Manias and Mimesis Applying René Girard’s mimetic theory to financial bubbles Tobias Huber huber.tobias.a@gmail.com Byrne Hobart bhobart@gmail.com October 11, 2019 ”I can calculate the motion of heavenly bodies, but not the madness of people.” Isaac Newton Abstract: While next-generation models in quantitative finance have illuminated the origins of market bubbles and crashes by incorporating herding and imitation behavior, the underlying cause of imitation in financial markets remains elusive. Given that imitation is at the core of bubbles, we need a deeper understanding of the phenomenon. In this paper, we apply René Girard’s mimetic theory in a series of case studies of historical speculative manias, from the 1840s railway mania to the ICO boom and collapse, and even to present-day mimesis-driven market distortions. 1 Introduction Bubbles shouldn’t exist. They represent anomalies that are irreconcilable with deeply enshrined beliefs in market efficiency and rationality. Yet, from tulips and dotcom stocks to Beanie Babies1 and Bitcoin2 , they are recurrent phenomena (see Kindelberger 2005). As bubbles and busts occur with increasing frequency and intensity, some more heterodox approaches in empirical finance started to incorporate the ingredients, such as herding behavior or positive feedback, which give rise to the infamous “madness of crowds” and “popular delusions” (see Spyrou 2013). Agent-based-models simulate, for example, how macro trends emerge from traders crowding into the same strategies (often modeled as a competition between “fundamental” investors and so-called “noise” traders). Herding-behavior is also embedded in a popular bubble/crash-detection model 1 2 See Bissonnette 2015 See Wheatley et al. 2019 1 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 in quantitative finance to identify unsustainable market regimes.3 But what’s the source of FOMO—this fleeting feeling that moves entire markets? While some of these next-generation models in quantitative finance have illuminated the origins of market crashes, the nature of the imitation still remains elusive. Now, given that imitation is at the core of bubbles, we need a deeper understanding of the “irrational exuberance” fuelling speculative manias. For this, we need to transcend the physics of finance and turn to the metaphysics of markets. 2 Mimesis and Bubbles: A Girardian View on Markets One highly-valuable and theoretically-powerful model of imitative contagion, which infects all domains of human existence, is found in the work of René Girard.4 In his theory of imitation, which spans religion, culture, art, philosophy, and anthropology, the source of violence and its social diffusion are explained by the theory of mimetic desire. One of Girard’s core insights—validated, for example, by the rise of countless Instagram influencers—is that our desire is mediated by the desire of others. Now, the concrete conceptual structure of mimetic desire is laid out in his 1972 book Violence and the Sacred. According to Girard, mimesis, which he analytically separates from imitation, is deeply antagonistic in nature—it operates as the engine of social rivalry and conflict. While imitation, on Girard’s model, refers to the positive effects of copying someone else’s behavior, mimetic desire—which desires the other’s desire—opens up a deeply violent dimension. Mimetic desire is contagious. As Girard shows, it accumulates under the social surface until the mimetic tension is violently discharged in a “sacrificial event.” As the mimetic rivalry intensifies, which is driven by constant social imitation, it threatens to erupt in violence. In ancient religions, this violence is collectively released through the sacrificial scapegoating of a victim, who is expelled by the community. After the sacrificial event, the sacred victim—which later, often, gets persevered in myth—eases the mimetic tensions and reconciles the threat of eternal violence. Girard argues that this communal sacrifice, an act of all-against-one violence meant to prevent all-against-all violence, is the origin of the sacred. Violent religious sacrifice, or other ritual practices, are needed so that violence can be constrained. In other words, the sacred, around which Girardian mimetic theory is organized, represents a social mechanism through which violence is “self-exteriorized.” The sacred—which is culturally encoded in social rules, systems of prohibitions and obligations, and religious rituals—channels the socially subversive and destabilizing violent forces, so that violence can more efficiently be contained. (See Figure 1). 3 In the so-called Log-Periodic Power Law Singularity model, imitation behavior generates competing positive feedback loops of high-return expectations and negative feedback spirals of bearish sentiment that express themselves in super-exponential price-growth, which, in turn, indicate the statistical existence of a bubble (see Sornette and Cauwels 2015). 4 Despite Peter Thiel‘s effort to popularize Girard’s theory by translating mimetic desire into economic competition, he still remains one of the most underrated thinkers of the 20th century. 2 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 1: The mimetic cycle So, if you belong to an archaic religious cult, the scapegoating is rather straightforward; you could simply sacrifice an animal or human to a God. Since time immemorial, God, or some other externalized authority acted as the universal regulator of social behavior. What do you do in a modern, desacralized society? The modern assumption is that we’ve moved past the old rituals, but Girardians view it as a regression: instead of obviating the need for ritual, we’ve recreated the primitive, ad hoc practice of scapegoating from which these rituals evolved. The frenetic build-up of bubbles and their violent collapse provides some of the purest examples of the mimetic process—they crystallize fear, hope, hype, overconfidence, or under-confidence. Markets perform a similar function to religions in another more literal sense: the translation of future cash flows into a present asset price is just another way of reconciling the demands of the eternal future to the here-and-now. In other words, markets—these sublime machines that synthesize beliefs and aggregate them into prices—instantiate a secularized version of the sacred. Desire and imitation spread through markets like a contagion. Amplified by highfrequency systems and momentum-driven trading strategies, the extreme reflexivity endemic in markets accelerates the inflation of bubbles. It also makes them excitable to the smallest of disturbances that can cascade into drawdowns, dislocations, or even abysmal crashes. It is this tendency of channeling our mimetic desires and violently discharging the accumulating mimetic tension that our hyper-globalized and interconnected markets share with ancient and more archaic sacrificial systems. Instead of some ritualistic sacrifice, you get catastrophic busts. Instead of expelling a victim from the community, you can scapegoat HFT algorithms or short-sellers. Financial markets are designed to be impersonal, but they still indulge in ritual: just think of IPOs and lockups. The IPO-process involves gathering a bunch of people in a very traditional, temple-like building, and having them ring a special bell and at a specified time. The ritual is purely symbolic—whether you fat-finger the bell early or late, the NYSE opens at 9:30:00:0000. Later, the lockup represents another sort of ritual: you’re richer than you’ve ever 3 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 2: Triangular desire been, but you can’t convert your wealth into consumption until a suitable time has passed. It’s the modern world’s answer to a medieval squire spending the day before his knighting in a state of fasting and prayer. (And indeed, many founders and early employees spend the six months after IPO praying that nothing major goes wrong.) In Lyft’s case, the scapegoating process has already started after shares crashed post-IPO.5 Girard speaks frequently of “triangular desire” (see Figure 2). A love triangle looks like a literary device—A and B both want C, which they can’t have, and this sets up dramatic tension to give the writer a better story. But to Girard, the love triangle is not an attempt to make a story more literary but to make it more realistic. All of our desires are mediated by the desires of others: C is irrelevant, A’s model of B and B’s model of A are the real locus of desire. In markets, triangular desire can work in two directions: on the behavior of speculators and the behavior of entrepreneurs. A speculator wants to be the person who bought Amazon at the IPO; the entrepreneur wants to be the person who took Facebook public at a twelve-digit market capitalization. Speculators can trivially emulate their mimetic models through leverage, i.e. through believing what the model believes, only more so. If you’re competing with someone who put 100% of their money into Bitcoin, you’ll never catch up if you make the same trade. But if you borrow to put 200% of your money into Bitcoin, you will—at least so long as your mimetic model was worth copying but was insufficiently certain of their own correctness. An entrepreneur must go to greater lengths to copy their model: they actually need to found a company. But it’s possible, and as bubbles advance we tend to see more companies following the exact template of exemplary predecessors. In the 