9 The Globalization of Economic Relations István Benczes In the past 30 years, the term ‘globalization’ has earned considerable credit in the social sciences and has also gone into common use in public debates. Nevertheless, there is hardly any consensus on either its precise meaning, or its determining forces or consequences. Held et al. (1999) offer a convenient starting point for any discussion on globalization by claiming that it ‘may be thought of initially as the widening, deepening and speeding up of worldwide interconnectedness in all aspects of contemporary social life’ (1999: 2). ‘Aspects’ can refer to ‘political, technical and cultural, as well as economic’ features (Giddens, 1999: 10), implying that globalization is best thought of as a multidimensional phenomenon. Consequently, approaching globalization from a purely economic perspective is ‘ … a categorical mistake. That said, few discussions of globalization can, or do, ignore its economic foundations’ (McGrew, 2008: 280). This chapter has been written within the spirit of such an approach. Without doubt, economic globalization does not constitute the whole story of contemporary globalization, 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 133 but in order to fully understand its meaning and implication, the economic dimension, as one of the major driving forces of the process of globalization, requires special attention. Following a short introduction, the first section is dedicated to the clarification of the definition, origin and consequences of economic globalization. As the two main fields of economic globalization have been finance and trade, the second section discusses the evolution of the major international monetary regimes, including the gold standard, the Bretton Woods system and European monetary integration. The third section discusses trade relations and trade policies, with a special focus on the unilateral trade regime of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries and the multilateral regime of the post-World War II era. WHAT IS ECONOMIC GLOBALIZATION? According to one of the most often cited definitions, 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM 134 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION [e]conomic globalization is a historical process, the result of human innovation and technological progress. It refers to the increasing integration of economies around the world, particularly through the movement of goods, services, and capital across borders. The term sometimes also refers to the movement of people (labor) and knowledge (technology) across international borders. (IMF, 2008) The phenomenon can thus have several interconnected dimensions, such as (a) the globalization of trade of goods and services; (2) the globalization of financial and capital markets; (3) the globalization of technology and communication; and (4) the globalization of production. What makes economic globalization distinct from internationalization is that while the latter is about the extension of economic activities of nation states across borders, the former is ‘functional integration between internationally dispersed activities’ Dicken (2004: 12). That is, economic globalization is rather a qualitative transformation than just a quantitative change. If, however, globalization is indeed a ‘complex, indeterminate set of processes operating very unevenly in both time and space’ (Dicken, 2004: xv), a more substantive definition for economic globalization is required than the one offered by the IMF (2008). The definition provided by Szentes (2003: 69) befits the purposes of this particular chapter: ‘In economic terms globalisation is nothing but a process making the world economy an “organic system” by extending transnational economic processes and economic relations to more and more countries and by deepening the economic interdependencies among them.’ The main advantage of the above definition is that although it does not deny the relevance of the ‘international’, ‘regional’ or ‘national’ levels, it refuses the assumption that the nation (state) is the only unit of analysis and that current trends in the world economy are simply the redesign of the external relations of interacting nations. Instead, it claims that economic activities and processes (production in particular) can be interpreted only in a global context, i.e. in an integrated world economy. 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 134 To what extent is the nation state still a relevant (f)actor is a major topic of current debates. For hyperglobalists such as Ohmae (1995), states ceased to exist as primary economic organization units in the wake of a global market. People are consuming highly standardized global products and services produced by global corporations in a borderless world. Globalization transforms the national economy into a global one where ‘there will be no national products or technologies, no national corporations, no national industries’ (Reich, 1991: 3). On a more balanced account, Boyer and Drache admit that ‘[g]lobalization is redefining the role of the nation state as an effective manager of the national economy’ (1996: 1), but refuse the hypothesis of uniform state policies and conceive the state as the main shelter from the perverse effects of a free market economy. It is, therefore, misleading to assume that globalization has relegated the nation state and its policies to an obsolete or irrelevant status; governments instead ‘are acting as the midwives of globalization’ (Brodie, 1996: 386). Even liberals recognize that economic openness has increased vulnerability, also admitting that states (national economic policies and the structure of domestic institutions) are not influenced uniformly by globalization (Milner and Keohane, 1996). As new actors appear on the stage of political and cultural globalization (such as the United Nations (UN) or non-governmental organizations (NGOs)), economic globalization produces its own new entrants as well. In all probability the major players of presentday global economy are the transnational corporations (TNCs). For some, contemporary globalization is equated primarily with TNCs, the main driving forces of economic globalization of the last 100 years, accounting for roughly two-thirds of world export (Gereffi, 2005).1 On the other hand, for realists, TNCs still represent national interest (Gilpin, 2001), while others (such as representatives of the dependency school) are liable to identify TNCs with the means through which the rich can exploit the poor. What is important to note 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS is that TNCs are constantly evolving: as economic integration is becoming more intensive, production disintegrates as a result of the outsourcing activity of multinationals (Feenstra, 1998). This move induced Gereffi (1999) to develop the concept of global commodity chains, an idea that reflects upon the increasing importance of global buyers in a world of dispersed production. IS ECONOMIC GLOBALIZATION A NEW PHENOMENON? Just as there is no single definition of globalization, there is no consensus on its origin, either. Yet, if we accept that economic globalization is a process that creates an ‘organic system’ of the world economy, it seems reasonable to look beyond the last 30 years or so. The question necessarily arises how far we should look back. Gills and Thompson (2006: 1) very wittily suggest that globalization processes ‘have been ongoing ever since Homo sapiens began migrating from the African continent ultimately to populate the rest of the world. Minimally, they have been ongoing since the sixteen-century’s connection of the Americas to Afro-Eurasia’. Frank and Gills (1993: 3) also call for a broader outlook, and located the origin of globalization in the (very) distant past: ‘the existence of the same world system in which we live stretches back at least 5,000 years’. The best known example of archaic globalization is the Silk Road, which connected Asia, Africa and Europe. Adopting Fernand Braudel’s innovative concept of ‘long duration’, i.e. a slow-moving, ‘almost imperceptible’ (1973: 22) framework for historical analysis, world-systems analysts identify the origins of modernity and globalization with the birth of sixteenth century longdistance trade. When Adam Smith wrote his magnum opus, An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations (1776), he considered the discovery of America by Christopher Columbus in 1492 and the discovery of the direct sea route to India by Vasco de Gama 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 135 135 in 1498 as the two greatest achievements in human history.2 In the course of a couple of decades these remarkable achievements were overshadowed by the breathtaking technological advances and organization methods of the