial transaction increases. In symbols, in the presence of two outputs (Q1 and Q2), total costs (C) are: C(Q1)<C(Q2) if Q1>Q2. Because of their large size, financial intermediaries are able to combine the funds of many investors. For example, a bank is able to use a standard loan contract for a wide range of loans. The unit cost of the contract per loan is much 71 24 Principles of banking and finance smaller for the bank than for an individual who has a loan contract drawn up when undertaking direct lending. Economies of scale are also important in lowering the costs of fixed investments, such as technology. • Economies of scope are another area of cost savings for financial intermediaries. These economies occur whenever there is a cost advantage to producing more than one product jointly rather than producing them separately. In symbols, C(Q1,Q2)<C(Q1) + C(Q2). Economies of scope are essentially concerned with deposit and payment services: deposits are the legal-financial claims by which banks both collect funds to sustain their lending activities, and satisfy the request of payment instruments. • Expertise to lower transaction cost. For example, they have expertise in information technology (e.g. ATM, automated teller machines, or POS, point of sales) aimed at providing low-cost liquidity services. Activity 4.3 Identify examples of the sort of transaction costs banks can reduce. The theory of transaction costs explains several factors: a. The distribution of financial transactions between financial intermediaries and financial markets. This distribution is based on the level of internalisation of transaction costs. Financial intermediaries are able to internalise many of the transaction costs because they have developed expertise and because they can take advantage of economies of scale and/or economies of scope. The difference in the level of internalisation of transaction costs explains why greater funds flow through financial intermediaries compared to financial markets. Therefore, the presence of transaction costs explains in part why indirect finance is much more important than direct finance. b. The distribution of financial transactions among different types of intermediaries. Each type of intermediary sustains different levels of transaction costs: from simple brokers (pure intermediation) to banks (most complete absorption of transaction costs). c. The presence of payment services (or liquidity services) provided by financial intermediaries, especially by banks. These services make it easier for customers to conduct transactions. This perspective on transaction costs, however, does not help to explain why a financial intermediary makes a better selection of investment opportunities. Moreover, recent technological innovations and new financial instruments have reduced transaction costs. Therefore, reduction in transaction costs cannot be the main reason for explaining the existence of financial intermediaries and additional theories are needed: these include the liquidity insurance theory and the asymmetric information theory. Liquidity needs 72 Economic agents are unsure about when they will require funds to finance consumption due to unforeseen events, and this creates a demand for liquid assets. By the law of large numbers, a large coalition of investors (such as a bank) will be able to invest in illiquid but more profitable assets, while preserving enough liquidity to satisfy the needs of individual investors. This means that financial intermediaries provide liquidity insurance, as postulated in the liquidity insurance theory also known as the consumption smoothing theory (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation How are financial intermediaries able to satisfy liquidity needs? According to the liquidity insurance theory, depository institutions are ‘pools of liquidity’ that provide households with insurance against idiosyncratic shocks that affect their consumption needs. Alternatively they can be seen as ‘consumption smoothers’ that enable economic agents to smooth consumption by offering insurance against shocks to a consumer consumption path. As long as the shocks in consumption needs across households are not perfectly correlated (or rather, they tend not to move together as explained in Chapter 8), the total cash reserve needed by a bank of size N (a coalition of N depositors) increases less than proportionally with N. This is the basic idea of the fractional reserve system, in which some fraction of the deposits can be used to finance profitable but illiquid loans. However, this is also the source of the potential fragility of banks – in the event that many depositors decide to withdraw their funds for reasons other than liquidity needs such as a general loss of confidence in the ability of the bank to remain solvent (as we will see in Chapter 5). Note that this theory is not specific to banks: it is also valid for any depository institution and for insurance companies. Asymmetric information: adverse selection and moral hazard As noted earlier, asymmetric information refers to the situation where one party to a transaction has less information than the other party, and thus is unable to make an accurate decision. This is an important aspect of most types of transactions, and particularly of transactions in financial markets. For example, potential investors in a firm have much less information than the managers of the firm, as they do not know how good the projects to be financed are, and they are not able to evaluate properly the risks and returns of these projects. Also, life insurance companies do not know the precise health of the purchaser of a life insurance policy. Similarly, banks do not know how likely a borrower is to repay. The consequences of asymmetric information can be ex-ante (adverse selection) or ex-post (moral hazard): • Adverse selection is the problem created by asymmetric information before the transaction occurs. It arises when the potential borrowers who are most likely to produce an undesirable (adverse) outcome are the ones who most actively seek out loans. Thus adverse selection increases the probability that bad credit risks will get loans. As a consequence, lenders may decide not to give any loans, even to good credit risks. • Moral hazard is the problem that occurs after the transaction is made. It is the risk (hazard) that the borrower will engage in activities that are undesirable (immoral) for the lender. These activities potentially reduce the probability that the loan will be repaid. Again, the consequence is that lenders may decide not to make any loans. Investors are more likely to behave differently when using borrowed funds rather than when using their own funds. Activity 4.4 As the concepts of adverse selection and moral hazard are extremely useful in understanding the existence, nature and role of financial intermediaries, read the case of Aunt Sheila, Aunt Louise and Uncle Melvin in Mishkin and Eakins (2009) p.27. Then answer the following question: 73 24 Principles of banking and finance How does the adverse selection problem explain why you are more likely to make a loan to a member of your family than to a person not belonging to your family? The concept of asymmetric information was proposed in the seminal contribution of Akerlof (1970). George Akerlof was a professor at the LSE in the late 1970s. He claimed that ‘the difficulty in distinguishing good quality from bad is inherent in the business world; this may explain many economic institutions and may in fact be one of the most important aspects of uncertainty’ (Akerlof, 1970, p.500). His analysis of the market for used cars (consisting of good cars and poor-quality cars) refers to a market where the seller has more information than the buyer regarding the quality of the product. The price the buyer pays must reflect the average quality of the cars in the market (between the low value of a poor-quality car and the high value of a good car). As a result of the adverse selection problem, only the owners of poor-quality cars will be happy to sell at this price, while the owners of good-quality cars will be reluctant to sell at this same price. The equilibrium in the market can be inefficient: the predominance of poor-quality cars implies a low number of transactions carried out in the market, because the buyers are reluctant to purchase a car unless they can obtain additional information. Applying this analysis to financial markets, in a market characterised by asymmetric information, lenders have less information than borrowers. Lenders will therefore charge an interest rate reflecting the average quality (risk) of borrowers in the market. This will be higher than good quality (low risk) borrowers will be willing to pay and so mainly poor quality (high risk) borrowers will seek a loan. So there will be a higher probability that a lender will lend to a high risk borrower. This will reduce the amount of lending that takes place in the market. Activity 4.5 Read the report on the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2001 awarded to George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz (available on the website http://nobelprize.org/nobel_ prizes/economics/laureates/2001/presentation-speech.html). Summarise the seminal contribution of George Akerlof on the analysis of markets with asymmetric information. Make sure you can see how their conclusions relate to financial intermediaries. (Do not spend more than 30 minutes on this activity.) Of interest here is how asymmetric information problems affect lending and borrowing. Asymmetric information can lead to the selection of the borrowers with the higher risk (adverse selection); or to an increase in the risks attached to making a particular loan as a consequence of the opportunistic behaviours of the borrowers (moral hazard). The next section analyses how financial intermediaries attempt to solve these problems. How adverse selection influences financial structure The adverse selection problem significantly affects the securities market (stocks and bonds), where issuers have more information than potential investors. When individual borrowers (firms) have private information on the projects they wish to finance, the functioning of the market can be inefficient. Given that a potential investor is not able to distinguish good (high return/low risk) and bad (low return/high risk) firms, he is inclined to pay a price reflecting the average quality. The owners (managers) of good firms know that their securities are undervalued at this price, and they are not willing to sell. Only bad firms are willing to sell at this price. 74 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation The consequence is that the potential investor has problems in selecting firms to invest in, and is thus most likely to decide not to buy any security in the market. These asymmetries impede the functioning of financial markets: they can either obstruct the conclusion of transactions (and cause the collapse of the market), or influence the level (and the quality) of production activities. Although the existence of organised financial markets partially reduces some of these problems, the solution to them has been the emergence of financial intermediaries, as shown in the next sections. The adverse selection problem explains one empirical fact emphasised above: why marketable securities – and stocks in particular – are not the primary source of external financing for firms. How to reduce/solve the problems arising from adverse selection To solve the adverse selection problem in financial markets, full information on the borrowers should be provided to the lenders. The following solutions exist to reduce/solve the adverse selection problem: 1. Private production and sale of information. 2. Government regulation. 3. Financial intermediaries. First, private companies can produce and sell the information needed by potential investors to distinguish good and bad firms and to select their securities. Information concerns the financial statements of firms and their investment activities. In the United States, private companies such as Standard and Poor’s, Moody’s and Value Line do this. Standard and Poor’s categorises corporate bond issuers into at least seven major classes according to perceived credit quality. The first four quality ratings – AAA, AA, A, BBB – indicate quality investment borrowers. (Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), Table 10.2, p.249, for a description of debt ratings.) The ratings below BBB are considered to be below investment grade and are sometimes referred to as junk bonds. Why do you think investors are willing to buy junk bonds? Activity 4.6 Analyse the Credit Model developed by Standard and Poor’s. Find out relevant information on their website (www.standardandpoors.com), under the section Products and Services. How do you think a firm reacts to a low rating by Standard and Poor’s? Adverse selection is not completely solved by the private production and sale of information because of the free-rider problem. This occurs when people who do not pay for information take advantage of information acquired by other people. If you buy the information on the quality of firms, as described in the last activity, you can use it to purchase undervalued securities of good firms. However, other investors (freeriders), who have not purchased the information, may observe your behaviour and buy the same security at the same time. The increase in the demand for the undervalued security will cause a build-up in its price to the true value. The effect is to negate the value of information. The freerider problem explains why investors are reluctant to buy information. Thus the adverse selection problem remains. Second, governments take steps to ensure that firms disclose full information to potential investors. In fact, financial markets are among the most heavily regulated sectors in the economy. In the USA, the Securities 75 24 Principles of banking and finance and Exchange Commission (SEC) is the government agency entrusted to promote the adherence to standard accounting principles and disclosure of information. However, disclosure requirements do not solve the adverse selection problem, as the recent collapse of the Enron Corporation demonstrates (refer to Box on p.374 of Mishkin and Eakins (2009)). Activity 4.7 Visit the website of the Securities and Exchange Commission, SEC (www.sec.gov/about/ whatwedo.shtml). Then find the equivalent authority in your own country, and what the main disclosure requirements are. If they are different, see if you can work out why, on the basis of the differences between your country and the USA. Third, financial intermediaries, and especially banks, produce more accurate valuations of firms and are able to select good credit risks thanks to their expertise in information production. One particular advantage that banks may have in relation to information production is information about potential borrowers from the transactions on their bank accounts: banks obtain a profile of the suitability for credit (and ability to repay the loan) from the accounts of their customers. By acquiring funds from depositors and lending them to good firms, banks earn returns on their loans that are higher than the interest paid to their depositors. Although it does not take into account the possibility that firms provide information to the market, the asymmetric information theory offers a convincing explanation of the existence of financial intermediaries. An important element of this explanation is that banks are able to avoid the free-rider problem because their loans are private securities, not traded in the open financial market. Therefore investors are not able to observe the bank and bid up the price of the loan to the point where the bank makes no profit on the production of information. Moreover, banks reduce the adverse selection problem by asking the borrower to provide collateral against the loan. Collateral is property promised to the lender if the borrower defaults. Therefore it reduces the losses of the lender in the event of a default. Activity 4.8 Can you explain how the presence of collateral reduces the adverse selection problem? Try to use an example. For instance, you want to borrow £1 million to buy a health and fitness club and you own a building whose value is £1.2 million. Therefore, financial intermediaries solve the adverse selection problem, whereas the private production of information and government regulation only reduce it. The presence of adverse selection explains: 1. why bank loans are the most important source of funds raised externally 2. why indirect finance is many times more important than direct finance. Further, there are several interesting corollaries: i. Banks are even more important in developing countries than in developed countries, because information about private firms is even harder to collect than in developed countries. ii. Large and well-known corporations have easier access to securities markets as the investors have more information about them. 76 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation iii. Recent improvements in information technology makes the acquisition of information easier for firms, and thus reduces the lending role of financial institutions. The empirical evidence in the United States in the last 20 years confirms this, as discussed in the last section of this chapter. A theory on financial intermediaries and adverse selection: informational economies of scale In the presence of adverse selection, there are scale economies in the lending-borrowing activity. In such a context, financial intermediaries can be seen as ‘information sharing coalitions’ as argued by Leland and Pyle (1977) in the informational economies of scale theory. Entrepreneurs can ‘signal’ the quality of their projects by investing more or less of their wealth in the firm. This partially reduces the adverse selection problem, since good firms can be separated from bad firms by the level of self-financing. However, if entrepreneurs are risk-averse, the ‘signalling’ is costly (i.e. good entrepreneurs are obliged to retain a substantial amount of the risk of their project). Nevertheless, information (not publicly available) on the quality of the projects can be obtained with an expenditure of resources. Interestingly, this information can benefit potential lenders. If there are economies of scale in the production of this information, specific organisations may exist to gather this information. Two problems hamper firms that sell information to investors: a. Quality of the information: buyers may not be able to ascertain the quality of the information (i.e. the distinction between good and bad information will not be apparent). As a consequence the price of the information will reflect average quality (as in the analysis by Akerlof above) so that firms that seek out high quality information will lose money.; b. Appropriability of returns, also referred to as free-rider problem (as discussed above, buyers may be able to share or resell the information to others, without diminishing its usefulness). Thus the firm that originally collected the information may not be able to recoup the value of the information. Both these problems can be solved if the firm gathering the information is a financial intermediary (such as a bank), buying and holding assets on the basis of its specialised information. Thus the information becomes embodied in its portfolio and hence, is not transferable. This provides an incentive for the gathering of this information. Once an organisation becomes better able than other lenders to sort classes of risks, borrowers of good risk wish to be identified, and to deal with an informationally efficient intermediary rather than with a set of lenders offering the value of the average risk. With the best risk ‘peeled off’, the average risk is less valuable, inducing borrowers of the next best risk to deal with the intermediary. Ultimately, borrowers of all types of risk will deal with intermediaries, with the only exception being the bottom class. How moral hazard influences financial markets Moral hazard has consequences for whether firms find it easier to raise funds with debt rather than with equity contracts: • Moral hazard in equity contracts qualifies as a special type known as the principal-agent problem (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Stockholders (called principals) own most of the firm’s equity, but they are not the same people as the managers (agents) of the 77 24 Principles of banking and finance firm. Managers have more information about their activities than stockholders so that there is asymmetric information. The separation of ownership and control, together with the asymmetric information, induce managers to act in their own interest rather than in the interest of stockholder-owners (i.e. managers have fewer incentives to maximise profits than stockholders). • Moral hazard in debt contracts is lower than in equity contracts but is still present. Debt contracts require borrowers to pay fixed amounts and let them keep any profit above this amount. Consequently, borrowers have incentives to take investments riskier than lenders would like. How to reduce/solve the problems arising from moral hazard in equity markets Several tools can be used to reduce/solve moral hazard in the equity market: 1. Monitoring. 2. Government regulation to increase information. 3. Financial intermediaries active in the equity market. 4. Debt contracts. First, stockholders can engage in the monitoring (auditing) of firms’ activities to reduce moral hazard. Several reasons explain why monitoring is needed: • to ensure that information asymmetry is not exploited by one party at the expense of the other • the value of equity contracts cannot be certain when the contract is made • the value of many financial contracts (i.e. future return on a stock) cannot be observed or verified at the moment of purchase, and the post-contract behaviour of a counterparty determines the ultimate value of the contract • the long-term nature of many financial contracts implies that information acquired before the contract is agreed may become irrelevant at the maturity due to changes in conditions. Nevertheless monitoring is expensive in terms of money and time, or rather it is a costly state verification. In addition, if you know that other stockholders are paying to monitor the activities of the firm you hold stocks in, you can free-ride on the activities of the others. As every stockholder can free-ride on others, the free-rider problem reduces the amount of monitoring that would reduce the moral hazard (principalagent) problem. This is the same as with adverse selection and makes equity contracts less desirable. Second, governments have incentives to reduce the moral hazard problem (just as with adverse selection). Several measures are used by governments: laws to force firms to adhere to standard accounting principles (i.e. to make profit verification easier); laws to impose stiff criminal penalties on people who commit the fraud of hiding/stealing profits. However, these measures are only partially effective as these frauds are difficult to discover. Third, financial intermediaries operating in the equity market are able to avoid the moral hazard problem. Venture capital firms are an example of an intermediary able to reduce moral hazard and avoid the free-rider problem.. They use their funds to help entrepreneurs to start 78 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation new businesses. In exchange for the use of the venture capital, the firm receives an equity share in the new business. Venture capital firms have their own people participating in the management of the firm (i.e. easier profit verification and thus lower moral hazard). Moreover, the equity in the firm is not marketable to anyone but the venture capital firm (i.e. this eliminates the free-riding of other investors on the venture capital’s verification activities). Fourth, debt contracts are a way to reduce moral hazard. Moral hazard affects equity contracts because they are claims on profits in all situations, whether the firm makes or loses money. Consequently, there is the need to structure a contract that confines moral hazard to certain situations, and thus reduces the need to monitor managers. This is a debt contract, a contractual agreement to pay the lender a fixed amount of money independently from the profits of the firm. Therefore debt contracts are preferred to equity contracts as they require less monitoring . The presence of moral hazard in equity markets explains why stocks are not the most important external source of financing for firms. How to reduce/solve the problems arising from moral hazard in debt markets Although debt contracts reduce the amount of moral hazard in comparison to equity contracts, they do not solve the problem. Borrowers have incentives to take investments riskier than lenders would like: borrowers, get all the gains from a risky investment if they succeed, but lenders lose most, if not all, of their loan, if borrowers do not succeed. The solution to the problems of moral hazard lies again in financial intermediaries. However, other tools also enable us to reduce moral hazard. The full range of tools includes: 1. making debt contracts incentive-compatible (i.e. align the incentives of borrowers and lenders) 2. monitoring and enforcement of restrictive covenants 3. financial intermediaries. First, borrowers are more likely to take on riskier investment projects when using borrowed funds than when using their own funds. Thus the moral hazard problem can be reduced by increasing the stake of borrowers own personal net worth (the difference between personal assets and liabilities) in the investment project. Now that borrowers could potentially lose some of their wealth if the project fails they have an incentive to make the project less risky. Thus, one way to reduce the moral hazard problem is to make the debt contract incentive-compatible, or rather to align the incentives of the borrowers and lenders. Activity 4.9 How does the moral hazard problem explain why you are more willing to make a loan to a borrower who uses his own capital to finance two-thirds of the total value of a project than one who uses of one-third? A second way in which the moral hazard problem can be reduced is by introducing restrictive covenants into debt contracts. A restrictive covenant is a provision aimed at restricting the borrower’s activity. There are four types of possible covenants: 1. Those which discourage undesirable behaviour by the borrower (i.e. not to undertake risky investment projects). Examples are: 79 24 Principles of banking and finance i. to use the debt contract only to finance specific activities, such as the purchase of a fixed asset ii. to prohibit the firm from issuing new debt, or disposing of its assets iii. to restrict dividend payments if some ratios (such as the leverage ratio, the ratio of debt to equity) has not reached a critical level iv. to limit purchases of major assets or merger activities. 2. Those which encourage desirable behaviour from the lender’s point of view. One example is a mortgage loan with a provision that requires the borrower to purchase life insurance that pays off the loan in the event of the borrower’s death. 3. Covenants that keep collateral valuable. 4. Covenants that provide information about the activities of the borrowing firm, such as quarterly accounting and income reports. The presence of covenants reduces moral hazard problems and explains why debt contracts are often complicated legal documents. Activity 4.10 Are accounts always reliable? In every country? Is this a problem where you live – untrustworthy accounts? What does this mean for moral hazard? Third, although covenants reduce moral hazard problems, they do not eliminate them: it is not possible to rule out every risky activity. Moreover, in order to make covenants effective, they must be monitored and enforced. Monitoring typically involves increasing returns to scale, which implies that it is more efficiently performed by specialised financial institutions. We made this point earlier in this chapter – look back to refresh your memory. Individual lenders tend to delegate the monitoring activities instead of performing them directly. Thus the monitor has to be given an incentive to do its job properly. However, because monitoring and enforcement are costly activities, investors can free-ride on the monitoring and enforcement undertaken by other investors. Thus in the bond market (as well as in the stock market) the free-rider problem arises. The consequence will be that insufficient resources will be devoted to these activities. Financial intermediaries, and especially banks, can be seen to provide solutions both to the incentive problem and to the free-rider problem. They solve the incentive problem using several mechanisms, such as reputation effects, and the option for depositors to withdraw their money should the bank managers prove incompetent. They do not face the same free-rider problem, as they primarily make private loans not traded on the market. Banks therefore gain the full benefits of their monitoring and enforcement activities and have an incentive to devote sufficient resources to them. The possibility of overcoming moral hazard with adequate instruments (such as screening and monitoring), favoured by the existence of established long-term relationships, enables this theory to emphasise the special nature and role of banks in the allocation process. Activity 4.11 Explain how loan contracts solve free-riding problems in a better way than bond contracts. If you need help, look at the Essential reading (Mishkin and Eakins, 2009, Chapter 15). 80 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation A theory on financial intermediaries and moral hazard: delegated monitoring Since monitoring borrowers is costly, it is efficient for surplus units (lenders) to delegate the task of monitoring to specialised agents such as banks. Banks have a comparative advantage relative to direct lending in monitoring activities in the context of costly state verification. In fact, they have a better ability to reduce monitoring costs because of their ability to diversify loans. This is the main idea of the delegated monitoring theory, as formulated by Diamond (1984). Several conditions are required for delegated monitoring to work: • existence of scale economies in monitoring, which means that a typical bank finances many projects • small capacity of investors as compared to the size of investments, which means that each project needs the funds of several investors • low cost of delegation, which means that the cost of monitoring the financial intermediary itself has to be less than the benefit gained from exploiting scale economies in monitoring investment projects. The framework of the delegated monitoring theory, as provided in Diamond (1984), is based on: the existence of n identical firms that seek to finance projects and the requirement by each firm of an investment of one unit. The cash flow y that the firm obtains from its investment is a priori unobservable to lenders. This is where moral hazard arises. Moral hazard can be solved by: • either ‘monitoring’ the firm (at cost K) • or ‘designing’ a debt contract characterised by a non-pecuniary cost C (i.e. unmonitored direct lending) Assume that K<C. If the firm has a unique financier, it would be efficient to choose the monitoring option. However, assume that each investor has available to lend only 1/m, so that m of them are needed for financing a project. Assume also that the total number of investors is m*n, so that all the projects can be financed. Direct lending implies that each of the m investors monitors the financed firm: the total cost is n*m*K. If a bank (financial intermediary) emerges, it can monitor each firm (total cost n*K). The benefits of a bank monitoring the debt arises from the specialised skill that a bank possesses and a reduction in the duplication of effort. Thus it makes sense for the bank to become a delegated monitor, which monitors borrowers on behalf of lenders (note that the bank is not monitored by its lenders – the depositors). Financial intermediation (delegated monitor) dominates direct lending as soon as n is large enough: this means that diversification exists (i.e. a large number of loans is held by the intermediary). Diversification is important because it reduces risk to the bank and so increases the probability that the intermediary has sufficient loan proceeds to repay a fixed debt claim to depositors. Before moving to the next section, focus your attention on Table 4.2, which provides a summary of the corollaries of the asymmetric information problem, the ways to reduce/solve the market imperfections and the relevant financial intermediation theories. 81 24 Principles of banking and finance Type of asymmetric information Adverse selection Moral hazard Corollaries Free-rider problem Principal-agent problem Ways to reduce/solve the market imperfection Private production Monitoring of equity contracts Government regulation Government regulation Financial intermediaries Debt contracts Free-rider problem Monitoring and enforcement of covenants Financial intermediaries Theory of financial intermediation Informational economies of scale (Leland and Pyle, 1977) Delegated monitoring (Diamond, 1984) Table 4.2: Asymmetric information problems and ways to reduce/solve them What is the future for financial intermediaries? The relevance of traditional banking has declined in recent years in countries such as the USA and the UK. The share of financial assets held by different types of US financial intermediaries changed over the period 1970–2005. As shown in Figure 4.2, since 1970 the bank share of financial assets has steadily declined, and thrift institutions (primarily savings and loan associations) have lost even more ground than banks. However, over the same period some other types of intermediaries, notably mutual companies, have increased their market share dramatically. (Read Boyd and Gertler, 1994.) Before reading further, see if you can guess why banks have lost out in some ways. Do you think they have been able to make gains in other directions? Think how they have done this. We shall see below that there is an interesting story of both decline and increase. The decline in the share of financial assets held by banks does not necessarily indicate that the banking industry is in decline. In fact we have two indicators that banks have been doing quite well. First, both the ratio of US commercial bank assets to nominal gross domestic product (GDP) and the ratio of commercial bank loans to nominal GDP increased over the last four decades (Boyd and Gettler, 1994). Second, as shown in Figures 4.2 and 4.3, US banking profitability relative to GDP has shown a sharp increase from 1992 and remained substantially stable over the 1993– 2006 period, after a bad performance in the late 1980s and early 1990s (Mishkin and Eakins, 2009). Specifically, the US banking return on equity (ROE) was 13.86 per cent in 1992 and 13.06 per cent in 2006, with a maximum of 16.03 per cent in 1993; return on assets (ROA) was 0.94 per cent in 1992 and 1.33 per cent in 2006 with a maximum of 1.4 in 2003. Similarly, EU banking ROE rose to just under 20 per cent in 2005 (up from 16.5 per cent in 2004) with a degree of dispersion of performances around the average ROE considerably narrower in 2005 compared with 2004. 82 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Insurance companies Pension funds Finance companies 1970 Mutual funds 1980 1990 Commercial banks 2002 S&Ls Credit unions 2005 Figure 4.2: Shares of financial assests held by different types of US financial intermediairies over the period 1970–2005 Source: Graph created using data from US Federal Reserve Flow of Funds Accounts, 9 June 2005. 1,6 1,4 1,2 1 0,8 0,6 0,4 0,2 20 06 20 05 20 04 20 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 19 99 19 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 91 19 90 19 89 19 88 19 87 19 86 19 85 19 84 19 83 19 82 19 81 19 80 0 Figure 4.3: Return on assets % 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 20 06 20 05 20 04 20 03 20 02 20 01 20 00 19 99 19 98 19 97 19 96 19 95 19 94 19 93 19 92 19 91 19 90 19 89 19 88 19 87 19 86 19 85 19 84 19 83 19 82 19 81 19 80 0 Figure 4.4: Return on equity % Source: Graph created using data fromt he FDIC website (www2.fdic.gov/qbp). 83 24 Principles of banking and finance This complex picture can be explained by looking at two main areas of banking activity (Mishkin and Eakins, 2009, Chapter 18): 1. Reduction in cost advantages in acquiring funds: in the 1960s the increase in inflation, associated with the regulatory restriction on interest payable on checkable deposits, increased the investors’ sensitivity to interest rate differentials. Therefore low-cost deposits from the public were not as readily available as a source of funds for banks. This had three main consequences. • First, a disintermediation process occurred: the low interest rate on chequeable and time deposits induced investors to take their money out of banks and to look for higher-yielding investment opportunities. • Second, money market mutual funds appeared in the early 1980s and grew dramatically in the USA: this new financial intermediary issued shares (like mutual funds) to raise funds to be invested in short-term money market securities, on which investors get interest payments. Moreover, they enable the investor to write cheques against the held shares (like banks), although they are not legally deposits and are not subject to reserve requirements and prohibitions on interest payments. As a result investors could both obtain checking account-like services and earn high interest. • Third, in the 1980s changes in regulation (elimination of ceilings on time deposit interest rates) helped banks in the competitive process for the acquisition of funds, but involved them in higher costs. Thus banks experienced a reduced cost-competitive advantage over other institutions. 2. Reduction in income advantages in using funds: • First, improvements in information technology and the diffusion of credit rating agencies make it easier for firms to issue securities directly to the public. These securities are either short-term (commercial papers) or long-term (bonds). Because investors can screen out bad and good credit risks, firms go to the cheaper commercial paper market – rather than to banks – to raise short-term funds. For the same reason, firms go to the bond market – and use banks less often – even if they are less well-known corporations with lower credit ratings. This explains the development of the so-called junk bond market, or rather long-term corporate bonds whose ratings have fallen below a given score calculated in accordance with credit rating agencies (rated below Baa by Moody’s rating agency or BBB by S&P). • Second, improvements in information technology and statistical methods favoured the process of securitisation, which is the process of transforming illiquid financial assets (such as loans and mortgages) into marketable securities (see Figure 4.5 to get a sense of the increase in the relevance of securitisation in the EU). Financial intermediaries can cheaply bundle together a portfolio of loans (e.g. mortgages, credit card receivables, commercial and computer leases) with varying small denominations (often less than $100,000), collect the interest and principal payments on the loans in the bundle, and then pay them out to third parties. By dividing the portfolio of loans into standardised amounts, the claims to the principal and interests can be sold to third parties as securities. These securities are liquid and well diversified. Financial institutions make profits by servicing the loans and charge a fee to the third party for this service. The development of securitisation allows other financial institutions, and not only banks, to originate loans, accurately evaluate credit risks, bundle these loans and sell 84 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation them as securities. Banks have therefore lost their advantage in the loan business. Of course, securitisation reached a peak in 2007 but has declined dramatically following the problems with securitised subprime mortgage debt and other securitised debt products during the financial crisis of 2007–09 – see Chapter 3 for more details. 250 € billions 200 150 100 50 0 '97 '98 '99 '00 '01 '02 '03 Figure 4.5: Securitisation activities in the EU (1997–2003) Source: Graph created using data from www.europeansecuritisation.com. Activity 4.12 What is the relevance of traditional banking in your country in comparison to the situation in the USA? How can you link this evidence with the arguments on bank-oriented systems and market-oriented systems presented in Chapter 3? What are the reactions of banks to this decline in their intermediation role? 1. They have expanded into new, riskier areas of lending (e.g. lending to real estate companies, to corporate takeovers and to leverage buyouts). The higher risk associated with these new areas of lending is well illustrated by the problems of the Japanese banking system in the 1990s. As a consequence of the deregulation process, Japanese banks expanded their lending rapidly during the 1980s. In particular, bank lending was increasingly directed towards the real estate and construction sectors. A sharp increase in interest rates in 1990 burst the asset price bubble, and land prices declined sharply over several years. This caused the emergence of a large number of ‘bad loans’ (loans that would not be repaid in full, if at all). Moreover, the economic downturn in Japan and the crisis in Asia have produced a further deterioration in bank loan portfolios. During 1997, the problems in the banking system became increasingly apparent when an attempted merger between the tenth largest commercial bank in Japan – Hokkaido Takushoku Bank – and a smaller regional bank stalled, leading to the collapse of the larger bank. Similar problems affected banks in the US and Europe during the financial crisis of 2007–09 as banks lent to borrowers to finance house purchases in a period of rapidly rising house prices. When the housing bubble burst the banks found themselves with large amounts of bad debt. This created serious solvency problems for many banks. 85 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 4.13 Read the International Monetary Fund Survey (August 17, 1998: pp.253–55) available at: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/pdf/081798.pdf. Write a one-page essay explaining the reasons for the Japanese banking sector problems, emphasising the failure of Hokkaido Takushoku bank. 2. Banks are now pursuing new off-balance sheet activities, such as loan commitments and letters of credit. These activities produce fee income instead of interest income. Note that total bank income can be expressed as the sum of net interest income (earnings from balance sheet assets net of interest costs) and non-interest income (non-interest earnings from off-balance activities). There has been a strong increase in income from off-balance sheet activities as a share of total bank income in the period since the 1960s. Given that the total profitability of banks has been substantially stable in this same period, this implies that the share of traditional banking businesses has declined. However, note that non-traditional activities might be riskier for banks. 