80s, Microsoft’s 5 https://cnb.cx/2CXvVvp 4 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 benefits were legendary: stock options, free food, even free soda. In the 90s, Internet companies compulsively topped one another with better fringe benefits, wilder parties, and more generous options. Of course, these companies didn’t compete to be as revolutionary as Microsoft had been at the same stage of its corporate existence. That’s hard to do—and hard for outside investors to notice. During bubbles, companies find it easier to replicate the surface attributes and let pattern-matching do the rest. One of the constraints Girard sees on runaway mimetic desire is social stratification. Don Quixote is a story about triangular desire mediated by a literary character: Don Quixote himself wants to emulate the knight Amadis of Gaul, “the only, the first, the unique, the master and lord of all those who existed in the world. . . ” Sancho Panza can copy Don Quixote’s desires, but only in a limited sense: much of what Quixote pursues is off limits to Sancho, and Sancho’s desires—food, money—are beneath Quixote’s notice. When Girard cites later works, like Dostoyevsky, Stendhal, and Proust, this social structure has broken down: The frivolous and seductive nobleman of the Louis XV era has been replaced by the scowling and morose gentleman of the Restoration. This depressing character lives on his property, he works hard, goes to bed early, and worst of all, even manages to economize. What is the significance of such austere morals? Is it really a return to the ”ancestral virtues”? This is what we are told constantly in the bien-pensant journals but there is no need to believe it. This gloomy, sour-tempered, and totally negative kind of wisdom is typically bourgeois. The aristocracy is trying to prove to the Others that it has ”earned” its privileges; that is why it borrows its code of ethics from the class which is competing for those same privileges. Mediated by its bourgeois audience, the nobility copies the bourgeoisie without even realizing it. In Memoirs of a Tourist Stendhal remarks sardonically that the revolution has bequeathed to the French aristocracy the customs of democratic, protestant Geneva. The present is a bizarre parody of even this social compression. What do we make of an unshaven young man who wears ripped jeans and a freebie t-shirt, sleeps until noon, doesn’t shave, and spends all day alone on a computer? Maybe he’s unemployed, and sleeps on his friend’s couch; maybe he’s a tech billionaire. It could go either way. Even the maitre d ’s of San Francisco’s finest restaurants probably can’t tell 100% of the time. This dissolution of social barriers intensifies competition by increasing the number of viable competitors. When there are no general obstacles to achieving one’s dreams, the temptation is to attribute any failure to the agency of someone else. Now, is it not blasphemous to exploit Girard’s mimetic theory for insights into such profane things as markets? Is it a sin to use elegant mathematics to render the blood spatter in a video game more realistic? Was it wrong to sell the “Salvator Mundi” for half a billion dollars? There isn’t an obvious answer. Sometimes, pure science, art, and philosophy need to serve practical purposes—sometimes a measure of the significance of 5 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 a theory is how far afield it can be applied. A better understanding of financial markets is one of them. So, Girard’s mimetic theory provides a template to better understand the nature of speculative bubbles. In the following section, we will now turn to historical cases studies of financial bubbles to identify the mimetic dynamics driving them. While many of the bubbles that we analyze below resulted in spectacular crashes, the mimetic dynamic fueling them doesn’t have to lead to systemic instability, but is often a necessary component in the process of technological innovation. Bubbles incubated, as we will show below, many revolutionary technologies and radical ideas. From the Manhattan Project and Apollo Program to Moore’s Law and 90’s techno-Utopianism, the mimetic desires underlying these bubbles resulted often in self-reinforcing feedback loops that lead to excessive enthusiasm and commitment by true believers and early adopters, beyond what would be rationalized by standard-cost benefit analyses.6 Now, as the case studies below show, bubbles are fueled by a mimetic desire that copies the superficial features of the object of speculation, but fails to derive the underlying principle. A better understanding of the mimetic process diving bubbles can, thus, be highly profitable as it can give you an edge over superficial imitation, which fails to pattern-recognize the feature that makes the speculative object of mimetic desire singular. 3 Mimetic Bubbles: Some Case Studies Violence and the Sacred abounds with case studies, from the Iliad and Oedipus the King to the rituals of the Dinka and Lovedu tribes. Fortunately, the history of finance is roughly coextensive with all of history. The first things worth writing down were the terms of deals—in what is perhaps a metaphor for the destructive nature of non-market conflict, some of the oldest writing we have consists of cuneiform tablets recording the terms of loans and forward commodities contracts. These were written on clay, which could be reused, but when a city was razed the fires would bake the clay, writing the contract from random-access memory to permanent storage.7 Financial markets are particularly well-documented because the tradable nature of obligations means that the exact terms need to be set forth explicitly. While absolute information availability has of course increased since the days of cuneiform, legal and cultural norms still put finance ahead of other fields: no government agency, nonprofit, or religious organization has the equivalent of the 10-K/investor deck/quarterly earnings call combo that makes investing such an enjoyable hobby for people who like to spend literally all of their time reading. This informational bounty gives us numerous case studies, from the British Railway Bubble to the present—and, as we’ll argue, to an area of the market that will in the 6 See Huber 2017 The sack of Ebla in 2,300 BC is one of the rare times that auto-save successfully preserved important business documents following a sudden loss of power. Not that it did them any good. 7 6 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 future be regarded as an enormous bubble. 3.1 The British Railway Mania: All Aboard the Hype Train In terms of GDP invested, the British Railway Mania was one of the largest financial bubbles in history. At its peak in 1847, railway investment was a staggering 7% of GDP; the modern US equivalent would be an investment bubble that produced $1.4 trillion in capital expenditures in a single year. Investor expectations during the bubble were surprisingly quaint; the ambitious expected to earn somewhere in the neighborhood of 10% per year on their investment, with no growth. While this may strike contemporary observers as a modest return, it was well ahead of the 3% that investors could expect to receive from long-term government bonds, or the 4% they could expect to receive from loans to companies. Unlike more recent equity bubbles, the railway bubble was not predicated on endless growth—the expectation was that railway companies would pay out all of their income each year. The bubble of the late 1840s echoed a similar, albeit much more modest, investing boom in the 1830s. That bubble, like many since, was launched by a sort of capstone development as part of a long-term technological trend. Steam power had been used for over a century, primarily as a more efficient way to pump water out of flooded mines. The low marginal cost of energy inputs for these devices provided an indirect subsidy for rapid improvements in engine technology: since coal was cheap, and getting cheaper, it made sense to build newer and more powerful steam engines. By 1830, this allowed the Liverpool and Manchester Railway to offer intercity steam passenger service. The mechanism for creating new railways lent itself to rivalrous competition: a new company would raise a small sum of money from early investors, trading on the prestige of its backers and the expectation of high returns. The railway owners would petition parliament for permission to build their railroad. Having secured permission, they would call down more capital from their initial investors, and begin laying track. Since any given city pair could generally support a single connection, there was fierce competition to be the first to build a new railway. Since the initial investment merely paid for surveys and lobbying, it was capital-efficient. And since railways used prominent backers to persuade both investors and legislators to back their plans, founders would often compete to get local grandees on board. While the actual data tell a compelling story—£107m invested over a three-year period in which annual GDP averaged £588m, a 50% run-up in share prices in three years, followed by a greater than 60% decline over the next half-decade—the single best summary is a short story, How We Got Up the Glenmutchkin Railway and How We Got Out of It, by railway attorney William Atoun, which Andrew Odlyzko uses to illustrate the bubble in his paper, Collective hallucinations and inefficient markets: The British Railway Mania of the 