British Industrial Revolution.3 From the early 1800s, following the Napoleonic wars, the industrial revolution spread to Continental Europe and North America, too.4 The economic nationalism of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, coupled with monopolized trade (such as the first multinational corporations, the British and the Dutch East India Companies, established in 1600 and 1602, respectively) did not favour, however, international economic integration. The total number of ships sailing to Asia from major European countries rose remarkably between 1500 and 1800 (in numbers: 770 in the sixteenth, 3,161 in the seventeenth and 6,661 in the eighteenth century; Maddison, 2001), but world export to world GDP did not reach more than 1 to 2 per cent in that period (Held et al., 1999). If global economy did exist in this period, then it was only in the sense of ‘trade and exchange, rather than production’ (Gereffi, 2005: 161). Countries were mostly self-sufficient and autarkic, the UK and the Netherlands being the only exceptions (though long-distance trade concentrated mostly on luxury goods). The real break-through came only in the nineteenth century. The annual average compound growth rate of world trade saw a dramatic increase of 4.2 per cent between 1820 and 1870, and was still relatively high, at 3.4 per cent between 1870 and 1913 (Maddison, 2001). By 1913, trade equalled to 16–17 per cent of world income, thanks to the transport revolution: steamships and railroads reduced transaction costs and bolstered both internal and international exchange (Held et al., 1999). The relatively short period before World War I (that is, 1870 to 1913) is often referred to as the ‘golden age’ of globalization, characterized by relative peace, free trade and financial and economic stability (O’Rourke and Williamson, 1999). 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM 136 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION The structural transformation of the Western world was, therefore, both a cause and an effect of intensified economic integration. By the second half of the nineteenth century, the division of labour entwined modern world economy. Consequently, sceptics of globalization, such as Hirst and Thompson (2002), recognize the origin of globalization in this particular era and argue that in some respects (especially with regard to labour mobility), nineteenth century world economy was even more integrated than the present. CONVERGENCE VERSUS DIVERGENCE Contemporary globalization is, however, considered to be a myth (Bairoch, 1993) not just because it is not without precedents. More concerns have been raised with regard to its impact on the worldwide distribution of income. Those in support of economic globalization emphasize its ability to foster universal economic growth and development. Dollar and Kraay (2002) argue that only non-globalizer countries failed to reduce absolute and relative poverty in the last few decades. On the other hand, countries that have embraced globalization (proxied by trade openness) have benefited from openness considerably.5 Consequently, ‘the problem […] is not that there is too much globalization, but that there is far too little’ (Wolf, 2004: xvii). On a more balanced account, the World Bank (2002) claims that globalization can indeed reduce poverty but it definitely does not benefit all nations. SubSaharan Africa, where roughly half of the population lives on less than US$1.25 (in purchasing power parity) a day, has been especially marginalized by globalization. Nevertheless, whereas at the beginning of the nineteenth century countries were moreor-less homogenous (i.e. poor and agrarian), by the start of contemporary globalization countries became highly stratified (Baldwin and Martin, 1999). The ratio of the richest 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 136 region’s GDP per capita to that of the poorest was only 1.1 in 1000, 2 in 1500 and still only 3 in 1820. It widened to 5 in 1871 and stood at 9 at the outbreak of World War I. In 1950 it climbed to 15 and peaked at 18 at the turn of the new millennium (Maddison, 2003).6 Why are less developed regions unable to catch up with developed ones – as predicted by standard economic theories such as the neoclassical Solow growth model? Bairoch (1993) argues that while in the developed part of the world, industrial revolution and intensified international relations reinforced growth and development on an unprecedented scale (as compared to the previous era), the rest of the world did not manage to capitalize on these processes. Reflecting upon the division of labour between developed and developing countries in the nineteenth century, Bairoch claimed that ‘the industrialisation of the former led to the de-industrialisation of the latter’ (1998: 11). The structural deficiencies of the world economy are heavily emphasized by the socalled structuralists. Structuralism is a ‘cluster of theories which emerged in the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s … [and] share the idea that North and South are in a structural relationship one to another; that is that both areas are part of a structure that determines the pattern of relationships that emerges’ (Brown, 2001: 197). The best known critical approach to the prevailing social division of labour and global inequalities is offered by worldsystems analysis, which claims that capitalism under globalization reinforces the structural patterns of unequal change. According to Wallerstein, capitalism, ‘a historical social system’ (1983: 13), created the dramatically diverging historical level of wages in the economic arena of the world system. Thus, growing inequality, along with economic and political dependence, are not independent at all from economic globalization. Accordingly, underdevelopment (i.e. a persistent lack of economic growth and development, together with impoverishment and even malnutrition) is not the initial stage of a historical and evolutionary 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS unilinear development process (as predicted by Rostow, 1960), but a consequence of colonialism and imperialism. But while for Hobson (1902/2005) imperialism was a kind of ‘conscious policy’ adopted by leading capitalist nations, Wallerstein and his followers identified imperialism as the product of the world capitalist system which has perpetuated unequal exchange. The modern capitalist system is unique in the sense that it created political structures that guaranteed an endless appropriation and accumulation of surpluses from the poor (or the periphery) to the emerging (or the semiperiphery) and – in particular – the advanced industrialized (or the core) countries. It is, however, not just that the periphery is dependent on the core: the latter’s development is also conditioned on the former. The link between these groups is provided via trade and financial transactions, and is organized by a dense web of businessmen, merchants, financial entrepreneurs and state bureaucrats. Globalization, the product of the long process of capitalist development, is, therefore, nothing new for world-system analysts; it is simply the relabelling of old ideas and concepts (Arrighi, 2005). INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEMS According to Krasner (1983:2), regimes can be thought of as all the ‘implicit and explicit principles, norms, rules, and decision making procedures around which actors’ expectations converge’. Consequently, an international monetary system or regime (IMS) ‘refers to the rules, customs, instruments, facilities, and organizations for effecting international payments’ (Salvatore, 2007: 764). In the liberal tradition, the main task of an IMS is to facilitate cross-border transactions, especially trade and investment. An international monetary system is, however, more than just money or currencies; it also reflects economic power and interests, as ‘money is inherently political, an integral 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 137 137 part of “high politics” of diplomacy’ (Cohen, 2000: 91). THE GOLD STANDARD The origins of the first modern-day IMS dates back to the early nineteenth century, when the UK adopted gold mono-metallism in 1821. Half a century later, in 1867, the European nations, as well as the United States, propagated a deliberate shift to gold at the International Monetary Conference in Paris. Gold was believed to guarantee a non-inflationary, stable economic environment, a means for accelerating international trade (Einaudi, 2001). Following Prussia’s victory over France in 1872, Germany joined the new regime. France decided to do so six years later. With the joining of the United States in 1879, the gold standard became the international monetary regime by 1880. Following the joining of Italy (1984) and Russia (1897), roughly 