3. Banks have also increased proprietary trading whereby they hold positions in assets and derivatives for speculative purposes (hoping to profit from price changes). This increased dramatically in the 15 years prior to the 2007 financial crisis. Of course a bank’s trading activities give rise to market risk which is discussed in more detail in Chapter 5. Activity 4.14 Visit the FDIC website at www2.fdic.gov/SDI/SOB/ and answer the following questions (produce a graph to support your answer): What is the share of the income of US banks coming from off-balance sheet activities? What was the trend during the period 1992–2006? Summary In this chapter we investigated how several theories explain why there are financial intermediaries. They exist to: • transform assets in order to satisfy simultaneously the different requirements of lenders and borrowers in terms of maturity, size and risk • reduce transaction costs by taking advantage of economies of scale, economies of scope and expertise • satisfy the liquidity needs of individual investors • reduce problems arising out of asymmetric information. On the one hand, financial intermediaries reduce adverse selection thanks to their expertise in information production and their ability to avoid the freerider problem by issuing private securities (loans) against collateral. On the other hand, they reduce moral hazard because they gain the full benefits of their monitoring and enforcement, and have an incentive to devote sufficient resources to these activities. The final issue concerns the future of financial intermediaries. The traditional intermediation services provided by banks have declined in recent years, and banks have sought to maintain profits by expansion into other areas of business. However, this expansion exposed banks to new and greater risks and contributed to the financial crisis of 2007–09. 86 Chapter 4: Role of financial intermediation Key terms adverse selection asset transformation asymmetric information delegated monitoring theory disintermediation diversifying risks economies of scale system economies of scope fractional reserve system free-rider problem informational economies of scale theory liquidity insurance theory liquidity transformation market imperfections maturity transformation moral hazard pooling risks principal-agent problem risk transformation Securities and Exchange Commision securitisation size transformation transaction costs theory of transaction costs A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why financial intermediaries exist • discuss how the presence of market imperfections explains the importance of financial intermediaries (and the relative unimportance of financial markets) in the financing of corporations • explain how financial intermediaries are able to reduce the transaction cost problem • explain how financial intermediaries are able to reduce/solve the problems arising from adverse selection and moral hazard • discuss the expected developments affecting the role of the different types of financial intermediaries (especially banks) in the future. Sample examination questions 1. Discuss how the key economic theories of financial intermediation enable us to understand the existence (and relevance) of financial intermediaries. 2. a. Describe how the presence of market imperfections explains the importance of financial intermediaries (and the relative unimportance of financial markets) in the financing of corporations. b. What are the forms of asset transformation undertaken by banks? 3. a. Explain how financial intermediaries are able to reduce transaction costs in the economy. b. Explain how financial intermediaries are able to reduce/solve the problems arising from adverse selection and moral hazard. 4. a. b. Explain the hypotheses, the framework and the main findings of the delegated monitoring theory. How is the free-rider problem related to information asymmetries in financial markets? 5. ‘There is evidence that traditional banking has declined in recent years in countries such as the USA and the UK.’ Discuss. 87 24 Principles of banking and finance 6. a. b. 88 What factors have caused the decline in the share of financial assets held by the US banks in recent years? What have been the main consequences of disintermediation for banks? Chapter 5: Regulation of banks Chapter 5: Regulation of banks Aims The aim of this chapter is to discuss the main reasons for the existence of banking regulation in most countries, and to illustrate the key economic reasons for and against banking regulation. Furthermore, it describes how regulation occurs in practice by analysing general issues of regulation and by giving some practical examples of the application of regulation (mainly in the USA, UK and New Zealand). Finally it examines the deficiencies in the regulatory framework revealed by the global financial crisis of 2007– 09 and examines the response of the regulatory bodies in their attempt to address these deficiencies. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why banks need regulation • illustrate the main cases of non-regulated banking systems in history and explain their economic rationale • explain the main arguments for and against the regulation of banking systems • explain how banks are regulated through traditional regulation mechanisms • discuss the problems with the traditional regulation mechanisms revealed by the global financial crisis of 2007–09 • evaluate the response of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision to the global financial crisis of 2007–09 • illustrate alternative regulation mechanisms • discuss the main implications of the recent trend in harmonising bank regulation across the world. Essential reading Dow, S. ‘Why the banking system should be regulated’, Economic Journal 106(436) 1996, pp.698–707. Dowd, K. ‘The Case for Financial Laissez-Faire’, Economic Journal 96(106) 1996, pp.679–87. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapter 20. Further reading Buckle, M. and J. Thompson The UK Financial System. (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2004)] Chapter 17. Freixas, X. and J.C. Rochet Microeconomics of Banking. (Boston, Mass.: The MIT Press, 2008) Chapter 9. Heffernan, S. Modern Banking. (Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, 2005) Chapters 4 and 5. Sinkey, J.F. Commercial Bank Financial Management in the Financial-Services Industry. (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education, 2002) Chapter 16. 89 24 Principles of banking and finance References Bank of England Discussion Paper ‘The role of macroprudential policy’, November 2009 (download from www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/ other/financialstability/roleofmacroprudentialpolicy091121.pdf) Freixas, X. C. Giannini, G. Hoggart and F. Soussa ‘Lender of last resort: a review of the literature’, Bank of England Financial Stability Review, November 1999 Kay, J. ‘Narrow banking: the reform of banking regulation’, Centre for the study of Financial Innovation, publication no. 88, September 2009 (also download from www.johnkay.com/wp-content/uploads/2009/12/JKNarrow-Banking.pdf). Mortlock, G. ‘New Zealand’s financial sector regulation’, Reserve Bank of New Zealand: Bulletin (2003) 66, pp.5–49. Introduction Several arguments on banking regulation deserve our attention: 1. Banking regulation now exists in virtually every country with a welldeveloped banking system. In fact, it is practically impossible to study the theory of banking without referring to bank regulation. Nevertheless, non-regulated banking systems have been introduced in some countries (so-called free banking). 2. In most countries the banking system is more heavily regulated than any other sector of the economy. 3. Banking regulation takes several forms, through the adoption of various regulation mechanisms. 4. A recent trend towards greater harmonisation of bank regulation across the major banking systems of the world is occurring. 5. The financial crisis of 2007–09 revealed several deficiencies in the system of bank regulation used in most countries. We address the following questions: • Why do banks need regulations? • Why not permit free banking within a market system, with the users making their own assessment of the quality of the liabilities issued by banks? • What are the reasons for and against regulation? • Why are banks singled out for special regulation? • What are the traditional regulation mechanisms? • What are the main problems in traditional regulation methods revealed by the financial crisis of 2007–09? • What has been the response of the regulatory authorities to the deficiencies in bank regulation revealed by the financial crisis? • Is there any alternative regulation mechanism? • What are the reasons for the recent international harmonisation in banking regulation? Free banking As a starting point, consider why regulation is required at all. Take a financial system that is unregulated – so-called free banking. This involves a financial system with no central bank or any other financial or monetary regulator, and no government intervention. It therefore allows financial 90 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks institutions to operate freely, subject only to market forces and the rules of ‘normal’ commercial and contract law. Free banking is an example of financial laissez-faire. One example of a free banking era was to be found in the USA from 1838 until 1863. Other relatively unregulated systems have been those in Scotland (1716–1845), Switzerland (after the Liberal revolution in the 1830s and 1840s until 1881), Canada (1820–1935) and Hong Kong (1935–64). A free banking system consists of banks whose deposits are largely repayable on demand and where those deposits are used as payment instruments. However, there is no central bank, no supervision of or restriction on the activities of banks, and no state insurance scheme for deposits. Free banks issue distinct private monies, called bank notes. These bank notes are perpetual, non-interest bearing debt claims that can be redeemed on demand. However, these bank notes are subject to the risk of failure of the issuer, and redemption means having to travel to the issuing bank. Two main arguments are made against private money issuance: • Some banks can over-issue their currency, making the conversion impossible (so-called wildcat banking). • Transaction costs increase when thousands (three thousand in the case of the USA and Canada in their periods of free banking) of distinct bank notes circulate in a given geographical area. The traditional, dominant view is that free banking is inherently unstable because of market failures arising from factors, natural monopolies and information symmetry. Free banking causes counterfeiting, wildcat banking, fraudulent banking, over-issue of bank notes and over-expansion by banks. Free banks are therefore prone to failures and lead to systemic banking instability. As a consequence several reasons have been advocated to justify banking regulation (as discussed in the next section). During the US free banking era, bank failures in Indiana, Wisconsin and Minnesota are usually cited as evidence of the instability of free banking. This traditional, negative view has come under increased scrutiny since the 1970s. Indeed, the failure of regulators to prevent the banking crisis of 2007–09 has again raised doubts about the ability of regulators to maintain a stable banking system. Even if bank regulation is present today in virtually every country, a small but growing number of economists are still in favour of free banking. One of the major arguments provided for the soundness of a free banking system is that competition in the supply of money forces banks to maintain either their reputation or convertibility of their liabilities (bank notes or deposits) into species or real commodities, which in turn prevents banks from over-issuing money. In contrast, a self-correcting mechanism does not exist under a monopolised supply of money by the government. Therefore free banking is more stable than central banking. In terms of regulation of the banking system, in the absence of a regulator and deposit insurance system depositors would become much more aware that if their bank failed they would lose their deposit. Depositors would therefore require greater reassurance that their deposit is safe. How would banks be able to provide that reassurance? There are essentially three mechanisms that banks can use: i. disclose lots of information including audited accounts 91 24 Principles of banking and finance ii. pursue prudent lending policies iii. hold adequate amounts of capital. These three mechanisms are interrelated with i more likely to lead to the pursuit of ii and iii. The question of what constitutes an adequate amount of capital is difficult to answer. The more capital a bank holds, the more resilient it is in the face of shocks (i.e. the more able the bank is to maintain its solvency in the event of losses). However, capital is costly – shareholders have to be paid dividends. A discussion of the importance of capital in the regulation of banking is covered later in this chapter. Free bankers argue that in a competitive banking system market forces would determine the optimal level of capital. If depositors want high levels of reassurance they will choose to place their deposits in banks holding high levels of capital. Please read Dowd (1996), an advocate of free banking, for further discussion. In your reading consider the following point in particular. Free bankers argue that in a banking system with no regulator, the market would regulate. Note that the market is essentially made up of the providers of finance to the bank (i.e. depositors, shareholders etc.). Think about how depositors and shareholders might regulate banks – note that regulation aims to encourage good, and discourage imprudent, behaviour. Why do banks need regulations? Several economic and non-economic reasons have been given to justify banking regulations. These include: to protect depositors, to assure the safety and soundness of banks, to avoid (or to limit) the effects of bank failures, to maintain monetary stability, to protect the payment system and to encourage efficiency and competition in the financial system and in the economy. Sudipto Bhattacharya, Professor of Finance at LSE, is an expert of financial intermediation and has studied the economics of bank regulation. The economic arguments on bank regulation can be properly understood by keeping in mind the pivotal position of banks in the financial system, especially in the payment systems, and in the financing (as a dominant or exclusive lender) of a large number of borrowers (as discussed in the previous chapter). This section examines the pros and cons of bank regulation in three domains: the fragility of banks, systemic risk and the protection of depositors. Fragility of banks The history of financial systems (as discussed in Chapter 3) shows that bank panics have been common in Europe and the USA throughout modern history (and in many emerging countries in recent years). When banks started to finance illiquid loans through demand deposits, most recessions were accompanied by loss of public confidence in the banking system, often leading to bank panics. At first, banks privately developed cooperative systems to protect their collective reputation. These systems were later taken on and transformed by central banks when governments decided to impose controls on banking systems. Moreover central banks started to offer ‘lender of last resort’ facilities in times of financial crises: central banks act as the ultimate supplier of liquidity to bank(s) threatened by a liquidity crisis. In recent times, central banks have led lifeboat rescues, whereby healthy banks take over the deposits of the troubled banks. 92 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks The fragility of banks derives from the combination of the two main functions. • One source of fragility is the role of banks in providing liquidity insurance to households (as discussed in Chapter 4). Banks can be considered as pools of liquidity to households that can deposit funds as insurance against shocks that affect their consumption needs. Some fraction of these deposits can be used by banks to finance profitable but illiquid investments (the so-called fractional reserve system). This represents a source of potential fragility of banks, if a high number of depositors all at once decide to withdraw their funds for reasons other than those of normal liquidity needs. • A source of mitigation of fragility is the role of banks in screening and monitoring borrowers who cannot obtain direct finance from financial markets. As we saw in Chapter 4, banks are able to produce a more accurate valuation of firms than other companies, and are also able to select good credit risks thanks to their expertise in information production. The nature of these two core services to depositors and borrowers explains the financial structure of banks: liquid liabilities (deposits) and illiquid assets (loans). This in turn explains the vulnerability of banks to runs. Systemic risk A crucial role of bank regulation, and specifically of central bank operations, is to prevent systemic risk (as we discussed in Chapter 3). This is the risk that the failure of a particular bank spreads to other, solvent banks. This happens because depositors are unable to distinguish between good and bad banks. The run on one bank, which can be justified if the bank has been imprudent, will lead to a run on solvent banks because of the asymmetric information problem. A solvent bank facing a run will quickly run out of liquidity to meet deposit withdrawals because most of its assets are long term in nature and cannot easily be liquidated. This is the fragility problem discussed above. A bank facing such a run may engage in a ‘fire-sale’ of assets (where assets are sold cheaply in order to achieve a quick sale) which will reduce the total value of the bank’s assets. Thus a bank that was once solvent can become insolvent by its attempts to generate liquidity. In a classic bank run retail depositors lose confidence in their bank’s ability to remain solvent or see problems at other banks and therefore join a run at their bank. However, in modern banking, liquidity is provided not just by retail deposits but by wholesale deposits through inter-bank and repo markets. Indeed, many banks became heavily dependent on wholesale market funding and funding through securitisation to finance their assets over the last decade. The recent banking crisis demonstrated that runs can develop in the wholesale markets as inter-bank lending drains away and lenders demand higher collateral requirements. Banks are therefore highly interconnected and a problem in one part of the banking system can quickly spread to other parts. Given the pivotal role of banks in intermediation and hence in underpinning economic activity the consequences of systemic failure of the banking system can be catastrophic. This is one of the primary reasons to justify external regulation of the banking system. Later in this chapter we examine why a build-up of systemic risk in the banking sector was not recognised (or not acted on) by regulators in the period before the financial crisis of 2007–09. This has led to calls for 93 24 Principles of banking and finance regulators to take a different approach to monitoring systemic risk through macro-prudential regulation. We will examine macro-prudential policy later in this chapter. The protection of depositors The protection of the public (especially depositors) and the safety of the payment system represent good justifications for (solvency) regulations of banks. Therefore prudential regulations are necessary because of the lack of expertise and knowledge of individual depositors to assess the quality of the bank. This suggests a differentiation in the degree of regulation imposed on retail and wholesale banks, because of the differences in the perceived expertise of their customers. (If you have forgotten what these types of banks do, look back at Chapter 2). Retail banking depositors are less knowledgeable than those of wholesale banks; therefore the need for regulation is greater in retail banking. These banks should be subject to fairly rigorous control, whereas wholesale banking can be subject to a much lighter prudential control. The differentiation of retail and wholesale (investment) banking became an issue following the financial crisis of 2007–09. Many banks are both retail and wholesale banks. The ending of Glass-Steagall in the USA allowed retail banks to engage in investment banking activities – see Chapter 3 for more discussion. Most banks in Europe are universal banks undertaking both retail and investment banking. This makes it difficult for regulators to regulate the retail banking operation more rigorously than the investment banking operation, as the two are intertwined. The reason why this became a concern following the recent financial crisis is that investment banking is inherently more risky than retail banking, but regulators are reluctant to let retail banks fail because of the consequences of such a failure, discussed below. Thus many universal banks around the world which got into severe financial difficulties, in large part because of the speculative activities of their investment banking operations, had to be rescued with state funds, so as to protect depositors’ funds in their retail operations and to prevent an escalation of systemic risk. The financial crisis is discussed in more detail in Chapter 3. In the absence of any regulations, bank failures may have two main consequences: • First, they are very costly, especially to the financers of the failing bank (such as depositors and the bank’s stockholders) and, to a lesser extent, to borrowers with a close relationship with the failing bank. In addition, they may also be very costly to other banks, because interbank lending accounts for a significant proportion of banks’ balance sheets. • Second, bank failures interrupt the payment system because of the pivotal position of banks in the management of the payment system. Bank failures are more serious than failures in the other sectors of the economy for two reasons. The unique feature of banks is that their creditors (depositors) are also their customers. Contrary to non-financial firms whose debt is held by professional investors (especially banks), the debt of banks is held in large part by uninformed, dispersed, small agents (mostly households) who are not in a position to monitor the bank’s activities. The general public (depositors) lack the information and expertise to differentiate between safe and risky assets (banks). In any case, for each individual to have to evaluate the soundness of a bank would be time-consuming and inefficient. The justification for regulation is conveniently summed up as ‘For the protection of depositors’. 94 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks Moreover, banks’ managers would not choose the optimal solvency ratio. Self-regulation faces the problem of conflicts of interest inside the banks – between managers, stockholders and bondholders. For example, in the case of a bank with a small number of deposit-holders who manage the bank themselves, these owner-managers will tend to choose an investment policy that is more risky than the rest of the depositors would like. Because of the lack of financial sophistication/information of these non-owner depositors, some institution or regulation must defend their interests. Read Dow (1996), an advocate of bank regulation. Activity 5.1 Download the two articles in essential reading: Dowd (1996) and Dow (1996), advocates of free banking and bank regulation respectively. Read these articles and summarise the main arguments for and against each of the two systems in relation to the following criteria: i. moral hazard ii. cost iii. efficiency iv. systemic risk Now try and explain why most banking systems around the world are heavily regulated. Arguments against regulation The arguments so far presented favour the regulation of banks. However, several arguments suggest that regulation can itself be a source of costs, negative effects and instability. The first argument is related to the costs in the form of real resources on both the regulators and the regulated. These costs are of four types: • the administrative costs of the regulatory authorities (i.e. employing staff to monitor banks) • the administrative costs associated with the banks’ own compliance activities (i.e. staff to produce return required by the regulator) • the cost of dedicated capital to comply with capital requirements (as discussed in the next section) • the contribution to funds needed to compensate the clients of other banks which have failed. To give you the magnitude of the first type of costs, the budget for the mainstream regulatory activities of the Federal Reserve System (FRS, one of several regulators in the US banking system) was $3268.1 million in 2007 (in comparison, the value added of the US banking industry to the gross domestic product is $569,700 million); while for the Financial Services Authority (FSA, the UK bank regulator) this cost was £298.9 million in 2006–07. Given that these costs are relatively high, it is a question of cost-benefit analysis to evaluate whether the benefits gained by prudential regulation outweigh the costs incurred. This trade-off explains why regulation should not be excessive but maintained at the minimum required to prevent bank runs. Activity 5.2 Find out who the bank regulator for your country is, and what the budget is for regulatory activities. Have there been any problems in recent years? Did they lead to a scandal and lots of press coverage? If so, were there changes in the regulations? 95 24 Principles of banking and finance Then there is the danger of regulation becoming so excessive that it reduces competition (i.e. regulation constrains banks’ diversification by limiting their portfolio choices or by restricting branching), it raises costs (and thus reduces profitability) and it lowers the rate of financial innovation. Another problem with regulation is that it creates moral hazard. Banks may take more risk if they know they are likely to be bailed out if they get into difficulties. Depositors are less likely to monitor what banks are doing if they know there is a regulator monitoring on their behalf and if the deposit insurance scheme provides full compensation in the event of bank failure. As a consequence depositors are more likely to place their deposits in banks paying the highest interest rates, which are likely to be the banks taking the most risk. Thus regulation may actually encourage risk taking – the very thing it is attempting to curtail. Finally, there is the danger that excessive regulation imposed in one centre will lead to the movement of the activity to centres where regulation is lighter. This explains the aim of the European Union regulator to achieve a common (called ‘harmonised’) regulation system across banks operating in different countries, sometimes referred to as the creation of a ‘level playing field’. Activity 5.3 Reflect for a moment on the job of the EU regulator of banking. We have seen how each country has its own unique mix of markets and banks, each with its own monetary history, and we can imagine how depositors in Italy and Sweden, in Greece and Belgium differ in what they want from their banks. Imagine you are a EU regulator of banking and think of the problems you’d have. Traditional regulation mechanisms Having established that there is a case for banking regulation, we investigate how regulation occurs in practice. There are several basic categories of traditional regulation mechanisms: • creation of a central bank • bank supervision (restrictions on entry, bank examination) • government safety net (deposit insurance) • bank capital requirements • assessment of risk management • monitoring of liquidity • disclosure requirements. Next we will look at each of these in turn. As we consider the possibilities, ask yourself how they contribute to solving the information asymmetry problem. (Note how this links to our discussion above about protection of depositors.) Creation of a central bank The creation of a central bank is a response to the need to control money supply. The usual argument for justifying the government monopoly in money supply is that the private issuance of means of payment could easily generate fraud, counterfeiting and adverse selection problems. In addition, controlling the money supply helps to stabilise the price level (so-called monetary control). Since the mid-1980s, most monetary authorities have used interest rates to implement monetary policy for the purpose of achieving price stability. 96 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks The second key function of a central bank is related to prudential control, which is the minimisation of financial crises (because of the social costs incurred in the event of a crisis). In this respect the role of ‘lender of last resort’ of a central bank matters in times of financial crisis, especially in the UK system. In contrast, in the USA there has always been a great deal of concern about the fact that a lender of last resort function could go against free competition in the banking industry. As a result the emphasis has always been on a decentralised structure of the central bank. The Bank of England, founded in 1694, laid the foundation for the development of central banks in other countries. The Federal Reserve Bank (FRS, know as The Fed) was created as a central bank for the US banking system as late as 1913. The Fed is made up of 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks and a Board of Governors. The primary function of The Fed is to pool the reserves of each of these banks. One of the most recent central banks is the European Central Bank (ECB), which was set up in Frankfurt in July 1998. The ECB, together with the central banks of the member states, forms the European System of Central Banks. Activity 5.4 Visit the website www.ecb.eu/ecb/html/index.en.html and summarise the structure and the main functions of the European Central Bank. Activity 5.5 Describe the structure and the main activities of the central bank of your own country. Bank supervision: restrictions on entry and bank examination Bank supervision, also referred to as prudential supervision, aims at overseeing those who operate banks, and how the banks are operated. It helps to reduce moral hazard and adverse selection in the banking industry through restrictions on entry and bank examinations. Chartering and licensing banks are two ways to prevent undesirable firms from entering into the banking sector, adopted respectively in the USA and UK. In the USA to operate as a commercial bank, a firm must obtain a national or state charter, granted by either the Comptroller of the Currency (an official in the US Treasury Department, in the case of a national bank) or by a state authority (in the case of a state bank). To obtain a charter, the potential bankers have to submit an application containing the operational plan of the bank. The regulatory authority then evaluates the soundness of the application (quality of the intended management, level of estimated future earnings, initial capital). In the UK any firm seeking recognised bank status from the Bank of England must offer a broad range of services (including deposit accounts, overdraft and loan facilities). A banking licence will only be issued to a firm that is well capitalised (paid-up capital and reserves of at least £5 million), has an adequate system of liquidity, internal control and a good quality of management. Moreover, the EU Second Banking Coordination Directive permits banks operating in other EU countries to set up branches throughout the EU on the basis of the authorisation provided by their own home supervision authority. Activity 5.6 Find out about the entry requirements in the banking sector of your own country, and briefly summarise them. Do you think they are sufficiently tough – or too tough? Could they be designed to keep out foreign competition? 97 24 Principles of banking and finance Banks’ regulatory agencies are responsible for ensuring that authorised banks continue to operate in a prudent manner (so-called prudential supervision) by carrying out bank examinations. An internationally recognised framework used by bank examiners to evaluate banks is the CAMELS system. Banks are scored on a scale of 1 (the best) to 5 (the worst), assessing six areas: 1. Capital adequacy 2. Asset quality 3. Management quality 4. Earnings’ performance 5. Liquidity 6. Sensitivity to market risk. Regulators can take formal actions to alter a bank’s behaviour (or even close the bank) if the CAMELS rating is sufficiently low. Activity 5.7 Now visit the website www.frbsf.org/econrsrch/wklyltr/wklyltr99/el99-07.html and summarise the main assessment areas of the CAMELS rating. Government safety net There are three ways in which governments provide a safety net for depositors: • central bank as a ‘lender of last resort’ • deposit insurance • direct funding by the government to troubled institutions. Lender of last resort The lender of last resort function is the provision of liquidity by the central bank to a bank (or the banking system as a whole) in times of financial distress. The central bank provides liquidity in exchange for financial assets. The function therefore increases the liquidity of the distressed bank’s balance sheet but does not increase the value of its assets. Normally the central bank only provides liquidity to banks that are solvent. However the distinction between a solvent and insolvent bank is not always clearcut, especially during a financial crisis. As we saw in Chapter 3 central banks around the world had to provide massive injections of liquidity into their banking systems in response to a severe liquidity crisis. The lender of last resort function can increase moral hazard as it may lead banks to expect liquidity support from the central bank if they get into difficulties. This may reduce the incentive of the bank to manage its liquidity risk effectively. The solution to this is for the central bank to provide liquidity support at rates that are higher than market rates in noncrisis periods. See Freixas et al. (1999) for further discussion of the lender of last resort role. Think about the moral hazard consequences of central bank liquidity support to banks during and after the global financial crisis of 2007–09. 98 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks Deposit insurance To avoid runs on banks and bank panics, governments have established deposit insurance schemes to provide protection for depositors. It is based on the notion that depositors have less incentive to join a run if they know their deposit is protected by an insurance scheme in the event of a bank failure. Under these schemes the bank pays a premium to a deposit insurance company, such as the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) in the USA, and in exchange its depositors have their deposit insured, up to a fixed limit, in case the bank fails. In the USA deposit insurance mechanisms were developed in 1934 by the Federal Reserve Bank as a response to the Great Depression bank panics. The steep decline in the bank failure rate from 28.16 per cent in 1933 to 0.37 per cent in 1934 after the establishment of the FDIC is commonly regarded as evidence of the effectiveness of deposit insurance in stabilising the banking industry. Following the USA, deposit insurance was later adopted by most developed countries with different modalities: • Insurance may be compulsory (all the members of the Federal Reserve System in the USA) or simply voluntary (non-members if they meet the FDIC admission criteria). • Insurance limits may differ widely from $250,000 in the USA to £50,000 in the UK (the UK limit will rise to the £sterling equivalent of 100,000 Euros in January 2011). • Insurance may cover different percentages of deposits, though the financial crisis of 2007–2009 saw most authorities raise the percentage of deposit covered to 100 per cent. Prior to October 2008 the UK deposit insurance coverage was 100 per cent of the first £2,000 then 90 per cent of the next £33,000. In the USA the FDIC uses two primary methods to handle a failed bank. In the first method, called the payoff method, the FDIC pays off deposits up to the $250,000 insurance limit. After the bank’s liquidation, the FDIC lines up with other creditors of the bank and receives its share of the proceeds from the liquidated assets. Typically, account holders with deposits in excess of the $250,000 limit get back more than 90 per cent (but the process can take several years). In the second method, called purchase and assumption method, the FDIC finds a merger partner who takes over all the deposits of the failed bank (not just those under $250,000) so that no depositor loses any money. This method has been used to implement the FDIC’s policy called too-big-to-fail: the big insolvent banks would get a large infusion of capital from the FDIC, which would then find a merger partner to take over the insolvent banks and their deposits. Originally the policy was limited to the 11 largest US banks, but has now been extended to big banks in general. The main problem with a system of 100 per cent insurance of deposits is that it creates a moral hazard problem. Depositors do not have incentives to monitor a bank’s activities: they do not withdraw deposits when they suspect that the bank is taking too much risk, as they know that they will not suffer losses if the bank fails. As a consequence, a bank’s management will have an incentive to undertake greater risks than they would otherwise have done. In addition, the problem with the too-big-to-fail policy is that it increases the moral hazard problem for big banks. A solution to the moral hazard problem lies in the use of a least cost approach for resolving bank failures, as adopted in the USA in 1991 by introducing the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act 99 24 Principles of banking and finance (FDICIA). Riskier banks are required to pay higher insurance premiums to the FDIC. If there is a system of risk-based deposit insurance premiums then banks will have an incentive to reduce these risks. Another solution to the moral hazard problem is the use of a co-insurance approach, which was the system in the UK prior to October 2008. The amount of deposit insured under the scheme would be less than 100 per cent (the coverage in the UK was, 100 per cent of the first £2,000 and 90 per cent of the next £33,000). Depositors have greater incentives to monitor (because of the threat of losing some of the deposits), but the percentage lost has to be kept to a (low) level that provides the incentive not to join a run. Note that banks pay a flat-rate premium linked to their deposits. Activity 5.8 Visit the website www.fdic.gov/deposit/insurance/risk/rrps_ovr.html and find an overview on risk-based assessment system. Summarise the main characteristics of each group. Too-big-to-fail problem The too-big-to-fail problem (also known as the too-important-to-fail problem) became a major issue during the 2007–09 financial crisis as many large banks came close to collapse. Too-big-to-fail banks, or large systemically important banks as they are often referred to, are banks that are considered to be so important within financial markets that their failure would have a catastrophic effect on those markets. The solution used for large distressed systemically important banks during the financial crisis was to use government funds to provide capital injections to the banks. In the US a number of banks were provided with capital injections under the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP). These included Citigroup and Bank of America which both received $45 billion of capital from the US government in return for the government having an equity stake in those banks. In the UK Lloyds Group and Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS) received capital injections from the government of £20.3 billion and £45.5 billion giving the government equity stakes of 41 per cent and 84 per cent in these banks respectively. These rescues have reinforced the view that some institutions are too big to be allowed to fail and this clearly causes a moral hazard problem. Before the crisis, though, there was a widely held view that large scale meant diversification and sophistication and this justified large banks having lower capital requirements. The repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act was also partly based on the view that large diversified institutions were beneficial due to economies of scale and diversification. Since the crisis this view has been challenged and solutions have been sought for the toobig-to-fail problem. There are essentially three solutions: i. actions to reduce the probability of failure of these institutions while leaving the size and range of activities unchanged ii. actions to reduce the size of these institutions or to make them less interconnected or to separate activities within the institution iii. actions to increase the range of resolution options, in particular to set out in advance resolution and recovery plans (often called ‘living wills’). To achieve i, larger banks will be required to hold larger amounts of capital and liquidity than smaller banks (a reverse of the policy pre-crisis). This has been the approach adopted in Basel 3 discussed below. To achieve 100 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks ii one proposal put forward is to move to a system of ‘narrow banking’. Under this proposal banks that take in insured retail deposits and provide retail payments systems would only hold government bonds as assets. See Kay (2009) for more detail. An alternative proposal is for a ‘new’ GlassSteagall Act that prohibits retail banks’ involvement in proprietary trading of assets. In other words retail banks would not be allowed to engage in trading assets such as CDOs that expose them to market risk. Finally, to achieve iii, there is now widespread acceptance that large banks need to produce ‘living wills’ that can be used to conduct an orderly-wind up of the bank in the event that it gets into severe financial difficulties. In practice regulatory authorities are likely to use a combination of all of these solutions to mitigate the too-big-to-fail problem. Activity 5.9 Download the report by John Kay on narrow banking from www.johnkay.com/wpcontent/uploads/2009/12/JK-Narrow-Banking.pdf Can you see any problems with the concept of narrow banking? Would narrow banks be intermediaries as defined in Chapter 4 of this subject guide? Bank capital requirements Bank regulations can reduce the bank’s incentive to take risks by introducing restrictions on asset holding and bank capital requirements, in particular: 1. restriction on holding risky assets (i.e. ordinary shares, known in the USA as common stocks) 2. limitation on the amount of loans, in particular the categories of the individual borrowers 3. reduction of the risk of the loan portfolio by diversification 4. maintenance of a sufficient level of bank capital. This last point suggests that the level of a bank’s capital is important in minimising the risk of insolvency of a bank (a long-term concept referring to the prospective ability of the bank to meet all its liabilities). Let us think a bit more about what exactly a bank’s capital is. A bank’s capital, equal to issued share capital and accumulated reserves, is the margin by which creditors are covered if the bank’s assets were liquidated. The capital absorbs any losses incurred by the bank on assets, and thus protects depositors and other creditors. Example: Consider a bank that has the following balance sheet: Assets($) Liabilities ($) Liquid assets 15 Government bills 20 Capital 10 Loans 65 Deposits 90 Total 100 Total 100 Suppose that a number of a bank’s customers unexpectedly default and the value of loans in the balance sheet is reduced by $5. What would be the consequence for the shareholders of the bank? The value of capital has to be reduced by $5 as well. Thus the shareholders bear the risk taken by the bank, while depositors are protected from asset losses by the bank’s capital. 101 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 5.10 What would be the consequence if the value of loans were reduced by $11? Leverage capital ratio A first measure of a bank’s capital requirement is the so-called leverage capital ratio, which is the amount of capital divided by the bank’s total assets. Activity 5.11* In the example above, what would the leverage capital ratio be? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. In the USA, under the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA), banks are now classified into five groups based on their capital. Banks that are ‘well capitalised’ have a leverage capital ratio exceeding 5 per cent, banks ‘adequately capitalised’ have a ratio higher then 4 per cent, while banks ‘undercapitalised’ fail to meet capital requirements. Banks in groups 4 and 5 are ‘significantly undercapitalised’ and ‘critically undercapitalised’, respectively. The equivalent measure used in the UK is the so-called gearing ratio, which is the amount of deposits and external liabilities divided by the bank’s total capital and reserves. The lower the gearing ratio, the lower the risk that the bank will lose its capital; therefore, the lower the risk of insolvency. The Bank of England does not impose a specific ratio as an acceptable measure: it will vary according to the nature of the bank’s business and assets (consensus approach). Risk–asset ratio under Basel 1 A second measure of a bank’s financial health is its risk–asset ratio, which is required to be above a prescribed minimum. A risk–asset ratio explicitly recognises that different assets on a bank balance sheet carry different degrees of risk. Formally it is the ratio of capital to weighted risk assets. The higher the risk associated with an asset, the greater the weight the asset receives. All international banks supervised in member countries (among the 100 countries are the USA, UK, Germany, France, Italy and Japan) accept the measure stated in the Basel risk–asset ratio, under the Basel Capital Adequacy Agreement of 1988 (now referred to as Basel 1, effective from January 1993). Under Basel 1, the minimum capital is specified as a percentage of the risk-weighted assets of the bank: Risk–asset ratio = Capital / Risk-weighted assets For regulatory purposes a bank’s capital is divided into two components: tier 1 and tier 2 capital. Tier 1 capital mainly consists of the issued share capital and the disclosed accumulated reserves. Tier 2 capital is mainly made up of medium- and long-term subordinated debt (debt instruments that rank below all other debt in the event of a bank’s default), general provisions and current year unpublished profits. A risk-weighted asset is calculated as the value of the asset multiplied by an appropriate risk rate. Four rates are used: 0 per cent (cash, cash equivalents and government securities in OECD countries), 20 per cent (interbank loans in OECD countries), 50 per cent (mortgages) and 100 per cent (commercial loans). A higher risk weight implies a higher exposure to credit risk. Off-balance sheet items are converted into credit risk equivalents and then assigned an appropriate risk weight. 102 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks The Basel risk–asset ratio is set at a minimum of 8 per cent for the total capital of each bank, and at a minimum of 4 per cent for Tier 1 capital. Activity 5.12* What risk–asset ratio would a bank have with capital of $1,600, cash $500, government bills $1,500, mortgages $14,000 and commercial loans $12,000. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. The main problem of the risk–asset ratio is the underlying assumption of risks’ independency, which permits a simple addition of the risk-weighted assets. However, portfolio theory states that risks may be interdependent in certain cases (we deal with this later in the guide): diversification makes the risk of the whole portfolio lower than the sum of the risks of individual securities (loans). Another problem with the risk–asset ratio is that it treats all commercial loans as equally risky (that is, they are all riskweighted 100 per cent). Market risk amendment The risk–asset ratio of Basel 1 addressed a bank’s exposure to credit risk, the risk that the promised cash flows from loans held by banks may not be paid in full. An amendment to Basel 1 (introduced in 1998) aimed to harmonise the treatment of market risk, the risk resulting from changes in market prices (please refer to Chapter 6 for a further discussion on credit and market risk). Market risk was incorporated into risk-based capital by using the building block approach. A minimum market risk capital requirement was set for any open positions in debt, equity and derivatives held in the bank’s trading books (where trading refers to positions taken with a view to resale for short-term profit). The long-term investments held by the bank would be subject to the original credit risk capital requirements. Therefore, the overall minimum capital requirement for a bank will be given by the capital requirements to cover credit risk from loans and long-term investments, and specific capital charges for market risk arising from open positions. An innovative feature of the market risk requirements is that they provide, for the use of banks’ own internal ‘value-at-risk’ (VAR), models for measuring market risk. The VAR model calculates an estimate of the maximum amount a bank can lose on a particular portfolio over a given holding period with an associate degree of statistical confidence (as described in Chapter 6). However, we saw in Chapter 3, in our discussion of the 2007–09 financial crisis, that banks had massively increased their exposure to market risk in the years preceding the crisis. When many of the securities giving rise to the market risk exposure reduced significantly in value the capital held against them was seen to be woefully inadequate. The response to this by the regulatory authorities has been to dramatically increase capital requirements for market risk – discussed below under Basel 3. After implementation of Basel 1, the problems, discussed above, became apparent and banks lobbied for a change in the rules. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision proposed a new capital accord (known as Basel 2). Minimum capital under Basel 2 Under Basel 2, (effective from end 2006), no change was proposed for the definition of capital, and the minimum capital coefficient of 8 per cent also remained unchanged. However, two main changes were introduced: 103 24 Principles of banking and finance • The credit risk assessment was updated in two ways. First, the present risk–asset ratio would be modified by separating commercial loans into different classes according to their risk measured by credit ratings from rating agencies (as described in Chapter 4). This is known as the standardised approach. It overcomes the problem with the current risk–asset ratio, which treats all loans as equally risky. Second, large international banks would be allowed to use their own internally generated credit rating (the Internal Ratings Approach) to determine the riskiness of each loan. Both these new approaches have the effect of reducing the capital required by banks. • The current risk categories of credit risk and market risk are being supplemented by a third risk category – operational risk, as described in Chapter 6 – which in future will have to be explicitly backed by capital. Under Basel 2, the minimum capital is specified as a percentage of the risk-weighted assets of the bank plus capital charges for market risk and operational risk: Risk–asset ratio = Capital /Risk-weighted assets + (Capital charges for market risk + Operational risk) x 12.5 Note, the 12.5 factor in this equation is used to convert the capital charges to an 8 per cent minimum. Another development in the Basel 2 Accord was to introduce the concept of three pillars of regulation. The three pillars are: 1. minimum capital requirements – as discussed above 2. supervisory review –an assessment by supervisors of the risk assessment processes used by banks 3. market discipline – greater disclosure of information by banks so that markets can provide an additional element of monitoring of banks. Activity 5.13 Visit the BIS website (www.bis.org/publ/bcbs107.htm) to get the full text of the Accord. Moreover, visit the Bundesbank website www.bundesbank.de/bankenaufsicht/ bankenaufsicht_basel_saeule1.en.php and summarise the three main pillars of Basel 2. Identify the innovations in comparison to Basel 1. The financial crisis and Basel 3 Before Basel 2 had been fully implemented around the world the financial crisis of 2007–09 occurred. However, as many countries had not implemented Basel 2 before the financial crisis began in 2007, it is unfair to say that the change to Basel 2 in some way created the crisis. However, the crisis clearly revealed that banks operating under the Basel capital adequacy framework (Basel 1 or 2) had insufficient capital in relation to the risks they faced. This inadequacy of capital was in terms of exposure to both credit risk and market risk. 104 Another criticism of the Basel capital adequacy framework is that it is procyclical in its operation. That is, it exacerbated the strength of the business cycle. Under the framework, capital requirements would tend to fall during the economic upswing where lending growth is strong and credit losses are low. This can tend to accentuate the upswing with well-capitalised banks able to expand lending aggressively. Conversely, in recessions capital requirements on banks increase as credit losses accumulate and banks facing capital constraints may cut back lending thus making the recession worse. As a consequence the amplitude of the business cycle is increased. Chapter 5: Regulation of banks In response to these problems adjustments to the Basel Capital Accord have been proposed by the Basel Committee (agreed in September 2010). The adjusted Accord is known as Basel 3. The main elements of Basel 3 are: 1. Common equity (defined as ordinary or common shares plus retained earnings) should form a greater part of tier 1 capital. There will be a minimum common equity to risk weighted assets ratio of 4.5%. Note that under Basel 2 there is no formal definition of common equity (sometimes referred to as core tier 1 capital). However, many regulators imposed a minimum common equity to risk weighted assets ratio of 2 per cent. 2. Tier one equity (made up of common equity plus other more strictly defined capital instruments – mainly preferred stock) to risk weighted assets must be greater than 6 per cent (compared to 4 per cent under Basel 2). 3. Total capital (Tier 1 plus Tier 2 capital) to risk weighted assets must be greater than 8 per cent (no change compared to Basel 2). 4. A capital conservation buffer equal to 2.5 per cent of risk weighted assets and made up of common equity. This buffer will allow banks to build up capital during ‘good times’ which can then be drawn on in times of financial stress. Restricting banks from paying dividends as capital approaches the minimum requirements will enforce this buffer. 5. In addition, national regulators will be able to impose an additional 2.5 per cent capital buffer when credit growth is judged to be excessive and there is a build-up of system-wide risk (this is known as a countercyclical capital buffer). This capital buffer can then be released during the downswing to enable banks to continue lending. 6. National regulators will also have further discretion to increase capital requirements for large systemically important banks (to address the too-big-to-fail problem discussed above). 7. There will also be a non-risk based leverage ratio to act as a ‘backstop’. This will be a ratio of tier 1 capital to total assets. The level has not been set at the time of writing but the proposal being tested is 3 per cent. This will guard against banks increasing lending at an excessive rate where this is not picked up by the risk-based measures. 8. Finally, there will be much higher capital requirements in relation to market risk. These requirements will be implemented in 2011. This is recognition that capital requirements against market risk were woefully inadequate. These requirements (except for 8) will be phased in between 2013 and 2019 to allow banks to increase their capital without harming economic recovery as economies around the world recover from the economic downturn that followed the financial crisis. It is important to note that the level of common equity will go up from 2 per cent under Basel 2 to 7 per cent (4.5 per cent + 2.5 per cent). In normal times banks will operate on a 7 per cent ratio. In times of financial stress banks will be allowed to reduce the capital conservation buffer towards zero. In times of financial stress the minimum common equity ratio will therefore be closer to 4.5 per cent. So, under Basel 3, regulators are placing greater emphasis on common equity to protect banks during times of financial stress. The procyclicality problem is addressed by points (4) and (5). 105 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 5.14* The capital requirements for banks under Basel 3 can be summarised as (per cent of risk weighted assets): Common equity Tier 1 Total Capital Minimum 4.5 6 8 Conservation buffer 2.5 Minimum plus conservation buffer 7.0 8.5 10.5 Counter-cyclical buffer range 0 – 2.5 Please see the following announcement from the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision for more information – download from: www.bis.org/press/p100912.pdf?noframes=1 Identify the following: i. In normal times (when there is no financial stress) what is the minimum common equity to risk weighted assets ratio? ii. In times of financial stress what is the minimum common equity to risk weighted assets ratio? iii. Under Basel 3 and in normal times (where there is no financial stress) what is the additional amount of total capital that banks have to hold in relation to risk weighted assets compared to Basel 2? iv. Where a regulatory authority applies the full counter-cyclical buffer to banks because credit growth is expanding rapidly, what is the minimum common equity to risk weighted assets that banks will be expected to meet? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Assessment of risk management The assessment of risk management is a new trend in bank supervision. Traditionally, the focus has been on assessment of the quality of the bank’s assets at a specific point in time and on their compliance with capital requirements. This is no longer felt to be adequate due to financial innovation. The use of new instruments (e.g. derivatives trading) implies that a bank that is quite healthy at a particular point in time can become insolvent very rapidly because of trading losses. This concern was heightened by the collapse of Barings in February 1995 following losses sustained in derivates trading. (Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), p.439 to understand better Barings’ problem.) This problem was addressed in Basel 2 by (i) new capital requirements for operational risk and pillar 2 which allows supervisors to assess the risk assessment processes and models used by banks. In the USA, bank examiners now place more emphasis on evaluating the soundness of risk management systems (as described in Chapter 6). Now bank examiners give a separate risk management rating to be included into the management component of the CAMELS system. Macro-prudential policy The traditional approach to regulation described in this chapter is prudential regulation of individual banks through setting rules on capital and liquidity adequacy through to bank examinations. This approach can be termed micro-prudential regulation as it is aimed at preventing systemic failure of the banking system (the primary aim of regulation) by 106 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks preventing the failure of individual banks. However, the financial crisis of 2007–09 showed that this approach failed to identify and prevent the build-up of systemic risk in the banking sector through common exposure to asset price bubbles and high degrees of inter-connectedness through derivatives and wholesale funding of liquidity. This has led regulators to consider an alternative approach to regulation – termed macro-prudential regulation – that aims to identify the build-up of systemic risk in banking due to external factors and to develop tools for intervening to reduce such systemic risk. Basel 3 introduces a macro-prudential element to capital controls with the capital conservation buffer and the discretionary capital buffer regulators can impose when credit growth in the banking system as a whole is growing excessively. This will need to be augmented with other monitoring and intervention techniques by national regulators. This is discussed further in a Bank of England discussion paper on the role of macroprudential policy (2009). Activity 5.15 i. Try to explain how the capital conservation buffer and the discretionary capital buffers introduced under Basel 3 (and discussed earlier in this chapter) may help regulators to manage systemic risk. ii. Read again the section on financial bubbles in Chapter 3 and then think about how regulators might intervene to prevent a financial bubble developing in the housing market. Monitoring of liquidity Liquidity is a short-term concept referring to the inability of a bank to meet deposit withdrawals even though it is viable in the long run. Liquidity can be provided in several ways: holding cash or assets which are easily liquefied, having an appropriate mismatching of portfolio cash flows from maturing assets, maintaining an appropriately diversified deposit base and having access to wholesale markets. These techniques are discussed in more detail in Chapter 6. Liquidity risk assessment was not given as much attention by regulators as capital assessment in the years before the financial crisis. Many banks became heavily reliant on wholesale funding and securitisation as sources of liquidity. As concerns about the solvency of some banks and the quality of securitisation products increased, these sources of liquidity began to close down as banks found they could no longer securitise assets or borrow easily from other banks through wholesale markets. As we saw in Chapter 3 in our discussion of the financial crisis, the early stages of the crisis showed up as liquidity problems at banks. Unprecedented levels of liquidity support were required from central banks in order to sustain the financial system and even with such extensive support a number of banks failed, were forced into mergers or required resolution.The regulators have therefore turned their attention to strengthening liquidity monitoring of banks. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision has proposed that banks should hold more high quality liquid assets. The high quality liquid assets should be assets that are capable of being sold (to generate liquidity) even during periods of extreme financial stress. During the 2007–09 financial crisis government bond markets operated reasonably normally; therefore bank regulators are likely to require banks to hold more high quality government bonds. 107 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 5.16 Think about the difference between a liquidity problem and an insolvency problem (where assets are less than deposits). Try to understand why increasing the amount of capital at a bank would help banks to increase their protection against insolvency but would not directly protect them from liquidity problems. Disclosure requirements Bank regulators can require the adherence to certain standard accounting principles and the disclosure of a wide range of information in order to enable the market to assess the quality of a bank’s portfolio and the amount of the bank’s exposure to risk. The disclosure of more public information aims to solve the free-rider problem (described above), which is the lack of incentives for individual depositors and other bank creditors to produce private information about the quality of a bank’s assets. The rationale is that market discipline has an important role to play in constraining a bank’s risk exposure. As we note above the third pillar of the Basel capital adequacy framework is market discipline. The basic bank disclosure issue relates to the amount of detail that should be supplied (i.e. with respect to non-performing assets, loan-loss reserves, derivatives activities) because more effective disclosure means greater transparency. In the USA the fact that bank regulators have become more ‘user-oriented’ in terms of financial disclosure is a manifestation of the ‘SEC effect’, which is the recognition of the need that (actual and potential) stockholders have full information through disclosure for making investment decisions. The ‘SEC effect’ mainly materialises as follows. First, banking agencies must adopt disclosure requirements substantially similar to the corresponding SEC regulations or publish reasons for the difference. Moreover, The Fed and FDIC have established Securities Disclosure Units (such as mini-SECs) within their own agencies. A bank with 500 or more shareholders is subject to SEC disclosure standards. A bank regulatory system can also be totally founded on disclosure requirements, as with the new alternative approach recently implemented in New Zealand (see next section). Alternatives to traditional regulation: disclosure-based regulation of banking An alternative to the traditional approach to the prudential regulation of the banking system has been undertaken in New Zealand since 1996. This system is based on disclosure requirements and uses market discipline to police the behaviour of banks. The rationale of this system is largely derived from the free banking approach previously discussed. The focus in New Zealand is on providing depositors and investors with reliable and timely information to assist them in making well-informed investment decisions, and on requiring issuers of securities and providers of financial services to comply with general consumer protection law. Unlike many countries, which have explicit depositor and investor protection objectives in the regulation of financial institutions and markets, New Zealand has no deposit insurance scheme and no explicit depositor protection objective in any financial sector regulation. Similarly, there is no investor protection scheme. 108 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks In New Zealand the approach to bank supervision is based on three pillars. The first pillar is ‘self discipline’, which involves reinforcing the incentives for banks to maintain the systems and capacity to identify, measure, monitor and control their risks and maintain prudent operations. This is the most effective means by which systemic soundness can be promoted, given that a bank’s directors and senior management team are best placed to understand, and to take responsibility for, the management of their banks’ risks. The aim is to align closely the incentives facing bank boards and the public policy objective of promoting a sound financial system. The main mechanisms for achieving this are: • promoting high quality, regular and timely financial public disclosure by banks, to sharpen the incentives for the prudent management of risks • promoting accountability for a bank’s directors, by requiring directors to sign attestations in their bank’s public disclosure statement on matters relating to the adequacy of their bank’s risk management systems • avoiding explicit or implicit government support for banks, and thereby sharpening the incentives for bank directors and senior management to take responsibility for their banks. The second pillar is ‘market discipline’. This is an important complement to self-discipline, as it helps to reinforce the incentives for the prudent management of banks. In an efficient market, the market rewards wellrun banks through a number of mechanisms (including through lower pricing for funding, greater access to funding, greater market share and higher share price). In contrast, poorly run banks tend to be penalised by the market. The ultimate market discipline for a bank is the capacity for creditors – particularly retail and wholesale depositors – to run on the bank, potentially forcing its closure. Effective market discipline is implemented in a number of ways: • maintaining a contestable and competitive banking system – there is no limit on the number of banks that may be registered in New Zealand • maintaining strong incentives for depositors to monitor and exert discipline on banks, by not having deposit insurance • ensuring that the market is well informed about a bank’s financial performance and condition, by requiring banks to issue quarterly disclosure statements and by requiring them to maintain and disclose a credit rating • maintaining a relatively low level of supervisory intrusion in the banking system, to reinforce the market’s view that the central bank (Reserve Bank of New Zealand) does not take responsibility for the prudent management of banks’ risks. The third pillar is ‘regulatory discipline’, or rather the use of limited regulatory and supervisory mechanisms by the central bank to reinforce incentives for banks to manage their risks prudently. The regulatory intervention is kept to a minimum to avoid creating unintended distortions to banking behaviour. The main involvement of the central bank comprises: • registering banks, by which the central bank seeks to ensure that only entities of good standing and sound risk management capacity may operate as registered banks 109 24 Principles of banking and finance • imposing selected prudential requirements on banks to reduce the probability of bank distress or failure to a very low (but not zero) level. Currently, the main prudential requirement relates to minimum capital ratios relative to risk weighted exposures • imposing particular corporate governance requirements on locally incorporated banks relating to the composition of a bank’s board of directors • requiring banks to issue quarterly disclosure statements covering a range of financial and prudential information and requiring the disclosures to be externally audited at financial year’s end and subject to audit review at the half year • monitoring banks’ financial and prudential condition on a regular basis, mainly using their public disclosure statements • meeting with banks’ senior management on an annual basis to discuss banks’ strategic direction and risk management issues, and meeting with the boards of directors of systemically important banks and with the auditors of banks on a regular basis • taking actions to respond to financial distress events – such as acting as lender of last resort to a solvent but illiquid bank, or giving directions to a bank in acute financial distress. The Reserve Bank has responsibility for the registration and supervision of banks for the purposes of promoting the maintenance of a sound and efficient financial system and of avoiding significant damage to the financial system, which could result from the failure of a registered bank. Unlike the supervisory authorities in many countries, the central bank does not register and supervise banks for the purpose of depositor protection: the focus is systemic stability. Another point of departure from the bank licensing arrangements of many countries is that, in New Zealand, it is not the business of banking that is subject to a licensing process; it is only the right to use the word ‘bank’ in a name, title or (in some situations) advertisements that is subject to registration. Any entity can conduct banking business, including deposit-taking, without being registered as a bank or being licensed in any other way. Indeed, registered banks are the only financial institutions in New Zealand that are subject to a comprehensive licensing and supervision framework. Critics of the New Zealand approach mainly argue that: • banks may be less willing to admit problems if that information is to be made public • depositors may not have the expertise to understand the information disclosed • unlimited liability for directors may discourage the best people from taking these positions, thus weakening the management of banks. International banking regulation Particular problems in bank regulation derive from the international nature of banking: banks can readily shift their business from one country to another. While regulators can closely supervise the operations of domestic banks in their own country, they have problems in examining the foreign operations of domestic banks or foreign banks with domestic branches. Moreover, in the case of international banking, it is not always clear which national regulator should have primary responsibility for supervising the bank. 110 Chapter 5: Regulation of banks A bank may exploit this by obtaining its licence in a country with weak regulation but conduct most of its operations in other countries. Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009) p.523 to better investigate the difficulties of regulating international banking, highlighted by the Bank of Credit and Commerce International (BCCI) scandal in 1991. In July 1992 the problems revealed by BCCI led to the Bank for International Settlements (and in particular, the Basel Committee) issuing a new set of minimum standards for the supervision of international banking. Under this agreement, a bank operating in many countries will be supervised by a single home-country regulator, which can ‘capably perform consolidated supervision’, with enhanced powers to acquire information. In addition, where a regulator believes that the home country regulation of a bank is not effective, it can restrict the operations of the foreign bank. Following this development, cooperation among regulators in different countries and standardisation of regulatory requirements represent the new trend in banking regulation. In this direction there have been the EU Second Banking directive (creation of the EU passport as discussed in Chapter 3), and the complementary directives aimed at providing harmonisation of solvency regulation across the EU (Basel 1,Basel 2 and Basel 3, as previously described). Summary To explain why banks are singled out for heavier regulation than other sectors of the economy is also to explain why banks should be regulated at all (free banking against banking regulation). There are three main reasons for banking regulation: • the fragility of banks, due to their role in providing liquidity insurance to depositors and in screening and monitoring borrowers • the existence of systemic risk, due to a run on solvent banks owing to the asymmetric information problem • the need to protect depositors because of their lack of the necessary expertise and knowledge to assess the quality of the bank. Having established that there is a case for banking regulation, in this chapter we investigated the traditional regulation mechanisms used in most countries: • creation of a central bank • bank supervision (restriction on entry and bank examination to oversee who operates banks and how they are operated) • government safety net (mainly through deposit insurance to avoid bank panics) • bank capital requirements (restrictions on measures such as leverage capital ratio and risk–asset ratio to reduce the bank’s incentives to take risks) • assessment of risk management, monitoring of liquidity and disclosure requirements. An alternative mechanism (implemented in New Zealand) is based on disclosure requirements only and uses the market discipline to police the behaviour of banks. The financial crisis of 2007–09 revealed many important deficiencies in traditional bank regulation mechanisms including capital requirements for credit and market risk and assessment of liquidity. These have been 111 24 Principles of banking and finance partly addressed by Basel 3 capital requirement changes and related developments in the areas of liquidity assessment. The final issue examined is the trend towards greater harmonisation of banking regulation across the world. Key terms assessment of risk management bank capital requirements bank examination bank supervision banking regulations bank’s capital Basel 1,2 and 3 central bank co-insurance approach counter-cyclicality deposit insurance disclosure requirements fragility of banks free banking gearing ratio government safety net least cost approach lender of last resort leverage capital ratio macro-prudential policy monitoring of liquidity narrow banking payoff method procurement and assumption method procyclicality protection of depositors prudential regulation prudential supervision restrictions on entry risk asset ratio systemic risk too-big-to-fail A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why banks need regulation • illustrate the main cases of non-regulated banking systems in history and explain their economic rationale • explain the main arguments for and against the regulation of banking systems • explain how banks are regulated through traditional regulation mechanisms • discuss the problems with the traditional regulation mechanisms revealed by the global financial crisis of 2007–09. • evaluate the response of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision to the global financial crisis of 2007–09 • illustrate alternative regulation mechanisms • discuss the main implications of the recent trend in harmonising bank regulation across the world. Sample examination questions 1. a. b. 112 Why do banks need regulations? How can deposit insurance provide stability in the banking system? 2. a. What are the forms of regulations designed to reduce moral hazard problems created by deposit insurance? Do they completely eliminate the moral hazard problem? b. What are the costs and the benefits of the ‘ too-big-to-fail’ policy? What are the recent regulatory restrictions to the use of this policy? Chapter 5: Regulation of banks 3. a. Which bank regulation concerns bank capital requirements? Discuss the system of capital regulation under Basel 1 and the main innovations introduced by Basel 2. b. What forms does bank supervision take, and how does it help in promoting a safe and sound banking system? c. How can disclosure requirements be used in banking regulation? Compare and contrast the experience of the USA and New Zealand. 4. a. Discuss to what extent the new Basel 3 capital requirements solve the problems revealed by the financial crisis of 2007–09. b. Discuss how effective the changes introduced in Basel 3 will be in preventing systemic risk in banking. 113 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 114 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking Chapter 6: Risk management in banking Aims The aim of this chapter is to explain the importance of risk management in modern banking, and to illustrate the economic rationale and technical aspects of the main techniques and models used by banks to manage credit risk, interest rate risk, liquidity risk and market risk. Furthermore it describes with practical examples how banks’ managers use these techniques and models in practice to protect against risk. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why risk management is important in modern banking • illustrate the main types of risks faced by banks (credit risk, interest rate risk, market risk, liquidity risk, operational risk) • explain and use the main techniques employed by banks to manage credit risk of single loans (screening and monitoring, credit rationing, use of collateral, endorsement) and credit risk of a loan portfolio (diversification) • explain and use the main approaches developed to manage interest rate risk (income gap analysis and duration gap analysis) • explain how liquidity risk can be managed appreciating the benefits and risks of the different methods • explain the main method developed to manage market risk (value-atrisk). Essential reading Gordy, M.B. ‘A comparative anatomy of credit risk models’, Journal of Banking and Finance 24(1–2) 2000, pp.119–49. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapter 24. Further reading Freixas, X. and J.C. Rochet Microeconomics of Banking. (Boston, Mass.: The MIT Press, 2008) Chapter 8. Heffernan, S. Modern Banking. (Chichester: John Wiley and Sons, 2005) Chapter 3. Saunders, A. and M.M. Cornett Financial Institutions Management: a Risk Management Approach. (New York, McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2007) Chapters 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12. References Altman, E.I. ‘Managing the commercial lending process’ in Aspinwall, R.C. and R.A. Eisenbeis Handbook of Banking Strategy. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1985) [ISBN 9780471893141] pp.473–510. Basel Committee on Bank Supervision Overview on the New Capital Accord. (Bank for International Settlements, January 2001) p.27. 115 24 Principles of banking and finance Introduction A major objective of banks is to increase returns to shareholders, without incurring increased risks. The financial crisis of 2007–09 revealed in a dramatic way the extent of the risks that banks had become exposed to and the inadequacy of many techniques that banks had been using to manage these risks. This has led to a rethink of risk management processes by both banks and regulators. Taxonomy of risk Since the risks that a bank has to manage are diverse, several classifications have been proposed, some of which are standard. The classification we use stems from the classification of banking activities. Thus, this section overviews the major risks facing banks: • credit risk • interest rate risk • market risk • liquidity risk • operational risk. The effective management of these risks is central to the banks’ performance, as explained in the following sections. In this chapter we investigate how banks manage four of these risks: credit risk, interest rate risk, liquidity risk and market risk. We also describe the economic rationale and technical aspects of the main techniques and models used by banks to manage their risks. Credit risk Credit risk is the risk that the promised cash flows from loans and securities held by banks may not be paid in full. It is related to the risk of default of a specific borrower, or to the risk of delay in servicing the loan. In either case, the present value of the bank’s assets declines and this undermines the solvency of the bank. Clearly, credit risk is the most important risk connected with the assets held by a bank. Figure 6.1 shows the percentage of total loans that were more than 90 days overdue for repayment made by US commercial banks and savings institutions since 1984. We can see from this figure that there was an improvement over the 1990s in the credit quality of loans. The credit quality then deteriorates sharply from 2007 as a result of the subprime mortgage crisis and the ensuing banking crisis and recession.There are two main reasons for the improvement over the 1990s/early 2000s: • First, the expansion of the US economy in the 1990s. Note, however, that the recession in the economy determined a turnaround in this pattern in the early years of the twenty-first century. • Second, the improvements in the ways banks measure and manage credit risk. The sharp decline in credit quality in 2007 is driven mainly by defaults on mortgage loans. One thing that is clear from Figure 6.1 is that an important factor determining credit risk is the state of the economy. As discussed later in this chapter, banks can manage credit risk by screening and monitoring, credit rationing, use of collateral, endorsement and diversification. 116 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking 6.00 % 5.00 % 4.00 % 3.00 % 2.00 % 2010: Q2 2009: Q1 2007: Q4 2005: Q2 2006: Q3 2004: Q1 2001: Q3 2002: Q4 2000: Q2 1999: Q1 1997: Q4 1995: Q2 1996: Q3 1994: Q1 1991: Q3 1992: Q4 1990: Q2 1989: Q1 1987: Q4 1985: Q2 1984: Q1 0.00 % 1986: Q3 1.00 % Figure 6.1: Non-current loan rate. FDIC-insured commercial banks and savings institutions 1984–2010 (Note: Non-current loans are loans that are 90 days or more past due.) Graph created using data from: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, 2010, www.fdic.gov Interest rate risk Interest rate risk is the risk incurred by a bank when the maturities of its assets and liabilities are mismatched and there are changes in market interest rates. This risk derives from a primary function of banks, known as maturity transformation (as described in Chapter 4): the liabilities (deposits) of banks are on average of a much shorter maturity than their assets (loans). A classic example of this type of mismatch was the large number of thrift institutions that suffered insolvency when interest rates unexpectedly increased in the 1980s. (Please refer to Chapter 2 for a description of the activities of a thrift institution; and read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), p.490–91 for a description of their insolvency during the 1980s). The change in market interest rates determines two main risks for a financial intermediary: • Income effect. This is either: the risk that the cost of reborrowing funds will be higher than the returns earned on asset investments, in the presence of longer-term assets relative to liabilities (known as refinancing risk). Example: Consider a bank borrowing $100 (liability) for one year, and investing in a $100 (asset) for two years. The maturity of its asset is longer than the maturity of its liability. Suppose that the cost of funds (liability) is 9 per cent per year, and the interest return on the asset is fixed for the 2 years at 10 per cent per annum. The bank faces the risk that interest rates change at the end of year 1. If interest rates increase and the bank can only borrow a new oneyear liability at 11 per cent, the bank would experience a loss over the second year of the investment (that is, 10 per cent asset return minus 11 per cent cost of funds). A good example is given by thrift institutions during the 1980s (mentioned above). or the risk that returns on funds to be reinvested will be lower than the cost of funds, when the bank holds shorter-term assets relative to liabilities (referred to as reinvestment risk). 