1840s. Glenmutchkin tells the story of a pair of affable punters who decide to cash in on the railway mania by promoting a new railway venture between two obscure Scottish towns. They acquire aristocratic backers (a local drunk who styles himself a laird), raise funds from socially-responsible investors (a puritanical merchant who invests on the condition 7 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 that the railway not operate on Sundays), and rush their plans to parliament before a competitor can get the rights. Their goal is not merely wealth, but status: the narrator says “Work I abhorred with a detestation worthy of a scion of nobility.” Glenmutchin is thus a story of dual mimesis: a promoter copying the means of New Money to live within the means of Old Money. Notably, to a contemporary reader it would be unclear which venture in particular Aytoun was mocking, because all the failures followed the same pattern: they used the healthy returns of projects like the Liverpool and Manchester Railway to justify ambitious traffic plans for railways connecting smaller locales, and tended to raise less money than was actually needed to complete construction—high demand for labor and materials meant that the shoddy copies were more expensive to produce than the valuable originals. “These were the first glorious days of general speculation,“ says Glenmutchkin’s narrator, “Railroads were emerging from the hands of the greater into the fingers of the lesser capitalists.” Perhaps the most Girardian narrative of the Railway Bubble was the story of George Hudson, “The Railway King.” Hudson formed the York and North Midland Railway in 1835, and cobbled together a larger system through aggressive mergers. Hudson used dubious financial maneuvers—paying dividends out of capital before earning enough to justify them, borrowing for working capital—and during a depression in 1849, his companies were unable to meet their loan payments. Hudson fled to the Continent, and spent his last years dodging creditors and the law. To outside investors, Hudson embodied the optimism of the railway boom: he built and acquired railways with gusto, helped consolidate the industry, and improved cooperation across different railway companies. Once the bubble popped, Hudson remained a symbol, now of the malfeasance inherent in late-bubble financial machinations. Edward Chancellor describes Hudson as a “scapegoat for the failed speculations,” a single person who could be blamed for the collective madness of the British investing class (see: Chancellor 1999: 150-151). Hudson was hardly the only perpetrator, though. Throughout the industry, promoters underestimated costs and overestimated demand, leading to returns well below the 10% investors expected. Railway shares, which were expected to be a safe and steady investment, lost half their value in the years after the bubble. This illustrates a common dynamic in the bubbles we study: the presence of leverage (both financial and operating) allows operators to choose how much risk to take. The truest believers in the bubble narrative take the biggest risks, and to the extent that their thesis is correct, they reap corresponding rewards. A charismatic entrepreneur can raise more funds, but in doing so becomes synonymous with the story they tell about their investment. When the bubble bursts, the story is revealed as a lie, or at least an exaggeration—which turns the greatest promoter into the greatest liar. Another dynamic we see in bubbles is that bubbles make the world more legible. The political scientist James C. Scott uses the term “legibility” to describe how states impose uniform standards on people and locations in order to more effectively conscript and tax them. A bubble does this as well: before the railway bubble, travel was uncertain, and 8 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 3: British railway share performance, 1830-1850. Source: Andrew Odlyzko, Collective hallucinations and inefficient markets: The British Railway Mania of the 1840s humans moved at the same speed as letters. In a horse-drawn world, you might expect a guest to arrive at home, and know roughly what month they’d arrive. With the rise of railway timetables, it was possible to know, down to the minute, when they’d reach the station. Other bubbles re-map the world in other ways: the growth of global trade led Parliament to offer a bounty for accurate measurements of longitude; the demands of commerce literally added another dimension to the world’s coordinate plane. In a credit bubble, legibility means a better understanding of the world as it is— more certainty about which debtors are money-good and which are not, which forms of collateral have what sort of value. In an equity bubble, legibility means a better understanding of the world as it can be; some kinds of knowledge (who will be where, and exactly when) are available only if the technology of the railway, and the accompanying information technology and social technology, are invented, turned into products, and scaled up. The legibility-inducing nature of bubbles creates a rivalrous dynamic because it requires visionaries to have a specific view of the future, incompatible with the status quo. A railway is not merely an investment with an expected return; it’s also a slap in the face for older social norms. For someone who benefits from the status quo, the new technology forces a difficult decision: accept higher returns, but risk one’s social standing, or fight. As the bubble grows in scope, the contradiction becomes more visible, leading to a third common characteristic of bubbles: the bifurcation of viewpoints into totallypositive or totally-negative. A single railway that replaces mules with steam engines on a single route is not a social crisis; a bubble that sends a meaningful fraction of 9 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 the economy into one sector, that creates a new rich class of people and turns any town not affected by the bubble into a backwater—that forces people to take sides. As the bubble grows, the easy opportunities vanish, so new investment requires ever more extreme estimates of future returns—in other words, as the bubble grows, it becomes an increasingly pure bet on a revolution. This amplifies volatility at the peak, and makes a collapse more catastrophic. If there’s a bubble company whose valuation is 2x that of a comparable legacy company, a prudent legacy investor might be interested in buying into the bubble if prices drop a little. But if the bubble asset’s valuation is 10x that of a comparable legacy company, there is no natural buyer outside the bubble constituency. Pyramiding leverage can transmute bank loans from a generic bet on credit into a bet on the bubble, but equity valuations are driven by small differences of opinion among true believers. This combination of leverage and bifurcation ultimately produces a crashing denouement; a decline in equity prices or an increase in defaults suddenly reveals that there is no marginal buyer waiting in the wings, and prices plummet. The revolution can still happen—England still has railroads, and other bubbles have also reworked the geography and culture of other countries despite ultimately leading to poor returns. But the utopia envisioned by the most aggressive participants is never realized. 3.2 The 1920s: An Electrifying Boom The boom of the 1920s was unprecedented, as perhaps the first large bubble celebrating technology as such rather than a specific technological advance. The bubble combined novel technology with new financing forms: prior to the bubble, public equity markets primarily focused on railroads, with a few listed financial firms. Ever since, industrial companies, retailers, and other non-finance and non-transportation equities have predominated.8 In many ways, this bubble relied on the infrastructure—and legibility—introduced by prior bubbles. A consumer products company like RCA could only ship radios to a national market because railroads had made such a national market accessible. And stores could only offer these new goods on credit because the banking system had grown large and robust enough to support consumer credit. Telegraph networks had been bootstrapped by the demands of the railroad and financial system—most telegraph lines ran along railroads and were used to coordinate traffic, while the first international telegraph line was originally used to transmit exchange rates. (To this day, investors refer to the GBP/USD exchange rate as “the cable,” named after the first submarine cable between London and New York. At scales large and small, information asymmetry exerts a gravitational pull dragging wealthy places together through 8 There was a push-and-pull effect, here. On the push side, more non-railroad businesses scaled up starting in the 20s. On the pull side, the rise of passenger cars sapped passenger traffic. Due to a confluence of events—the Great Depression increasing government power, World War Two subsidizing the growth of motor vehicle factories, and postwar economic prosperity—car owners became a major political constituency, and as a result the interstate highway system finally crippled passenger rail in the US. 10 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 cultural exchange and communications. Even now, fashion trends—whether based on fabric or finance—move from Menlo Park to Manhattan faster than they move from Menlo Park to Sacramento.) The 20s bubble was built on