70 per cent of the nations participated in the gold standard just before the outbreak of World War I (Meissner, 2005). In practice, the gold standard functioned as a fixed exchange rate regime, with gold as the only international reserve. Participating countries determined the gold content of national currencies, which in turn defined fixed exchange rates (or mint parities) as well. Consequently, ‘common adherence to gold convertibility … linked the world together through fixed exchange rates’ (Bordo and Rockoff, 1996: 3). Monetary authorities were obliged to exchange their national currencies for gold at the official exchange rate without limits on international markets. One of the main strengths of the system was the tendency for trade balance to be in equilibrium. Balanced positions were ensured by the automatic price-specie flow mechanism, which assumed a passive change in money supply and a full flexibility in internal prices. David Hume (1752) was the first to elaborate on this mechanism by developing his quantitative theory of money. Accordingly, as a deficit nation’s gold reserves diminished 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM 138 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION (since its import was financed by gold), its general price level started to decline as well, which restored its competitiveness on international markets. The price that such countries had to pay for the automatic adjustment mechanism was the loss of autonomy in monetary policy. In practice, it also meant that deficit nations were enforced to initiate serious deflationary policies. In order to assess whether the gold standard was successful, a good reference point is offered by Eichengreen (1996: 1), who claims that the role of a properly designed IMS ‘is to lend order and stability to foreign exchange markets, to encourage the elimination of balance-of-payments problems, and to provide access to international credits in the event of disruptive shocks’. The regime was indeed able to create stability; it also helped nations to restore equilibrium in their current accounts and provided an almost unlimited access to world finance. The outbreak of World War I brought an end to the classical gold standard. Participating nations gave up convertibility and abandoned gold export in order to stop the depletion of their national gold reserves. Although the UK did attempt a return to the gold standard at pre-war price levels in 1925, it did not finally succeed. The overvalued pound sterling and the emergence of new rivals, especially the United States and France, reduced the competitiveness of the UK substantially. As opposed to the pre-World War I era, the UK could not finance its current account deficit by capital inflow anymore; therefore, it had no other choice but to abandon the gold standard once and for all in 1931. Indeed, the 1930s became the darkest period of modern economic history. Competitive devaluations, along with tough capital controls and the imposition of (prohibitive) tariffs, induced a race to the bottom which culminated in a devastating drop of international transactions. The negative spiral of the 1930s provided historical evidence to the close relationship between exchange rate policy and trade measures (Eichengreen and Irwin, 2009). 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 138 The change from the gold standard to competitive devaluations and floating was, however, more than a simple shift from one financial regime to another. In Karl Polányi’s (1944) views, the deep structural changes of the time, which were partly the causes and also the consequences of universal suffrage (labourers managed to influence domestic politics), made the governments reluctant to defend a pegging system at any cost. In the classical gold standard regime, deflationary policies were endorsed without much hesitation. After World War I, however, labourers became more and more successful in preventing incumbents from adopting welfarereducing austerity measures. THE BRETTON WOODS SYSTEM AND ITS DISSOLUTION The dramatic consequences of the beggar-thyneighbour policies of the inter-war period and the wish to return to peace and prosperity impelled the allied nations to start negotiations about a new international monetary regime in the framework of the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire (US), in July 1944. Delegates of 44 countries managed to agree on adopting an adjustable peg system, the gold-exchange standard. The US dollar was the only convertible currency of the time, so the United States committed itself to sell and purchase gold without restrictions at US$35 dollar an ounce. All other participating but non-convertible currencies were fixed to the US dollar. The goldexchange standard was not the only competing idea on the table, however. The British economist, John Maynard Keynes, proposed ambitious reforms for the post-war era and recommended the creation of an international clearing union, a kind of global bank, along with the introduction of a new unit of account, the ‘bancor’ (Keynes, 1942/1969). Nevertheless, the United States insisted on its own plan and branded the British proposal as a serious blow to national sovereignty. 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS Delegates also agreed on the establishment of two international institutions. The International Banks for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) became responsible for post-war reconstruction, while the explicit mandate of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) was to promote international financial cooperation and buttress international trade. The IMF was expected to safeguard the smooth functioning of the gold-exchange standard by providing short-term financial assistance in case of temporary balance of payments difficulties. As opposed to Keynes’s plan of a new international clearing union, the Bretton Woods system did not prevent countries from running large and persistent deficits (or surpluses) in their balance of payments. Although nations were allowed to correct the official exchange rate in order to eliminate deficits (hence the name, adjustable peg system), adjustments did not happen frequently. The UK, for instance, was put under constant pressure by speculators to devaluate its currency (it did so only once in 1967). Abstention from devaluations that were believed to be humiliating triggered investors to relocate their capital outside Britain. The US’s situation was unique, however. During the first few years of the new regime, the country managed to maintain a surplus in its balance of payments. As soon as Europe regained its pre-World War II economic power, the external position of the United States turned into a persistent deficit as a natural consequence of becoming an international reserve currency. Nevertheless, by the mid-1960s, the dollar became excessively overvalued vis-à-vis major currencies. As a response, foreign countries started to deplete the US gold reserves. Destabilizing speculations, fed by the huge balance of payments and trade deficit, along with inflationary pressures, forced the United States to abandon the gold-exchange standard on 15 August, 1971.7 Although industrialized countries were keen to return to some kind of a controlled exchange rate mechanism under the so-called 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 139 139 Smithsonian Agreement (a de facto dollarstandard) in December 1971, neither the devaluation of the US currency (and the revaluation of the partners’ currencies), nor the dollar’s non-convertibility to gold managed to stabilize world finances. In early 1973, industrialized countries decided to float their currencies and intervene in financial markets only in case of drastic short-term fluctuations. Longer-term prices of currencies were determined by demand and supply forces exclusively. This shift in exchange rate policy was acknowledged by the Jamaica Accords in 1976. Managed floating, however, did not perform any better, either; in fact, advanced countries had to interfere on a few occasions in order to avoid calamity. In 1985 for instance, G7 countries agreed on a substantial devaluation of the US dollar under the Plaza Agreement, as a result of an increasing pressure of domestic US manufacturers and agrarians to restore their competitiveness on world markets. Two years later, in 1987, the Louvre Accord was drawn up in order to defend the dollar from further devaluation on the markets. While the United States might have benefited from these globally coordinated actions, one of the main losers was evidently Japan. The appreciation of the yen proved to be disastrous for the Japanese economy, which faced a decade-long struggle in the 1990s as a partial consequence of the ‘dollar politics’ (see Destler and Henning, 1989). The 1990s saw the