117 24 Principles of banking and finance Example: Consider a bank borrowing $100 (liability) at 9 per cent (cost of funds) for two years, and investing $100 (asset) at 10 per cent (return on assets) for one year. The maturity of its liability is longer than the maturity of its assets. The bank is exposed to an interest rate risk: it does not know at which rate it can reinvest in the second period. Suppose that the interest rate earned on its assets falls to 8 per cent at the end of the first year; in this case the bank would face a loss (that is, 8 per cent asset return minus 9 per cent cost of funds). In recent years, a good example of this exposure has been provided by banks that borrowed fixed-rate deposits, while investing in variable rate loans. • Market value effect. This risk refers to the change in the present value of the cash flows on assets and liabilities. As we will see in Chapter 7, the price of an asset or liability is equal to the present value of the relevant cash flows. Therefore, rising interest rates increase the discount rate on those cash flows and reduce the price of the asset or liability. Conversely, falling interest rates increase the price. Banks protect themselves against interest rate risk by matching the maturity of their assets and liabilities. Therefore, matching maturity is generally seen as the best method to hedge interest rate risk for a bank. Note, however, the matching maturities policy is not necessarily consistent with the active asset transformation function (i.e. transforming shortterm deposits into long-term loans, as we described in Chapter 4) and may also reduce profitability (i.e. lower returns from risk-bearing asset transformation). As a result, in the real world, all banks tend to mismatch their balance sheet maturities to some degree. To manage interest rate risk, banks use two main methods: income gap analysis and duration gap analysis (discussed later in this chapter). Market risk Market risk is the risk related to the uncertainty of a bank’s earnings on its trading portfolio caused by changes in the market conditions, such as interest rates, equity return, exchange rates, market volatility, and market liquidity. Therefore market risk is actually a collection of different risks including interest rate risk, equity price risk, commodity price risk and foreign exchange risk. These risks are associated with active trading of assets and liabilities (and derivatives) rather than holding them over longer horizons. Note that assets held for trading are held in a bank’s trading book which is distinct from the loans held in a bank’s banking book. In recent years, trading activities of banks have risen considerably, and the income from them has increasingly replaced the income from traditional banking activities (loans and deposits). The financial crisis of 2007–09 revealed the extent of the build-up of risk in banks’ trading books and the inadequacy of the capital held to protect a bank against trading book losses. One problem in particular that emerged was that banks’ trading books had become increasingly exposed to credit risk as banks held mortgage-backed securities and other structured securities such as CDOs along with credit derivatives. These securities had (an indirect) credit risk exposure as the value of them was linked to some underlying set of loans. However, as they were securities they were put in the trading book and benefited from lower capital requirements. The differences in capital requirements for banking book and trading book exposures may actually have contributed to regulatory arbitrage, encouraging banks to securitise assets in the banking book and hold more credit risk exposures in the trading book. In Chapter 5 we covered the changes to the regulatory 118 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking regime introduced after the financial crisis to try to eliminate this regulatory arbitrage and to assess more appropriately the level of capital banks need to set aside against market risk. Indeed, as we saw in Chapter 5, some commentators have suggested that banks should not be allowed to engage in both collecting retail deposits and trading assets. The method for measuring market risk exposures is to calculate the Value at Risk (VaR) and then to hold capital to cover this. We examine the VaR method later in this chapter. Activity 6.1 Try to understand the difference between credit risk and market risk. Why do you think regulators seriously underestimated the amount of capital banks had to set aside against market risk prior to the financial crisis of 2007–09? Liquidity risk Liquidity risk for a bank comes in a number of forms. On the liabilities side of the balance sheet it comes from loss of funding. A bank’s main funding is essentially made up of two types: retail funding and wholesale funding. As we will examine later in this chapter the increasing reliance by banks on wholesale funding as a result of practising liability management has increased banks’ exposure to loss of wholesale funding in times of financial market stress. However, much of the literature on liquidity risk focuses on the risk of an unexpected large withdrawal of funds by retail depositors (and the consequent obligation for the bank to make payments) which may oblige the bank to liquidate assets in a very short period of time and at low prices. This type of risk comes from the specificity of the demand deposit contract: depositors are allowed to demand repayment of their money at any time. If enough depositors demand repayment then a ‘run’ develops on the bank and as we saw in Chapter 5, the ‘run’ mentality can be contagious and this gives rise to systemic risk. The assets side of the balance sheet liquidity risk can come from the ability of a bank to sell/securitise assets to raise funding. This is a market related liquidity risk as a banks’ ability to raise liquidity by selling/ securitising assets depends to a large extent on the state of the market it is trying to sell/securitise into. In times of financial stress it may not be possible to sell assets quickly or securitise them. Before the financial crisis of 2007–09 many banks had come to rely upon regular securitisation of mortgage assets to fund to new business. In times of financial stress it may not be possible to securitise, so banks that had become dependent on securitisation (e.g. Northern Rock in the UK) found themselves with a severe illiquidity problem. The management of liquidity risk by banks includes diversifying funding sources and holding a greater stock of high quality liquid assets that can be sold in times of financial stress. We will examine methods of liquidity management later in this chapter. Mechanisms to limit the possible contagion of liquidity problems including deposit insurance, lender of last resort and capital requirements are explained in detail in Chapter 5. Operational risk Operational risk is ‘the risk of direct or indirect loss resulting from inadequate or failed internal processes, people, and systems or from external events’ (the definition provided by the Basel Committee on Bank Supervision, 2001, Bank for International Settlements). The Bank for International Settlements (BIS) is the principal organisation of Central 119 24 Principles of banking and finance Banks in the major economies of the world, and as we saw in Chapter 5, the Basel Committee issued the Basel 1, 2 and 3 Capital Accords. As discussed in Chapter 5, under Basel 2, the Basel Committee has proposed that operational risk will be a new type of risk to be considered in determining a banks’ capital requirements. Activity 6.2 Visit the Bank for International Settlements website www.bis.org/publ/bcbs42.htm and summarise the main sources of operational risk. Policies to reduce risk We have looked at the five main risks faced by banks. Now we consider in turn how banks (and other financial intermediaries) can minimise the four most important risks: credit risk, interest rate risk, liquidity risk and market risk. Credit risk management There are several ways to minimise credit risk: • screening • monitoring • credit rationing • use of collateral and endorsement • diversification. Screening To overcome adverse selection in loan markets, banks have to screen out the bad credit risks from the good ones in order to maximise the shareholders’ value added through credit risk management. To accomplish effective screening, banks have to acquire information on a potential borrower. The reason for doing this is to measure the probability of the borrower’s default, known as measurement of credit risk. At the retail level, much of the information needs to be collected internally or bought from external credit agencies. There are several models to assess the default risk on loans. They vary from the relatively qualitative to the highly quantitative models. We classify them in three broad groups: (i) qualitative models, (ii) credit scoring models and (iii) newer models based on financial market data. Qualitative models Qualitative models (also referred to as expert systems) are based on the subjective judgment of the bank’s manager on the probability of default of the borrower, and they are used in the absence of publicly available information on the quality of the borrower. Information can be collected from private sources (e.g. credit and deposit files) and commercial external sources (e.g. credit rating agencies). The quantity of information used is determined by the size of the loan exposure and the cost of collecting information. Key information in the overall credit decision can be divided into: 1. Borrower-specific factors that are idiosyncratic to each borrower. They refer to: borrower’s reputation (or past credit history) arising from the long-term borrowing–lending relationship; borrower’s leverage 120 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking (ratio of debt to equity) because in presence of large amounts of debt, the probability of the borrower’s default increases (due to an increase in the borrower’s interest charges, which have an impact on its cash flows); volatility of the borrower’s earnings, which is negatively linked with the borrower’s ability to meet fixed interest and principal charges. 2. Market-specific factors that have an impact on all borrowers at the time of the credit decision. Examples of these factors are: the business cycle phase and the level of interest rates (high interest rates denote restrictive monetary policy and may encourage borrowers to take excessive risks and/or to encourage only the most risky borrowers to apply). Activity 6.3 Which of the two sets of factors above is more likely to affect adversely small businesses than large businesses in the credit-assessment process by a bank? Credit scoring models Credit scoring models are mathematical models used to observe the characteristics of the loan’s applicant, either to calculate the applicant’s probability of default (expressed by a score) or to sort borrowers into different default risk classes. Credit scoring models include two broad families: linear probability models and linear discrimination analysis. The same models are used to credit score individuals or corporations, though the variables used to determine the score differ: an individual might be scored on the basis of age, sex, marital status, number of children, income, employment and past repayment records of loans and credit cards, whereas a firm might be evaluated on different financial ratios (such as leverage ratio or profitability ratio). The linear probability models use data from past defaulters and healthy borrowers to identify the explanatory variables (such as leverage or earnings) that are statistically significant in explaining why an individual or a firm defaults on a loan. The old borrower’s characteristics are used as inputs into a model that explains the past repayment experience. The past performance is then used to forecast the probability of a new borrower defaulting at a later date. Example: Suppose that there are two factors (Xi) affecting the past default experience: the leverage ratio (D/E) and the volatility of a borrower’s earnings (EV). Based on past experience, the linear probability model is estimated as: Z = 0.5 (D/E) + 0.6 (EV) where Z is the expected probability of default. Assume that the borrower has D/E = 0.4 and E = 0.25, the expected probability of default (Z) = 0.5 (0.4) + 0.6 (0.25) = 0.35. Activity 6.4* Suppose the estimated linear probability model is Z = 1.1 X1 + 0.1 X2 + 0.5 X3, where X1 = 0.75 is the leverage ratio, X2 = 2.5 is the sales-asset ratio and X3 = 0.15 is the borrower’s profitability ratio. a. What is the projected probability of repayment for the borrower? b. What is the projected probability of repayment if the leverage ratio is 0.4? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. 121 24 Principles of banking and finance Discrimination models divide borrowers into high or low default risk classes on their observed characteristics. For example, for US publicly traded manufacturing firms a widely used model has been developed by Altman (1985). The measure of the default risk (Zi) depends on the value of various financial ratios of the borrower (Xi) and the weighted importance of these ratios (based on past observed experience of defaulting and non-defaulting firms). Altman’s discriminant function can be written as: Z = 1.2X1 + 1.4X2 + 3.3X3 + 0.6X4+ 1.0X5 where X1= working capital/total assets; X2 = retained earnings/total assets; X3= earnings before interests and taxes/total assets; X4 = market value of equity/book value of long-term debt; X5 = sales/total assets. The higher the value of Z, the lower the default risk. There are several problems associated with discrimination models. First, they usually discriminate only between two extreme cases: default and non-default status. Second, there is no economic rationale for expecting weights and variables to remain constant over short periods. Third, these models ignore important – but difficult to quantify – characteristics, such as reputation. Newer models based on financial market data The newer models are based on financial market data to make inferences on the default probability. Therefore, they are most relevant to the valuation of loans to large borrowers in the corporate sector. Two examples of these newer approaches are: CreditMetrics and Credit Risk+. CreditMetrics J.P. Morgan and its co-sponsors introduced CreditMetrics in 1997. It uses the value-at-risk (VaR) framework to value (and measure the risk) of nontradable assets (such as loans). The idea of this method is to answer the following question: ‘If next year is a bad year, how much will the bank lose on its loans or loans’ portfolio?’ (Please read the section on VaR later in this chapter to appreciate the VaR concept.) Each borrower is assigned a credit rating, and a transition matrix is used to determine the probabilities that the borrower’s credit rating will be upgraded or downgraded, or that it defaults. CreditMetrics calculates the portfolio value by randomly simulating the credit quality of each borrower. The credit instruments are then repriced under each simulated outcome, and the portfolio value is simply the aggregation of these prices. Credit Risk+ Credit Risk+ is a model developed by Credit Suisse Financial Products, which attempts to estimate the expected loss of loans and the distribution of those losses. The method – based on mathematical models used in the insurance industry – aims to calculate the bank’s required capital reserves to meet losses above a certain level. Activity 6.5 Download and read the journal article by Gordy (2000) listed in Essential reading, section 3.3 only, and answer the following question: ‘How does the Credit Risk+ model differ from the CreditMetrics model?’ 122 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking Monitoring To reduce the moral hazard problem, banks monitor the borrower’s activities (and their risk). There are two ways of monitoring credit risk: to write covenants into loan contracts and to establish long-term customer relationships. Writing covenants into loans The loan contract may contain covenants restricting or encouraging various future actions of the firm to enhance the probability of the repayment (as described in the section on moral hazard in Chapter 4). The rationale behind covenants is that the loan is backed both by the firm’s assets and also by the stream of future cash flow produced by the firm. Long-term customer relationship benefits The existence of long-term customer relationships benefits the bank as well as the borrower. In the case where the borrower has previous loan contracts with the bank, there are lower costs of monitoring for the bank because the monitoring procedures have already been established. As a consequence of the lower costs, the borrower may obtain loans at lower interest rates. Moreover, the borrower has the incentive to avoid risky activities, even if these activities are not specifically addressed in the covenants of the loan contract. In case the bank is not satisfied with the borrower’s behaviour, the bank may discourage the borrower from these activities by threatening to refuse new loans in the future. In Chapter 2 we saw that long-term customer relations are more likely to be established in bank-based systems. Credit rationing There are two forms of credit rationing: 1. A bank refuses to make a loan of any amount to a borrower, who is willing to pay a higher interest rate. 2. A bank makes the loan but reduces the size of the loan to a lower amount than the one the borrower requires. The first type of credit rationing is justified by the adverse selection problem. The loan rate should consist of a market rate, a risk premium (the riskier the borrower, the higher the risk premium), and administration costs. However, because of adverse selection, a borrower may agree to pay a higher rate because she/he knows that her/his default probability is high. High loan rates may increase the probability of loan default. The bank would therefore not make any loan (even at the higher rate). The second type of credit rationing aims to solve the moral hazard problem. The larger the loan, the higher is the incentive of the borrower to engage in activities that increase the default probability. As a consequence, in retail markets, banks normally quote one loan rate (or a very narrow range of rates) and then restrict the amount individuals or firms can borrow according to some criteria (such as wealth). Collateral and endorsement Another way of managing credit risk is through collateral and endorsement. Loans with collateral requirements are often referred to as secured loans. Collateral are the assets used by the borrower to guarantee the repayment of the debt. In case of bankruptcy, the lender can sell these assets and use the proceeds. Once the asset is used as collateral, the borrower is assumed not to dispose of it. 123 24 Principles of banking and finance Assets that are commonly used as collateral are: real estate properties, cars and goods that can be mortgaged; equipment and inventories; accounts receivable; securities and savings accounts. The bank determines the maximum amount of the loan in proportion with the collateral. What factors must the bank remember when accepting collateral? The higher the volatility of the collateral’s value and the lower its marketability, the smaller the amount of the loan. On average, banks can lend up to 90 per cent of the value of high-trade treasury bills, but only up to 75 per cent of the value of high-capitalisation stocks, and much less on inventories. In the case of commercial loans, a particular form of collateral required by banks is known as compensating balances: a firm receiving a loan must keep a required minimum amount of funds in a cheque account at the bank. There is a difference between the USA and Europe, since in the USA shortterm loans tend to be unsecured, whereas in Europe they tend to be either collateralised or endorsed by a third party. If a loan is endorsed by a third party (just in case the borrower goes bankrupt), the third party is committed to repaying the debt. This additional guard against loss from default is similar to providing collateral as far as the lending bank is concerned. Diversification The techniques discussed in the previous sections (screening and monitoring, credit rationing, use of collateral, endorsement and loan covenants) allow banks to measure and manage risk on individual loans. However, banks own loan portfolios which are collections of risky assets. Combining loans together in a portfolio should allow the bank to diversify and so reduce the overall riskiness of its loan portfolio. Diversification is achieved by lending to different types of borrowers (and avoiding a concentration of loans to one type of borrower). As we show in Chapter 8 in relation to equity portfolios, diversification enables the bank to reduce individual firm-specific credit risk (risk of default specific to the borrowing firm associated with the specific projects undertaken by the firm), but it leaves the bank exposed to systematic credit risk (factors that simultaneously increase the default risk of all firms in the economy). If banks choose loans that yield returns that are negatively correlated, they are able to diversify away all non-systematic risk (see p.171 for a definition of non-systematic risk). Banks can use migration analysis to measure credit risk concentration in their loan portfolios and concentration limits to manage the concentration of risk in their portfolios. Migration analysis In migration analysis, banks monitor the credit ratings (as provided by a ratings agency such as Standard and Poor’s or Moody’s) of a number of firms in an industry. If they decline faster than the historical trend of the industry, banks reduce the lending to that industry. A loan migration matrix provides the probability of a pool of loans being upgraded, downgraded or defaulting over some period. Example: Consider the following hypothetical rating migration matrix (each cell is made up of transition probability): 124 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking Risk grade at the end of the year AAA-A BBB-B CCC-C Default Risk grade at AAA-A .85 .10 .04 .01 beginning of BBB-B .12 .83 .03 .02 the year CCC-C .03 .13 .80 .04 Table created using data from: Saunders, A. and Cornett, M.M. Financial institutions management: a risk management approach. (New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2007) p.349. Consider loans graded BBB-B at the beginning of the year: historically (on average) 12 per cent have been upgraded to AAA-A, 83 per cent have remained at BBB-B, 3 per cent have been downgraded to CCC-C, and 2 per cent have defaulted by the end of the year. Suppose that a bank is evaluating the credit risk of grade BBB-B rated borrowers. In the case where over the last few years a higher percentage (e.g. 5 per cent) of these grade BBB-B loans have been downgraded to CCC-C, and a higher percentage (e.g. 3 per cent) have defaulted, the bank may restrict the proportion of lower-quality loans (those rated BBB-B and CCC-C), and increase the proportion of grade AAA-A loans. Concentration limits Concentration limits are set by banks in terms of the proportion of the loan portfolio that can go to any single borrower or type of borrower. Banks typically set concentration limits to reduce exposures to certain industries and/or geographic areas. Bank regulators impose a limit on loan concentration to individual borrowers equal to 10 per cent of a bank’s capital. Interest rate risk management One of the most important risk management functions in banking is asset-liability management or ALM, broadly defined as the coordinated management of banks’ balance sheet activities driven by interest rate risk. The two main ALM techniques, normally used to manage interest rate risk, are: • income gap analysis • duration gap analysis. Income gap analysis The gap is the difference between interest-sensitive assets (assets whose interest rates will be repriced at or near current market interest rates within a certain time horizon) and interest-sensitive liabilities (liabilities whose interest rates will be repriced over given future periods). Under US Federal Reserve Bank regulations, each of the bank’s assets and liabilities is classified according to the following maturities (known as time buckets)– the asset or liability is repriced: overnight >one day–3 months; >3 months–6months; >6 months–12 months; >12 months–5 years; >5 years. This model is known as the maturity gap approach (or repricing model). Note that a simpler version of this method is known as basic gap analysis, where the bank has to assess which assets and liabilities are interest-sensitive that is, which have interest rates repriced within a certain time horizon (usually within one year). The problem of the basic gap analysis is that many of the assets and liabilities that are not classified as interest-sensitive have different maturities. 125 24 Principles of banking and finance Under the income gap analysis (maturity gap approach), banks report the gap in each maturity bucket, calculated as the difference between ratesensitive assets (RSA) and rate-sensitive liability (RSL) on their balance sheets. This can be written as: GAP = RSA – RSL (6.1) A positive GAP implies interest sensitive assets > interest sensitive liabilities. A rise in interest rates will cause a bank to have interest revenues rising faster than interest costs; thus the net interest margin and income will increase. A decline in interest rates will increase liabilities costs faster than assets returns; as a consequence the net interest margin and income will decrease. Bank managers can calculate the income exposure to changes in interest rates in different maturity buckets, by multiplying GAP times the change in the interest rate: ∆I = GAP * ∆i (6.2) where: ∆I = change in the banks’ income; ∆i = change in interest rate. Some problems with income gap analysis Income gap analysis is essentially a book value accounting cash flow analysis of the income gap between interest revenues and interest costs over given periods of time. Therefore, the main problem of income gap analysis is that it ignores market value effects of interest rate changes. In fact, when interest rates change, there is a market value effect (change in the present value of the cash flows of assets and liabilities) in addition to an income effect (immediate interest received or paid on them). As a consequence, the income gap analysis is only a partial picture of the true interest rate exposure of a bank. This contrasts with the market valuebased duration models discussed in the section below. Another problem with income gap analysis is that rate-insensitive assets and liabilities (whose interest rates are not repriced) actually have a component that is rate sensitive. A bank receives a runoff cash flow from these rate-insensitive items that can be reinvested at the current market interest rates. Examples of these items are long-term assets and liabilities, such as fixed-rate mortgages (e.g. mortgages with a 30-year maturity repaid within one year by the homeowner) and savings deposits. For example, some 30-year original maturity mortgages may have only one year left before they mature; that is, they are in their 29th year. And virtually all long-term mortgages pay at least some principal back to the bank each month. As a result, the bank receives a runoff cash flow from its conventional mortgage portfolio that can be reinvested at current market rates. Bank managers can deal with this problem by identifying for each rate-insensitive asset and liability the estimated runoff cash flow. For example, 20 per cent of the fixed-rate residential mortgages are assumed to be repaid within one year and 20 per cent of savings deposits become rate-sensitive liabilities within one year. These runoff cash flows are then added to the value of the rate-sensitive assets and liabilities. Furthermore, the income gap analysis ignores the effects of the changes in interest rates on off-balance sheet instruments. 126 Despite these problems, the income gap analysis provides a picture of the overall balance sheet mismatches and the cash flow consequences of interest rate changes. It still takes place in most banks, but it is used in conjunction with other risk management tools. Chapter 6: Risk management in banking Activity 6.6* Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), pp.624–25 and consider the following balance sheet of International Bank (in millions): Assets Liabilities and Equity Variable-rate mortgages $ 20 Money market deposits $5 Fixed-rate mortgages (30 years) $ 25 Savings deposits $20 Commercial loans $ 50 Variable rate CD (<1year) $30 Physical capital $5 Equity $45 Total assets $100 Total liabilities and equity $100 Answer the following questions: a. What will be the net interest income at the year end if interest rates increase by 1.5 per cent, from 8 per cent to 9.5 per cent? Explain with basic gap analysis. (Use the following assumptions on the runoff cash flows: fixed-rate mortgages repaid during the year: 20 per cent; proportion of savings deposits that are ratesensitive: 20 per cent). b. What happens to the income, if the International Bank decides to convert $10 millions of its existing fixed-rate mortgages into variable-rate mortgages? c. What happens to the income, if International Bank revises the estimate of the percentage of the saving deposits that are rate-sensitive from 20 per cent to 15 per cent? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Duration gap analysis A market value-based model of measuring and managing interest rate risk is duration gap analysis. We first illustrate the concept of duration (and its technical and economic meanings), and then explain why duration gap analysis provides a more accurate measure of a banks’ interest rate risk exposure than income gap analysis (described in the previous section). Macaulay duration and modified duration Duration has two main meanings: • Macaulay duration measures the average financial life of an asset or liability • modified duration expresses the interest sensitivity of an asset or liability’s value. Macaulay duration takes into account the time of arrival (or payment) of all the cash flows as well as the maturity of the asset (liability). Technically the Macaulay duration is a weighted average of the maturities of the cash payments, where the weights are the relative present values of each cash flow. It measures the period of time required to recover the initial capital investment. The formula for the calculation of the Macaulay duration of any fixed-rate security can be written as: ∑ CF x DF x t ∑ CF x DF N D= t =1 t t N t =1 t t ∑ PV x t ∑ PV N = t =1 t N t =1 (6.3) t where: 127 24 Principles of banking and finance D = Macaulay duration measured in years CFt = Cash flows received on the security at the end of period t N = Last period in which the cash flow is received DFt = Discount factor = 1/(1+i)t, where i is the current market interest rate PVt Present value of the cash flow at t = CFt × DFt = Example: Consider a seven-year Eurobond with 8 per cent coupon and yield; current market interest rate 11 per cent. t CFt DFt CFt x DFt CFt x DFt x t 1 8 0.9009 7.21 7.21 2 8 0.8116 6.49 12.98 3 8 0.7312 5.85 17.55 4 8 0.6587 5.27 21.08 5 8 0.5935 4.75 23.75 6 8 0.5346 4.28 25.68 7 108 0.4817 52.02 364.14 85.87 472.39 D = 472.39/85.87 = 5.502 years The Macaulay duration allows for the possibility that the average life of an asset or liability differs from their respective maturities. The duration is lower than the maturity because the bond pays some cash flows prior to maturity. Note that it is only for zero-coupon bonds (bonds sold at a discount from face value on issue, repaid at the face value on maturity, with no intermediate cash flows) that Macaulay duration equals its maturity. The Macaulay duration of a portfolio of securities is the weighted average of the durations of the individual securities, with the weights reflecting the proportion of the portfolio invested in each security. Activity 6.7* Using the method illustrated in the above example, answer the following questions: a. Calculate the duration of a three-year 6 per cent coupon bond when the market interest rate is 4 per cent. b. What is the Macaulay duration of the portfolio made up of 20 per cent invested in the seven-year Eurobond (described in the example above) and 80 per cent in the three-year coupon bond (described in (a)? Then read the section on ‘Calculating duration’ in Mishkin and Eakins (2009), pp.61–68, to analyse a different method of calculating the Macaulay duration. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. There are three important features of duration: • Macaulay duration increases with the maturity of a bond (this can be seen by calculating the duration of a five-year Eurobond with the same coupon (8 per cent) and market interest rate (11 per cent) as the Eurobond in the example above). • Macaulay duration decreases as market interest rate increases: higher rates discount later cash flows more heavily, and the weights of those later cash flows decline when compared to earlier cash flows. 128 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking • Macaulay duration decreases as the coupon interest rate increases: the larger the coupons, the more quickly cash flows are received by investors and the higher the weights of those cash flows. Modified duration is a direct measure of the interest rate sensitivity of an asset or liability. It answers the question: how much will the security price change for a given change in market interest rates (when interest rate changes are relatively small)? This can be written as: %∆P ≈ – Dx ∆i 1+i (6.4) where: %∆P = (Pt+1–Pt)/Pt is the percentage change in the price of the security from t to t+1. The larger the Macaulay duration, the more the price of an asset (or liability) is sensitive to changes in market interest rates. From equation (6.4), the so-called Modified duration (MD) can be calculated as Macaulay duration divided by 1 plus the market interest rate; that is: (6.5) MD = D 1+i Activity 6.8* Recall from the previous activity the three-year coupon bond and answer the following question: If the interest rate decreases from 4 to 3 per cent, what will be the percentage change in the price of the bond? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Duration gap analysis Banks manage interest rate exposure, taking into account the effects of changes in interest rates both on income and market value, by using duration. Moreover, knowledge of the duration of their assets and liabilities enables banks to immunise their balance sheets against interest rate risk. The additive property of duration allows bank managers to determine the effects of a change in interest rates on the market value of net worth by calculating the average duration for assets and for liabilities and then using those figures to estimate the effects of the change in interest rates. The overall duration gap (DURgap) can be calculated as follows: ( L x DUR l A ( DURgap = DURa – (6.6) where: DURa = average duration of assets DURl = average duration of liabilities L = market value of liabilities A = market value of assets. Note that if the duration of assets and liabilities are matched (DURgap=0), then the balance sheet is said to be ‘immunised against unexpected changes in interest rates’. Immunisation can be used to obtain a fixed yield for a given period of time because both sides of the balance sheet are protected against interest rate risk. 129 24 Principles of banking and finance Duration gap can be used to calculate the change in the market value of net worth (∆NW) as a percentage of total assets induced by a change in interest rates (recall equation 6.4): ∆NW ∆i ≈ – DURgap x A 1+i (6.7) Example: Suppose a bank’s management calculate that: Da = 5 years; Dl = 3 years. Suppose also that interest rates are expected to rise from 8 to 9 per cent. The bank’s balance sheet is assumed to be: Assets ($ millions) Liabilities and equity ($ millions) A = 100 L = 90 E = 10 100 The duration gap for the bank is: ( ( DURgap = DURa – ( L x DUR = 5 – 90 x3 l 100 A ( 100 = 2.3 years The potential loss to equity holders’ net worth (as a percentage of assets) is: 0.01 – ∆NW ∆i = 0.0213 = – 2.13% ≈ – DURgap x = – 2.3x A 1+i 1.08 With total assets totalling $100 million, the fall in the market value of net worth is $2.13 million. Activity 6.9* If the bank revises the estimates of the duration of the assets to four years and liabilities to two years, what is the effect on net worth if interest rates rise by 1.5 per cent? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Regulators (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation and Basel Committee) are increasingly suggesting the use of this model to determine an appropriate level of capital reserves for banks exposed to interest rate risk. However, it is important to point out some problems with the duration gap analysis. First, the duration measure assumes a linear relationship between interest rates and asset values (flat interest rate yield curve and parallel shifts). However, the relationship is normally convex. The greater the convexity, the less useful is duration gap analysis. In addition, duration gap analysis is based on the approximation in Equation (6.4), and thus only works well for small changes in interest rates. In order to overcome these problems, banks use more sophisticated approaches to measure interest rate risk, such as the value-at-risk (VaR) analysis (described later in this chapter). Liquidity risk management One important strategy that banks can adopt in managing liquidity risk is to maintain a stable deposit base. One method of achieving this is for banks to diversify their deposit base by attracting in deposits from different types of depositors. This will bring about a greater independence of withdrawal risks as it is unlikely, unless in times of crisis or loss of confidence in the bank, that all depositors will look to withdraw deposits 130 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking at the same time. Of course, retail deposits provide banks with core (stable) deposits, as these depositors tend to be more loyal as they source other services from the bank and have the protection of deposit insurance. Another technique banks can use is to hold large stocks of liquid assets that can be converted into cash at times of liquidity need. A bank holding a buffer of reliable high-quality liquid assets, such as short-term government securities, can draw on them immediately in the event of a sudden withdrawal of market liquidity or an unexpected increase in its funding requirement. Of course, safe, liquid assets offer lower returns than other types of assets, so there is an opportunity cost in maintaining such a liquidity cushion on the balance sheet. This opportunity cost led banks to seek alternative ways of managing their liquidity risk in the 1970s and most banks turned to liability management. This involves the active management of its liability structure to manage its liquidity requirements. The greater emphasis placed on liability management has allowed banks to reduce their holdings of liquid assets over time. For UK banks the average ratio of liquid assets to total assets in the 1960s was approximately 30 per cent. This ratio fell markedly over the next 40 years so that in the years before the crisis it was less than 5 per cent. Banks have increasingly relied upon liability management and later securitisation to manage liquidity risk. Liability management is conducted at both retail and wholesale level. At the retail level it involves setting interest rates, levels of service etc. to maintain deposits. Of course if banks wish to increase deposits they will need to offer a higher rate of interest to retail depositors. This takes time and can be costly as the higher rates are paid to all depositors. An alternative way of increasing deposits is to borrow it from the wholesale markets (e.g. the inter-bank market). This may involve paying a higher interest rate as higher rates are generally paid on wholesale deposits. However, the higher rate is only paid on the marginal amount raised from the wholesale markets. The lower cost and flexibility of the use of wholesale funding has led most banks to increase their reliance on wholesale deposit funding. However, the financial crisis of 2007–09 demonstrated that wholesale funding is a more risky source of funding. Inter-bank markets effectively dried up as banks became concerned about lending to other banks as they were unsure which banks were sound. In the ‘search for yield’ in the years leading to the financial crisis of 2007–09 (see Chapter 2) there was a rapid expansion of structured financial instruments; for example, where individual loans are packaged into tradable securities, such as residential mortgage-backed securities, or where the risk of a pool of loans is packaged into complex securities offering different levels of exposure to the potential losses in the pool (a collateralised debt obligation). The demand for these structured financial instruments allowed many banks to take advantage of the new sources of wholesale funds available from securitisation. By applying an originate and distribute model many banks tapped this new source of funding on a large scale (see Chapter 2 for more explanation of securitisation). However when the ability to securitise disappeared at the start of the financial crisis, those banks that had become dependent on the liquidity provided by securitisation found themselves in severe illiquidity situations. The problems with heavy reliance on wholesale funding and securitisation to manage liquidity in times of financial stress has led regulators to force banks to hold higher levels of high quality liquid assets (see Chapter 5). In other words, banks are being forced to go back to the practice of asset management to manage liquidity risk. 131 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 6.10 Try to understand why relying on liability management to manage liquidity risk is less costly but higher risk compared to asset management (holding a stock of liquid assets). What are the risks to a bank of relying on liability management? What is likely to happen to the profitability of banks if they are forced to increase their holdings of liquid assets? Market risk management Market risk measurement is important for several reasons. It provides information on the risk exposure taken by a bank’s traders, which has to be compared with the bank’s capital resources. It enables banks to compare the returns to market risk in different areas of trading, in order to identify the areas with the greatest potential returns per unit of risk where they need to direct more capital and resources. Finally, under the current regulations of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision on market risk and capital requirements, in certain cases banks are allowed to use their own (internal) market risk models to calculate their capital requirements (see the section on Bank capital requirements in Chapter 5). Value-at-risk (VaR) approach In its most general form, the Value-at-Risk (VaR) measures the potential loss in value of a risky asset or portfolio over a defined period for a given confidence interval. Thus, if the VaR on a portfolio is $10 million at a one-day, 95 per cent confidence level, there is a only a 5 per cent chance that the value of the portfolio will drop more than $ 10 million over any given day. Another way of putting this is to say 95 days out of every 100 the value of the portfolio will drop by no more than $10 million. Note that VaR is not a measure of the worst case scenario as with a 95 per cent confidence interval 5 days out of every 100 the losses over one day on the portfolio will exceed $10 million. To calculate the VaR for an asset or portfolio the distribution of returns on the asset or portfolio needs to be specified. This distribution can be determined from historic data, from assuming that returns follow a normal distribution or by a technique called Monte Carlo simulation. The historical method is based on an evaluation of the past performance of the asset or portfolio on the assumption that past performance is a fairly accurate predictor of future performance. The returns performance of the asset or portfolio are then ordered and the desired percentile is read off. For example, consider a dealer working for a bank with a $20 million portfolio. Suppose the dealer has compiled from historical information the following information about the change in the value of a portfolio over a one day period. Change in Value 132 Probability < -$1,000,000 .01 -$500,000 to -$999,999 .04 -$250,000 to -$499,999 .15 $0 to -$249,999 .30 $1 to $249,999 .30 $250,000 to $499,999 .15 $500,000 to $999,999 .04 > £ $1,000,000 .01 Chapter 6: Risk management in banking From the above table we can easily define the daily VaR at a 95 per cent confidence interval, which is -$500,000. There is a 4 per cent chance of a loss of between $500,000 and $999,999 plus a one percent chance of a loss of at least $1 million. Thus, the bank can expect to lose at least $500,000 5 per cent of the time. Or 95 per cent percent of the time the loss to the bank will be no more than $500,000. The bank can then set aside an appropriate amount of capital to cover this potential loss. One problem with the historical method is that the historical data used to produce the distribution should be representative of all possible states of the portfolio. To achieve this would require many years of returns data which is unlikely to be available. The second approach is to assume the returns on the asset or portfolio follow some statistical distribution (e.g. normal, lognormal etc.). A typical distribution used for estimating a VaR is the normal distribution. The advantage of this approach is that relatively little information is needed to construct the distribution and compute the VaR – just the mean and standard deviation of the distribution. 