many technological innovations, but the two key ones were internal combustion and electricity. Both led indirectly to the financial innovation of retained earnings. For a railroad, high retained earnings make little financial sense. Capital expenditures either occur continuously (replacing engines as they wear out, adding small branch lines) or in a large discrete burst (adding a new trunk route connecting two major cities). This led to a model in which a company would distribute essentially all of its retained earnings as a dividend each year, with an expected longterm growth rate of somewhere between zero (the naive model) and the growth rate in population in the areas served. For an industrial concern in a growth industry, distributing all earnings makes little financial sense, because growth is more continuous. Prior to the 1920s, electric utilities started retaining a large share of their earnings, and reinvesting the proceeds in additional capacity. A company that provided enough power to illuminate the rooms of the rich one year might try to serve the middle class over the next decade, and everyone some time after that. Meanwhile, the availability of electricity provided an implicit subsidy for manufacturers, and, later, domestic appliances. Electricity exerted a profound impact on manufacturing; it literally reshaped factories. Prior to electrification, factories were generally powered by a single line shaft, which distributed mechanical power to every part of the factory. Electrification allowed a more distributed approach—instead of a factory radiating out from a single power source, power could be distributed directly to machines. Prior to electrification, factories were generally multistory (decreasing the average physical distance to a single power source), while post-electrification factories are generally single-story buildings spread out over a wide area. This physical change in the constraints of manufacturing led to a change in the relationship between investors and companies—instead of investing in a single project of approximately fixed scale, shareholders owned a company that could continuously reinvest and incrementally expand. This was a sea change in how investors thought about company returns. The earlier paradigm was that shareholders were simply the most junior claimants on the returns of a set of fixed assets, like a railroad or factory. A company would return most of its profits as dividends, and expand by issuing more stock and bonds. Electrification enabled continuous, rather than discrete, reinvestment, meaning that the default plan for an industrial company was indefinite growth. As electricity usage scaled up, the relative advantages of electrification multiplied: at a large scale, an electrified factory could outproduce a comparable steam-powered one. At a smaller scale, a traditional factory that had excess capacity could face competition from a nimbler electrified competitor. More electrified factories subsidized more, and more efficient, power generation, which pushed down the cost per kilowatt-hour. This also provided an implicit subsidy for more efficient electrical equipment, further 11 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 accelerating the transition. (One can see a similar dynamic today in computing-heavy businesses, as cloud computation turns servers from capex to opex while relentlessly lowering their cost.) This leads to a meaningful change in the cause and magnitude of valuation changes. In a zero-growth model, the net present value of a security is just the present cash flows, discounted back at some rate that incorporates their variability. So an investor who tolerates an 8% return for a given stream of cash flows would value $1m in annual profits at $1m/0.08, or $12.5m. When a company can grow at a steady pace, the value of the cash flows can be approximately modeled as (cash flow minus capital expenditures for growth)/(discount rate - growth rate). So if the same company can reinvest half of its cash flow and expect to grow at 5% annually, its net present value is $500k/(8%-5%), or $16.7m. Crucially, as the growth rate approaches the discount rate, the price/earnings multiple (i.e. the inverse of the discount rate minus the growth rate—33.3x in the case of the growth company, 12.5x in the case of the static company), asymptotically approaches infinity. If investors believe the true long-term growth rate is 6%, the price/earnings multiple is 1(8% - 6%), or 50x. At 7% growth, 100x. At 8% growth or higher, the theoretical valuation is infinite. The body of theory behind these valuations was not actually developed until the 1930s. John Burr Williams published his Theory of Investment Value, which discusses the net present value model, in 1938. (Notably, Benjamin Graham, the “father of value investing,” also published his masterpiece, Security Analysis, in 1934, the midst of the Great Depression. A collapse in asset prices causes a lot of harm, but it does give the busy investor enough free time to sit down and invent a good theory about where all their money went.) While the theory didn’t quite exist yet, that theory merely formalized facts about investor behavior. Implicitly, investors were ordering valuations by growth rates—if company X traded at 10 times earnings, and Y grew faster than X, Y was worth some premium. The internal combustion engine as a technology didn’t exert the same kind of influence on companies’ approaches to shareholder returns, but it did enhance the trend: auto companies were voracious consumers of capital, and as Henry Ford realized, they paid well enough to expand their own market. GM could and did pay a dividend, but reinvested profits in continued growth—and more than doubled its annual production from 1925 to 1928 as a result. Mass media became a more important factor in the 1920s, first as a consequence of underlying technology changes and later as a force directly intertwined with the bubble. Increased urbanization grew the population that could subscribe to a daily newspaper, while the abundance of new consumer products gave newspapers something worth selling, and growth in consumer credit let them sell to buyers who could not, strictly speaking, afford it. The rise of mass media created a mimetic dynamic to market-price movements. It was widely understood by contemporary traders that the markets were manipulated, but to the average trader this implied an opportunity, not a risk: famous bulls and bears 12 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 would assemble pools to drive stocks up or down, publicizing them through rumors and newspapers. While a modern reader might associate RCA with a name like Sarnoff, an investor in the 1920s would be more likely to associate RCA with Mike Meehan, who organized multiple pools to manipulate the stock higher. Over the course of the 1920s, RCA advanced from a low of 1 12 in 1921 to a high of 114 34 in 1921, making investors who bought and held (and sold at the right time) rich. But the stock was quite volatile throughout this period, so an investor who timed the market well—who bought on margin before the Meehan Pool pushed the stock up another ten points, and sold before it drifted down—would have outperformed even this impressive growth. Early investor pools touted promising new developments at a company: new products, faster growth, or at least the promise of a higher dividend. Over time, though, the pool itself became a catalyst: as stocks became less connected to individual catalysts and more linked to the pool operators themselves. Rumors of the involvement of Meehan, or of Jesse Livermore, the most famous of the era’s speculators, could single-handedly move the stock. Leverage introduces a strong temptation towards mimetic behavior, because a levered investor compounds their net worth faster than an unlevered one, and given enough leverage and enough outperformance, a small investor can catch up to a wealthier one. In the 1920s, borrowing 50-60% of the value of a stock was considered conservative, and investors could borrow as much as 90% of their purchase value. Over a long enough time period, an investor who consistently borrowed 90% of their money and didn’t get wiped out could catch up to an unlevered investor in the same asset, no matter how large the initial gap. As in other bubbles, escalating asset price appreciation led to escalating mimesis. Traders started out following individual companies, noting their technology-driven growth. Over time, they followed fads rather than firms—after Lindberg’s flight across the Atlantic, aviation-related stocks popped, including Seaboard Air Lines, a railroad. And at the peak, they chased other investors. When a famous plunger like Mike Meehan was rumored to be buying RCA, the important detail was Meehan, not RCA. Individual investors were not the only market participants to recognize the power of leverage to magnify returns. Among the largest growth companies in the 1920s were electric utilities. The most iconic of the electric utility entrepreneurs was Samuel Insull. A British immigrant, Insull moved to the US in his early 20s to work as Thomas Edison’s assistant. When Edison refused to make him president of Edison Electric (the predecessor to today’s General Electric), Insull took control of Chicago Edison company in 1887, where he pioneered demand-based metered pricing and rapidly expanded his company. Over time, the Insull complex, renamed Commonwealth Edison, expanded through both