triumph of the neoliberal, pro-market Washington Consensus. Its programme points were advocated and disseminated by the major international financial institutions.8 The IMF used these points as part of its adjustment requirements (or conditionalities) in exchange for financial assistance. Several countries, especially the so-called emerging markets such as Mexico, Brazil or the East Asian tigers, deregulated their financial sectors and fully liberalized capital transactions from the late 1980s onwards. Reforms, however, were not supplemented by strengthened domestic supervision or monitoring. Additionally, these 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM 140 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION currencies were pegged to the US dollar, which happened to appreciate substantially during the 1990s and caused a loss in the price competitiveness of emerging markets. The unregulated and free flow of capital, the huge current account deficits and the soft pegging regimes made these economies highly vulnerable, resulting in a financial crisis that first hit Mexico in 1994 and reached East Asia in 1997–8. The Washington Consensus and its freemarket ideology has been criticized by many right from its conception. Stiglitz (2002) blamed the IMF and its rigid conditionalities for the failed development performance of the periphery. His main argument was that free-market policies such as liberalization or privatization could not deliver the expected results in an environment of imperfect or incomplete markets and inadequate or missing institutions. From a wider perspective, Wallerstein (2005) commented the change of economic thinking of the late 1980s and early 1990s by arguing that ‘development was suddenly out. Globalization arrived in its wake … Now, the way to move forward was not to import-substitute but to export-orient productive activities. Down not only with nationalized industries but with capital transfer controls; up with transparent, unhindered flows of capital’ (2005: 1265). EUROPEAN MONETARY INTEGRATION In the post-World War II era, the United States originally wanted to implement the Morgenthau Plan, which intended to downsize the German economy into a pastoral and agricultural one. As a response to the USSR’s push for communism in Eastern Europe and the rise of socialist and communist parties in the West, the plan, however, became quickly abandoned, and the United States started to advocate an economically and militarily strong Germany and Western Europe. The United States activated its post-war reconstruction programme, the Marshall Plan, in 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 140 1948, which was administered by the Organization for European Economic Cooperation, the predecessor of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). The miraculous growth performance of Western Europe prompted a closer cooperation on a regional level, resulting finally in the European Coal and Steel Community in 1951.9 This was followed by the signing of the Rome Treaty in 1957, which established the European Economic Community (EEC), and was the first major step towards an ‘ever closer union’. The original six founding members (Germany, France, Italy, Netherlands, Belgium and Luxembourg) aimed at the creation of a common market, where goods, services, capital and labour moved freely. Originally, the European six did not plan any direct cooperation in the field of finance or exchange rate policies. The collapse of the Bretton Woods system, however, placed the EEC under pressure, and member countries eventually agreed on setting up a regional monetary regime, the European Monetary System (EMS) in 1979. The EMS was a unique system, since neither the US dollar, nor gold could play a role in the stabilization process of exchange rates. Instead, a symmetric adjustable peg arrangement, the European Exchange Rate Mechanism, was created (Gros and Thygesen, 1998). The success of the EMS and the total abolishment of capital controls by the end of the 1980s opened the way for Jacques Delors, then President of the European Commission, to propose a radical leap forward in European economic integration. With the support of both late French President Francois Mitterrand and German Chancellor Helmut Kohl, the foundations of a new European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) were laid down in the Maastricht Treaty in 1992. By 1999, the member states of the EMU abandoned their national currencies and delegated monetary policy onto a supranational level, administered by the European Central Bank (ECB), whose primary goal has been 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS the maintenance of price stability. The first ten years of the EMU were an evident success for participating countries: trade and capital transactions increased; economies became more integrated; macroeconomic stability was restored and the euro became the second most widely used reserve currency (European Commission, 2008). The global financial and economic crisis of 2008–9, however, posed dramatic challenges for the European Union (EU). The euro-area is suffering from serious design flaws. The ECB is not a lender of last resort, that is, it cannot bail out individual countries which have lost their monetary authority (that is, they cannot devaluate their currency or reduce domestic interest rates in case of troubles). The EU is not a fiscal union either; therefore, it does not have any specific means to fix financial difficulties on a community level. Yet, the financial and economic crisis, which culminated in an EU-wide sovereign debt crisis by late 2009, has demonstrated that the troubles of some member states can easily undermine the stability of the whole zone; contagion has become a real threat. As a response to the crisis, the EU enacted a three-pillar financial rescue programme in 2010, comprising the following: (1) the European Financial Stability Mechanism, (2) the European Financial Stability Facility; and (3) the financial assistance of the IMF. Since the three-pillar system was designed for a temporary period only, the EU has decided to activate its own permanent rescue facility, the European Stability Mechanism, from 2013 onwards. The critics of the Eurozone have always underlined the fact that EMU would never be able to qualify for a well-functioning and stable monetary zone without a common budget of the size of federal countries such as the United States (Feldstein, 1997). The future of the EMU depends on the willingness of member states to agree on more fundamental changes in the governance of the Eurozone. One of the most promising ideas is to develop the current structure into a fiscal union, supported by a pan-European banking supervision. These innovations may 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 141 141 lay down the foundations of a political union as well in the distant future. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND TRADE POLICIES The late Nobel-laureate economist, Paul Samuelson, was once asked if he could name one proposition which he considered as both valid and non-trivial in the social sciences. Samuelson famously referred to David Ricardo’s comparative advantage theory (Samuelson, 1995). According to Ricardo (1817), a country such as England could benefit from voluntary trade even if its trading partner (which in the original example was Portugal) was more effective in producing both wine and clothing. England should specialize in the production of the good with less disadvantage and let Portugal produce the other product. The appeal of the theory is that every single nation must have a comparative (that is, relative) advantage in something irrespective of its initial conditions.10 But trade is not without politics. Alexander Hamilton and Friedrich List recognized quite early on (i.e. in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth century, respectively) that voluntary trade can have very different distributional effects and it can also hinder the long-term development prospects of the country producing the lower value added (i.e. agricultural) products. A temporary retreat from international trade can thus be beneficial for the less effective nation. In his so-called ‘infant industry argument’, List (1841/1928) did not oppose the Ricardian comparative advantage theory; but he did warn that trade patterns should not be considered as static. Instead, by temporarily restricting the free flow of goods, a national industry can be established, thereby fostering long-term economic growth and political power. In the realist and (neo)mercantilist school, protection is, in fact, still a natural way of securing national objectives (Gilpin, 2001). 