0.34 0.475 0.135 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 STDEV Figure 6.2 Standard normal distribution If a 95 per cent confidence level is required, meaning we wish to have 5 per cent of the observations in the left-hand tail of the normal distribution, this means that the observations in that area are 1.645 standard deviations away from the mean. To take an example, if a portfolio of assets of value $10 million has a standard deviation of returns of 12.48 per cent (note this standard deviation will have been calculated using a portfolio approach and knowledge of the covariances or correlations between returns on assets in the portfolio – this approach is discussed further in Chapter 7). The 95 per cent VaR is equal to 1.645 * 0.1248 = 0.205296. In $ terms the VaR = $10 million * 0.205295 = $2,052,960. A stricter VaR would be one with a 99 per cent confidence interval which implies one percent of observations would lie in the left tail of the distribution. This would mean that the losses incurred would exceed the VaR on only 1 day out of every 100. In this case, assuming a normal distribution, the observations in the left hand tail of the distribution would be 2.33 standard deviations away from the mean. The main drawbacks of this approach are: i. the variance-covariance approach assumes stable correlations over time. We saw in the recent financial crisis that during times of financial stress the correlations between asset returns tend to move towards +1. 133 24 Principles of banking and finance ii. it assumes a normal distribution which is not always appropriate. Returns in markets are widely believed to have ‘fatter tails’ than those of a normal distribution. A fatter tail implies that extreme events have a higher probability (i.e. a greater chance of occurring) than that predicted by a normal distribution. This last technique of Monte Carlo Simulation basically involves the development of a model for the returns on an asset or portfolio and then randomly generating outcomes for returns to determine the distribution of outcomes. We do not consider this method further in this sysllabus. Activity 6.11 Try to answer the following questions: 1. Why is a Value-at-Risk measure no guide to a worst case scenario? How can regulators address this problem when assessing a bank’s exposure to credit risk? 2. What were the main problems with the Value-at-Risk method revealed by the financial crisis of 2007–09? Summary The main objective of banks is to maximise profits and shareholder value added, and risk management is crucial to the achievement of this goal. The chapter investigated the key financial risks modern banks are exposed to (credit risk, interest rate risk, liquidity risk and market risk), and considered how these risks should be managed. The main techniques and models used by banks to manage risks were grouped in accordance with the type of risk: • Credit risk management of single loans uses screening and monitoring, credit rationing, use of collateral, endorsement; whereas diversification enables banks to manage credit risk of their loan portfolio. • Interest rate risk management employs two main approaches: income gap analysis and duration gap analysis. • Liquidity risk management is achieved using diversification of deposits, liability management and holding a stock of good quality liquid assets. • Market risk management mainly uses the value-at-risk method. Key terms 134 Altman’s discriminant asset-liability management concentration limits covenants CreditMetrics credit rationing credit risk credit risk management Credit Risk+ diversification duration gap analysis endorsement expert systems foreign exchange risk income effect income gap analysis interest rate risk linear linear discrimination analysis liquidity risk long-term customer relationship Macaulay duration market risk market value effect maturity gap approach migration analysis Modified duration monitoring operational risk probability models refinancing risk reinvestment risk screening use of collateral Value-at-risk (VAR) Chapter 6: Risk management in banking A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain why risk management is important in modern banking • illustrate the main types of risks faced by banks (credit risk, interest rate risk, market risk, liquidity risk, operational risk) • explain and use the main techniques employed by banks to manage credit risk of single loans (screening and monitoring, credit rationing, use of collateral, endorsement) and credit risk of a loan portfolio (diversification) • explain and use the main approaches developed to manage interest rate risk (income gap analysis and duration gap analysis) • explain how liquidity risk can be managed appreciating the benefits and risks of the different methods • explain the main method developed to manage market risk (value-atrisk). Sample examination questions 1. a. What are the purposes of credit scoring models? What types of credit scoring models exist? b. What are the main problems in using discrimination analysis to evaluate credit risk? c. Can a bank keep borrowers from engaging in risky activities if there are no covenants in the loan contract? d. How do loan portfolio risks differ from individual loan risks? What is migration analysis? How do banks use it to measure credit risk concentration? 2. a. What is the income gap analysis? What is a maturity bucket in the income gap analysis? b. What are some of the weaknesses of the income gap model? c. What is runoff cash flow, and how does this amount affect the income gap analysis? d. Calculate the duration on a five-year 8 per cent coupon bond when the interest rate is 3 per cent. If interest rates rise from 3 to 4 per cent, what will be the approximate percentage change in the price of the bond? 3. The following balance sheet is available (amounts in $ millions and duration in years) for First Bank: Amount Duration Loans 2,725 4.0 T-bonds 300 2.2 Deposits 2,225 1.5 Equity 500 a. What is the average duration of all the assets? b. What is the average duration of all the liabilities? c. What is the duration gap? What is the interest rate risk exposure? 135 24 Principles of banking and finance d. What is the forecast impact on the market value of equity caused by a 0.5 per cent increase in interest rates? e. What is the forecast impact on the market value of equity caused by a 0.25 per cent decrease in interest rates? f. What are the limitations of duration gap analysis? 4. a. What is meant by liquidity risk? b. Why did liquidity risk facing banks increase in the years leading up to the financial crisis of 2007–09? c. How can banks manage liquidity risk? 5. a. What is meant by market risk? Why is the measurement of market risk becoming important in the management of banks? b. Discuss the use of Value-at-Risk methods for evaluating a bank’s exposure to market risk. 136 Part III: Principles of finance Part III: Principles of finance Overview As discussed in Chapter 2, securities and financial markets are two of the three entities of a financial system, together with financial intermediaries. But thus far we have not analysed the nature of financial securities and the functions of financial markets. The key objective of this part of the subject guide is to move to an examination of financial markets, and to answer the following question: How do financial markets perform the function of channelling funds from saver-lenders to spender-borrowers? In order to do so, this part answers the following consequential questions: 1. What real assets should spender-borrowers invest in? How can real assets be evaluated? How can the securities issued by the spenderborrower be evaluated? (Chapter 7) 2. What are the risk and return characteristics of securities and portfolios formed by saver-lenders? How can securities be priced in equilibrium?(Chapter 8) 3. How good are financial markets in establishing ‘fair prices’ for securities? Do security prices fully reflect all available information, a condition referred to as efficient market hypothesis? (Chapter 9) In Part III we will answer each of these questions, and thus provide an overview of the so-called principles of finance. The topics contained in these chapters are of necessity more mathematical than those covered earlier in the syllabus. However, the mathematics used has been kept at a basic level, and supplementing the chapters with the relevant readings should provide you with all the technical tools. 137 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 138 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation Aims The aim of this chapter is to describe how to value real assets and financial assets. It provides the economic rationale and technical aspects of the main techniques used to value real assets and to choose among alternative real assets (known as capital budgeting): Net Present Value (NPV), Internal Rate of Return (IRR), and payback period. Furthermore, it describes the methods used for the valuation of financial assets, both bonds and common stocks. Practical examples on how to use these techniques and methods are provided. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain how to value real assets and financial assets • calculate the present value of cash flows • describe the Net Present Value (NPV) technique and its properties, and use it to appraise real assets • describe the Internal Rate of Return (IRR) technique and its limitations, and use it to appraise real assets • describe the payback period technique and its limitations, and use it to appraise real assets • evaluate the NPV method in relation to the other capital budgeting techniques • explain the valuation method of bonds, and be able to compute the price of a bond • explain the main valuation methods of common stocks, and be able to compute the price of a common stock. Essential reading Brealey, R.A., S.C. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2010) Chapters 2, 3, 4 and 5. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapters 3 and 11. Further reading Copeland, T.E., J.F. Weston and K. Shastri Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Boston, London: Pearson Addison Wesley, 2005) Chapter 2. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002) Chapters 9 and 10. Smart, S.B., W.L. Megginson and L.J. Gitman Corporate Finance. (Mason, Ohio: South-Western/Thomson Learning, 2004) Chapters 4 and 7. 139 24 Principles of banking and finance Introduction As illustrated in Chapter 2, the main function of financial markets is to channel funds from saver-lenders to spender-borrowers. A typical spender-borrower is represented by firms, whereas a typical saver-lender is constituted by stockholders and bondholders. Firms cannot forget about investors when they analyse and choose investment projects, as investors will buy the securities they issue on the financial markets to finance their investments in real assets. The choice about the real assets in which firms should invest is known as capital budgeting. Real assets are investments that generate cash in the future, but which are not traded on financial markets like financial assets. In making capital budgeting decisions, the fundamental objective of firms is to maximise the value of the cash invested by their stockholders and bondholders. Investments in real assets by firms have to generate at least adequate returns, where ‘adequate’ means returns at least equal to the returns available to investors outside the firm in the financial markets. The issue of securities by firms is needed to finance the purchases of real assets. The value of real assets determines the value of the firm, and thus the value of the cash flows that will be distributed to stockholders and bondholders. Therefore securities and real assets are valued (respectively by firms and investors) on the basis of the same principle: the maximisation of the present value of the cash flows (generated by the real asset or the security). In this chapter we thus analyse the investment decision rules (known as capital budgeting techniques) used by firms to evaluate real assets. The main technique is the Net Present Value (NPV); alternative project appraisal methods are the Internal Rate of Return (IRR) and the payback period. Moreover, we investigate the methods used for the valuation of securities, both bonds and stocks. These techniques are explained in a wide range of textbooks. If for some reason you do not have the essential readings available, make sure you look for alternatives in the further reading. The concept of present value The first basic principle in finance is that one dollar today is worth more than a dollar tomorrow. The reason for this is that the dollar today can be invested, and start to earn interest immediately. This argument characterises the time value of money. One method used to illustrate the time value of money is the present value (also termed discounted value). It represents the value today of a cash flow received in t years’ time, and is calculated by multiplying the cash flow by a discount factor. Formally the present value (PV) of a future cash flow can be written as: PVt = Ct (1+r)t (7.1) where: Ct = cash flow generated by a real asset at time t 1 = discount factor, which is the value today of $1 received at time t (1+r)t 140 r = annual compounded interest rate required to accept the delayed payment, termed discount rate. Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation The term ‘compounded’ means that there is the opportunity to earn interest on interest payments already received. The opportunity to earn interest on interest is not provided by an asset that pays simple interest. In this chapter the implicit assumption is that discount rates are compounded rates. Example: Assume a compounded interest rate of 8 per cent. The PV of $1,000 to be received in two years’ time is: ( 1,000 1.082 ( $857 = . Present values obey the principle of value additivity: the present value of many cash flows combined is the sum of their individual present values. The PV of a cash flow stream (C1, C2, C3,…, CN received at years 1, 2, 3, .., N) can be calculated as: PV0 = C1 (1 + r) 1 + C2 (1 + r) 2 + C3 (1 + r) 3 + ... + CN (7.2) (1 + r)N Example: Assume a compounded interest rate of 8 per cent. The PV of $1,000 to be received at years one to three is ( 1,000 1,000 1,000 + + 2 1.083 1.08 1.08 ( $2,576 = . There are some special cases of the PV formula. When the cash flow (Ct) will be generated forever (and thus t is infinity), this is termed a perpetuity. A perpetuity is a stream of fixed cash flows (C) received at the end of every year from now until the end of time. The PV of a perpetuity can be calculated as: C PV = r (7.3) Example: Assume an interest rate of 8 per cent. The PV of a perpetuity that promises a payment of $1,000 per year is ( 1,000 0.08 ( $12,500 = . Equation (7.3) can be generalised to allow the annual cash payment to grow at a fixed rate. This is referred to as a growing perpetuity, which is a perpetual cash flow stream that grows at a constant rate (denoted as g) over time. The value of a growing perpetuity can be calculated as: C PV = r – g (7.4) Example: Assume an interest rate of 8 per cent. The PV of a growing perpetuity that promises an initial payment of $1,000 and growth of 3 per cent is: 1,000 . $20,000 = 0.05 ( ( Activity 7.1* Assume an interest rate of 7 per cent annually, and calculate the PV of the following cash flows: 1. €5,000 to be received in five years’ time. 2. €5,000 to be received at the end of each of the first five years, and €2,000 at the end of years six to eight. 141 24 Principles of banking and finance 3. €5,000 to be received from year one to infinity. 4. €5,000 to be received as a growing perpetuity (growth rate = 4 per cent). *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Net present value (NPV) and the valuation of real assets The Net Present Value (NPV) technique uses the discounting principle based on the present value to evaluate real assets (also referred to as investment projects). The NPV of a project is just the sum of the present values of all the cash inflows (C) generated by the project to the firm in each of the next t years, less the sum of the present values of the cash investment (I) associated to the same project. We normally assume one cash investment at the stat of the project. The formula for the NPV calculation is: N Ct (7.5) –I NPV = ∑ t t =1 (l + r) If the NPV is positive, the project should be accepted as it generates receipts (cash inflows) higher than cash investments (payments). As its worth is more than the cost, the project makes a net contribution to the value of the firm. Conversely, if the NPV is negative, the project should be rejected. If the NPV is zero, the firm is free to accept or reject the project. The rate of return used to discount the expected cash inflows has to be the rate of return offered by equivalent investment alternatives in the capital market. This discount rate is termed opportunity cost of capital. The label ‘opportunity’ derives from the fact that it represents the return forgone by investing in the project rather than in financial assets (securities). Consequently it is a market-determined opportunity cost. The assumption is that shareholders can reinvest their money at this market-determined rate. Note that in the context of a firm, the label ‘cost of capital’ indicates that the costs of all the sources of capital (both equity issues and debt issues) have to be taken into account. Usually, managers use the same rate to discount cash flows occurring in different years (and we do the same in the following sections). With a flat interest rate term structure (short-term rates being approximately the same as long-term rates as explained in Chapter 2), this assumption is correct. However, when the term structure is not flat, different rates should be used to discount cash flows in different years. The cash flows discounted in equation (7.5) above are the incremental cash flows, which are the additional cash flows from the project. Therefore sunk costs have to be excluded from the above calculation, because they are incurred whether or not the project is accepted. One implicit assumption about cash flows associated with the investment project is that they can be estimated without error. However, in the real world, the cash flows associated with investment projects represent forecasts, and not real values. Therefore the cash flows have to be estimated in an uncertain framework. As we will see in Chapter 8, risk affects return. Following on from this, an important principle in finance states that a safe dollar is worth more than a risky one. This principle also affects the calculation of NPV. Under uncertainty the NPV methodology still holds, but it has to be modified. It requires the use of expected cash flows and expected rate of return (as defined and calculated in Chapter 8). Example: Consider a firm that has to decide on the purchase of new equipment (termed project A). Assume that the relevant opportunity cost 142 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation of capital is 9 per cent, and the investment cost is £1,500. The cash inflows generated by the new equipment would be £500 over four years. The NPV of project A is: NPV = 500 500 500 500 – 1,500 = + £119.86 + + + (1.09)3 (1.09)4 (1.09)1 (1.09)2 As the NPV of project A is positive, it should be accepted. Activity 7.2* Assume an interest rate of 7 per cent. Calculate the NPV of each of the following projects, and state whether each of them should be accepted or rejected. •• Project B costs $1,100 immediately and generates $600 for each of the next 5 years. •• Project C costs $1,400 immediately. It generates $500 in year 1. It costs an extra $300 in year 2, and generates $500 in years 3, 4 and 5. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. In the presence of well-functioning financial markets (offering identical borrowing and lending opportunities, as defined later in Chapter 9), the channelling of funds from saver-lenders to spender-borrowers makes both parties better off. The condition for this to happen is that both parties decide by following two equivalent rules: • Net present value rule: firms have to invest in real assets with a positive NPV. In fact, the maximisation of the NPV increases the market value of the stockholder’s share in the firm. • Rate of return rule: stockholders and bondholders have to invest in securities with a return higher than the rate of return on equivalent investments in the capital market. Therefore the NPV rule enables firms to maximise shareholder wealth. NPV and mutually exclusive projects Mutually exclusive projects are a set of projects of which only one can be chosen at a given time. Firms have to choose one project among several that do the same job: for example, a manually controlled machine versus a computer controlled machine. Given that present values obey the additivity principle, it follows that the NPV also possesses the additivity property. Assume that a firm has only two projects (X and Y); the NPV of projects X and Y is equal to the NPV of project X plus the NPV of project Y. (Note that the additivity property holds because present values are all measured in today’s dollars.) This can be written as: NPV (X+Y) = NPV (X) + NPV (Y) (7.6) The additivity property implies that the value of the firm is simply the sum of the values of the separate projects. Because of the additivity property, when there are mutually exclusive projects, the NPV method indicates that the project with the largest positive NPV should be adopted. The reason for this is that the project with the largest NPV generates the largest NPV of the firm’s aggregated cash flows. One example clarifies the point that the choice of project relies on the additivity property. Assume that project X is a positive NPV project, while project Y is a negative NPV. The joint project (X+Y) will have a lower NPV than project X on its own. The NPV enables managers to avoid choosing bad projects just because they are packaged with good ones. 143 24 Principles of banking and finance NPV and limited funds The concept of limited funds refers to a situation where the amount of money available is less than the total investment cost of all the projects. With regard to the limited funds condition, we note that for safe projects, most firms would have no difficulty in raising more capital from financial markets and financial intermediaries. However, many large firms impose capital budgets on their divisions and subsidiaries as part of their internal control system, and this generates the situation of limited funds. Even when there are limited funds, the NPV additivity property enables firms to choose the best project. In practice, the choice of the projects can be made as follows. First, by calculating the NPV of all the feasible combinations of possible projects (by summing the NPV of all their constituents thanks to the additivity property). Second, by choosing the combination with the greatest NPV. Other real asset appraisal techniques The NPV method is the optimal technique for the valuation of real assets because it enables the management to maximise the expected wealth of shareholders. In practice, however, several other techniques are used, such as the Internal Rate of Return (IRR) and the payback period (analysed below). Internal rate of return (IRR) The internal rate of return (IRR) is the rate at which the present values of the cash inflows associated with a project equal the cash investment. The IRR is the discount rate that makes the NPV equal to zero. Mathematically, the IRR is found by solving this equation: N NPV = ∑ t =1 Ct (l + IRR)t –I=0 (7.7) The calculation of the IRR involves an iterative process, which can be viewed as a trial and error procedure (most electronic spreadsheets and financial calculators are able to do this). The choice of projects is made by comparing the IRR to a required rate of return termed hurdle rate (R*). If the IRR is higher than the hurdle rate, the project has to be accepted. Conversely, if the IRR is lower than the hurdle rate, the project has to be rejected. The hurdle rate is usually represented by the risk-free interest rate where cash flows are riskless (as assumed in the present analysis). The decision process can be represented by a graph, where the NPV is on the vertical axis, and the discount rate on the horizontal axis. In Figure 7.1, the IRR is higher than the hurdle rate (R*), and thus the project represented by this curve should be accepted. Note that if the hurdle rate is the opportunity cost of capital used in the NPV calculation, then the two methodologies (IRR and NPV) would give the same result, and thus the same investment recommendation. 144 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation NPV Project A IRR 0 R* R Figure 7.1: IRR and hurdle rate Example: Consider the purchase of additional machinery. The investment cost of the project is $9,500 today. Positive cash flows equal to $4,000, $5,000 and $4,000 will be generated respectively in years 1, 2 and 3. This cash flow structure can be summarised as follows: Cash flows ($) Project C0 C1 C2 C3 A –9,500 +4,000 +5,000 +4,000 Finally assume a risk-free rate of 7 per cent. The IRR is the rate in the equation: NPV = – 9,500 + 4,000 4,000 5,000 + + =0 (l + IRR) (l + IRR)3 (l + IRR)2 Let us arbitrarily try a 10 per cent discount rate. The NPV is not zero, it is positive (+ $1,273). As the NPV is positive, the IRR must be greater than 10 per cent. Let us try a 20 per cent discount rate. The NPV becomes negative (–$380). Therefore the IRR must be lower than 20 per cent. Plot these two combinations on a graph like Figure 7.1, and choose the IRR that gives the desired NPV of zero. This occurs when the IRR is 17.5 per cent. The IRR is higher than the hurdle rate (equal to the risk-free rate, 7 per cent), and thus the project is accepted. Instead of plotting the two points for NPV and discount rate on a graph and reading off the IRR from the graph we can use a linear interpolation method to estimate a value for the IRR. Here we assume the relationship between NPV and discount rate between the two points is linear. In fact, as we can see from Figure 7.1 the relationship is non-linear. By applying linear interpolation we will always find an approximate value for the IRR. Therefore, it is important that the two discount rates that we interpolate between are reasonably close together. The closer they are together, the more realistic our assumption of a linear relationship between NPV and discount rate becomes and the more accurate is our estimate of IRR. Of course, the two points we interpolate between must involve a positive NPV and negative NPV so that the line between the points captures the IRR (where NPV = 0). The formula for finding the IRR using linear interpolation is: IRR = r1 + [(NPV1 / (NPV1 + |NPV2|))] * (r2 – r1) where: 145 24 Principles of banking and finance r1 = lower discount rate r2 = higher discount rate NPV1 = NPV estimated using r1 |NPV2| = NPV estimated using r2 (note |NPV2| = absolute value of NPV2 For the example above: IRR = 10 + [(1,273 / (1,273 + 380))] * (20–10) IRR = 17.70% Note this is a slightly higher estimate than that obtained from reading off a graph. Of, course, because of the shape of the curve representing the relationship between NPV and discount rate, using linear interpolation to estimate the IRR will always lead to an over-estimate. A more precise estimate can be found by interpolating over a smaller range of discount values, say between 15 per cent and 20 per cent. When the discount rate is 15% the NPV is $389. Interpolating between 15 per cent and 20 per cent: IRR = 15 + [{389 / (389 + 380))] * (20 – 15) IRR = 17.53% Activity 7.3* Consider project ABC that costs $1,300 immediately. It generates $500 in year 1. It costs an extra $500 in year 2, and generates $1,600 in year 3. Assume a risk-free rate of 7 per cent. Then answer the following questions: 1. Calculate the IRR of project ABC, and state whether it should be accepted or rejected. 2. Would your decision remain the same if you use the NPV as a decision rule? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Limits of the IRR method In the IRR method, the discount rate is not the market-determined opportunity cost of capital as in the NPV: the discount rate is the IRR. The IRR assumption is that shareholders can reinvest their money at the project’s own internal rate, which is the same IRR. In contrast, the NPV assumes that shareholders can reinvest their money at the opportunity cost of capital determined by the market. Under the IRR, this assumption about the reinvestment rate implies that different rates can exist for projects with the same risk. Why should investors be able to reinvest at different rates for different projects with the same risk? Actually, in well-functioning capital markets, investors are not able to do so. This suggests that where there are perfect capital markets, it is the NPV and not the IRR method that makes the correct assumption about the reinvestment rate. Furthermore, in the evaluation of mutually exclusive projects, the IRR can lead to choices that do not maximise shareholders’ wealth. This usually happens when there are two projects (A and B), when one of the two (project A) is a longer-lived asset project (larger cash flows but occurring later). As shown in Figure 7.2, the IRR of both projects A and B exceed the hurdle rate (R*). Moreover, the IRR of project B is greater than the IRR of project A, and thus project B should be preferred. However, when the discount rate is low, B has the higher NPV; when the discount rate is high, A has the higher NPV. If we assume the hurdle rate is the opportunity cost of capital (used in the NPV calculation), then the NPV of project A is 146 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation higher than the NPV of project B. Therefore project A should be preferred. This implies that the additivity property does not apply to the IRR. The project with the largest IRR (B) is not the project with the largest NPV, and thus it is not the best choice in a set of mutually exclusive projects because it does not maximise shareholder wealth. Many managers, however, would choose project B on the basis of the IRR rule. The preference of managers for the IRR method could be justified under the assumption of a shortage of funds (see the previous comments on NPV and limited funds) because the cash flows of the shorter-lived project could finance another later project (whereas the longer-lived project would not allow them to do so). NPV NPV NPV A Project A B Project B 0 R R* IRR IRR A B Figure 7.2: IRR and mutually exclusive projects Finally, the IRR method can give either more than one solution or no solution. Because of possible changes in the structure of cash flows over time, several IRR can simultaneously satisfy equation (7.7). One example of a project with two IRR is a coal-mining investment, with the following cash flow structure: negative initial cash flows (creation of the mine), series of positive cash flows, and final negative cash flow for the land reclamation. As shown in Figure 7.3 below, for project C there are two IRR that make NPV equal to zero. Which IRR should the firm’s manager prefer in order to maximise shareholder wealth? The IRR does not give an answer to this question. NPV Project C 0 IRR C IRR C R Figure 7.3: Multiple IRR It is also possible to have no IRR, as shown in Figure 7.4 (opposite). Project D has a positive NPV at every discount rate, and thus is a very good project. However there is no IRR. In a case where the signs of the cash flows of project D were reversed (as in project E), the project would have no IRR and always have a negative NPV. The absence of IRR does not indicate whether a project creates or destroys value. From the above analysis, it is clear that the IRR method has strong limitations when evaluating real assets with the objective of maximising 147 24 Principles of banking and finance shareholders’ wealth. However, nowadays many companies use the IRR technique, and not the NPV. Although IRR seems easier to understand by non-financial managers, caution has to be used because of the limitations outlined above. The main concern is related to the drawbacks of the IRR rule in evaluating mutually exclusive projects, because of the inability of non-financial managers to evaluate all the possible projects. Project D R 0 Project E Figure 7.4: Non-existing IRR Activity 7.4 What are the reinvestment assumptions of NPV and IRR? Which is the correct assumption? Payback period method The payback period method evaluates real assets based on the number of years needed to recover the initial capital investment for the project. The firm decides a fixed payback period, for example two years. The project is accepted if it generates enough cash flows in the first two years to repay the initial investment. The project is rejected if it does not generate enough cash during the first two years. Example: Consider the following projects F and G: Cash flows ($) Project C0 C1 C2 C3 F –2,200 +600 +500 +2,000 G –2,200 +350 +2,100 0 The payback period is three years for project F, and two years for project G. Assuming an opportunity cost of capital of 9 per cent, the NPV of project F is equal to +$314, while the NPV of project G is –$111. (As a self-assessment exercise, check whether these NPVs are correct.) The NPV rule says accept project F and reject project G. However, if the firm uses the payback period rule with a cut-off period of two years, project G would be accepted (positive cash flows of $2,450 higher than the initial investment of $2,200) whereas project F would be rejected (positive cash flows of $1,100 lower than the initial capital investment of $2,200). The payback period rule supports an investment decision opposite to the one indicated by the NPV method. The accepted project G would actually decrease shareholder wealth. Note that where the firm chooses a cut-off period of three years, both projects would be accepted. 148 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation Activity 7.5* Consider the three projects I, L, M: Cash flows ($) Project C0 C1 C2 C3 C4 I –1,500 300 550 600 400 L –300 100 200 200 –100 M –6,200 2,000 3,000 2,000 5,500 a. Calculate the payback period of each project. b. Which project does the firm accept if the cut-off period is three years? c. If the firm invests in projects with the shortest payback period, which project would it invest in? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Limits of the payback period method The first limit of the payback period is that it ignores the cash flows after the cut-off date. Project F is rejected with a cut-off period of two years notwithstanding the large cash flow generated in year 3. The choice of the cut-off date is extremely critical, and should be tailored to the project’s life. Otherwise, poor, shorter-lived projects could be accepted at the expense of good, longer-lived projects. Secondly, the payback period rule ignores the time value of money (a foundation principle in finance, applied in both the NPV and IRR methods). Example: Consider the same project G of the previous example and project H, with the same cash flows, but with reversed occurrence dates. Cash flows ($) Project C0 C1 C2 C3 G –2,200 +350 +2,100 0 H –2,200 +2,100 +350 0 The payback rule suggests that both projects G and H should be accepted. However, the NPV of project H (+$21) is positive, while the NPV of project G (–$111) is negative. Activity 7.6 Here is a difficult question – see if you can answer it. How can we avoid the drawback? This drawback could be avoided by discounting the cash flows generated during the payback period. This alternative method, which takes into account the time value of money, is termed a discounted payback period. Nevertheless it does not avoid the first limitation of the payback period method. Overall, the payback period is a particularly simple ad hoc method, with theoretical limits much stronger than the ones of the IRR method (analysed in the previous section). This completes our review of the main techniques used to value real assets purchased by spender-borrowers. 149 24 Principles of banking and finance Valuation of financial assets (securities) Next we look at techniques used to evaluate financial assets (securities) issued by spender-borrowers on the financial markets to collect funds from the saver-lenders. The valuation of financial assets is based on the same present value principle underlying real asset valuation. The value of any asset (real or financial) equals the present value of all its future benefits (typically cash flows). This implies that pricing a financial asset requires knowledge of both its future benefits and the appropriate discount rate that converts future benefits into a present value. The degree of uncertainty about future benefits and discount rates varies according to the type of financial asset. As described in Chapter 2, financial assets can be classified in several broad groups: government bonds, corporate bonds, and preferred and common stocks. For government bonds investors know the future benefits (stream of cash flows) with a high degree of certainty. In contrast, for common stocks, estimating future benefits is quite challenging. As a consequence of the higher degree of uncertainty about future benefits, a higher discount rate has to be used in discounting those benefits to present value. In the following subsections we focus on the valuation methods of bonds and common stocks. Note that in this chapter we do not consider the relationship between risk and return for risky assets, which will be investigated in Chapter 8. Activity 7.7 What are the cash flows available to an investor in stocks? Which security (stock or bond) is on average more volatile? Compare the problem of estimating stock cash flows to that of estimating bond cash flows. Bonds As illustrated in Chapter 2, bonds can be classified into coupon bonds and zero coupon bonds. The differences in the characteristics of these two types of bonds require the use of different valuation methods. Coupon bonds The value of coupon bonds equals the present value of future interest and principal payments to be paid to the lender (bondholder) by the borrower (issuer of the bond). Recalling the present value principle, the price of a coupon bond (Pcb,ann) with annual coupon payments can be written as: Pcb,ann = N –1 ∑ t =1 c×P P×(1+c) + (1+rann)t (1+rann)N (7.8) where: P = principal payment c = annual coupon rate, that is the interest rate rann = annual compounded discount rate. • The principal is the face value of the bond. • The interest payment (coupon) is a specified percentage of the principal. This percentage is represented by the annual coupon rate. 150 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation • The discount rate is the required annual compounded rate of return on similar bonds. This is the return investors give up when they buy a specific bond. (Note that risk affects the required rate of return, as we will explain in Chapter 8.) Example: Assume you buy on 1 January 2010, a 2012 UK Treasury bond, with a coupon rate of 4 per cent and a face value of £1,000. The discount rate is 2.5 per cent, which is the interest rate offered by other mediumterm UK Treasury bonds on 1 January 2010. The interest payments received at the end of years 2010 and 2011 are £40 (= 4% of the face value of £1,000). At the maturity date (end of 2012), the government pays the principal (£1,000) plus the interest (£40). To value the bond, we need to discount the cash flows at the discount rate (2.5 per cent): Pcb,ann = PV = 40 40 40 = £1,042.83 + + 2 (1.025) (1.025)3 1.025 Activity 7.8* Now try one for yourself. Calculate the price of a four-year coupon bond, with principal $5,000, annual coupon rate 4 per cent, and required annual rate of return 8 per cent. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. In equation (7.8) the assumption is that coupon payments occur annually. In practice, most US government bonds make coupon payments semiannually (every six months). Therefore the price of a coupon bond with semi-annual coupon payments (Pcb,sem) is: Pcb,sem = 2N –1 ∑ t =1 c c P×(1+ ) ×P 2 2 + (1+rsem)t (1+rsem)2N (7.9) where: c/2 = semi-annual coupon rate (= annual coupon rate/2) rsem = semi-annual compounded discount rate (= annual compounded discount rate/2). Example: Recall the previous 2012 UK Treasury bond, and assume it makes semi-annual coupon payments. The semi-annual discount rate is 1.25 per cent (=2.5/2). Thus we have 6 six-month coupon payments of £20. The price becomes: Pcb,sem = PV = 20 20 20 20 1,020 20 + + + + + 2 3 4 5 (1.0125) (1.0125) (1.0125)6 1.0125 (1.0125) (1.0125) = £1,043.10 Activity 7.9* How does your answer to Activity 7.8 change with semi-annual coupon payments and a semi-annual discount rate of 4 per cent? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Zero coupon bonds The price of a zero coupon bond (bond with no coupon payments, such as a US Treasury bill) can be easily calculated by setting c=0 in equation (7.8). Formally, the price of a zero coupon bond can be calculated as: P (7.10) Pzcb = (1+r)N 151 24 Principles of banking and finance Example: Consider a Treasury bill maturing in six months and paying $10,000. Assuming a compounded annual rate of 4.08 per cent, the price today is $9,800. The price today is determined by discounting the value in 6 months ($10,000) by the six-month discount rate (4.08/2 = 2.04%: P = 10,000 / (1.0204) = $9,800 Common stocks (i.e. ordinary shares) Like the pricing of bonds, the valuation of common stocks requires us to calculate the present value of all future benefits. To value a share such as Tesco plc, we can use discounted cash flow (DCF) models. DCF models assume that the value of a stock is equal to the present value of the cash flows the stockholders expect to receive from the firm. Unlike bonds, which have contractual cash flows (interest and principal payments), common stocks have unspecified cash flows. What are the cash flows expected from common stocks? Common stockholders have to consider how much cash the firm will generate now and in the future, how much of that cash the firm will reinvest to finance growth, and how much the firm will distribute to stockholders via dividends. Therefore common stocks simply deliver a stream of uncertain future dividends to stockholders. However, we know that common stockholders receive payoffs in two forms: cash dividends and capital gains (or losses). Why are capital gains and losses apparently absent from the model used for the valuation of common stocks? Is this a problem? Dividend discount model To answer the above questions let us start with the definition of expected return on a stock over the next year (E(R)). It is a function of the expected dividend and expected capital gain. Formally this can be written as: E(R) = DIV1+P1– P0 P0 (7.11) where: DIV1 = expected dividend to be paid at time 1 P0 = current price of the stock P1 – P0 = capital gain on the stock. (Please refer to Chapter 8 for an investigation of the expected rate of return.) Rearranging equation (7.11), we can predict the current price of a stock in terms of forecasted dividends and expected price next year. Formally, this is: DIV1+P1 P0 = (7.12) 1 + re where: re = required annual rate on similar equity stocks. This is the return that can be earned in the financial market on securities of comparable risk. This discount rate reflects not only the time value of money, but also the riskiness of the stock (please refer to Chapter 8 to investigate the risk– return relationship). 152 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation Equation (7.12) is the fundamental valuation formula. It represents a market equilibrium condition: if it does not hold, stocks will be underpriced or over-priced (please refer to Chapter 9 to understand why this equation represents an equilibrium condition in efficient markets). When we come to use this equation, we immediately realise that we must estimate the price of the stock at time 1 in order find the value today. However, future stock prices are not easy to determine. What does determine future stock prices? The answer is contained in the same equation (7.12). The expected price at time t can be expressed as the expected dividends at time t+1 plus the price at the end of year t+1. Therefore, in equation (7.12), P1 could be replaced by (DIV2+ 2)/(1+re): P0 = DIV1 DIV2+P2 + 1 + re (7.13) (1 + re )2 The current price of a stock relates to the expected dividends for two years (DIV1 and DIV2) plus the forecasted price at the end of year two (P2). Accordingly, in equation (7.13), P2 could be expressed as (DIV3+P3)/ (1+re). Can you see that we can look as far into the future as we like? If we consider a period of N years, by extending equation (7.13), we predict the current price of a stock in terms of dividends over N years and the price at the end of year N: P0 = = DIV1 + P1 (1 + re ) + DIVt N ∑ = (1 + r )t + t =1 e DIV2 (1 + re ) 2 PN + DIV3 (1 + re )3 +...