internal reinvestment and aggressive acquisitions. At its peak, the company had assets of over $500m backed by $27m of equity through a pyramid of holding companies. Insull had the great misfortune of being featured on the cover of Time the month after the crash of 1929. When his subsidiaries had trouble rolling over debt, the liquidity 13 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 4: The Dow, from bubble to crash. Source: Macrotrends.net crisis quickly worked its way up the holding company structure, causing Commonwealth Edison to collapse. Insull was tried for fraud, and, though acquitted, died in poverty, with 84 cents in his pocket and $14 million in debt. The rise and collapse of his empire transformed Insull from man to symbol: he began his career as a sideman to the celebrity entrepreneur Edison, became a symbol of corporate success thanks to laudatory media coverage and his wide investor base, and eventually came to symbolize the excessive power of the plutocracy—when Franklin Roosevelt mentioned him in a speech, it was not alongside other executives. Roosevelt railed against “the Insull monstrosity,” condemning “the Ishmaels and the Insulls,” turning Insull himself from a mortal to a mythic figure.9 3.3 Conglomerates: The Best and the Brightest The 1960s saw the rise of a new corporate form, organized by a new kind of elite. American regulation saw a step-function change following the disastrous collapse in the 1930s (even today, the ‘34 Act and ‘40 Act are frequently cited; American securities regulation largely consists of riffs on New Dealers’ ideas). Large trusts collapsed under 9 FDR’s speech captures something important about the pace of technological change. To justify regulation of public utilities, he cites the four hundred-year-old English legal tradition of regulating ferry prices due to their essential and monopolistic nature. Insull’s reward for aggressive risk-taking was that, in a single generation, he helped make his industry so valuable it became too important for someone like him to be entrusted with it. 14 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 their own financial weight, while newly-invigorated antitrust laws made such companies untenable. At the same time, the business of business turned into an academic discipline. Equity investors, enticed by the market’s healthy returns in the 1950s and increasingly forgetful of the 1930s, flocked to the markets, investing both directly and through the new vehicle of mutual funds. Mutual funds were both a cause and a symptom of a general decline in economic inequality. While captains of industry through the 1920s had been wealthy and powerful, and speculators had aspired towards similar wealth and power, the decrease in inequality following the Depression, the New Deal, and the financially repressive war years made the middle class a larger factor in financial markets. And while many individuals purchased stocks for their own account, institutions became an increasingly important factor: total institutional ownership of US equities was under 5% in 1940, under 8% in 1950, but over 20% by the early 1970s. Stocks were increasingly owned by institutions, and the practice of business was, increasingly, institutionalized. In 1949, there were a total of around 3,000 MBAs. The 653 who graduated from Harvard that year were among history’s luckiest people; within 25 years, nearly half held the title Chairman, CEO, and COO—and, in a statistic that tells us a bit about inflation and a lot about income inequality, 20% of them were millionaires. The Depression and the Second World War had created a demographic pinch in business, and especially in finance. A weak economy presented few opportunities for promotion, and few opportunities to climb the ladder by switching jobs; the war also took young people out of the corporate rat-race for half a decade. This led to a boardroom population dominated by people whose careers had peaked in the 1920s and whose most formative experience was the 1930s. When younger investors finally started running major companies and serious money in the 1950s, it led to a massive change in corporate and investment strategy. The trend towards institutionalizing both the practice of business and the practice of investing, coupled with stricter antitrust enforcement, led to the creation of conglomerates. Aggressive antitrust enforcement meant that companies had difficulty acquiring direct competitors, suppliers, or customers, which limited the natural opportunities for growth through acquisition. However, there was ample institutional capital available to any company that could realistically promise steady growth. In response, company managers started acquiring businesses far removed from their core operations. At first, they could simply bottom-feed; there were many “leftover” companies that had survived the Depression and the war years, and were trading at cheap valuations. A conglomerate could take advantage of the valuation arbitrage, by offering its high-multiple shares for the low-multiple shares of acquirees. However, this led to a problem: over time, most of the small, forgotten public companies got snapped up by larger companies, or had their valuations buoyed by tenacious value investors. So the conglomerateurs turned to larger companies, which put them in conflict with the elites. Leasco is an instructive case. Leasco was founded by Saul Steinberg in 1961, when 15 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 he was 22 years old. Initially, the company took advantage of two simple arbitrages. First: IBM preferred to lease, rather than sell, computers, and depreciated their computers aggressively. By buying IBM computers, leasing them at slightly lower rates, but depreciating them much more slowly, Leasco could report higher profits, at least in an accounting sense. While Leasco’s profits near the end of a lease would be lower (either the hardware would be obsolete, or Leasco would be depreciating an asset that IBM would have already depreciated to zero), short-term profits would give Leasco access to capital, which it could use to grow its assets. As long as growth was high enough, most of Leasco’s assets would be young enough to report high profits. Second: Leasco benefited from a change in tax laws enacted in 1962, which gave companies a 7% tax credit on capital expenses. Both of these subsidized Leasco’s growth, but they also forced it to continue growing to maintain its valuation. By 1968, Leasco needed an alternative source of growth. They found one in conglomeratizing: Leasco made an unsolicited offer to buy Reliance Insurance, a 150-year-old company ten times Leasco’s size. Computer leasing and insurance offer minimal synergies (insurance might theoretically be a cheap source of capital for a leasing company, but state insurance regulators take a dim view of insurers using their float to juice the returns of related parties). However, Leasco could make a financial argument: their high valuation gave them immense buying power, while Reliance’s slow growth depressed its own valuation. The offer succeeded—although Reliance was able to negotiate a better price by, among other things, claiming that it was negotiating to sell itself to a different leasing company. A year later, Steinberg attempted to acquire the much larger Chemical Bank, in a deal that was scotched when Chemical called in favors with journalists and legislators to kill the offer. To Steinberg, the Wharton-educated outsider with an enormous bankroll provided by giddy investors, this was a simple commercial transaction. He had valuable stock, and was offering to exchange it for Chemical’s cheaper shares. To Chemical, the whole deal was anathema; a speculator and accounting con-artist who optimized his operations down to the decimal point but was not, in the end, producing any real value. Leasco had its ammunition: its stock had appreciated faster than any other member of the Fortune 500 over the previous five years. Chemical Bank had its own, though: its board included the chairman of AT&T, the finance chairman of U.S. Steel, the presidents of du Pont and IBM, a member of Texaco’s executive committee, and the former president of the NYSE. It was a veritable Who’s Who of the American business establishment (Leasco compiled their dossier on Chemical through the literal Who’s Who, which did not have a single Leasco board member listed.)10 Chemical also had some financial resources of its own, and hinted that Leasco’s ability to make a compelling offer was contingent on a high stock price. In the three weeks after the press started reporting on a possible Leasco offer for Chemical, Leasco’s stock dropped from $140 to under $100. 10 All this is from John Brooks’ entertaining history of the 60’s stock market, The Go-Go Years. 