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM 142 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION Reformist and radical (new left and neoMarxian) theorists, such as Emmanuel (1972) or Amin (1976), argued, however, that unequal exchange is a fundamental and systemic distinguishing characteristic of modern world economy.11 The social division of labour contributes to the economic development of the core and hinders development at the periphery. By grasping the leading role in the transformation of the world economy, Europe, and later on its Western offshoots, managed to gain control of the rest of the world, creating a unique and unfair global division of labour (Wallerstein, 1974, 1980).12 Core economies ‘have had [thus] the best of two worlds, both as consumers of primary commodities and as producers of manufactured articles, whereas the underdeveloped countries had the worst of both worlds, as consumers of manufactures and as producers of raw materials’ (Singer, 1964: 167).13 According to Amin (1993), if the world economy is such that it benefits core countries at the expense of the periphery, the latter should adopt protectionism in its extreme form of de-linking, i.e. a total breaking up of the ties between the subordinated developing economies and the core. International trade can trigger tensions not just between nations, but also within a particular country. Gains from trade within a country will affect the relative well-being of its citizens, especially producers and consumers, differently, who will, therefore, either support or oppose trade. Based on the Stolper–Samuelson theorem, which claims that international trade benefits the domestically abundant factor of production (land, labour or capital) and weakens the scarce factor, Rogowski (1990) managed to demonstrate how the owners of the locally abundant factor of production increase their political power and influence as well. Consequently, the coalitions of potential losers of trade provide permanent source for a strong advocacy of protectionism from the least developed countries to the most advanced economies, including the EU or the United States. 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 142 UNILATERAL TRADE ORDER In seventeenth and eighteenth century Europe international trade was basically a means to accumulate surplus (gold reserves) in the balance of payments by stimulating export and restricting import. The mercantilist era of the time was best characterized, therefore, as a zero-sum game on the global level. Trade and trade policies served the interest of monarchs from Portugal to England, who financed wars and consolidated authority over domestic constituents with the help of accumulated gold stocks.14 The surge of international trade arrived only with Europe’s industrial revolution and the consequent repeal of the British Corn Laws in 1846 in particular. Industrialists triumphed over landowners and farmers, opening the way for further industrialization in Britain. The so-called Cobden-Chevalier treaty of 1860 allowed the UK and France to specialize in commodities based on their respective comparative advantages and to achieve further advances in industrialization. Voluntary trade also helped to avoid the eruption of an abrupt war between the two countries (Dunham, 1930).15 Several other bilateral trade agreements followed suit across Europe, each built upon the so-called most-favoured nation (MFN) principle, which stated that any negotiated reciprocal tariff reductions between two parties should be extended to all other trading partners without conditions. Overall average tariffs declined from 16.3 per cent (1859) to 6.3 per cent (1875) in Britain, from 11.8 per cent to 6.5 per cent in France, from 7.1 per cent to 2.5 per cent in Germany and from 7.3 per cent to 3.6per cent in Austria-Hungary (Lampe, 2008). Europe witnessed the emergence of a sort of multilateral system of bilateral agreements, giving birth to the ‘first common market’ in the second half of the nineteenth century (Marsh, 1999). The era, however, was not without conflicts and interruptions to free trade (Findlay and O’Rourke, 2007). The United States adopted a highly protective import substitution industrialization with tariffs on manufacturing goods, 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS averaging at 45 per cent. From the 1860s onwards, France, the Scandinavian countries and to a lesser extent even the UK enacted a few protectionist measures as a response to the inflow of cheap agricultural products from the overseas territories and the industrialization efforts of catching-up countries like Germany and the United States. Nevertheless, neither the prevailing unilateral trade regime, nor the hegemonic position of the UK was threatened. Britain remained powerful enough both in economic and military terms; it could also rely on the vast reserves of its colonies, especially India (Arrighi and Silver, 2003). World War I, however, was a dramatic blow to free trade. Protectionism, in turn, was detrimental to development, peace and stability (Ruggie, 1982). Two rounds of World Economic Conferences in 1927 and 1933 failed to deliver tariff reductions and exchangerate stabilization because of the unwillingness of the United States to take the role of the hegemon as a successor of a weakened Great Britain. Domestic politics in the United States evidently turned against restrictions-free trade as a consequence of the Great Depression of 1929–33. The Smoot-Hawley Act of 1930 increased tariffs to record-high levels in the United States. Retaliation was the rational response from trading partners and international trade dropped by one- to two-thirds as a consequence (Irwin, 1998).16 The enactment of the US Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act in 1934 eventually put a stop to any further decline in international trade. The Act allowed the president to determine trade policies and also eased the pressure put on the Congress for protection. In practice, the Act was a return to the principle of MFN and it provided a solid base for a renewed international trade regime following World War II. MULTILATERALISM: FROM THE GATT TO THE WTO While the United States was reluctant to take a leadership role after World War I, this was naturally not the case two-and-a-half decades 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 143 143 later. The dollar became a world currency, backed by two-thirds of the world’s gold reserve in 1950 (Green, 1999). The United States was the largest aid donor, mostly in the form of the Marshall Plan. Due to the total collapse of the European and Japanese manufacturing industries, the global role of US manufacturing increased substantially, accounting for 60 per cent of the world’s total in 1950, while its export amounted to one-third of the world’s total (Branson et al., 1980). As opposed to the pre-World War I regime of non-institutionalized unilateralism, the new trade regime was more or less a liberal, multilateral rules-based system backed by a solid legal approach to trade relations (Winham, 2008). According to Ruggie (1982), it was a compromise between the extreme liberal international regime of the long nineteenth century and the economic nationalism of the inter-war period. Originally, the new international trade regime should have been steered by the International Trade Organization (ITO), which was originally conceived as one of the three pillars of the Bretton Woods system (the other two being the IMF and the IBRD). Although the United States played an undisputable role in creating the ITO, a series of vetoes in the US Congress blocked its formation. In place of a unique trade organization, nations committed to a world of lowered tariffs decided to coordinate their actions under the auspices of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). The GATT exerted influence via a series of multilateral trade negotiations (or rounds). The first five rounds concentrated on tariff cuts exclusively (see Table 9.1). From 1964 onwards, the scope of trade negotiations experienced a slow but steady expansion. The creation of the European Economic Community in 1957 enforced the United States to adopt the Trade Expansion Act of 1962 and to call for a new round, the so-called Kennedy Round. The result was an across-the-board cutting (replacing the previous practice of item-by-item cuts) and reduction of non-tariff barriers, especially that of 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM 144 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION Table 9.1 GATT trade rounds Year Place/Name Subjects covered 1947 1949 1951 1956 1960–1961 1964–1967 1973–1979 1986–1994 Geneva Annecy Torquay Geneva Dillon Round Kennedy Round Tokyo Round Uruguay Round Tariffs Tariffs Tariffs Tariffs Tariffs Tariffs and anti-dumping measures Tariffs, non-tariff barriers, ‘framework agreements’ Tariffs, non-tariff barriers, rules, services, intellectual property, dispute settlement, textiles, agriculture, creation