+ DIVN+PN (1 + re )N (7.14) (1 + re )N As the horizon period N approaches infinity, the present value of dividends accounts for an increasing proportion of the total present value of dividends and terminal price (note that the total present value is always equal to 100). At infinity, the present value of the terminal price approaches zero. (Have a look at Figure 4.1 in Brealey, Myers and Allen as an example of the decreasing relevance of the present value of the future price, and the increasing relevance of the stream of dividends.) Therefore, the value of common stocks equals the present value of future periodic dividends that stockholders expect the firm to distribute forever. This is known as the dividend discount model. Formally, the price today of a common stock (P0) can be written as: ∞ P0 = ∑ t =1 DIVt (1 + re )t (7.15) where: DIVt = dividends to be paid annually at time t. Because a common stock does not have a fixed lifetime, an infinite stream of dividends must be forecast. Even if capital gains do not appear in equation (7.15), it has been derived from the assumption that the current price of a stock is determined by the expected dividends and the capital gains over the next periods (remember equation 7.12). In short, stock valuation does not ignore capital gains, even if they do not appear in the valuation formula. 153 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 7.10 What do you think of the following statement? ‘You say stock prices equal the present value of future dividends? That’s crazy. All investors look for capital gains!’ Do you agree or disagree? See if you can find reasons for your view in what we say above. To implement equation (7.15) we need to know: • all the future dividends received until infinity • the appropriate discount rate. It is impractical to use the model in its purest form because we do not know the value of all the dividend payments to infinity. We therefore have to make a simplifying assumption about how the future stream of dividends evolves from the current dividend. Two possible assumptions are now discussed. Zero growth model The simplest scenario assumes a constant dividend stream (DIV = DIV1 = DIV2 =…= DIV∞). The valuation formula reduces to the equation for the present value of a perpetuity (illustrated at the beginning of this chapter). This is referred to as a zero-growth model. Formally, this is: DIV1 (7.16) P0 = r e Example: Consider stock ABC, which is expected to pay a dividend of $9.5 forever. The price today of the stock, assuming a required rate of return of 11 per cent, is $86.4. Gordon growth model Alternatively, expected dividends can be assumed to grow at a constant rate g per annum. To value such a common stock we just use the present value formula of a growing perpetuity (illustrated at the beginning of this chapter). The constant growth model is commonly called the Gordon growth model of equity valuation. The price of such a stock is: D1 (7.17) P0 = r – g e where: D1 = dividend expected at time 1 g = constant growth rate. Note that D1 is the next or expected dividend payment in the next period (period 1). Sometimes this may be seen as the company having announced its next dividend. More often this will not be known and we have to estimate it from the current dividend (D0) using: D1 = D0 (1+g) A key input in this model is the growth rate, the estimation of which is very challenging. The two main determinants of a firm’s growth rate are: the size of the new investments made by a firm, and the rate of return of the new investments. Another problem is that a firm’s growth may not be constant. Small firms with a new product may experience very rapid growth in their early years and then growth may slow down to more normal levels before possibly declining. Another problem is that some 154 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation firms may not pay dividends. Where this occurs, alternative valuation methods are required (outside the scope of this syllabus). Example: Consider stock WZY, which is expected to pay a dividend of $5 one year from now and this dividend is expected to grow at 5 per cent per year forever. Assuming a required rate of return of 11 per cent, the price today would be $83.3. Activity 7.11* Consider the following two stocks: •• Stock X is expected to pay a dividend of $11 forever. Stock Y is expected to pay a dividend of $6 next year. Thereafter the dividend growth is expected to be a constant annual rate of 6 per cent forever. Assuming that the required rate of return on similar stocks is 12 per cent, calculate the price of the two stocks. Which one is more valuable? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Summary In this chapter, we investigated how to value real assets and financial assets (i.e. securities). Financial assets are issued by spender-borrowers on the financial markets to collect money from saver-lenders, in order to buy real assets. We use the same concept in the valuation of both real and financial assets: discounting future cash flows back to their present value. Capital budgeting, which refers to the choice among alternative investments in real assets, uses several appraisal techniques. The NPV method enables firms to make choices that maximise the wealth of shareholders, whereas the IRR is sub-optimal in this regard. Investment decisions among alternative securities use valuation methods to determine the price of bonds and common stocks. These methods are differentiated on the basis of the degree of uncertainty about future cash flows and discount rates to be used in determining the present value. Key terms additivity property capital budgeting techniques discounted cash flow dividend discount model Gordon growth model hurdle rate incremental cash flows Internal Rate of Return (IRR) limited funds multiple IRR mutually exclusive projects Net Present Value (NPV) opportunity cost of capital payback period method present value zero-growth model A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain how to value real assets and financial assets • calculate the present value of cash flows • describe the Net Present Value (NPV) technique and its properties, and use it to appraise real assets • describe the Internal Rate of Return (IRR) technique and its limitations, and use it to appraise real assets 155 24 Principles of banking and finance • describe the payback period technique and its limitations, and use it to appraise real assets • evaluate the NPV method in relation to the other capital budgeting techniques • explain the valuation method of bonds, and be able to compute the price of a bond • explain the valuation methods of common stocks, and be able to compute the price of a common stock. Sample examination questions 1. Consider a project with the following cash flows: Cash flows (£) Project C0 C1 C2 A –1,000 +2,000 +750 a. How many internal rates of return does project A have? b. If the hurdle rate were 20 per cent, would you accept the project? Explain your answer. c. Describe the IRR method. Discuss the limitations of this method when compared to the NPV technique. 2. Consider the two following mutually exclusive projects (B and C): Cash flows (£) Project C0 C1 C2 C3 B –1,500 +600 +500 +100 C –1,500 0 +200 +1,400 a. Assuming an opportunity cost of capital of 10 per cent, what is the NPV of the two projects? Which project would you accept? b. What is the IRR of the two projects? Which project would you choose if the hurdle rate is equal to the opportunity cost of capital (10 per cent)? c. Discuss the reinvestment assumptions underlying the NPV and IRR method. d. How can we appraise a set of investment projects when funds to finance those investments are constrained? 3. At the end of January 2005, the interest rate on US government bonds maturing in 2008 is about 2 per cent. Value a bond with a 4 per cent coupon maturing in January 2008. a. Assume annual coupon payments and annual compounding. b. Assume semi-annual coupons and a semi-annual discount rate of 1 per cent. c. Describe the techniques used to value financial assets. Compare and contrast the methods used in the pricing of bonds and common stocks. 4. Consider the following three stocks: • Stock A is expected to pay a dividend of $5,000 next year. Thereafter the dividend growth is expected to be a constant annual rate of 6 per cent forever. 156 Chapter 7: Capital budgeting and valuation • Stock B is expected to pay a dividend of $5,000 next year. Thereafter the dividend growth is expected to be a constant annual rate of 20 per cent for 6 years (and zero thereafter). • Stock C is expected to pay a dividend of $1,200 forever. a. Assuming that the required rate of return on similar equities is 11 per cent, calculate the price of the three stocks. Which one is more valuable? b. Derive the dividend discount model for valuing stocks and discuss the assumptions that can be made to make the model practical. c. Why are capital gains apparently absent from the dividend discount model? 157 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 158 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Aims The aim of this chapter is to outline how risk affects the return of a security (or portfolio of securities), and hence how risk affects the value of the security (portfolio) in equilibrium. First, we illustrate how to calculate risk and return of individual securities and portfolios. Further, we explain how mean-standard deviation portfolio theory enables us to identify the optimal holding of securities for a risk-averse investor. Then we look at two key economic theories on asset pricing: the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) based on the mean-standard deviation framework, and an alternative model known as Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT). Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain how risk affects the return of a risky asset, and hence how risk affects the value of the asset in equilibrium • calculate risk and return for individual securities and portfolios, and understand the basic statistical tools of expected returns, standard deviations and covariances • explain the mean-standard deviation portfolio theory, and the meaning of its key concepts (efficient frontier, feasible region, capital market line, and optimal portfolio) • illustrate the effects of diversification • explain the main assumptions and results of the CAPM • illustrate the key concepts of the CAPM (beta and security market line) • explain the main assumptions and results of the APT • compare the theoretical and empirical validation of the CAPM and APT. Essential reading Brealey, R.A., S.C. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2010) tenth edition Chapters 7 and 8. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapter 4. Further reading Copeland, T.E., J.F. Weston and K. Shastri Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Boston, London: Pearson Addison Wesley, 2005) Chapters 4, 5, and 6. Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, S.J. Brown and W.N. Goetzmann Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2007) pp.59 and 61. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002) Chapters 4, 5 and 6. Luenberger, D.G. Investment Science. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1998) Chapters 6 and 7. 159 24 Principles of banking and finance References Chan, K.C., N. Chen and D. Hsieh ‘An Exploratory Investigation of the Firm Size Effect’, Journal of Financial Economics 14(3) 1985, pp.451–71. Chen, N. ‘Some Empirical Tests of the Theory of Arbitrage Pricing’, Journal of Finance 38(5) 1983, pp.1393–414. Chen, N., R. Roll and S. Ross ‘Economic Forces and Stock Market’, Journal of Business 59(3) 1986, pp.383–403. Dimson, E., P. Marsh and M. Staunton ‘Global evidence on the equity risk premium’, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 15(4) 2003, pp.27–38. Jacquier, E., A. Kane and A.J. Marcus ‘Geometric or Arithmetic Means: A Reconsideration’, Financial Analysts Journal 59(6) 2003, pp.46–53. Lintner, J. ‘The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets’, Review of Economics and Statistics 47(1) 1965, pp.13–37. Markowitz, H.M. ‘Portfolio Selection’, Journal of Finance 7(1) 1952, pp.77–91. Roll, R. ‘A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory’s Tests; Part 1: On Past and Potential Testability of the Theory’, Journal of Financial Economics 4(2) 1977, pp.129–76. Ross, S.A. ‘The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing’, Journal of Economic Theory 13(3) 1976, pp.341–60. Sharpe, W.F. ‘Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk’, Journal of Finance 19(3) 1964, pp.425–42. Introduction In light of the main function performed by financial markets – to channel funds from saver-lenders to spender-borrowers (as discussed in Chapter 2) – we now turn to the pay-off required by saver-lenders when they invest in the financial assets (securities) issued on the financial markets by the spender-borrowers (such as industrial firms) to finance their investments in real assets (discussed earlier in Chapter 7). Two main attributes characterise the pay-off of a security: return and risk. But thus far we have said little about where the expected return used in the valuation methods (as explained in Chapter 7) comes from, or about the relationship between the two attributes. The objective of this chapter is to demonstrate how the risk of a security affects the return required for it, and hence how risk affects the value assigned to the security in equilibrium. Risk and return of a single financial security Risk and return are the two main attributes of a financial security. The actual return of a security is the amount received divided by the amount invested. However, when securities are originally acquired, their returns are usually uncertain because their prices are subject to changes. For instance, say I bought shares in XYZ company in 2000 expecting a return of 10 per cent per annum for 7 years. Instead, my return was –20 per cent. Can you see that the actual return is –20 per cent, not what I had hoped to get? This implies that a variety of return outcomes are likely to exist, each occurring with a specific probability. Accordingly, the return measure of a risky asset is considered to be a random variable. For analytical purposes the uncertainty of the return is measured by the expected (average) return. To provide a quantitative measure of the expected return we normally use the weighted average of all possible returns, where the weights are the probabilities of occurrence of that return. Formally, this is: 160 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return (E)R = p1 R1 + p2 R2 + ... + pn Rn (8.1) where: (E)R = expected return Ri = return of the state of nature i n = number of possible states of nature (outcomes) pi = probability of occurrence of the return Ri. Note that returns and their probabilities are not usually known. However, in practice, historical average returns and number of past observations are often used as proxies. Figure 8.1 shows a typical distribution for historical returns on stocks in major corporations. Each point of the curve represents a stock. Based on past performance in the overall market, we estimate that the expected return is 13 per cent. We recognise that there can be significant deviations from the mean (13 per cent). In fact it is quite possible that return could be –10 per cent in one year and +35 per cent in the next year. (Note that the return can become arbitrarily large, but can never be less than –1, which represents the complete loss of the original investment in the stock.) Number of observations –1 13 Rate of return (%) Figure 8.1: A typical distribution of past rate of returns on stocks The variation around the expected return is a measure of the risk of a security. This is a measure of how far the actual return differs from the expected return. To provide a quantitative measure of the degree of possible deviations from the expected return we normally use a measure of dispersion of a distribution of historical returns: the variance. We frequently use the square root of the variance, called standard deviation. The standard deviation is a statistical measure of how variable the returns are around the average return. More formally, to calculate the standard deviation of returns we need to calculate the expected return (E)R, then to subtract the expected return from each return to get a deviation. Then we square each deviation and multiply it by the probability of occurrence of that outcome. Finally we add up all these weighted squared deviations and take the square root, that is: σ = √ p1(R1−(E)R)2 + p2(R2−(E)R)2 + ... + pn(Rn−(E)R)2 (8.2) The higher the standard deviation, the greater the variability, and hence the higher the risk. Example: Consider First Class, a stock with a return of 24 per cent onehalf of the time and 10 per cent one-half of the time. The expected return is 17 per cent (=0.5*0.24+0.5*0.10). The standard deviation is 7 per cent: = √ 0.5(0.24 − 0.17)2 + 0.5(0.10 − 0.17)2 161 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 8.1* Consider Second Class, a stock with a return of 16 per cent two-thirds of the time and 9 per cent one-third of the time. Then answer the following questions: 1. What is the expected return of the stock? 2. What is the standard deviation of the returns on the stock? 3. Is the Second Class stock more or less risky than the First Class stock? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Empirical evidence on risk, return and their relationship What are the levels of risk and return of financial securities around the world? The next activity enables you to find out some empirical evidence on risk and average returns associated with different classes of securities (stocks and bonds) for different countries. Activity 8.2 Download the Credit Suisse Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2010, available at: http://tinyurl.com/DMS2010 Carefully read the country profiles for the 19 countries focusing on figure 3 in each profile which shows the returns and risks of major asset classes from 1900 to 2009. The empirical evidence provided in the ‘Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2010’ shows both real and nominal returns. (Note that the difference between nominal and real performance rates arises because the purchasing power of income is reduced by inflation.) Among the 19 countries under investigation over 110 years, the best performer for stocks over the very long term is Australia, with an annualised percentage real return of 7.5 per cent since 1900, compared to a world average of 5.4 per cent. The worst performer for stocks is Italy with an annualised percentage real return of about 2.1 per cent since 1900. The best performer for bonds is Denmark, with an annualised percentage real return of 3.0 per cent since 1900, compared to a world average of 1.7 per cent. The worst performer for bonds is Germany, with an annualised percentage real return of about –2.0 per cent since 1900. Let us now focus on the USA. To find out the risk and average returns associated with different classes of securities in the US market, move to the next activity. Activity 8.3 Visit the Morningstar website at http://corporate.morningstar.com/ib/documents/ SampleContent/MktChartsImages.pdf and analyse the figure ‘Stock, Bonds, Bills and Inflation’. This Morningstar’s figure shows the amount available in 2006 by investing $1 at the start of 1926 in each of the four security classes (small companies’ stocks, large companies’ stocks, government bonds and Treasury bills). Values take into account inflation (i.e. real returns). By 2006, the performances in real terms are (in increasing order): Treasury bills (a money market debt instrument) grew to $18, long-term government bonds grew to $71, large stocks grew to $5658, and small stocks grew to $13796. The performance of each security class coincides with the intuitive risk ranking. Following on, we turn our attention to the relationship between risk and 162 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return 9.07 9.01 13.00 13.0 13.04 17.0 19.12 16.48 14.24 12.00 9.36 7.12 4.48 2.24 0.00 6.00 sto mm on S& P co ck s( m sto Sm all fir on mm Co ck s 0) 50 nd bo te ra po Co r me nt ve rn Go Risk premium (Extra return versus T-bills) s s nd bo ry su Tre a Average annual rate of return (nominal) Average annual rate of return (real) 3.00 2.01 5.07 2.07 1.08 3.09 0.080 bil ls % return. Figure 8.2 shows the risk (measured as risk premium, i.e. the extra return versus Treasury bills) and return (as measured by the average nominal and real annual rate of return) of US financial instruments over the period 1926–2000. Treasury bills were the least profitable (3.9 per cent nominal annual rate of return), but were also virtually risk-free (0 per cent risk premium). Common stocks obtained the highest average return (13 per cent nominal annual return), but also experienced the highest risk (9.1 per cent risk premium). Figure 8.2: Average rate of return and risk premium in the US Source: Figure created using data from: Brealey and Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance (2003) Table 7.1, p.186. A first interesting fact about the relationship between risk and return emerges: this relationship is positive. In other words, the performance of each security class increases with the risk ranking. This occurs because investors require compensation for bearing risk. The higher the risk associated with a financial instrument, the higher the return investors require to hold a financial asset. Moreover the relationship between risk and return varies over time, as shown in the next activity. Activity 8.4 Visit the Morningstar website at http://corporate.morningstar.com/ib/documents/ SampleContent/MktChartsImages.pdf and analyse the figure on ‘Reduction of risk over time’. This Morningstar’s figure provides evidence on how risk reduces over time. In the US market (with reference to the years 1926–2006), the level of risk (measured in terms of variability of returns) decreases by holding financial securities over longer periods of time. When the holding period is one year only, the level of dispersion of returns is very high: between –50 per cent and +135 per cent for small company stocks, and between 0 per cent and +20 per cent for Treasury bills. When the holding period is up to 20 years, the level of variability of returns is much more limited: between +5 per cent and +20 per cent for small company stocks, and between 0 per cent and +7 per cent for Treasury bills. Note that when the holding period is up to 20 years, the average returns of different security class converge towards the average nominal values analysed above. Specifically, they are: 12.6 per cent for small company stocks, 10.4 per cent for large company stocks, 5.5 per cent for government bonds and 3.7 per cent for Treasury bills. 163 24 Principles of banking and finance A second interesting fact about the relationship between risk and return emerges: the relationship changes over different holding periods. Specifically, the level of risk tends to reduce over longer holding periods. Risk and return of a portfolio: portfolio analysis A portfolio is a combination of different assets held by an investor. The share of the value of each individual asset over the total value of the portfolio is referred to as the weight of the asset in the portfolio. Obviously the sum of the weights of all the assets of the portfolio must be one (unity). Example: Consider an investor with a portfolio composed of two stocks: 75 The Coca Cola Company stocks and 50 Microsoft stocks. On 28 February 2008 the market prices of the two stocks were: The Coca Cola Company $41.16, Microsoft $26.67. The total value of the portfolio is $4,420. The portfolio weight for The Coca Cola Company is therefore 69.8 per cent. Activity 8.5* Calculate the portfolio weight for Microsoft. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. The expected return of a portfolio – (E)Rp – is simply the weighted average of the expected returns of the individual stocks of which the portfolio is composed, where the weights are the portfolio weights. Formally, this is: (E)Rp = w1 (E)R1 = w2 (E)R2 + ... + wn (E)Rn (8.3) where: wi = portfolio weight for stock i. Going back to our example, assume that the expected return over the coming year will be 10 per cent for The Coca Cola Company and 15 per cent for Microsoft. The expected return of the portfolio of the investor is 11.5 per cent = (0.698 × 0.10 + 0.301 × 0.15). The calculation of the risk of the portfolio is much more complex. We need to understand the statistical concept of correlation, which measures the degree to which two returns tend to move together. A positive correlation means that the two returns tend to move together; a negative correlation implies that the two returns tend to move in opposite directions; a zero correlation indicates that the returns of the stocks are wholly unrelated. A statistical measure of correlation is known as the correlation coefficient. It is simply the covariance divided by the product of the respective standard deviations. Formally the correlation coefficient is defined as follows: σ1,2 (8.4) ρ1,2 = σ σ 1 2 where: σ1,2 = covariance between stocks 1 and 2, which is a measure of the degree to which the two stocks move together over time (covary). The portfolio variance is the weighted average of several components: a) the variance of the returns on each stock (σi2 with i = 1,2) multiplied by the square of its portfolio weight (xi2); b) the covariance between stocks 1 and 2. Formally, this is: 2 σ 2p = w 21 σ 21 + w22 σ 2 + 2w1w2 ρ1,2 σ1σ2 (8.5) The portfolio standard deviation is of course the square root of the variance. Note that the standard deviation of a portfolio is simply the weighted average of uncorrelated (i.e. ρ1,2= 0). 164 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Now, given the expected returns, return variances and correlation coefficient for any set of assets, we should be able to calculate the expected return and variance of a portfolio composed of these assets. Example: Recalling our portfolio composed of The Coca Cola Company and Microsoft, let us calculate its variance. In the past the standard deviations were 35 per cent for The Coca Cola Company and 50 per cent for Microsoft. Assume that the two stocks are positively – but not perfectly – correlated (i.e. ρ1,2= 0.5). The variance of the portfolio is 11.9 per cent = [(0.698)2 × (0.35)2], + [(0.302)2 × (0.50)2] + 2 (0.698 × 0.302 × 0.5 × 0.35 × 0.50). Therefore the standard deviation is 34.5 per cent. Activity 8.6* Using the same weights and standard deviations given above, calculate the portfolio return variance in these three cases: 1. Negative correlation between returns, ρ1,2 = – 0.3. 2. Perfect positive correlation between returns, ρ1,2 = 1. 3. Uncorrelated returns, ρ1,2 = 0. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Benefits of diversification From most of the above calculations, you can note that the variance of the portfolio return is lower than that of any individual asset. This suggests that by forming portfolios (or by including additional assets in the portfolio), risk-averse investors are able to reduce risk. This process is referred to as diversification. The reason this works is that, in real stock return data, the correlations between returns are less than perfect. Note that diversification does not work in the extremely rare cases where returns move perfectly together. Conversely, if returns are uncorrelated, it is possible through diversification to reduce risk to zero. As shown in Figure 8.3 diversification can significantly reduce risk. The portfolio variance falls as the number of assets held increases. This benefit can be achieved even with a relatively small number of stocks (around 20 stocks). 60 Portfolio standard deviation 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 Number of assets Figure 8.3: Benefits of diversification Source: Graph created using data from: Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, S.J. Brown and W.N. Goetzmann Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2007) p.59. 165 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 8.7 Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009), p.75 (footnote 2) and summarise their example of how diversification works. The effectiveness of diversification in reducing the risk of a portfolio varies from country to country as shown in Figure 8.4. In Switzerland, Germany and Italy stocks tend to move together (high covariance), and thus diversification is less effective. Instead, in Belgium and the Netherlands, much more of the risk of holding individual stocks can be diversified away because of the low covariance. 90,00 80,00 70,00 60,00 50,00 40,00 30,00 20,00 10,00 0,00 Switzerland Germany Italy UK France US Netherlands Belgium International stocks Figure 8.4: Percentage of the risk on an individual security that can be eliminated by holding a random portfolio of stocks (1975) Source: Graph created using data from: Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, S.J. Brown and W.N. Goetzmann Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2007) p.61. Activity 8.8 Now think about what an investor in say, Germany, can do to achive greater risk reduction. The investor could invest some of their wealth in stocks listed outside of Germany. In fact many investors and investment funds diversify their portfolios internationally. However, this brings an additional risk – exchange rate risk. That is, the value of the foreign investments may decline due to changes in the exchange rate. Mean-standard deviation portfolio theory The aim of this section is to identify the optimal holding of risky assets for a risk-averse agent, since the investor seeks to minimise risk. This is known as the mean-standard deviation portfolio theory, and was developed by Markowitz (1952). The assumption is that agents have preferences that only involve expected portfolio returns and return standard deviations. The utility function is increasing in expected portfolio returns, and decreasing in return standard deviation. Efficient frontier and optimal portfolio with no risk-free asset Let us first consider two risky assets named X and Y. (We thus assume that there is no risk-free asset.) The two assets can be combined, according to some weights, to form a portfolio (a new asset). The diagram shown in 166 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Figure 8.5 describes the mean (Y-axis) and the standard deviation (X-axis) of any risky asset, and each point in this diagram represents an asset. As the portfolio weights for the two assets vary from 0 to 1, the portfolio goes from one that contains only asset X, to one that contains a mixture of assets X and Y, and then to one that contains only asset Y. As the portfolio weights vary, the new portfolios trace out a curve that includes assets X and Y. This curve, which looks something like the curved shape in Figure 8.5, is named the mean-standard deviation frontier. It shows the expected return and risk that could be achieved by different combinations (portfolios) of the two risky assets, and enables understanding of how investors view the trade-offs between means and standard deviations when they choose the portfolio weights of the assets to include in their portfolios. Note that an implicit assumption is made that investors are prohibited from short selling the assets (and thus borrowing the required money). As the investor’s preferences are increasing in return and decreasing in standard deviation (the investor wants to go up and to the right within the area of the diagram), the optimal portfolio will always lie on the frontier and to the right of the point labelled V. This point V represents the minimum-variance portfolio (i.e. a portfolio that offers the minimum risk). The minimum variance portfolio is found by differentiating the equation for the portfolio variance (equation 8.5) with respect to one of the weights, say, w1. The derivative of this equation is then set to zero and solved for w1. 2 2 2 w1 = (σ 2 − σ1σ2 ρ1,2) / (σ 1 + σ 2 − 2 σ1σ2 ρ1,2) The weight of the other asset (w2) in the minimum variance portfolio is found from: w2 = 1 – w1 Using the two calculated weights in equations 8.3 and 8.5 will give us the expected return and standard deviation of the minimum variance portfolio. Expected return (E)R Y V M -SD frontier X Standard deviation (σ) Figure 8.5: Mean-standard deviation frontier (2 risky assets) Only the upper part of the mean-standard deviation frontier will be of interest to risk-averse investors. In fact only the portfolios on the frontier and to the right of V maximise the expected return for a given standard deviation. In the absence of a risk-free asset, this set of portfolios (on the 167 24 Principles of banking and finance Expected return (E)R frontier and to the right of V) is termed the efficient frontier (as shown in Figure 8.6). This is the group of portfolios that both minimise risk for a given level of expected return, and maximise expected return for a given level of risk. B A Efficient frontier v Standard deviation (σ) Figure 8.6: Efficient frontier (2 risky assets) Activity 8.9* Risky asset A has an expected return of 15% and a standard deviation of 25% Risky asset B has an expected return of 35% and a standard deviation of 40%. If the correlation between the returns on assets A and B is 0.25 and the assets are combined in the following proportions: A B 1 1 0 2 .75 .25 3 .5 .5 4 .25 .75 5 0 1 Calculate i. the expected return and standard deviation for the 5 portfolios ii. the expected return and standard deviation for the minimum risk portfolio iii. plot all the portfolios calculated in (i) and (ii) on a graph and identify the efficient frontier. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. In order to identify the optimal portfolio (of two risky assets) for a given investor, we need to identify a set of preferences for this investor. This set of preferences towards risk and return can be represented by an indifference curve. Figure 8.6 shows two indifference curves for investors A and B respectively. The quite steep indifference curve on the left represents a relatively risk-averse investor (investor A), while the flatter indifference curve on the right represents a less risk-averse investor (investor B). The optimal portfolio is the portfolio where the investor’s indifference curve is tangent to the mean-standard deviation frontier. These two optimal portfolios (for the two different investors) are identified on Figure 8.6 at points A and B. In Figure 8.7 we draw the mean-standard deviation frontier for N risky assets using every possible weighting scheme. The set of all points 168 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Expected return (E)R representing portfolios made from N assets is called the feasible set or feasible region. The shape of the frontier is the same as in the case of two risky assets (as drawn in Figure 8.5). The difference is that the shaded area represents feasible but inefficient portfolios, which do not maximise the expected return for a given standard deviation. Feasible region Standard deviation (σ) Figure 8.7: Mean-standard deviation frontier (N risky assets) Activity 8.10* Consider a rational investor who has to choose one portfolio. Which portfolio would always be preferred for each of the following pairs of portfolios? 1. Portfolio A E(R) = 17% σ = 16% Portfolio B E(R) = 17% σ = 6% 2. Portfolio C E(R) = 15% σ = 16% Portfolio D E(R) = 12% σ = 16% *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Mean-standard deviation frontier with arbitrary correlation (ρ) In the last section, the mean-standard deviation frontier has been identified by assuming that the return correlation coefficient was between plus and minus one. Figure 8.8 shows the locus of the return-standard deviation frontier assuming different correlation coefficients. When there is perfect correlation (ρ = +1), the return–risk combinations are represented by a straight line. When the risky assets have less than perfect correlation (ρ <+1), the investor can reduce the portfolio risk by diversification. (As previously discussed, the standard deviation of this portfolio is less than the weighted average of the two standard deviations.) This gives the curvature to the left. The correlation determines the degree of curvature: the lower the correlation, the more distended the curvature. Finally, when the investor can include in the portfolio a risk-free asset with a return perfectly negatively correlated (ρ = –1), the return-risk combinations are represented by a pair of lines. 169 24 Principles of banking and finance Expected return (E)R B CML1 A CML2 K Rf M -SD frontier Standard deviation (σ) Figure 8.8: Mean-standard deviation frontier with arbitrary correlation The introduction of a risk-free asset: the capital market line Expected return (E)R Let us now introduce a risk-free asset, with expected return Rf and zero standard deviation. (As discussed in Chapter 2, in the USA the least risky asset is a US Treasury bill.) In Figure 8.9 we have plotted the expected return and risk of a portfolio composed by the risk-free asset and a combination of risky assets. A range of combinations of the risk-free asset and a portfolio of risky assets exist and two possible combinations (labelled CML1 and CML2) are shown in Figure 8.8. Note that CML stands for capital market line. ρ= −1 Rf ρ= 0 ρ= −1 ρ= +1 Standard deviation (σ ) Figure 8.9: Mean-standard deviation frontier (risk-free asset and N risky assets) We now need to identify the optimal portfolio for an investor who wants to hold a risk-free asset in addition to N risky assets. What is the optimal portfolio of risky assets for the investor? The optimal portfolio is represented by point K in Figure 8.8. The reason for this is that an investor will prefer to be somewhere on CML1 rather than any other CML (joining the risk-free asset to the efficient frontier (such as CML2).as all points along CML1 are superior (in terms of return for a given risk) to points on say, CML2. In presence of a risk-free asset and N risky assets, the efficient set becomes the optimal capital market line (CML1). We have achieved a very important result known as two-fund separation. Any risk-averse investor can form the optimal portfolio by combining two funds. The first is the risk-free asset, the second is the risky 170 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return asset portfolio K. The degree of risk-aversion determines the portfolio weights placed on the two funds. For example, in Figure 8.9, investor A is more risk-averse than investor B, and thus A puts more weight on the risk-free asset. This result allows us to identify the optimal portfolio of risky assets, K, that all investors who invest in risky assets will choose to hold irrespective of their risk preference. The two-fund separation theorem forms the starting point for the important Capital Asset Pricing Model, discussed in the next section. Optimal portfolios of the risk-free asset and the risky portfolio, K, lie along CML1 such that points to the left of K represent lending portfolios where the investor invests positive amounts in the risk-free asset. Points to the right of K represent borrowing portfolios where the investor borrows at the risk-free rate to increase the amount of funds they can invest in the optimal risk assets portfolio K. An example will help to illustrate this. Suppose an investor has $10,000 to invest. The expected return on portfolio K is 15 per cent and the standard deviation of returns is 20 per cent. The risk-free rate of interest is 5 per cent. A risk-averse investor may wish to invest half of his/her wealth ($5,000) in the risk-free asset and half ($5,000) in portfolio K. What is the expected return and risk for this efficient portfolio, say, A? E(RA) = 0.5 × 5% + 0.5 × 15% = 10% σA = 0.5 × 0 + 0.5 × 20% = 10% Note that the standard deviation of portfolio A is simply a linear weighted average of the individual risks of the two funds. Of course, the standard deviation of the risk-free asset is zero so the risk of this efficient lending portfolio is simply the weight assigned to portfolio K multiplied by the risk of portfolio K. A more risk-seeking investor may choose to borrow, at the risk-free rate, an amount of $5,000 giving him/her a total of $15,000 to invest in portfolio K. The expected return and risk of this borrowing portfolio, say B, is given by: E(RB) = −0.5 × 5% + 1.5 × 15% = 20% σB = −0.5 × 0 + 1.5 × 20% = 30% Activity 8.11 How can investors identify the best set of efficient portfolios of common stocks? What does ‘best’ mean? Asset pricing models The problem we want to solve in this section is to determine the correct, arbitrage-free, or fair price of an asset in equilibrium. In order to do so, it is necessary to identify theories that enable us to deduce this equilibrium price of a risky asset. We analyse first the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), which identifies the equilibrium price within the framework of the mean-standard deviation frontier. We then move to the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT), which does not require the assumption that investors choose their portfolios on the basis of means and standard deviations, but rather on the basis that two assets that are the same cannot sell at different prices. The CAPM model has been developed primarily by Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965), and the APT by Ross (1976). 171 24 Principles of banking and finance Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) To implement the mean-standard deviation frontier requires observing the optimal portfolio, which is the tangent portfolio (as discussed in the previous section). However, it is impossible to derive the tangent portfolio simply from observed returns on large numbers of risky assets. We thus need a theory that identifies the tangent portfolio from sound theoretical assumptions. This section develops one such theory, the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). To begin our discussion of the CAPM, let us first present the assumptions that underlie the theory: 1. Investors maximise their utility only on the basis of expected portfolio returns and return standard deviations. 2. Unlimited amounts can be borrowed or loaned at the risk-free rate. 3. Markets are perfect and frictionless (i.e. no taxes on sales or purchases, no transaction costs and no short sales restrictions). 