16 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Chemical also considered another option: mimicking Reliance. They looked into acquiring another insurance company, similar to Reliance, to create an antitrust obstacle to the acquisition. A large, staid company faced a threat from an outsider, and in addition to attacking directly they attempted to mold their business into the form of the outsider’s. As Girard says in Violence and the Sacred, “Both parties in this tragic dialogue have recourse to the same tactics, use the same weapons, and strive for the same goal: destruction of the adversary.” Leasco had grown by following the business blueprint of an earlier age: a single charismatic founder, high leverage, high-wire acquisitions, aggressive use of government subsidies and loose accounting standards. Chemical was the result of exactly the same sorts of behavior—generations earlier. When Steinberg used his Robber Baron-style tactics against an established company, whose directors largely hailed from Robber Barons’ creations, they fought back, and won. Leasco had done an end-run around the establishment, offering Big Blue’s hardware on terms Big Blue wasn’t interested in matching, but it eventually reached a size where the optimal move was to join rather than compete with the establishment. But establishments stay established through resistance to joiners, and Chemical played its role to perfection. In retrospect, we can see that Chemical’s defenses were both costly and pointless. Their aggressive manipulation of politicians, the media, and perhaps the stock market fended off one attacker, but Chemical was ultimately sold to another financial services conglomerate decades later. (That company, Chase, is now run by a CEO who had cut his teeth at an acquisitive financial-services conglomerate that pyramided up small acquisitions until it could acquire an insurance company, and then merged that insurance company—successfully—with a larger New York bank.) “The targets are individuals,” says Girard, but “it is the institutions that receive the blows.” After the deal fell apart, Steinberg—who had been profiled by Forbes the year before as the richest American under thirty in history—lamented that “I always knew there was an establishment—I just used to think I was a part of it.” Perhaps he was, and his non-membership was an illusion held by the Chemical board, or a trick they pulled on their defenders. All parties involved were rich, power-hungry, and willing to bend the rules to get what they wanted. As Girard quotes Stendhal saying, “The pettier the social difference, the more affectation it produces.” The Steinberg cycle—fighting the establishment, attempting to converge on it, and finally getting rejected by it—happened in parallel with James Ling’s Ling-Temco-Vought. Ling founded an electrical contracting company, which grew big enough to list its stock (but small enough that he distributed prospectuses at the Texas State Fair), and then cobbled together a collection of electronics-related companies and aerospace firms, before going further afield (meatpacking) and aiming for larger targets (Jones & Laughlin Steel). To investors, Ling looked like a financial wizard, able to juggle complex offerings, buybacks, spinoffs, and tracking stocks. The truth was more prosaic: Ling’s first few companies were high-growth electronics companies, which commanded high P/E ratios. He used his highly-valued stock to buy companies in slower-growing industries. If a 17 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 company earning $10m that trades at 20 times earnings uses stock to buy another company earning $10m that trades at 10 times earnings, the combined company has 50% more shares outstanding but twice the earnings—so earnings per share rise by 33%. This encouraged conglomerates to acquire ever-dowdier companies at ever-larger scale. Ling’s downfall was more straightforwardly due to excess risk-taking and high leverage. Unlike Steinberg, he didn’t have a confrontation with the moneyed upper-class— perhaps because, to Texans like Ling, the big rich were newly-rich enough that merely having a high net worth was sufficient, and perhaps because while Steinberg went after a local company, Ling’s biggest acquisition was Pittsburgh-based Jones & Laughlin. Ling was ultimately brought down by intense regulatory scrutiny. Although his company was wildly, perhaps pointlessly diversified, the justice department accused him of unspecified antitrust violations. The ensuing negative publicity prompted a boardroom coup. Years later, D Magazine would describe the directors’ motivation in ousting Ling thusly: “Ling would become a highly visible scapegoat to blame for the company’s problems.” When he was a highly-levered acquirer in a bull market, Ling was a genius who could do no wrong, who made the cover of Time in 1969. A few years later, when a weaker stock price crippled his acquisition campaign and revealed the shoddiness of LTV’s underlying businesses, it was Ling again who was synonymous with the fate of the entire company. In finance, well-funded outsiders eventually have enough access to capital and desire for growth that their only option is to merge, literally, with the establishment. Girard argues that Dionysian festivals that culminate in a brutal and personal sacrifice often begin with “the deliberate violation of established laws. . . the overall elimination of differences. Family and social hierarchies are temporarily suppressed or inverted; children no longer respect their parents, servants their masters, vassals their lords. . . for the duration of the festival unnatural acts and outrageous behavior are permitted, even encouraged.” Baby Boomers look back nostalgically at the 60s as a festival of Dionysian excess, which ended with a spate of horrifically violent acts—but the same Dionysian process of upending hierarchies, flattening distinctions, and ultimately scapegoating an individual also occurred at the corner of Wall and Broad. The Dyonisian process reached its endpoint in the 1980s, when the Maenads of private equity finally dismembered the last of the conglomerates. Private equity acquirers set M&A records buying conglomerates like Beatrice and RJR Nabisco, with the express purpose of selling off the pieces and turning them into more focused companies. 3.4 Mimesis Dot Com The dot-com bubble is worth considering in light of the 1960s electronics boom. In some ways, the 90s were the product of a multi-decade Kulturkampf as the long-hairand-sandals crowd wrested control of the computing industry from the buzz-cuts-and- 18 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 5: Conglomerates vs the S&P 500. Source: Conglomerate Boom 2.0: A Stable Platform? JHL Capital Group 19 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 button-down engineering establishment.11 The dot-com bubble was defined by mass mimesis, even down to the name. When Jeff Bezos called his company “Amazon.com,” it was a triumphantly nerdy decision, equivalent to Id Software naming themselves Doom.exe. Amazon chose the name to differentiate itself from companies that were less focused on the Internet. (The “Amazon” in the name was a deliberate choice, albeit a more prosaic one; the web was small enough at the time that many directories were alphabetical, and “Am-” was enough to put Amazon first.) In the late 90s, the mimetic bubble strategy was to consider the success of Amazon and start an online bookstore whose name ended in dot-com. barnesandnoble.com raised $450m in May of 1999. When Books-a-Million announced an updated website, it sent their stock from $3 to $47 in days (and then back to $10 in a few weeks). Neither was much of a business. But the correct move was to do something that was as daring in 1998 as selling books online was in 1994. Something like competing with Yahoo and Altavista in search. Looking back at Amazon, the Platonic form of the business was not “let’s sell books on the Internet.” It was something more like this: Internet use is growing rapidly, and the Internet provides a new layer between consumers and producers—it literally reshapes the supply chain, by allowing a store to have an infinite stock of products, to display real reviews, and to remember every customer and recommend new things they will enjoy. What industry is most amenable to being reshaped by this? It needs to be an industry where there are a variety of products, all of which can be identified by a single name that someone could type into a search bar. In addition, to have meaningful economics, it needs to be an industry where supply is fragmented. Finally, it must be an industry where the value-to-weight ratio makes it economical to ship products directly to people’s homes. What product fits all these desiderata? Books. So books are the first thing Amazon sold, but they’re not the thing Amazon existed to sell. From the beginning, Amazon’s plan was “Books, and . . . ’ Amazon’s thesis can be modernized in another way. They found a structured database: the listings of books available from wholesalers. They made a web front-end, and harvested the value of easier access, multiplied by the growth of the Internet population. Google did the same thing: they found a less structured database, consisting of the link graph.12 11 The counterculture fought this war on many fronts. It’s worth noting that LSD was invented by a research chemist working for a large, established Swiss chemical conglomerate, and popularized by, among others, the author of an elegiac novel about the destruction of the German elite in World War I; “magic mushrooms” first came to America’s attention when a J. P. Morgan Vice President wrote about them for Henry Luce’s Time. Psychedelic culture, like the computer, was invented by squares and appropriated by hippies. 