of the WTO, etc. No. of participating countries 23 13 38 26 26 62 102 123 Source: WTO (2012) anti-dumping measures (Evans, 1971). In the 1970s, the Tokyo Round proceeded with the same extended mandate, and, besides tariff cuts, it also adopted a series of codes of conduct, such as the subsidies code or the government procurement code (Deardorff and Stern, 1983). The most famous multilateral trade negotiations were carried out under the Uruguay Round between 1986 and 1994. While earlier trade negotiations proved to be successful in reducing tariffs, a series of other punitive measures (namely non-tariff barriers) were imposed by countries. Also, the pattern of international trade changed dramatically. Trade gravitated to multi- or transnational corporations, which tried to optimize their operations worldwide by allocating resources (including manufacturing capacities) based on principles other than comparative advantage. By the early 1980s, intra-industry or even inter-company trade has become the determining feature of the international division of labour (Dunning, 1990.) The pervasive influence of TNCs resulted in a change in the politics of trade. According to Held and McGrew (2001: 325), ‘it is global corporate capital, rather than states, which exercises decisive influence over the organization, location and distribution of economic power and resources’ in the contemporary world economy. The Uruguay Round extended multilateral rules to new issues and sectors, such as agriculture (which culminated in a bitter dispute between the United States and the EU). 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 144 Furthermore, it invited a large number of developing countries to participate in trade negotiations, and it also created a new and more efficient dispute settlement mechanism (Walter and Sen, 2009). The major outcomes of the trade negotiations were the agreements on trade-related investment measures (TRIMs), trade in services (GATS) and traderelated aspects of intellectual property rights (TRIPs). The agreements were advocated by major advanced countries and targeted mostly developing nations with huge service market potential (especially in finance and telecommunication). After almost 50 years of rules-based trade negotiations, the Uruguay Round gave birth to a ‘real’ international trade institution, the World Trade Organization. The WTO was launched on 1 January 1995 and has become an official forum for trade negotiations. As opposed to the GATT, it is a formally constituted organization with legal personality. Although the developing countries represented a unified front for a new round of trade negotiations in Seattle, 1999, the ministerial conference closed without reaching concrete results. Nevertheless, Seattle demonstrated the strength of NGOs and anti-globalization movements, which protested not only in favour of the disadvantaged and less-developed countries but also against the current status quo of world affairs – including the dominance of the US economy, the selfish interest of large multinational corporations and the assumed discriminatory workings of the WTO. 2/26/2014 11:30:48 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS Expectations were once again on the rise in Doha in 2001. The quasi-official Doha Round could have become a round on economic development, but the positions of the opposing parties were so rigid that it eventually failed to meet expectations. Developing nations insisted on the correct and full implementation of the Uruguay Agreement (especially in the sphere of agriculture), while the United States tried to keep labour and environmental issues on the agenda, and the EU wished to negotiate and codify competition and investment policies. None of the following ministerial conferences could reach a real breakthrough.17 The stalemate between the two major camps, however, pushed developing countries to unite and strengthen their positions within the WTO by forming a pressure group called the Group of 20 (G20). The unprecedented coalition accounts for almost two-thirds of the world’s population and onequarter of global agricultural export (Narlikar and Tussie, 2004). DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE Developing nations did not participate actively in multilateral trade negotiations for a relatively long time. Apart from the socalled East Asian newly industrializing countries, which adopted an outward-oriented development strategy, most of the developing countries did not manage to integrate into the post-World War II trading system successfully. On the one hand, they followed an inward-looking, import-substitution industrialization strategy, which did not favour trade openness (Findlay and O’Rourke, 2007). On the other hand, advanced economies were also reluctant to open their markets to commodities such as textile or agriculture products in which developing countries had a natural comparative advantage. The first major change in this state of affairs happened in 1964, when the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) was established with the joint 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 145 145 effort of the developing world. The aim of UNCTAD was to promote trade and cooperation between the developing and the developed nations. A decade later plans for a new international economic order were laid down, with the multiple objectives of providing preferential access to advanced countries’ markets, renegotiating debt, establishing international commodity agreement (to stabilize primary product prices),18 providing transfer of technology, and increasing aid substantially (Salvatore, 2007). Nevertheless, the two oil crises and the consequent slowing down of economic activity in the developed nations swept these initiatives away. Instead, advanced countries adopted highly protective measures (both tariffs and non-tariff measurements) in order to cushion the negative effects of the economic stagnation of the 1980s. The change in the behaviour of developing countries arrived with the Uruguay Round. Originally, the round was meant to be a grand bargain between developed and developing economies (Ostry, 2002). The former were expected to open their markets, especially to agricultural and textile products, whereas the latter accepted the new regulation on intellectual property rights and services. While developing countries have opened up their service markets, their export of agricultural products is still blocked by advanced nations. Agriculture has a share of one-third to a half of the total economic output in most developing countries. Without the liberalization of agriculture, it is simply impossible for developing nations to fully integrate into the global economy. By quantifying the gains from the round, Harrison et al. (1997) argued that the aggregate welfare gains were between US$100 (in the short run) and US$170 billion (in the long run) annually. Developing countries, however, might have easily found themselves on the losers’ side – at least in the short term. Hertel et al. (1998) have also acknowledged that Africa is a potential loser of the Uruguay Round. Khor (1995) thus views the WTO as the means by which 2/26/2014 11:30:49 AM 146 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION industrialized countries can gain access to the markets of developing countries. In fact, a number of criticisms have been voiced with regard to the current trade regime. Wade (2003), for example, has condemned the three major trade agreements, i.e. the TRIMS, the GATS and the TRIPS, for constraining the available set of industrial policies for development to such an extent that development ladder of developing economies had been practically kicked away. DiCaprio and Amsden (2004) regard the WTO as a logical consequence of the Washington Consensus approach to development, which considers domestic interventions highly distortive and ineffective. Stiglitz (2002) argues that today’s advanced economies applied such ‘distortions’ widely at the onset of their own development. It is hypocritical, therefore, to enforce developing countries to fully liberalize their trade and financial sector. All in all, the current trade regime and especially its main propagator, the WTO, is heavily criticized for ‘a striking asymmetry. National boundaries should not matter for trade flows and capital flows but should be clearly demarcated for technology flows and labor flows … This asymmetry … lies at the heart of inequality in the rules of the game for globalization’ (Nayyar, 2002: 158). DISCUSSION QUESTIONS 1 Why did the Bretton Woods System collapse in the 1970s? 2 In what ways is market globalism embedded in contemporary global economic relations? 3 To what degree has intergovernmental cooperation to limit exchange rate volatility enabled the globalization of finance? 