4. Investors have homogeneous beliefs regarding future returns, which means that all investors have the same information and assessment about expected returns, standard deviations and correlations of all feasible portfolios. (Note that assumptions 1–3 were implicit in the mean-standard deviation analysis, while assumption 4 is an additional one needed to develop the CAPM.) From these assumptions, the main conclusion of the CAPM is that in equilibrium the tangent portfolio of risky assets must be the market portfolio. From the two-fund separation theorem everybody will hold a risk-free asset and a combination of risky assets. Furthermore, as everybody shares the same beliefs, everybody will use the same efficient fund of risky assets. This fund must be the market portfolio. Each investor will hold the same portfolio as everybody else; in other words, everybody will hold the market portfolio. The market portfolio is the portfolio comprising all assets, where the weight on each asset is the market capitalisation (also called market value) of that asset divided by the total market capitalisation of all risky assets. These weights are termed capitalisation weights. The market portfolio should include all risky assets and therefore all stocks and bonds listed on all exchanges and those traded over-the-counter as well as non-financial assets (such as real estate and durable goods). Therefore, the exact composition of the market portfolio is unobservable. Consequently, the implementation of the CAPM requires using proxies for the market portfolio. A frequently used proxy is a broadbased equity index such as the S&P500 (500 typically larger market capitalisation stocks traded on the NYSE and Nasdaq). Capital market equilibrium requires that the demand for risky assets be identical to their supply. The demand for risky assets is represented by the optimal portfolio chosen by investors, whereas their supply is given by the market portfolio. Under the CAPM assumptions, the equilibrium between risk and return can be expressed as: E(Ri*) = Rf + βi [E(RM) – Rf] (8.6) where: βi = the covariance of the returns on asset i with the return on a market portfolio, divided by the variance of the market return. Formally, this is: βi = σiM / σ2M 172 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return E(RM) = expected return on the market portfolio [E(RM) – Rf] = market risk premium, which is the amount by which the return of the market portfolio is expected to exceed the risk-free rate. The CAPM enables us to figure out what returns investors are looking for from particular security. Specifically, under the CAPM framework, the expected return of a given risky asset (or portfolio of assets) is equal to the risk-free rate plus a market risk premium multiplied by the asset or portfolio beta. To calculate this, we need three elements: • risk-free rate • beta • market risk premium. We showed estimates of the risk-free rate in the paragraph on ‘Empirical evidence on risk, return and their relationship’; and we will do the same for beta and market risk premium in the next paragraphs. Beta Under the CAPM framework, the standard deviation of an asset by itself is no longer an important determinant of the expected return of that asset. What is important is the beta of the risky asset (βi), which measures the sensitivity of an individual security to the market movements. The expected returns increase linearly with beta. Stocks with betas greater than 1.0 tend to amplify the overall movement of the market: generally speaking we expect aggressive companies or highly leveraged companies to have high betas. Conversely, stocks with betas between 0 and 1 tend to move less than the market: and therefore are typically conservative companies. A stock with a beta equal to one will mimic the market. Example: Consider the beta of Microsoft stock, which is equal to 1.527 (this estimate is provided by various data service organisations such as Bloomberg, and it is calculated by using a record of past stock values). This β value means that on average, when the market return increases by an extra 1 per cent, Microsoft’s return will rise by an extra 1.527 per cent. When the market decreases by an extra 2 per cent, Microsoft stock return will fall an extra 2 ×1.572 = 3.144 per cent. Activity 8.12 Visit the Yahoo finance website at http://finance.yahoo.com/. Download the beta values for the following companies: Amazon.com, Coca-Cola Co, Exxon Mobil, General Electric, General Motors, Google Inc., Hewlett Packard Co. (To do this, insert the name of the company in the section ‘Get Quotes’, and then click on ‘Key statistics’ under ‘Company’). Now rank these companies on the basis of their betas, identify the minimum and the maximum value, and explain the reasons for the differences. Activity 8.13 Decide whether each of the following statements is true or false. The expected return of an asset with a beta of 0.5 is half the expected return of the market. If the beta of an asset is lower than 0, the CAPM implies that its expected return will be lower than the interest rate. The beta of a portfolio (βp) is simply the weighted average of the betas of the individual assets in the portfolio (Bi), where the weights are the portfolio weights (wi). Formally this is: 173 24 Principles of banking and finance βp = ∑wβ i i (8.7) Market risk premium What about the value of the market risk premium? The market risk premium cannot be measured with precision, and practitioners and scholars are still debating about its magnitude and the method to be used for the estimation. Specifically, it can be estimated either by using an arithmetic average or a geometric average of historical returns. 2.24 7.05 6.02 5.08 5.06 4.05 7.04 4.00 5.03 5.02 3.01 6.01 6.08 4.08 6.06 5.03 6.04 8.02 10.00 3.04 4.06 5.07 5.00 4.04 3.02 3.36 2.07 4.48 4.06 6.00 5.09 7.12 7.01 7.00 8.24 9.06 8.05 9.36 9.05 10.48 10.06 With regard to the magnitude, some recent empirical evidence, as summarised in Figure 8.10, shows that the annualised arithmetic equity risk premium relative to bills was 7.05 per cent for the USA, 6.02 per cent for the UK and 5.09 per cent for the world index for the years from 1990–2001. These values are somewhat lower than the historical average risk premium over the longer period 1926–2000: for example, for the USA the risk premium over 1926–2000 was equal to 9.1 per cent (= 0.13 – 0.039; see Figure 8.2). The value of the market risk premium varies internationally: over the period 1990–2001, the risk premium in Denmark was only 3.02 per cent (bottom end), whereas in Germany it was up to 10.0 per cent and in Italy to 10.06 per cent. Some of these variations may reflect differences in risk (i.e. Italian stocks may have been particularly variable and investors may have required a higher return to compensate). Geometric Arithmetic 1.12 US UK W or Au ld str ali Be a lgi um Ca na De da nm ar k Fra nc Ge e rm an y Ir e l an d Ita ly Th e N Jap a et he n r So land ut h s Af ri c a Sp ain Sw ed Sw en i tz er lan d 0.00 Figure 8.10: Market risk premium (relative to bills) around the world (1990–2001) Source: Figure created using data from Dimson, Marsh, Staunton (2003). As regard to the method to be used for the estimation, Figure 8.10 reveals that the risk premium measured by geometric averages is much lower than the premium based on arithmetic averages. For example, the annualised geometric equity risk premium relative to bills was 5.06 per cent for the USA (instead of 7.05 per cent). Accordingly, the Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2005 (LBS/ABN Amro) estimates that the plausible forwardlooking risk premium for the world’s major markets would be of the order of 3 per cent relative to bills on a geometric mean basis, whereas the corresponding arithmetic mean risk premium would be around 5 per cent. Which method should be preferred? The arithmetic average is the norm for the estimation, but the debate is still open (for example Jacquier et al., (2003) show that the correct estimation requires compounding at a weighted average of the arithmetic and geometric historical averages). 174 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Security market line The CAPM equilibrium relationship between risk and return has a very simple graphical representation. The CAPM formula can be seen as a linear relationship between the expected return and β, which is known as the security market line (SML). As shown in Figure 8.11, beta is on the horizontal axis, while the expected return is on the vertical axis. The expected return on a risk-free asset is Rf. An asset with β of unity has an expected return equal to that of the market E(RM): this asset is the market portfolio (M). Therefore the security market line is a straight line emanating from the risk-free point and passing through the market portfolio. In equilibrium every stock must lie on the security market line: no stock can lie below or above the security market line. This happens because any investor can always obtain a market risk premium of βi[E(RM) – Rf] by holding a combination of the market portfolio and the risk-free asset. Expected return (E)R Example: Consider Microsoft stock. Given a beta equal to 1.527, a market risk premium of 9 per cent, and a risk-free rate of 3.5 per cent, the expected return for Microsoft must be 11.9 per cent [= 0.035 + 1.527 × (0.09 – 0.035)]. M E(R M ) SML Rf 1 Beta (β) Figure 8.11: Security market line Activity 8.14* Assume that the return on US Treasury bills is 3 per cent, the expected return on the market portfolio is 12 per cent. On the basis of the CAPM: 1. Draw a graph showing the relationship between the expected return and beta. 2. What is the risk premium on the market? 3. What is the required return on a stock with a beta of 1.5? 4. What is the beta of a stock if the market return is expected to be 12.5 per cent? *The solution to part of this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Diversifiable risk and market risk In equilibrium two assets with identical expected returns must have identical betas, although their standard deviations can differ. The reason for the difference in the standard deviation is that a portion of risk can be eliminated through diversification (as discussed before). The risk that can be eliminated by diversification is known as diversifiable risk (or unique, specific, non-systematic risk), which is the risk peculiar to a company or its immediate competitors. Investors do not need any reward to bear such risk, and hence diversifiable risk does not affect expected 175 24 Principles of banking and finance returns. However, there is some risk that cannot be avoided, regardless of how much investors diversify. This risk is known as market risk (or systematic, undiversifiable risk), which can be thought of as the risk of the market as a whole. The exposure of an asset to such risk can be summarised by beta. For a reasonably well diversified portfolio only market risk matters. Recall Figure 8.3, which shows that the portfolio standard deviation depends on the number of securities in the portfolio. Following on, as shown in Figure 8.12, by adding securities, and therefore by diversification, portfolio standard deviation decreases until all diversifiable risk is eliminated, and only market risk remains. (If you have only one stock, diversifiable risk is very important; however, if you hold a portfolio of 20 or more stocks, only market risk matters.) The magnitude of market risk depends on the average betas of the securities included in the portfolio. σ Diversifiable risk β Market risk Number of securities Figure 8.12: Diversifiable and market risk Theoretical and practical limitations of the CAPM The tests of the CAPM investigate how well it describes reality. However, even before we examine these tests, it is useful to develop an asset pricing model based on more realistic assumptions. The CAPM developed in the previous section is termed the standard CAPM because it provides a complete description of the behaviour of capital markets if each of the underlying assumptions are held. A wide literature examines the effects of modifying these assumptions, with a special emphasis on two of them: the ability to lend and borrow infinite sums of money at the risk-free rate (in the real world, generally the risk-free rate is not a real rate because of uncertainty about inflation, and borrowing rates are higher than lending rates), and the absence of personal taxes. The removal of these assumptions leads to the development of the non-standard forms of the CAPM. (Note that in practice none of these modified versions is as widely used as the standard CAPM.) From a theoretical perspective, the implementation of the CAPM requires the use of proxies for the market portfolio because the exact composition of the market portfolio is unobservable (as explained earlier). As argued by Roll (1977), the unobservability of the market portfolio makes the CAPM untestable. Given that the quality of the proxies used for the market portfolio cannot be guaranteed, it is not possible to test the CAPM. There could be two alternative situations. 176 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return • First, it might be the case that the market portfolio is efficient (and hence the CAPM is valid), but the proxy chosen is inefficient (and hence the empirical tests incorrectly reject the CAPM). • Second, the proxy for the market portfolio might be efficient (and hence the empirical tests validate the CAPM), but the market portfolio itself is not efficient (and hence the validation is false). Academics have been debating whether the CAPM is testable for many years without arriving at a consensus; nevertheless the model is widely applied by practitioners and largely tested by researchers by using several proxies for the market portfolio. These tests provide valuable – but not conclusive – insights on the appropriateness of the CAPM. Overall, these tests provide broad support for the CAPM by showing that the expected return increased with beta over the period 1931–91, even if less rapidly than the CAPM has predicted. However, critics of the CAPM pointed out two problematic pieces of empirical evidence. • First, in recent years the slope of the security market line has been much flatter than one would expect from the CAPM. This means that high-beta stocks performed better than low-beta stocks, but the difference in their actual returns was not as great as the CAPM would predict. This evidence is against the CAPM. However, the supporters of the CAPM argue that the evidence could be due to the fact that the CAPM itself is concerned with expected returns, whereas the tests only use actual returns. Actual returns do reflect expectations, but they are also largely affected by noise. • Second, factors other than beta (such as firm size, book-to-market ratio, price-to-earnings ratio and dividend yield) have all been found in empirical studies to explain ex-post realised returns (after controlling for beta). This contrasts with the CAPM, which predicts that beta is the only factor that explains expected returns. For example, small capitalisation stocks (known as small-cap) did better than large capitalisation stocks over the period 1932–97. Although they have higher betas, the difference in betas is not enough to explain the difference in returns. It seems that investors saw risks in small-cap that were not captured in their beta. One explanation for this result could be ‘data-snooping’ or ‘data mining’. (This refers to the fact that many researchers look at past sample returns, and they are bound to find a strategy that, just by pure chance, has worked in the past.) Actually, the supporters of the CAPM proved that the small–large cap results vanished once they were discovered. This empirical evidence can suggest either that the CAPM does not hold or that tests do not prove anything about the CAPM because of Roll’s insights. The controversial nature of the evidence and the difficulties in interpreting this evidence have led to other asset pricing theories, such as the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (discussed in the next section). Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) The alternative asset pricing paradigm, known as Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) is, in some ways, less complicated than the CAPM. It simply requires that the returns on any stock be linearly related to one factor (or a set of factors), as with factor models (discussed below). 177 24 Principles of banking and finance Factor models The basic idea of factor models is that all common variations in stock returns are generated by movements in one factor (or a set of factors). The simplest factor model is a one-factor model, which assumes that there is only one factor. Formally, it can be written as: Ri = ai + bi1F1 + εi, E(εi) = 0 (8.8) where: ai = expected level of return for stock i if all factors have a value of zero. F1 = value of the factor 1 that affects the returns on stock i. The factor is posited to affect all stock returns, although different stocks can have different sensitivities. The factor can be represented by macroeconomic conditions, financial conditions or political events. Examples are: market index (e.g. S&P500), yield spread (return on long-term government bonds less return on 30-day Treasury bills), interest rate (change in Treasury bill return), change in the forecast of real GNP (Gross National Product), and change in forecast of inflation. bi1 = sensitivity of the returns on stock i to factor 1. High values of bi1 imply that variations in F cause very large movements in the return on stock i; whereas small values indicate that stock i reacts only slightly to changes in F. εi = random error term. This random stock return is termed the idiosyncratic return component for stock i. It has a mean equal to zero and variance equal to σ2ei. Moreover, it is uncorrelated across stocks and with F; thus Cov (εi, εj)= 0, and Cov (εi, F)= 0. The idiosyncratic return comes from events that are unique to the firm. Examples of the idiosyncratic return can be a legal action against the company of stock i, or the unexpected departure of a company’s CEO. A generalisation of equation (8.8) represents a multi-factor model, where a set of j factors affects the returns on stock i: Ri = ai + bi1F1 + bi2F2 + ...+ (εi), E(εi) = 0 (8.9) To determine the return on a portfolio, given the above factor structure, we need to calculate the portfolio weighted averages of the individual factor sensitivities. An example could clarify this simple calculation. Example: Consider two stocks (X and Y), whose returns are determined by the following one-factor model: Rx = 0.03 + 0.9F1 + εx; RY = 0.06 + 0.8F1 + εY To determine the return of an equally weighted portfolio of the two assets (½ stock X and ½ stock Y), we simply need to form a weighted average of the stock sensitivities of individual factors: Thus the portfolio return can be written as: ap = 1 1 (0.03 + 0.06) = 0.045 ; bp = (0.9 + 0.8) = 0.85 2 2 Thus the portfolio return can be written as: RP = 0.045 + 0.85F1 + εP Activity 8.15* Assume that the portfolio weights of the above stocks (X and Y) are 0.25 and 0.75. Using the data of the previous example, compute the portfolio return representation. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. 178 Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Arbitrage Pricing Theory The Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) is based on the primary – simple – assumption that when returns are certain, investors prefer greater returns to lesser returns. The mechanism for doing so involves the use of arbitrage portfolios, and thus the following four assumptions: 1. There are no arbitrage opportunities. Arbitrage opportunities represent the possibility of earning riskless profits by taking advantage of differential pricing for the same asset. There are two possible ways to define arbitrage strategies. First, to invest in a set of assets that yield positive immediate cash inflow (obtained by the sale of assets at a relatively high price and the simultaneous purchase of the same assets at a relatively low price), with no loss in the future. Second, to invest today in costless investment strategy, and to obtain positive future cash inflows (as described above). In both cases, when returns are certain, any investor who prefers greater returns to lesser returns would invest as much as possible. Under the APT, these investment strategies should not be permitted in properly functioning financial markets. 2. Returns of risky assets can be described by a factor model, as described in the previous subsection. 3. Financial markets are frictionless (i.e. there are no transaction costs or related market frictions). 4. There is a large number of securities and so investors hold welldiversified portfolios. This implies that diversifiable risk does not exist. (Note that the sources of risk for any individual stock are: risk arising from macroeconomic factors, which cannot be eliminated by diversification; and diversifiable risk associated with events that are unique to the firm, which can be totally eliminated by diversification.) Under the APT, the absence of arbitrage opportunities places restrictions on the relationship between the expected returns on individual assets (and hence on a well-diversified portfolio) given the factor structure underlying returns. The key to the APT is that a factor model with no arbitrage opportunities implies that assets with the same factor sensitivities must offer the same expected returns in financial market equilibrium. Therefore the expected risk premium on an individual asset (equal to the expected return on an individual asset minus the risk-free rate) depends on the sum of the expected risk premiums associated with each factor multiplied by the asset sensitivity to each of these factors. Thus the expected return on an individual asset can be written as: E(R*X)= Rf + b1x λ1 + b2X λ2 +...+bjX λj (8.10) where: λj = (RFj– Rf), which is the risk premium over the risk-free rate associated with factor j. The risk premium is affected only by macroeconomic factors, and not by unique risk (note the similarity with the CAPM). Moreover, it varies in direct proportion to the asset’s sensitivity to the factor. For example, consider a risk premium equal to 5 per cent for the real GNP factor. It means that stocks with a positive average sensitivity to changes in real GNP (i.e. with b = 1) give an additional return of 5 per cent a year compared with stocks completely unaffected by real GNP. Conversely a risk premium equal to –1 per cent for the inflation factor means that stocks with average exposure to inflation give a 1 per cent less return than stocks with no exposure to inflation. (Note that an asset with zero sensitivity to each factor is essentially risk-free, and thus must be priced to offer the risk-free rate.) 179 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 8.16* Consider a two-factor APT model. The factors and associated risk premiums are: Factor Risk premium Change in GNP 6% Change in long-term interest rates 1.5% Assuming a risk-free rate equal to 6 per cent, calculate the expected rates of return on the following stocks: a. A stock whose return is uncorrelated with all the two factors. b. A stock with a positive average exposure to each factor. *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Theoretical and empirical validation of the APT The APT provides an interesting alternative perspective to that of the CAPM on the nature of equilibrium. From a theoretical point of view, however, the theory is far from easy to implement. The advantage of the APT is that it does not require us to identify and measure the market portfolio (solving most of the problems presented in the previous subsection on the theoretical limitations of the CAPM). The disadvantage is that it does not tell us what the underlying factors are (unlike the CAPM, which collapses all the macroeconomic factors into the market portfolio). Empirical research is still in the early stages as regards the APT, and is not as well developed as the literature on the CAPM. Many studies have been particularly interested in whether the APT explains the size effect discussed about the CAPM. Although the evidence is not conclusive, the majority of the studies (see among others: Chen, 1983; Chan, Chen and Hsieh, 1985) find that the size effect becomes negligible in a multi-factor framework. Other studies focused on the identification of the factors with significant effects on risk premiums. Chen, Roll and Ross (1986) emphasise the relevance of growth in real GDP, interest spread and changes in default spreads. Summary 180 The main objective of this chapter was to illustrate modern portfolio theory. In order to do so, it began with an analysis of the risk–return characteristics of individual securities and portfolios. It then moved to the identification of the optimal portfolio of securities for a risk-averse investor, taking into account the risk–return trade-off. This requires the understanding of several important concepts, such as efficient frontier, feasible region, and capital market line. The mean-standard deviation analysis leads to a key result known as two-fund separation: any riskaverse investor forms an optimal portfolio by combining a risk-free asset and a specific risky asset portfolio. This framework underlies the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) used for the pricing of risky assets. The CAPM states that in equilibrium the optimal risky portfolio must be the market portfolio: thus the expected return of a risky asset has to be equal to the risk-free rate plus a market risk premium multiplied by the asset beta (β). An alternative asset pricing model is the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT), which in a context of no arbitrage opportunities derives expected returns on the basis of factor models. It asserts that assets with the same factor sensitivities must offer the same expected returns in equilibrium. A comparison of the theoretical and empirical validation of the two asset pricing theories concluded the chapter. Chapter 8: Securities and portfolios – risk and return Key terms actual return Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) asset pricing models beta Capital Asset Pricing Model capital market line (CAPM) capitalisation weights correlation coefficient diversifiable risk diversification efficient frontier efficient set expected return expected risk premium factor models feasible region frontier market risk mean-standard deviation minimum-variance portfolio modern portfolio theory optimal portfolio portfolio risk risk-free asset security market line standard deviation two-fund separation variance A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain how risk affects the return of a risky asset, and hence how risk affects the value of the asset in equilibrium • calculate risk and return for individual securities and portfolios, and understand the basic statistical tools of expected returns, standard deviations and covariances • explain the mean-standard deviation portfolio theory, and the meaning of its key concepts (efficient frontier, feasible region, capital market line, and optimal portfolio) • illustrate the effects of diversification • explain the main assumptions and results of the CAPM • illustrate the key concepts of the CAPM (beta and security market line) • explain the main assumptions and results of the APT • compare the theoretical and empirical validation of the CAPM and APT. Sample examination questions 1. a. ‘The more risk-averse investors are, the more likely they are to diversify.’ Is this statement true, false or uncertain? Explain your answer. b. When the number of assets included in a portfolio increases, what is the effect on the portfolio standard deviation? When the number of assets increases towards infinity, towards what value does the portfolio standard deviation converge to? c. What does the mean-standard deviation frontier look like in the presence of two risky assets (and no risk-free asset)? How does it change when there is a risk-free asset? Why does one line, the capital market line, dominate all the other possible portfolio combinations? d. Explain the tangent portfolio. 2. An investor has two assets available named X and Y. Asset X has an expected return of 7 per cent and a standard deviation of 4 per cent. Asset Y has an expected return of 12 per cent and a standard deviation of 6 per cent. 181 24 Principles of banking and finance a. Assume the investor places portfolio weight ½ on asset X, and ½ on asset Y. Assuming that the returns to the two assets are perfectly positively correlated, calculate the expected return and the standard deviation to the portfolio. b. How would your answer change if the correlation coefficient were 0.5? c. Graphically depict the mean-standard deviation frontier implied in parts a) and b). d. In general, what does the mean-standard deviation frontier look like when the correlation coefficient is between –1 and +1? 3. What is the two-fund separation theorem? What implications does it have for the optimal portfolio of risky assets held by investors? How does the CAPM address this problem? 4. Under the CAPM framework, what is the market portfolio? What is the security market line? What is the significance of the beta of a risky asset? Support your answer with graphical evidence. 5. What is a factor model? What does absence of arbitrage mean? How is the Arbitrage Pricing Theory derived from the two previous notions? 182 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information Aims The aim of this chapter is to investigate whether stock prices reflect all available information in financial markets, and hence whether the efficient market hypothesis holds. In this chapter we will explain that the main objective of informational efficiency tests is the ability of investors to make excess returns on a certain information set. We then analyse the three broad observable information sets commonly used to define informational efficiency: weak-form, semi-strong-form and strong-form efficiency. Finally, we illustrate the key empirical evidence in favour of or against each of the three forms of efficiency. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • explain whether stock prices reflect all available information, and hence whether the efficient market hypothesis holds • explain the relevance of the efficient market hypothesis, and derive the hypothesis from a theoretical perspective • explain the concept of excess returns in the context of informationefficient markets • describe the three main forms of market efficiency (weak-form, semistrong-form and strong-form) • discuss the empirical evidence in favour of weak-form efficiency (random walk behaviour of stock prices, uselessness of technical analysis) and against weak-form efficiency (presence of calendar effect, small firm effect and mean reversion) • discuss the empirical evidence in favour of semi-strong-form efficiency (incorporation of earnings-announcement information) and against semi-strong-form efficiency (market overreaction and underreaction to new information) • discuss the empirical evidence in favour of strong-form efficiency (mutual fund performance) and against strong-form efficiency (excess return of corporate insiders). Essential reading Brealey, R.A., S.C. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, London: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2010) tenth edition Chapter 13. Mishkin, F. and S. Eakins Financial Markets and Institutions. (Boston, London: Addison Wesley, 2009) Chapter 6. Further reading Copeland, T.E., J.F. Weston and K. Shastri Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Boston, London: Pearson Addison Wesley, 2005) Chapter 10. Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, S.J. Brown and W.N. Goetzmann Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2007) Chapter 17. 183 24 Principles of banking and finance Smart, S.B., W.L. Megginson and L.J. Gitman Corporate Finance. (Mason, Ohio: South-Western/Thomson Learning, 2004) Chapter 10. References Allen, F. and R. Karjalainen ‘Using Genetic Algorithms to Find Technical Trading Rules’, Journal of Financial Economics 51(2) 1999, pp.245–71. Ball, R. and P. Brown ‘An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers’, Journal of Accounting Research 6(2) 1968, pp.159–78. Bernard, V. and J. Thomas ‘Post-earnings announcement drift: Delayed price response or risk premium?’, Journal of Accounting Research 27(3) 1989 supplement, pp.1–36. Brock, W., J. Lakonishok and B. LeBaron ‘Simple Technical Trading Rules and the Stochastic Properties of Stock Returns’, Journal of Finance 47(5) 1992, pp.1731–764. Carhart, M.M. ‘On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance’, Journal of Finance 52(1) 1997, pp.57–82. Cheng-few L., D.C. Porter and D.G. Weaver ‘Indirect tests of the HaugenLakonishok small-firm/January effect hypotheses: window dressing versus performance hedging’, The Financial Review (1998) 33, pp.177–94. DeBondt, F.M. and R. Thaler ‘Further Evidence on Investor Overreaction and Stock Market Seasonality’, Journal of Finance 42(3) 1987, pp.557–80. Fama, E. ‘Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work’, Journal of Finance 25(2) 1970, pp.383–417. Fama, E. ‘Efficient Capital Markets II’, Journal of Finance 46(5) 1991, pp.1575– 618. Fama, E. and K.R. French ‘Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock Prices’, Journal of Political Economy 96(2) 1988, pp.246–73. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman ‘Mutual Fund Performance: an Analysis of Quarterly Portfolio Holdings’, Journal of Business 62(3) 1989, pp.393–416. Haugen, R. and J. Lakonishok The Incredible January Effect. (Dow Jones-Irwin, Homewood, Illinois, 1988) [ISBN 9781556238710]. Jegadeesh, N. and S. Titman ‘Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency’, Journal of Finance 48(1) 1993, pp.65–91. Jensen, M.C. ‘The performance of Mutual Funds in the Period 1945–64’, Journal of Finance 23(2) 1968, pp.389–416. Keim, D.B. ‘The CAPM and Equity Return Regularities’, Financial Analysts Journal 42(3) 1986, pp.19–34. Lo, A. and C. MacKinlay ‘Stock Market Prices do not Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test’, Review of Financial Studies 1(1) 1988, pp.41–66. Patell, J.M. and M.A. Wolfson ‘The Intraday Speed of Adjustment of Stock Prices to Earnings and Dividend Announcements’, Journal of Financial Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.223–52. Poterba, J.M. and L.H. Summers ‘Mean Reversion in Stock Prices: Evidence and Implications’, Journal of Financial Economics 22(1) 1988, pp.27–59. Introduction In Chapter 7 we learned the methods used for security valuation. The main aim of this chapter is to investigate how good the financial market is at establishing prices for securities by using all available information. A financial market is referred to as informational efficient, when security prices fully reflect all available information. This form of efficiency is referred to as informational efficiency. Informational efficiency is a more specific form of the general valuation efficiency, which refers to whether the prices of the securities traded on 184 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information a market reflect the true fundamental (also termed intrinsic or fair) value of the securities. Under valuation efficiency, all prices are always correct, and reflect market fundamentals (items that have a direct impact on future cash flows of the security). Therefore, the market price of a security is the fair price, and has to be equal to the expected cash flows from the security using all relevant information. Informational efficiency is a more specific form of efficiency than valuation efficiency, because it assumes that expectations are optimal forecasts using all available information, but not that market prices reflect the fair value. Valuation efficiency and informational efficiency are conditions for the achievement of the most general efficiency condition of financial markets: allocative efficiency. This refers to whether a market allocates productive resources to the most productive investments in performing its main function of channelling funds from saver-lenders to spenderborrowers (as described in Chapter 2). This requires asset prices to reflect accurately the discounted stream of future cash flows the asset is expected to generate over its existence (see Chapter 7). The price of an asset then acts as a signal directing resources from savers into the common stocks yielding the highest returns and from firms into the real assets yielding the highest returns. This relationship between informational efficiency and allocative efficiency is captured in the following opening paragraph from Fama’s 1970 review of the evidence on market efficiency: The primary role of the capital market is allocation of ownership of the economy’s capital stock. In general terms, the ideal is a market in which prices provide accurate signals for resource allocation: that is, a market in which firms can make productioninvestment decisions, and investors can choose among the securities that represent ownership of firms’ activities under the assumption that security prices at any time ‘fully reflect’ all available information. A market in which prices always ‘fully reflect’ available information is called ‘efficient’. Fama, (1970) Informational efficient markets The concept of informational efficient markets is of fundamental importance for several reasons. First, the main objective of capital budgeting is to maximise shareholder wealth, which implies the maximisation of the value of the firm’s stocks (please refer to our discussion on the Net Present Value in Chapter 7). As a consequence, it is important that financial markets are able to value the firm’s stocks correctly. The signal given by the financial market to the stockholders (through the price) has to reflect the firm’s decisions on investment projects in a correct way. Moreover, capital budgeting techniques use a discount rate for the appraisal of real assets. If financial markets were inefficient, it would be virtually impossible for managers to take rational capital investment decisions on behalf of stockholders because it would be impossible to identify the opportunity cost of capital to be used in the Net Present Value calculation. Therefore different investments with the same degree of risk could generate different rates of return, and the managers would not be able to choose the best available forgone rate of return. Finally, one main assumption in portfolio theory is that a financial market is reasonably efficient (please refer to our investigation of the mean185 24 Principles of banking and finance standard deviation theory in Chapter 8). If a financial market is inefficient in pricing securities, then the equilibrium return (measured by the Capital Asset Pricing Model or the Arbitage Pricing Theory) would lose credibility. Note that the concept of informational efficiency refers to individual markets, and not to the markets as a whole. For example, market A can be efficient, whereas market B can be inefficient. Moreover, the reference is mainly to financial markets, because of their nature (low transaction costs, continuous trading by skilled operators, and nature of the pay-offs perceived on securities traded in these markets). A theoretical framework In order to derive a theoretical framework for informational market efficiency, we need to recall from Chapter 7, equation 7.11 regarding the estimation of the expected rate of return on a stock (E(R)). We can generalise this equation for every financial asset (both bonds and stocks) in any period t to t+1 by writing the following equation: C+Pt+1 – Pt (9.1) E(R) = Pt where: C = cash flow received from the security (dividend or coupon) in the period t to t+1 Pt = price of the security at time t Pt+1 = price of the security at time t+1. The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) assumes that financial markets are efficient when security prices incorporate all available information. Therefore, in efficient markets the expected value has to be equal to the forecasted value using all available information. This means that in efficient markets the expected return on a security (E(R)) will be equal to the optimal forecast of the return using all available information (RF), which formally can be written as: E(R) = RF (9.2) Although we cannot observe the expected return, we learned in Chapter 8 how to measure the value of E(R). Therefore, equation (9.2) has important implications for how prices of securities change on financial markets. We know that in equilibrium (when the quantity of securities demanded is equal to the quantity supplied), the expected return (E(R)) equals the equilibrium return (E(R*)), derived either with the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) or the Arbitage Pricing Theory (APT), as described in Chapter 8. Implicit in the notion of an efficient market is the assumption that a fair price for a security exists. This fair price is known as the equilibrium price. Formally, in equilibrium: E(R)=E (R*) (9.3) To describe the pricing behaviour in efficient markets, we can replace E(R) with E(R*) in equation (9.2). Thus we obtain: E(R*)=RF (9.4) This means that current prices in financial markets have to be set so that the optimal forecast of a security return equals the expected return in equilibrium. The alternative way to express this concept is to say that in efficient markets security prices fully reflect all available information. Therefore from equation (9.1): RF = 186 C + Pt+1 – Pt = E(R* ) Pt (9.5) Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information Concept of excess returns As we argued in Chapter 7, and explained in the previous section, equation 9.1 is the fundamental valuation formula, and represents a market equilibrium condition. Consider a stock with an actual return lower than the return on other securities of equivalent risk, and hence an actual price higher than the fair price. If the actual return is 10 per cent and the expected return is 20 per cent, investors would shift their capital to other securities. This process would decrease the current price of the stock, thereby increasing its actual return. If the actual return of a stock was 40 per cent, and thus was higher than the expected return of 20 per cent, the actual price would have been lower than the fair price. There would be an excess return, and the adjustment process would reverse. Investors would buy more of this stock, and this in turn would drive up its actual price relative to the fair price. In order to implement the calculation of excess return (also termed abnormal return, unexploited profit opportunity or riskadjusted returns), we need to find a model to estimate the expected return. As we learned in Chapter 8, several pricing models quantify the expected return in equilibrium. These models are the CAPM and the APT. The equilibrium price is one that produces a return that is just equal to that which investors holding the security require. The equilibrium return varies according to the riskiness of the securities (as fully explained in Chapter 8). A fairly popular choice of the model generating expected return is the market model, which recognises that some stocks are more affected than others by fluctuations in the market. It estimates the expected return on a stock by regressing actual returns on the stock against those of the market. As a consequence, this excess return measure abstracts from changes in the stock prices resulting from marketwide influences. Thus the excess return can be calculated as the difference between the actual return on the market and the equilibrium expected return. Therefore, the excess return at time t (RtX ) is: Rtx = Rt – E(Rt*) (9.6) where: Rt = actual return on the market at time t E(Rt*) = expected equilibrium return at time t. Activity 9.1* The actual return on stock ABC is 10 per cent, and the equilibrium return is 12 per cent. What is the excess rate of return on stock ABC? What if the actual return was 15 per cent? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. Let us now introduce the optimal forecast of return using all available information (RF). The excess return notion still holds. Consider a stock with an equilibrium return of 15 per cent, and a price at time t lower than the expected price at time t+1. If the optimal forecast of the return is equal to 30 per cent, there is an excess return. Investors can earn an abnormally high rate of return because RF>E(R*). In an efficient market this implies that investors would buy more of this stock, and this in turn will drive up its current price relative to the expected future price, thereby lowering RF. When the current price has increased sufficiently so that RF=E(R*), the efficient market condition is satisfied. Similarly, if the 187 24 Principles of banking and finance optimal forecast of the return is 5 per cent, and the equilibrium return is 10 per cent, the stock would be a poor investment [RF<E(R*)]. Therefore, investors would sell the stock, the current price will be driven down relative to the expected future price, and the optimal forecast of the return will increase until RF=E(R*). If we assume this forward-looking perspective, we can still define excess return by replacing the actual return of a security on the financial market with the optimal forecast return. The excess return at time t (RtX) is the difference between the optimal forecast of the return and the expected return in equilibrium: Rtx = Rt F– E(Rt*) (9.7) The objective of our attention when testing the efficient market hypothesis is the excess return derived in equations (9.6) and (9.7). As described in the next section, the efficient market hypothesis is concerned with the ability of investors to make an excess return based on certain information sets. In an efficient market, no investor can make excess returns based on the available set of information. They can only earn normal returns, which here means equilibrium returns. The joint hypothesis problem Before proceeding to the analysis of the different forms of market efficiency resulting from the availability of different information sets, we need to emphasise the main problem associated with the calculation of excess returns. As illustrated in Chapter 8, there are strong theoretical and empirical limitations in the validation of the CAPM and APT models. On the one hand, the unobservability of the market portfolio makes the CAPM untestable. On the other hand, the APT does not require identifying the market portfolio (solving the main CAPM problem), but it does not tell us what the underlying factors are (unlike the CAPM, which collapses all the macroeconomic factors into the market portfolio). Therefore the choice of the model used to adjust actual returns in the excess return calculation may be wrong. This implies that abnormal returns may be incorrectly quantified, and then used in the test of the efficient market hypothesis. This implies that the same efficient market hypothesis would become untestable because of the joint hypothesis problem. The test is affected by two problems: a. informational efficiency b. accuracy of the equilibrium expected returns. If the test indicates the presence of excess return, this would imply that markets are inefficient. However, the inefficiency of the markets could be determined by the use of an incorrect technique for the measurement of the excess return. Therefore we do not know whether the market is efficient but the excess return measurement is wrong, or the market is actually inefficient. Levels of informational market efficiency: weak, semistrong and strong forms As previously stated, an efficient market is a market where excess returns based on a set of available information are eliminated. In order to make this definition useful in an empirical context and to test market efficiency, we need to specify broad observable information sets. In this regard the main reference is the famous survey of market efficiency proposed by Fama (1970). The three varieties of market efficiency identified by Fama (1970) are: 188 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information • Weak-form efficiency: a market is said to be weak-form efficient when prices fully reflect all historical information. Historical information includes past prices and returns, past data on the financial characteristics of the firms, and information on macroeconomic conditions. If a market is efficient in the weak-form sense, investors are unable to make consistently excess returns by analysing past data. • Semi-strong-form efficiency: a market is termed semi-strong efficient when prices fully, accurately and speedily reflect all new public information. Furthermore, prices have to reflect all past public information: if the market is semi-strong efficient, it will also be efficient in the weak-form. New public information includes financial accounts, company announcements and information in the financial press. If a market is efficient in the semi-strong form, investors are unable to make excess returns based on this publicly available information, because this information will already be reflected in the prices of the security on the market. • Strong-form efficiency: a market is referred to as strong-form efficient when prices reflect all information, both public and private. This is the most extreme form of market efficiency. Private information does not refer just to insider information (for example, a company’s directors informed about future merger and acquisition plans), but also to information that investors and analysts can get through their own analysis (for example, managers of mutual funds). If a market is efficient in the strong-form, then no investor is able to earn excess returns for a sustained period of time based on any information available. Because of the inability to beat the market consistently, there is no point in paying for specialist advice because no one can have an information advantage. The scope of the information sets used in Fama’s definitions is increasing. The largest information set is associated with strong-form efficiency (relevant public and private information), the smallest to weak-form efficiency (past data only). Note these information sets are nested so the semi-strong information set contains the weak-form set and the strong form set contains both the weak form and semi-strong form sets. Activity 9.2 Is the following statement true, false or uncertain? ‘An efficient market is one in which no one ever profits from having better information than the rest.’ The efficient market hypothesis has strong implications in terms of security analysis and security trading. If a financial market is efficient in the weak-form sense, trading rules based on the examination of past prices are worthless. Therefore it would be impossible to identify mispriced securities by using technical analysis. Technical analysis is the study of charts of stock price movements to discover particular recurrent patterns (such as trends or cycles). When technical analysts realise that one of these patterns is starting to develop for a specific stock, they believe they are able to predict future stock prices. In a weakly efficient market, technical analysis is worthless because past information is already reflected in current prices. 189 24 Principles of banking and finance Activity 9.3 Visit the StockCharts.com website at www.stockcharts.com/education/Overview/ techAnalysis1.html to familiarise yourself with the basics of technical analysis and chart analysis. Note that the graphs provided in this website are illustrative and you do not have to learn about them in detail. If a financial market is semi-strongly efficient, trading rules based on publicly available information are suspect. As a consequence, not only technical analysis but also fundamental analysis would be worthless. Fundamental analysts acquire a wide set of publicly available information to determine the intrinsic value of a firm on the basis of their assumptions about the company, the industry and the general economy. This value is then compared with the market price to provide a buy, sell or hold recommendation. (Fundamental and technical analysis will be developed in later subjects in the programme, such as 143 Valuation and securities analysis.) However, if the market is semi-strongly efficient, the likely implications of publicly available information are already reflected in market prices. Activity 9.4 Visit www.investorguide.com/igustockfundamental.html to familiarise yourself with the basics of fundamental analysis. Finally, if strong-form efficiency exists, investors would not even be able to get excess returns from inside information because stock prices would reflect all public and private information. Note that this implies that investing in funds run by fund managers with alleged superior forecasting ability will not lead to sustained above normal profits, as no fund managers could possess such private information. Empirical evidence on efficient markets The vast majority of the empirical literature tests the first two varieties of market efficiency: weak-form efficiency and semi-strong-form efficiency. The reason for this is that strong-form efficiency is more difficult to test. In the following subsections, we focus our attention on the empirical evidence in favour of or against each of the three forms of the EMH. Evidence in favour of market efficiency Early empirical tests of the efficient market hypothesis provide evidence in favour of market efficiency, at least in the weak- and semi-strongforms. In the following subsections, we analyse the key phenomena used by researchers to support the three forms of market efficiency. For each of them we provide a theoretical explanation of why the phenomenon is consistent with the relevant efficiency form, and then we illustrate the main studies analysing the phenomenon and their results. Random walk behaviour of stock prices and weak-form efficiency It is said that prices of securities follow a random walk when they are equally likely to go up or down on any particular day irrespective of what happened to the price on the previous day. Consider the following example to clarify the concept of random walk. You are given $1,000 to play a game. At the end of each day a coin is tossed. If it comes up heads, you win 4 per cent of your investment; if it is tails, you lose 3 per cent. At the end of the first day it is equally likely to land on 190 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information heads or tails. Therefore your capital at the end of the first day can equally be $1,004 or $997. At the end of the second day, the coin is tossed again. The outcomes associated with the positive first-day outcome ($1,004) are $1,044 or $974. This is a random walk because the changes in value are independent of one another. Activity 9.5* At the end of the second day, what are the outcomes associated with the negative firstday outcome ($997)? *The solution to this activity can be found at the end of the subject guide in Appendix 1. If security prices follow a random walk, investors cannot gain information about future prices on the basis of past prices. Any information contained in past prices is already reflected in current prices. Therefore the financial market is said to be weak-form efficient. Early empirical evidence on whether future stock returns can be predicted on the basis of current and past changes rejects this hypothesis. This confirms that stock prices follow a random walk, and supports weakform efficiency. Refer to Figure 13.2 in Brealey, Myers and Allen to find empirical evidence that supports the random walk behaviour of four market indexes: FTSE 100 (UK), Nikkei 500 (Japan), DAX 30 (Germany) and Standard & Poor’s Composite (USA). Each point in these scatter diagrams shows the return in successive weeks on the index. The wide scatter of points shows that there is almost no correlation between the returns in successive weeks. Activity 9.6 Is the following statement true, false or uncertain? ‘If financial markets are weak-form efficient, they have no memory’. Explain your answer. Technical analysis and weak-form efficiency As argued in the previous section, past stock prices cannot be used to predict future price changes because prices of securities follow a random walk. Therefore technical analysis, which identifies trading rules based on past data to forecast future changes, should not be able to predict future stock prices successfully. The consequence is that trading rules based on technical analysis should not consistently be able to generate excess returns. In fact, if investors observed the existence of such trading rules generating excess returns, then they would adopt these rules and excess returns generated in the past would be eliminated. This would support market weak-form efficiency. Overall, empirical evidence shows that technical analysis does not outperform the market, and that successful past forecasting does not imply future market outperformance. The proof that returns generated by rules based on technical analysis do not outperform the market is provided by – among others – Allen and Karjalainen (1999). This evidence supports the weak-form efficiency of financial markets. However, some other researchers are more favourable towards technical analysis, and find that such trading rules can generate excess returns: for example Brock, Lakonishok and LeBaron (1992) observed the success of technical analysis for foreign exchange rates and the US stock index. Such results do not support market efficiency in its weak form. 191 24 Principles of banking and finance Earnings announcements and semi-strong-form efficiency Semi-strong efficiency implies that stock prices reflect all publicly available information. Early empirical tests of semi-strong efficiency related to the changes in stock prices determined by earnings or dividend announcements. These studies found that if the information were publicly available, after positive earnings or dividend announcements, there would be no change in the stock price. The stock price increased in anticipation of the earning/dividend increase, and once the increase had been announced, the stock price maintained the new level. This supports semistrong-form efficiency (Ball and Brown, 1968). In recent studies, the main concern in testing semi-strong efficiency relates to the speed with which new and unexpected information is incorporated into stock prices. (Note that this information has to be new and unexpected.) Events analysed in the literature are: earnings announcements, dividends announcements and news of a takeover. Let us consider a positive (negative) unexpected earnings announcement (a picture of the financial health of the firm). In a semi-strong efficient market, we expect stock prices to increase rapidly in response to the announcement of earnings higher than the expected level (good news about the firm) or to decrease rapidly to the announcement of earnings lower than the expected level (bad news). Empirical evidence suggests that new information is quickly and accurately reflected in stock prices. If actual income differs from the expected income, the financial market typically has reacted in the same direction. Unexpected earnings increase (decrease) experienced by the good (bad) news firms lead to increased (decreased) prices (the seminal contribution by Ball and Brown, 1968, provides this evidence). Moreover, the adjustment to unexpected earnings or dividends announcements is rapid. The major part of the adjustment in stock prices occurs within 5 to 10 minutes of the announcement (as shown by Patell and Wolfson, 1984). Activity 9.7 Is the following statement true, false or uncertain? ‘If financial markets are efficient in the semi-strong-form, investors can trust stock prices.’ Mutual fund performance and strong-form efficiency Strong-form efficiency implies that stock prices fully reflect all available information, both public and private. Therefore there is no investor with superior ability to beat the market. Empirical tests of strong-form efficiency include studies of whether there is an investor or groups of investors that have consistently earned excess returns. Because of the lack of data, the group most frequently tested is managers of mutual funds. Empirical evidence suggests that the managers of mutual funds do not beat the market. Actually, actively managed mutual funds underperform other broad-based portfolios with similar characteristics (for example Carhart (1997) finds that nearly 1,500 US mutual funds underperformed the market in approximately half the years between 1962 and 1992). Moreover, even mutual funds that performed well in the past are not able to beat the market again in the future (as shown by Jensen, 1968; Grinblatt and Titman, 1989). The good performance in the past does not indicate that the mutual fund (or investment adviser) will perform well in the future. This is consistent with strong-form efficiency. 192 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information Activity 9.8 If your investment advisor has been right in seven previous buy and sell recommendations, should you continue listening to his advice? This empirical evidence on mutual funds, consistent with strong-form efficiency, explains why many mutual funds have given up the pursuit of superior performance by active management of the fund, and turned to simply tracking a benchmark market index. This enables mutual funds to maximise diversification and reduce management costs. Evidence against market efficiency All the early empirical evidence generally supports the market efficiency hypothesis. However, in recent years, empirical studies have started to show the existence of some anomalies which are inconsistent with the efficient market hypothesis. In the following subsections we focus on these anomalies by relating each of them to the relevant efficiency form. Small firm effect and weak-form efficiency A piece of empirical evidence inconsistent with random walk behaviour is the so-called small firm effect. There is evidence that next period’s returns of small firms’ stocks have been positively correlated with previous returns even for weekly and monthly periods (as shown in Lo and MacKinlay, 1988). As a consequence, a trading rule suggests forming portfolios of small stocks to earn excess returns. Several theories have been developed to explain the small firm effect: • Low liquidity of small firms or inappropriate measurement of risk for small firm stocks. Investors demand a higher expected return to compensate for some risk, which is not captured in the beta under the CAPM model (recall the empirical evidence against the CAPM due to small-cap stocks, as illustrated in Chapter 8). • Data-snooping, or rather the fact that the superior performance of small-caps is a coincidence, due to the large number of researchers analysing past performance to find out specific patterns (recall again the data-snooping explanation used for small-caps in Chapter 8). Actually, in the USA, the small firm effect is limited to a relatively short period: the 1970s and the 1980s. Note, however, that the phenomenon is pervasive, and can be observed in many other countries. • Weak-form market inefficiency; an anomaly that provided investors with an opportunity to make excess returns over a period of two decades in the USA. However, although many investors tried to exploit such an anomaly, it was very difficult to make profits out of it consistently from the 1990s on. Therefore it is not obvious that the return predictability for small stocks implies weak-form market inefficiency. Calendar effects and weak-form efficiency A calendar effect represents a pattern in stock returns related to either the day of the week, the week of the month or the month of the year. One famous empirical finding is the so-called January effect, which shows that stock returns (particularly for small stocks) are greater in January than in any other month of the year. Other examples of calendar effects are the lower returns on Monday than in other days of the week, and the occurrence of most daily returns at the beginning and end of the day. 193 24 Principles of banking and finance Let us focus on the January effect. The January effect seems to indicate a trading rule: buy small stocks at the end of December and sell them at the end of January. In this way you will make a profit. Why is the existence of the January effect problematic? Assume that all investors observe such a January strategy generating excess returns. All investors would follow it. But the consequence would be an increase in prices at the end of December (because of the increase in demand), and a decrease at the end of January (due the increase in supply). Therefore excess returns would tend to be eliminated. The continued existence of the January effect is puzzling. Specifically, it is inconsistent with random walk behaviour, and gives strong indications against weak-form market efficiency. Several hypotheses have been advanced to explain this effect. These include: • Association of the January effect with the small firms effect (analysed in the previous paragraph): as reported in Fama (1991), over the period 1941–81, the return experienced in January was 8.06 per cent for small stocks and 1.342 per cent for large stocks. In both cases the January return was higher than the average return in other months, but also most of the January effect was associated with small stocks. Note however that in recent years – the period 1981–91 – the difference in January returns between large and small stocks was less pronounced. • Taxation impacts (i.e. tax-selling hypothesis). Activity 9.9 Explain why the tax issue can be a potential explanation of the January effect, and why it is not completely plausible. Please compare your answer with the explanation below. • Investors sell securities for which substantial losses have been incurred before the end of the year, in order to benefit from a tax loss. Such investors do not invest the proceeds back into the market until the new year. The selling in December would depress prices, whereas the purchasing in early January would generate increases in prices. However, even this explanation does not seem completely plausible: in fact, we do not observe in financial markets any negative December effect when the tax-loss incentive induces selling the stocks. • Implications of the remuneration structure of fund managers. Haugen and Lakonishok (1988) hypothesise that portfolio manager behaviour around the turn of the year may be a major cause of the January/ small firm effect and that the effect may result from window dressing or performance hedging. Window dressing is a strategy used by fund managers near the year or quarter end to improve the appearance of the fund performance before presenting it to clients or shareholders. To window dress, the fund manager will sell stocks with large losses and purchase good performing stocks near the end of the quarter. To understand performance hedging, note that fund managers are compensated for achieving returns above some benchmark. Managers will then sell risky stocks once the benchmark has been reached and then buy them again in January after the bonus has been paid. Window dressing can be value reducing (because of the unnecessary transaction costs necessary to discern true rather than ‘dressed up’ portfolio composition) whereas performance hedging may be associated with investor value maximisation (thanks to the possibility to lock in superior performance). Cheng-few, Porter and Weaver (1998) suggest that the hypothesis of performance hedging is more likely than the one of window dressing. 194 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information Mean reversion and weak-form efficiency Mean reversion means that stocks with a low return today show a high return in the future, and vice versa. Some empirical evidence shows that stocks that have done poorly in the past three to five years will tend to do well in the next three to five years (as demonstrated by Fama and French, 1988; and Poterba and Summers, 1988). Mean reversion enables investors to predict changes in the future prices. Therefore, stock prices do not follow a random walk. This seems to indicate inefficiency in the weakform. Note, however, that the evidence on mean reversion is not conclusive, as some empirical studies show a diminished importance of the mean reversion phenomenon after the Second World War. Activity 9.10 Draw a diagram with ‘time’ on the horizontal axis, and ‘excess return’ on the vertical axis. Draw a curve showing the mean reversion behaviour of stock prices, as described above. Market overreaction and semi-strong-form efficiency There is another anomaly related to earnings announcements. Although empirical evidence generally confirms rapid adjustment to new information (see our previous evidence in favour of the semi-strong-form efficiency), recent evidence shows that stock prices do not instantaneously adjust. Two key anomalies are pointed out: stock price overreaction and underreaction. Market overreaction means that prices may disproportionately increase (decrease) due to good (bad) news announcements, and the pricing error is corrected only slowly. Some empirical evidence shows that adjustment to extreme bad news takes several months: there is a market overreaction and subsequent gradual adjustment (see for example the evidence in Ball and Brown, 1968, then confirmed by Bernard and Thomas, 1989). Bernard and Thomas (1989) calculate the Cumulative Abnormal Returns (CAR) for 10 portfolios with different levels of unexpected good or bad earnings over the years 1974–86. CAR are measured for the pre- and post- announcement period. Portfolio 10 contains the 10 per cent of the stocks with the highest earnings performance, portfolio 1 the lowest 10 per cent. As shown in Bernard and Thomas (1989, p.10), portfolio 10 (extreme good news) disproportionately increases its performance in the days immediately preceding the announcement, and portfolio 1 (extreme bad news) disproportionately decreases its performance. However, in the medium-long term after the announcement, the performance of portfolio 10 decreases and the performance of portfolio 1 markedly increases. It seems that there is an overreaction before the announcement, and then the market needs subsequent gradual adjustments to correct the overreaction to the unexpected information. As a consequence investors could get excess returns by implementing a trading strategy: to buy (sell) stocks immediately after the announcement of bad (good) news, and sell (buy) them after several months when the price has risen (fallen) again. This trading strategy is known as contrarian strategy. The possibility to implement a contrarian strategy profitably in such a framework is inconsistent with semi-strong-form efficiency. Some empirical studies (see, for example, DeBondt and Thaler, 1987) indicate that portfolios composed of extreme ‘losers’ (stocks that have performed poorly in the recent past) dramatically outperformed portfolios composed of extreme ‘winners’ (stocks that have increased in price in the 195 24 Principles of banking and finance recent past). In the 36 months after each portfolio formation, extreme loser portfolios earned 25 per cent more than extreme winner portfolios. Once again, the evidence suggests the possibility of getting excess returns from a contrarian strategy. But in this case, such a possibility is inconsistent with the weak-form efficiency because the definition of winners and losers is based on historical returns and not on the release of a new piece of information. Underreaction and semi-strong-form efficiency Underreaction to earnings announcements means that stock prices do not fully incorporate the new information embodied in the unexpected earnings announcement. Looking again at Bernard and Thomas (1989, p.10), portfolio 10 outperformed portfolio 1 in the two months following the announcement, and the difference in the excess returns has been equal to +4 per cent. Prices of good news stocks continue to rise in the two months after the earnings announcement, whereas prices of bad news stocks continue to fall. Investors thus can get an excess return in the short term by buying good news stocks and selling bad news stocks. Such a trading strategy is known as momentum strategy. The possibility to implement a momentum strategy profitably in such a framework is inconsistent with semi-strong-form efficiency. Accordingly, in the context of weak-form efficiency, some empirical evidence (see results in Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993) suggests buying past winner stocks and selling past losers to get excess returns. Here the definition of winners and losers is based on historical prices and not on the release of any new information. To buy stocks that have increased in price in the recent past and to sell those that have performed poorly yields significant excess returns over 3- to 12-month holding periods. Once again this evidence suggests excess returns associated with a momentum strategy, but this evidence is inconsistent with the weak-form efficiency (not the semi-strong-form) because the strategy is based on historical prices only. Note that both overreaction and underreaction alternatively characterise the behaviour of prices in financial markets, and empirical evidence provides a roughly equal number of examples of overreaction and underreaction. Corporate insiders and strong-form efficiency Corporate insiders, for example a company’s directors, use insider information to buy stocks prior to stock price rises and to sell prior to stock price falls. Therefore they aim to earn excess returns from trading in their own company’s stocks. Empirical evidence shows that insider trades can be used to predict subsequent stock price changes. This is inconsistent with strong-form efficiency. Activity 9.11 Read Mishkin and Eakins (2009) p.141 and re-read the section on financial bubbles in Chapter 3 of this subject guide. Now think about whether financial bubbles are evidence against the EMH. Mishkin and Eakins refer to the concept of rational bubbles. Do you think this provides support for the EMH in the presence of financial bubbles? 196 Chapter 9: Financial markets – transmission of information Summary The chapter investigated whether stock prices reflect all available information in financial markets. If the efficient market hypothesis holds, investors are unable to make excess returns on a certain information set. Commonly, three broad observable information sets are used to define informational efficiency: weak-form, semi-strong-form and strong-form efficiency. The empirical evidence overwhelmingly suggests that financial markets are weak-form efficient: just refer to the random walk behaviour of stock prices, and to the uselessness of technical analysis. Nevertheless several important anomalies have to be taken into account: calendar effects, small size effect, and long-term mean reversion behaviour of stocks. The evidence on semi-strong efficiency is more mixed. The rapid incorporation of new and unexpected information is in favour of semistrong-form efficiency; whereas the phenomena of market overreaction and underreaction to new information are against it. Anyway, the majority of empirical evidence does suggest that prices fully, accurately and speedily reflect all new public information in most stock markets. Strongform efficiency has received least attention in empirical studies because intuitively it is more difficult to believe that markets are strongly efficient and because it is more difficult to get empirical data. But despite these difficulties, there is evidence that stock markets may be efficient in the strong-form (mutual fund performance). At the same time, the evidence on corporate insider profits goes against strong-form efficiency. Overall we have seen that it is difficult to get a definitive answer on informational market efficiency. Instead of dichotomised categories of efficient and inefficient financial markets, it seems more sensible to define different degrees of efficiency, and classify certain markets (or markets at certain times) as being more efficient than others. Key terms abnormal returns allocative efficiency anomalies available information calendar effects contrarian strategy earnings announcements efficient market hypothesis excess return informational efficiency insiders January effect joint hypothesis problem market overreaction market underreaction mean reversion momentum strategy random walk semi-strong-form efficiency small firm effect strong-form efficiency technical analysis valuation efficiency underreaction weak-form efficiency A reminder of your learning outcomes By the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential readings and activities, you should be able to: • understand whether stock prices reflect all available information, and hence whether the efficient market hypothesis holds • understand the relevance of the efficient market hypothesis, and derive the hypothesis from a theoretical perspective • explain the concept of excess returns in the context of informationefficient markets 197 24 Principles of banking and finance • describe the three main forms of market efficiency (weak-form, semi-strong-form and strong-form) • discuss the empirical evidence in favour of weak-form efficiency (random walk behaviour of stock prices, uselessness of technical analysis) and against weak-form efficiency (presence of calendar effect, small firm effect and mean reversion) • discuss the empirical evidence in favour of semi-strong-form efficiency (incorporation of earnings-announcement information) and against semi-strong-form efficiency (market overreaction and underreaction to new information) • discuss the empirical evidence in favour of strong-form efficiency (mutual fund performance) and against strong-form efficiency (excess return of corporate insiders). Sample examination questions 198 1. a. In what ways does informational efficiency affect capital budgeting and portfolio theory? b. What is the theoretical framework for the derivation of the efficient market hypothesis? c. What are excess returns? What techniques are used for their calculation? d. How does the joint hypothesis problem affect the interpretation of results on efficient markets? 2. a. Compare and contrast the weak-form, the semi-strong-form and the strong-form efficiency of financial markets in the test of the efficient market hypothesis. b ‘If stock prices follow a random walk, investors can earn excess returns by using trading rules based on past data’. Is this statement true or false? Explain your answer. c What is the empirical evidence against weak-form market efficiency? Illustrate the phenomena identified by these studies. d What is the empirical evidence in favour of and against the semi-strong form of market efficiency? Appendix 1: Solutions to numerical activities Appendix 1: Solutions to numerical activities Answers to ‘Activities’ marked with an asterisk Chapter 5 Activity 5.11 The leverage capital ratio is 10% (=$10/$100). Activity 5.12 Risk-weighted assets are: •• Cash (500*0%)0 Government bills(1,500*0%) Mortgages (14,000*50%) Loans (12,000*100%) Total •• Risk asset ratio =1,600/19,000=8.42% 0 7,000 12,000 19,000 Activity 5.14 i. 7% ii. 4.5% iii. 2.5% (10.5–8) iv. 9.5% Chapter 6 Activity 6.4 e. The projected probability of repayment for the borrower is 1.15. f. If the leverage ratio is 0.4, the projected probability of repayment is 0.765. Activity 6.6 a. Three steps are needed to answer point a. i. To determine the amount of rate-sensitive assets: Commercial loans $50 Fixed-rate mortgages (=20%*25) $5 Variable-rate mortgages $20 $75 ii. To determine the amount of rate-sensitive liabilities: Money market deposits $5 Variable-rate CD $30 Savings deposits(=20%*20) $5 $40 iii. What happens when interest rates increase by1.5%? Increase in income on assets (=1.5%*75) $1.125 Increase in payments on liabilities (=1.5%*40) $0.600 Increase in net income $0.525 199 24 Principles of banking and finance b. Two steps are needed to answer point b. i. To determine the amount of rate-sensitive assets: Commercial loans $50 Fixed-rate mortgages(=20%*15) $3 Variable-rate mortgages $30 $83 The amount of rate-sensitive liabilities remains $40. ii. What happens when interest rates increase by 1.5 percent? Increase in income on assets (=1.5%*83) $1.245 Increase in payments on liabilities (=1.5%*40) $0.600 Increase in net income $0.645 c. Two steps are needed to answer point c. i. To determine the amount of rate-sensitive liabilities: Money market deposits $5 Variable-rate CD $30 Savings deposits (=15%*20) $3 $38 The amount of rate-sensitive assets remains $75. ii. What happens when interest rates increase by 1.5 percent? Increase in income on assets (=1.5%*75) $1.125 Increase in payments on liabilities (=1.5%*38) $0.570 Increase in net income $0.555 Activity 6.7 a. The Macaulay duration of a three-year 6 per cent coupon bond is 2.838 years. b. The Macaulay duration of the portfolio (20 per cent invested in the seven-year Eurobond and 80 per cent in the three-year coupon bond) is 3.3708 years. Activity 6.8 The approximate percentage change in the price of the bond is +2.75 per cent. Activity 6.9 The duration gap for the bank is 2.2 years. The potential loss to equity holders’ net worth (as a percentage of assets) is: ∆NW ≈ – DUR x ∆i = – 2.2 x 0.05 = – 0.03055 = – 3.055% gap 1.08 1+i A With total assets totalling $100 million, the fall in the market value of net worth is $3.055 million. Chapter 7 Activity 7.1 1. The PV of 5,000 euro to be received in five years’ time is 3,565 euro. 2. The PV of 5,000 euro to be received at the end of each of the first five years, and 2,000 euro at the end of years six to eight, is 24,242 euro. 3. The PV of a perpetuity that promises 5,000 euro per year is 71,428 euro. 4. The PV of a growing perpetuity that promises an initial payment of 5,000 euro and growth of 4 per cent is 166,667 euro. 200 Appendix 1: Solutions to numerical activities Activity 7.2 •• The NPV of Project B is $1,461, and thus it should be accepted. •• The NPV of Project C is –$50, and thus it should be rejected. Activity 7.3 1. The IRR of project ABC is 8.1 per cent, and thus it should be accepted (IRR higher than the hurdle rate equal to 7 per cent). 2. The decision remains the same under the NPV rule (positive NPV equal to $36). Activity 7.5 a. Payback period of each project: Project I=4years; Project L=2years; Project M=3years. b. The firm accepts Projects L and M if the cut-off period is three years. c. If the firm invests by choosing projects with the shortest payback period, it would invest in Project L. Activity 7.8 The price of a four-year coupon bond, with principal $5,000, annual coupon rate 4 per cent, and required annual rate of return 8 per cent, is $4,337. Activity 7.9 In the case of semi-annual coupon payments and a semi-annual discount rate of 4 per cent, the price of the bond in Activity 7.8 becomes $4,328. Activity 7.11 The price today of stock X would be $91.67, whereas the price of stock Y would be $100. Therefore, stock Y is more valuable than stock X. Chapter 8 Activity 8.1 1. The expected return of Second Class stock is 13.67 per cent. 2. The standard deviation of the returns on the stock is 4.69 per cent. 3. Second Class stock is less risky than First Class stock. Activity 8.5 The portfolio weight for Microsoft is 30.2 per cent. Activity 8.6 The portfolio return variance in these three cases is: 1. 6.03 per cent with correlation of –0.3. 2. 15.6 per cent with correlation of 1. 3. 8.2 per cent with correlation of 0. Activity 8.9 E(R) σ i. 1. 15 25 2. 20 22.3257 3. 25 24.8244 4. 30 31.3996 5. 35 40 201 24 Principles of banking and finance ii. w1 = 0.7826 w2 = 0.2173 hence E(R) = 17.17 σ = 22.7954 Activity 8.10 1. Portfolio B would always be preferred over Portfolio A. 2. Portfolio C would always be preferred over Portfolio D. Activity 8.14 2. The risk premium on the market is 9 per cent 3. The required return on a stock with a beta of 1.5 is 16.5 per cent. 4. If the market return is expected to be 12.5 per cent, the beta of the stock is 1.42. Activity 8.15 The stock sensitivities on individual factors are: ap = (0.25.0.03) + (0.75.0.06) = 0.0525 bp = (0.25.0.9) + (0.75.0.8) = 0.825 Thus the portfolio return can be written as: Rp= 0.0525 + 0.825 F1+εp Activity 8.16 a. If a stock return is uncorrelated with either of the two factors, the expected rate of return on the stock is 6 per cent. b. If a stock return has a positive average exposure to each factor, the expected rate of return on the stock is 13.5 per cent. Chapter 9 Activity 9.1 a. The excess rate of return on stock ABC is negative (–2 per cent), when the actual return is 10 per cent and the equilibrium return is 12 per cent. It becomes positive (+3 per cent) if the actual return is 15 per cent. Activity 9.5 b. At the end of the second day, the outcomes associated with the negative first-day outcome are $1,037 and $967. 202 Appendix 2: Sample examoination paper Appendix 2: Sample examination paper Important note: This Sample examination paper reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 2010−2011. The format and structure of the examination may have changed since the publication of this subject guide. You can find the most recent examination papers on the VLE where all changes to the format of the examination are posted. Time allowed: three hours. Candidates should answer FOUR of the following EIGHT questions: ONE from Section A, ONE from Section B, and TWO further questions from either section. All questions carry equal marks. A calculator may be used when answering questions on this paper and it must comply in all respects with the specification given in the Regulations. Section A Answer one question from this section and not more than a further two questions. You are reminded that four questions in total are to beattempted with at least one question from Section B. 1. a. What are the main implications of the presence of market-based and bank-based financial systems nowadays? (12 marks) b. Discuss the reasons and the consequences of the decline in the share of financial assets held by banks in recent years. (13 marks) 2. a. How are financial intermediaries able to reduce/solve the problems arising from adverse selection? (9 marks) b. Discuss how to reduce/solve the problems arising from moral hazard in equity markets. (7 marks) c. Explain the hypotheses, the framework and the main findings ofthe delegated monitoring theory. (9 marks) 3. a. What are the methods used to handle a failed bank in the USA? (8 marks) b. What are the mechanisms of deposit insurance adopted in the USA and in the UK? (4 marks) c. Explain the risk-asset ratio under Basel 1 and discuss the main problems that have been identified with it. How will it changeunder Basel 2? (13 marks) 4. a. Name and briefly describe the three types of market efficiency. (6 marks) b. Discuss the empirical evidence in favour of weak-form market efficiency. Illustrate the key results identified by these studies. (9 marks) c. Discuss the empirical evidence on market overreaction and underreaction. (8 marks) 203 24 Principles of banking and finance Section B Answer one question from this section and not more than a further two questions. You are reminded that four questions in total are to be attempted with at least one question from Section A. 5. a. Consider a three-factor Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) model. Factor Risk premium Sensitivity to each factor Change in GDP 5% 1 Change in interest rate 1% 0.5 Inflation ratio 2.5% 0 a. Assuming a risk-free rate of 4%, calculate the expected return of this stock. (4 marks) b. What are the assumptions under the APT? What is the expected risk premium? (11 marks) c. Under the CAPM framework, what is the optimal portfolio? Explain your answer. (10 marks) 6. Consider the two following mutually exclusive projects (X and Y): Cashflows(£) Project C0 C1 C2 C3 X –2,200 0 +600 +2,000 Y –2,200 +1,000 +800 +600 a. Assuming an opportunity cost of capital of 11 per cent, what is the NPV of the two projects? Which project would you accept? (4 marks) b. What is the IRR of the two projects? Which project would you choose if the hurdle rate is equal to the opportunity cost of capital (11 per cent)? (6 marks) c. Explain the IRR method. Discuss the limits of this method when compared to the NPV technique. (10 marks) d. Discuss the limits of the payback period method. (5 marks) 7. At the end of January 2008, the interest rate on US government bonds maturing in 2010 is about 2.5 per cent. Consider a corporate bond with a coupon rate equal to 4 per cent, and maturity in January 2010. a. Using the data shown above, determine the value of the corporate bond by assuming annual coupon payments and annual compounding. (4 marks) b. Calculate the duration of the US government bond assuming annual coupons and annual discount rate. (5 marks) c. Formally derive and discuss the dividend discount model used for the valuation of common stocks. (9 marks) d. What are the factors that affect Macaulay duration? (7 marks) 8. What is meant by interest rate risk? What are the two main effects of interest rate risk? (5 marks) a. Explain how a bank can use duration gap analysis and income gap analysis to manage interest rate risk. Critically discuss the problems associated with income gap analysis. (8 marks) 204 Appendix 2: Sample examoination paper b. Consider the following balance sheet of Bank One: Assets(£) Liabilities and Equity(£) Variable-rate mortgages 10 Money market deposits 20 Fixed-rate mortgages 10 Savings deposits 30 Commercial loans 45 Equity 30 Physical capital 15 Total 80 Total 80 What will be the net interest income at the year end if interest rates decreased by 0.5 per cent, from 4.5 to 4 per cent? Explain using basic gap analysis. (Use the following hypothesis on the runoff of cash flows: fixedrate mortgages repaid during the year: 25 per cent; proportion of savings deposits that are rate-sensitive: 25 per cent). (12 marks) END OF PAPER 205 24 Principles of banking and finance Notes 206