12 You can think of the link graph as a structured database if you think of it as an enormous table made of the Cartesian product of all pages on the web, where every entry is True or False depending on whether a page links to another page or not. It’s very sparse, since there were 75m pages in Google at the time that it started, so there would be a 75m row by 75m table, the vast majority of whose entries were “False”. The PageRank algorithm simplifies this from something that would be impossible to store to something that could only be stored and processed by someone with access to the computing resources 20 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 6: The Nasdaq Composite, 1995-2003. Source: BigCharts.com Extracting this fundamental lesson might be called either a Platonic Mimesis or Principal Component Analysis Mimesis, depending on whether one’s background is in liberal arts or hard science. We’ll use the less clunky one. Platonic Mimesis means identifying the core thesis of Amazon, an idea so core it might not have been apparent to Bezos that this was what Amazon has accomplished, or to Larry and Sergei that it was what they had copied. By copying at a fundamental level, they differentiated at every visible level. Google is in a deep way a spiritual successor to Amazon. When Amazon was founded, the salient feature of the Internet was its incredible growth rate: Internet use was growing at a 2,300% annual pace in 1994. In 1999, this growth had created a problem: the growth rate in garbage far exceeded the growth rate in quality. Once again, the question was: how will the Internet reshape the supply chain? But in this case, it wasn’t the supply chain of physical goods, but the supply chain of knowledge. How do we learn what we need to know? There’s a Platonic symmetry between the backgrounds of Amazon’s and Google’s founders. Jeff Bezos worked at a hedge fund. Hedge funds have the rare distinction of being an industry defined entirely by compensation structure: whatever you do, if it involves public markets and you’re paid approximately 2% of assets and 20% of profits to do it, you work at a hedge fund. Google’s founders were, of course, grad students. Their job is meant to be as fully disconnected from financial considerations as possible—if what you’re paid has zero connection to either the resources you have stewardship over of—to pick a random example—Stanford University. 21 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 or how well you manage them, you’re probably an academic. The ideal life to a grad student is a life of study and research, culminating in tenure; after working their way up a hierarchy of work whose economic output is never measured, they reach their career peak—tenure, an indefinite exemption from thinking about the job market.13 So it makes sense that Bezos would start out by thinking of businesses that already existed, and ask how the Internet would change them. Half a decade later, Larry and Sergei built a company whose product was seen as a loss leader by everyone in the industry, and railed against ads as a corrupting influence. Google did eventually introduce ads, of course, and sold $116bn worth of them in 2018, making them the world’s single largest ad company.14 Amazon was born as a business plan, but turned into a collection of science projects; Google was born as a PhD thesis and, especially under the influence of CFO Ruth Porat, turned into an exceptionally well-run business worthy of countless B-school case studies. Google’s science projects are a line item on the P&L and fodder for puff pieces. At Amazon, a single weird science project, Jeff Bezos’ mandate that every part of Amazon should interface with every other part through APIs, led to AWS, which is the majority of the company’s market value. Superficially, then, the stories of Amazon and Google are in tension with one another. The hyper-commercial business, founded by a financier, making products available to the mass consumers versus the anti-commercial academic project making knowledge available to everyone. At a higher level of abstraction, both companies were the result of smart, driven people asking: what technological change is most misunderstood today, and how can we build an institution that fills the gap between what is now possible and what currently exists? Google was incorporated roughly half a decade after Amazon. And roughly half a decade after that, a young founder identified an even sparser graph that was also rapidly moving online and could be represented as an HTML front-end to a database. The result was Facebook. Even more so than other bubbles, the dot-com bubble was the triumph of legibility. 3.5 Searching for Another Satoshi: The ICO Bubble On January 8, 2009, the pseudonymous programmer Satoshi Nakamoto released, on an obscure cryptography mailing list, the white paper and software of bitcoin—“a new electronic cash system that’s fully peer-to-peer, with no trusted third party” (Nakamoto 2008). 13 Ironically, this monastic detachment from grubby commercial concerns is subsidized by college endowments, whose investments skew heavily to, wait for it, hedge funds. Further ironies abound. Bezos’ hedge fund was founded by a college professor, and mostly hired academics. And while Stanford is not technically a hedge fund, it did end up with a healthy stake in Google. 14 This is one of history’s most extreme ideological reversals. To find anything comparable, you have to look back to figures like Martin Luther, devout Catholic cleric who split the church in two, or Napoleon, who joined a movement opposed to monarchial overreach and wound up being a dictator. While this pattern is striking, it’s a pattern, not exactly an outlier: If you’re sufficiently committed to destroying some powerful institution, you eventually end up forming an even more powerful institution, and since that institution is subject to the same evolutionary pressures, it copies features of what it replaces. 22 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 What followed was one of the most intense bubbles in history. Over the past two years—in a series of speculative boom and busts—bitcoin’s price super-exponentially increased from zero to almost $20,000 at the peak of the so-called “crypto mania” in early 2018. Bitcoin’s rise spawned one of the purest mimetic bubbles—the ICO mania of 2017. Since it inception, thousands copies of Bitcoin—so-called altcoins—have been released in Initial Coin Offerings, or ICOs. While more than $20 billion have been raised through ICOs since 2017, most of the projects have already failed. Some, in fact, did not launch anything other than a plagiarized whitepaper and a working address to receive funds. The ICO-bubble was driven by the mimetic desire to copy Nakamato’s invention of Bitcoin. While they all published a white paper, they failed to replicate Bitcoin’s “immaculate conception.” On January 12, 2009, Nakamoto sent the first Bitcoin transaction to Hal Finney. When Nakamoto released his code and whitepaper—when Bitcoin’s price was $0—only an obscure group of early adopters, which consisted mainly of cryptographers, cypherpunks, and developers, was interested in Bitcoin. Bitcoin’s increasing price attracted new early technology adopters and ideologically motivated entrepreneurs and investors, which started to invest in the Bitcoin infrastructure. The gradual build-out of the Bitcoin infrastructure, the first rudimentary exchanges, for example, such as the infamous Japan-based Mt. Gox exchange, which allowed the conversion from fiat currency into Bitcoin, attracted early retail investors. The liquidity that these early speculators provided triggered an inflow of more capital and attention—this resulted in 2013 in the first bitcoin bubble in which bitcoin’s price peaked at $1,100. After the collapse of the bubble, which was followed by a two-year bear market, regulated exchanges, such as GDAX, and OTC brokers, such as Cumberland Mining, started to enter the market. The inflow of retail investors, deepening of liquidity, and the entrance of institutional investors gave in 2017 rise to the largest bitcoin bubble yet when the price spiked to almost $20,000. Bitcoin’s adoption can, thus, be characterized by a fractally repeating, exponentially increasing series of bubbles. It is this sequences of speculative bubbles that bootstrapped a new form of digital money, which had zero value, to a network that, at the peak of the last bubble, was valued at more than $320 billion. These bubbles represent unsustainable accelerating phases of price corrections and rebounds, which are driven by self-reinforcing feedback loops of herding behavior and FOMO. Each bitcoin hype-cycle and speculative bubble intensified the mimetic desire to buy bitcoin. As bitcoin’s price spirals upward, more and more investors are drawn into the bubble by their desire not to miss out on another price increase. While Bitcoin—the protocol and protocol-native cryptocurrency—has properties that renders them clearly superior to other cryptocurrencies or assets, the bitcoin bubbles are mimetic phenomena. It seems that Nakamoto was aware of the mimetic dynamics that drive speculative bubbles. In a forum post on the P2P Foundation website, dated February 18, 2009, he described the mimcetic feedback loop embedded in Bitcoin: “As the number of users grows, the value per coin increases. It has the potential for a positive feedback loop; as users increase, the value goes up, which could attract more users to take advantage of 23 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 the increasing value.” In some sense, Nakamoto seems also to have been aware of the Girardian mimetic conflict, which, ultimately, results in scapegoating. On December 12, 2010, Nakamoto published the last message on BitcoinTalk, when bitcoin was $0.20, and then, after a few