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 NOTES 1 Hirst and Thompson (1996:185) sceptics of contemporary globalization, claim accordingly that the basic difference between an internationalized economy and a strictly global economy is that in the case of the latter ‘economic outcomes are determined wholly by world market 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 146 11 forces and by the internal decisions of transnational companies’. Quoted by Tracy (1990). The industrial revolution of course was well on the track at the age of Adam Smith already. The textile industry was on a steady rise from the 1720s. The second half of the eighteenth century witnessed the discovery and the widespread use of the steam engine. European economies and their offshoots grew at moderate levels in today’s standards but it outpaced extensively the pre-Industrial Revolution era growth performance. Annual growth rates accelerated from 0.14 per cent between 1500 and 1820 to 0.9 per cent in the following 50 years and peaked at an annual average of 1.33 per cent between 1870 and World War I (Maddison, 2001). They argue that due to increased trade openness, globalizers (including China and India) achieved an average annual growth rate of 3.5 per cent and 5.0 per cent in the 1980s and 1990s, respectively, as opposed to non-globalizer rates of 0.8 per cent and 1.1 per cent for the same periods. The richest region includes the United States, Canada, Australia and New Zealand. Africa is the poorest. Apart from the closure of the so-called ‘gold window’, the United States also initiated a wage freeze and an import surcharge (Bordo, 1993). The ten points of the Washington Consensus are the following: 1. fiscal policy discipline; 2. effective public spending; 3. tax reform; 4. competitive exchange rates; 5. trade liberalization; 6. financial market (interest rate) liberalization; 7. liberalization of foreign direct investment; 8. privatization; 9. deregulation; 10. security of property rights (Williamson, 1994). Major European economies regained their 1939level of GDP by 1951 (Crafts and Toniolo, 1996). As an illustration let us assume that Portugal produces nine units of wine and six units of clothing in one labour hour, while England produces three units of each. Although Portugal has an absolute advantage in the production of both goods, it is, however, more productive in wine than in clothing if compared to England (9/3 versus 6/3). Portugal should concentrate, therefore, on the production and export of wine and England should specialize in the production of clothing. If the two nations engage in voluntary trade, each can increase its overall wealth, i.e. more wine and clothing can be produced in total than without specialization and trade. Emmanuel (1973), who developed the concept of unequal exchange, has been heavily criticized by Amin (1976), who claims that exchange (the ‘surface phenomenon’) cannot be separated from production. 2/26/2014 11:30:49 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS 12 Asia possessed roughly two-thirds of world GDP in 1700, while the West accounted for onequarter only. By 1950, the West had a 60 per cent share, while Asia fell to 20 per cent (Dicken, 2004: 34–5). 13 Albeit the concept of unequal exchange has gained substantial theoretical support, there has been much less interest in its empirical testing. One exception, however, is Köhler and Tausch (2002). 14 ‘Trade policy deals with the economic effects of direct or indirect government intervention … [it] deals with the winners and losers that arise from government intervention in markets’ (Kerr, 2007: 1). 15 That international trade can enhance peace and international political relations is a strong assertion in liberal political theory, too (see Keohane, 1984). For a more critical approach, see Strange (1985). 16 See Eichengreen (1989) on the political economy of the Act. 17 Ministerial conferences in order of time were the Cancún (2003) meeting, the Hong Kong meeting (2005), and two conferences in Geneva (2009 and 2011). 18 The share of primary commodity export was 81 per cent in Africa, 79 per cent in the Pacific Island states, 72 per cent in the former Soviet Union countries and 55 per cent in Latin America and the Caribbean in 2009 (UNDP, 2011). REFERENCES Amin S (1976) Unequal development. Sussex: The Harvester Press. Amin S (1993) The challenge of globalisation: Delinking. In: The South Centre: Facing the challenge. London: ZED Books, pp.132–8. Arrighi G (2005) Globalization in world-systems perspective. In: Appelbaum LL and Robinson WI (eds) Critical globalization studies. London: Routledge. pp. 33–44. Arrighi G and Silver B (2003) Polanyi’s double movement. The belle époques of British and US hegemony compared. Politics & Society 31(2): 325–55. Bairoch P (1993) Economics and world history: Myths and paradoxes. Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf. Bairoch P (1998) International industrialization levels from 1750–1980. In: O’Brien P (ed.) Industrialization. London: Routledge, pp.3–35. Baldwin RE and Martin P (1999) Two waves of globalisation: Superficial similarities, fundamental differences. NBER Working Paper No. 6904. Bordo MD (1993) The Bretton Woods international monetary system: A historical overview. In: Bordo 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 147 147 MD and Eichengreen B (eds) A retrospective on the Bretton Woods System: Lessons for international monetary reform. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 3–108. Bordo MD and Rockoff H (1996) The gold standard as a good housekeeping seal of approval. Journal of Economic History 56(2): 389–428. Boyer R and Drache D (1996) Introduction. In: Boyer R and Drache D (eds), States against markets: The limits of globalization. London: Routledge, pp. 1–30. Branson WH, Giersch H and Peterson PG (1980) Trends in United States international trade and investment since World War II. In: Feldstein M (ed.) The American economy in transition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp.183–274. Braudel F (1973) The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean world in the age of Phillip II. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Broadberry S, Fremdling R and Solar P (2010) Industry. In: Broadberry S and O’Rourke K (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe, Vol. 1. pp.164–88. Brodie J (1996) New state forms, new political spaces. In: Boyer R and Drache D (eds) States against markets: The limits of globalization. London: Routledge, pp. 383–98. Brown C (2001) Understanding international relations. Houndmills: Palgrave. Cohen B (2000) Money and power in world politics. In: Lawton TC, Rosenau JN and Verdun AC (eds) Strange power. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate Publishing, pp. 91–113. Crafts N and Toniolo G (1996) Economic growth in Europe since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Deardorff AV and Stern RM (1983) Economic effects of the Tokyo Round. Southern Economic Journal 49(3): 605–24. Destler IM and Henning RC (1989) Dollar politics: Exchange rate policy-making in the US. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Di Caprio A and Amsden A (2004) Does the new international trade regime leave room for industrialization policies in the middle-income countries?’ World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalization, ILO, Working Paper No. 22. Dicken P (2004) Global shift: Reshaping the global economic map in the 21st century. London: SAGE. Dollar D and Kraay A (2002) Spreading the wealth. Foreign Affairs 81(1): 120–33. Dunham AL (1930) The Anglo-French Treaty of Commerce of 1860 and the progress of the industrial 2/26/2014 11:30:49 AM 148 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION revolution in France. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Publications. Dunning JH (1990) The globalization of firms and the competitiveness of countries. Lund: Institute of Economic Research. Eichengreen B (1989) The political economy of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff. Research in Economic History 12, 1–43. Eichengreen BJ (1996) Globalizing capital: A history of the international monetary system. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Eichengreen BJ and Irwin DA (2009) The slide to protectionism in the Great Depression: Who succumbed and why? NBER working paper No. 15142. Einaudi L (2001) Money and politics: European monetary unification and the international gold standard, 1865–1873. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Emmanuel A (1972) Unequal exchange: A study of the imperialism of trade. New York: Monthly Review Press. European Commission (2008) EMU@10: Successes and challenges after 10 years of Economic and Monetary Union. European Economy No. 2, June, Brussels. Evans JW (1971) The Kennedy Round in American trade policy: The twilight of the GATT? Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Feenstra RC (1998) Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(4): 31–50. Feldstein M (1997) The political economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union: Political sources of an economic liability. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(1): 3–22. Findlay R and O’Rourke KH (2007) Power and plenty: Trade, war, and the world economy in the second millennium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Frank AG and Gills BK (1993) The world system: Five hundred years or five thousand? London: Routledge. Gereffi G (1999) International trade and industrial upgrading in the apparel commodity chain. Journal of International Economics 48(1): 37–70. Gereffi G (2005) The global economy: Organization, governance, and development. In: Smesler N and Swedberg R (eds) Handbook of economic sociology. Princeton, NJ University Press, pp.160–82. Giddens A (1999) Runaway world. Lecture 1 – Globalisation. London: BBC Reith Lectures. Gills BK and Thompson WR (2006) Globalization, global histories and historical globalities. In: Gills, BK and Thompson WR (eds) Globalization and global history. London: Routledge, pp.1–15. 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 148 Gilpin R (2000) The challenge of global capitalism: The world economy in the 21st century. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Gilpin R (2001) Global political economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Green T (1999) Central bank gold reserves: An historical perspective since 1845. World Gold Council Research Study No. 23. Gros D and Thygesen N (1998) European monetary integration. London: Longman. Harrison GW, Rutherford TF and Tarr DG (1997) Quantifying the Uruguay Round. The Economic Journal 107(444): 1405–30. Held D, McGrew A, Goldblatt D, et al. (1999) Global transformations: Politics, economic s and culture. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Held D and McGrew A (2001) Globalization. In: Krieger J (ed.) Oxford companion to politics of the world. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hertel TW, Masters WA and Elbehri A (1998) The Uruguay Round and Africa: A global, general equilibrium analysis. Journal of African Economies 7(2): 208–34. Hirst P and Thompson G (1996) Globalization in question: The international economy and the possibilities of governance. Cambridge: Polity Press. Hirst P and Thompson G (2002) The future of globalization. Cooperation and Conflict 37(3): 247–65. Hobson JA (1902/2005) Imperialism, a study. New York: Cosimo. Hume D (1752) Political discourses. Edinburgh. Reprinted. In: Rotwein E (ed.) Writings on economics. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. IMF (2008) Globalization: A brief overview. Issues Brief Issue 02/08. Washington, DC. Irwin DA (1998) The Smoot-Hawley tariff: A quantitative assessment. The Review of Economics and Statistics 80(2): 326–34. Keohane RO (1984) After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Kerr WA (2007) Introduction to trade policy. In: Kerr WA and Gaisford JD (eds) Handbook on international trade policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, pp.1–8. Keynes JM (1942/1969) Proposals for an International Currency (or Clearing) Union. In: Horsefield JK (ed.) The International Monetary Fund 1945–1965: Twenty years of international monetary cooperation. Vol. III, Washington, DC: IMF, pp. 3–19. Khor M (1995) The WTO and the South: Implications and recent developments. Third World Network. 2/26/2014 11:30:49 AM THE GLOBALIZATION OF ECONOMIC RELATIONS Köhler G and Tausch A (2002) Global Keynesianism: Unequal exchange and global exploitation. Huntington, NY: Nova Science Publishers. Krasner S (1983) Structural causes and regime consequences: Regimes as intervening variables. In: Krasner S (ed.) International regimes. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, pp.1–22. Lampe M (2008) Bilateral trade flows in Europe, 1857– 1875: A new dataset. Research in Economic History 26: 81–155. List F (1841/1928) The national system of political economy. New York: Longmans, Green. Maddison A (2001) The world economy: A millennial perspective. Paris: OECD. Maddison A (2003) The world economy: Historical statistics. Paris: OECD. Marsh PT (1999) Bargaining on Europe. Britain and the first common market, 1860–1892. New Haven: Yale University Press. McGrew A (2008) The logics of economic globalization. In: Ravenhill J (ed.) Global political economy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 277–313. Meissner CM (2005) A new world order: Explaining the international diffusion of the gold standard. Journal of International Economics 66(2): 385–406. Milner H and Keohane R (1996) Internationalization and domestic politics: An introduction. In: Milner H and Keohane R (eds) Internationalization and domestic politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 3–24. Narlikar A and Tussie D (2004) The G20 at the Cancun Ministerial: Developing countries and their evolving coalition in the WTO. The World Economy 27(7): 947–66. Nayyar D (2002) Cross-border movements of people. In: Nayyar D (ed.) Governing globalization. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.144–76. Ohmae K (1995) The end of the nation-state: The rise of regional economies. New York: Simon and Schuster Inc. O’Rourke KH and Williamson JG (1999) Globalization and history. The evolution of a nineteen-century Atlantic economy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Ostry S (2002) The Uruguay Round North-South grand bargain: Implications for future negotiations. In. Kennedy DLM and Southwick JD (eds) The political economy of international trade law. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 285–300. Polányi K (1944) The great transformation. New York: Rinehart. Reich RB (1991) The work of nations: Preparing ourselves for 21st century capitalism. New York: Knopf Doubleday Publishing Group. 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 149 149 Ricardo D (1815) An essay on the influence of a low price of corn on the profits of stock. John Murray: London. Rogowski R (1990) Commerce and coalitions: How trade affects domestic political alignments. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Rostow W (1960) The stages of economic growth: A non-communist manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ruggie JG (ed.) (1982) International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization 36(2): 379–415. Salvatore D (2007) International economics. Hoboken: John Wiley & Son. Samuelson PA (1995) The past and the future of international trade theory. In: Levinsohn J, Deardorff AV and Stern RM (eds) New directions in trade theory. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press, pp. 17–22. Singer HW (1964) International development: Growth and change. New York: McGraw-Hill. Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: W Strahan and T Cadell. Stiglitz J (2002) Globalization and its discontents. New York: Norton. Strange S (1985) Protectionism and world politics. International Organization 39(2): 233–59. Szentes T (2003) World economics 2. Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó. Tracy JD (1990) The rise of merchant empires. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. UNDP (2011) Towards human resilience. New York: UN. Wade RH (2003) What strategies are viable for developing countries today? The World Trade Organization and the shrinking of ‘development space’. Review of International Political Economy 10(4): 621–44. Wallerstein I (1974) The modern world system: Capitalist agriculture and the origins of the European world economy in the 16th century. New York: Academic Press. Wallerstein I (1980) The modern world system II: Mercantilism and the consolidation of the European world economy, 1600–1750. New York: Academic Press. Wallerstein I (1983) Historical capitalism with capitalist civilization. London Verso. Wallerstein I (2005) After developmentalism, and globalization, what?’ Social Forces 83(3): 1263–78. Walter A and Sen G (2009) Analyzing the global political economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 2/26/2014 11:30:49 AM 150 THE SAGE HANDBOOK OF GLOBALIZATION Williamson J (1994) The political economy of policy reform. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Winham GR (2008) The evolution of the global trade regime. In: Ravenhill J (ed.) Global political economy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp.137–71. 09_Steger et al_Ch-09.indd 150 Wolf M (2004) Why globalization works. New Haven: Yale University Press. World Bank (2002) Globalization, growth and poverty. Washington, DC. WTO (2012) The GATT years: From Havana to Marrakesh (http://www.wto.org/English/thewto_e/whatis_e/ tif_e/fact4_e.htm). 2/26/2014 11:30:49 AM