email exchanges, disappeared. While he mined an estimated 700,000 bitcoin—which are currently worth around $8.2 billion—he never sold a single bitcoin. He seemed to have sacrificed everything to Bitcoin and completely disappeared. Through his pseudonymity and disappearance, he most likely avoided the scapegoating that would have occurred were his identity known. Satoshi is a unique figure in a Girardian sense. So little is known about him that it’s effectively impossible to compete with him. You can’t be Satoshi-but-more-charismatic, because nobody knows for sure that they’ve met him. You can’t be Satoshi-but-moreparanoid, because he still hasn’t been firmly identified. You can’t be Satoshi-but-moreforward-thinking, unless you start now and develop something that’s a bigger deal than Bitcoin ten years from now, without getting caught. And all of this means that Bitcoin is a perfect focal point for a sustained bubble. Essentially Satoshi has done in life what Romulus did in legend; transform from a human being into an abstract and untouchable symbol of the institution he founded. While later ICO’s all superficially copied bitcoin, such as its code or published whitepapers, it is precisely this “immaculate conception” of bitcoin that all later ICO failed to replicate. Bitcoin—its pseudonymous creator and launch on an obscure mailing list, its technology and incentive design—represent a singular event that cannot be repeated or copied. The altcoin bubble recalls other historical bubbles. In the 1840s, railroad promoters would claim that various members of the English nobility had invested in their enterprises, whether or not this was strictly true. In 2017, it was de rigueur for new crytpocurrency startups to claim that their advisors included famous cypherpunks and investors, even if these advisors were not involved or were—in the case of Hal Finney—deceased. Price appreciation attracts mimesis, and a crescendo of copies is often enough to halt price appreciation. With Bitcoin trading at just above half of its peak value, it’s both too late to call it a failure and too early to call it a success. But as the ICO bubble and collapse shows, there was more to Bitcoin than just a whitepaper, some source code, and a rabid fanbase. Bitcoin combined two features that no previous digital currency had matched and that no future one could: it was just good enough, and it was first. 3.6 The Factor Investing Bubble: Mimesis Made Manifest The peak of every bubble feels like the end of history: asset prices may be volatile (in the case of equity bubbles) or stable (in credit), but either way they only make sense in light of some step-function change in the way the world works.15 15 It’s useful to distinguish between equity and credit bubbles. While they both involve higher asset prices, the fundamental theses are generally reversed. An equity bubble is a bet that the future will be radically different, that the upside from new ventures is unbounded. A credit bubble is the inverse, a bet that the future will be like the past, only more so. In an equity bubble, since investors are extrapolating 24 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 7: Total Cryptocurrency Market Capitalization, 2016-2019. Source: CoinMarketCap.com What, then, should we make of factor investing? Does it imply that the history of discretionary investing has an unknown start date but a definite end point? In his Advances in Financial Machine Learning, Marcos Lopez de Prado says: Discretionary portfolio managers (PMs) make investment decisions that do not follow a particular theory or rationale (if there were one, they would be systematic PMs). They consume raw news and analyses, but mostly rely on their judgment or intuition. They may rationalize those decisions based on some story, but there is always a story for every decision. Because nobody fully understands the logic behind their bets, investment firms ask them to work independently from one another, in silos, to ensure diversification. If you have ever attended a meeting of discretionary PMs, you probably noticed how long and aimless they can be. Each attendee seems obsessed about one particular piece of anecdotal information, and giant argumentative leaps are made without fact-based, empirical evidence. While this is more than a little rude—he probably won’t get invited to any more meetings with discretionary PMs—there’s a grain of truth. Quantitative investors do come up with theories, and these theories can be empirically verified. Or rather, they can collect data, and out-of-sample data can match a theory or refute it. In a sense, the discretionary investor has one theory, a theory so fundamental it’s left unstated: that changes in fundamentals drive changes in asset prices. A quant may have many observations—that momentum persists, that positive carry predicts higher returns, that small-caps outperform large-caps and that a price-to-book ratios mean revert over time. But in another sense, the quant has many theories but no underlying theory. After all, if there are reasons for these observations, the reasons can apply differently in different cases, i.e., they can be applied in a discretionary way. far into the uncertain future, volatility tends to be high—if you go from thinking the Internet will multiply the economy’s value tenfold to thinking it will double it, you’re still an optimist, but your price target just cratered by 80%. Credit positions only get more valuable as the consensus view of the future narrows, so they tend to involve lower volatility. This taxonomy is imperfect—it implies that stat arb is a credit bubble while new-issue junk bonds in the early 80s were an equity bubble—but it’s a good distinction to keep in mind. 25 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Price-to-book may be mean-reverting because investors overweight the saliency of changes in earnings. Or price-to-book may be mean-reverting because it reflects the fact that companies with low returns on equity tend to be more vulnerable to extreme downside moves. (Warren Buffett first invested in Berkshire-Hathaway when it was a textile manufacturer selling at below tangible book value. When the textile operations were liquidated in 1985, looms Berkshire had bought for $5,000 four years before were sold for $26 apiece, below the cost of removing them.) Momentum might work because it identifies cases where anchoring bias prevents investors from appreciating important news. Or it could work because it systematizes fear-of-missing-out, creating a sort of Faux MO that’s quicker than the real thing. Systematic investing matches Rene Girard’s description of snobbery in Proust: The snob is also an imitator. He slavishly copies the person whose birth, fortune, or stylishness he envies... The snob does not dare trust his own judgment, he desires only objects desired by others. That is why he is the slave of the fashionable. Discretionary investors tend to quantify their views, and many of them form their opinions through what we would consider quantitative processes today. Benjamin Graham data-mined his way to the conclusions in Security Analysis. Michael Milken originally touted high-yield bonds because an NBER study showed that low-rated bonds persistently outperformed investment-grade credits. Philip Fisher, the dean of the qualitative investment school, relentlessly quantified his own efforts (in his growth-investing opus, Common Stocks, Uncommon Profits, he notes that the average return from ideas pitched to him by other investors slightly exceeded his average return from ideas he found himself). So many of the great qualitative investors might be categorized as a discretionary layer on a quantitative signal. Conversely, there’s an underlying theory that explains quants’ behavior: by backtesting different signals, they’re implicitly reverse-engineering the thought processes of successful investors. This is not how they frame it, or how they think about it. If you pressed them, they would say that some signals produce value because investors are irrational—but every successful investor is necessarily the more rational counterparty to a given trade, so this is another way of saying that quants are copying what successful investors have done. In some cases, this is explicit: quantitative investors have produced factor analyses of various famous investors’ returns (Buffett, as it turns out, is long the low-vol and quality factors.) To the extent that a backtest observes a law of nature, one can describe a discretionary investor as an amateur quant for whom luck and a concentrated portfolio more than compensated for their primitive wetware computing setup. But to the extent that backtests reveal things that turned out to be true, a different suggestion presents itself: good investors identify good investments ex ante; quants determine what these investments had in common ex post.16 16 You can reinterpret Warren Buffett and Peter Lynch’s careers as a series of macro bets, primarily on the fact that the US would relatively de-industrialize, but continue to grow consumption, which would 26 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 The quantitative viewpoint is the financial equivalent of strict materialism; discretionary strategies imply some sort of transcendence. Sometimes this is in the sense that the idiosyncratic returns of a given asset can be meaningfully predicted. In other cases, discretionary investors are recapitulating Keynes’ critique of econometrics: that inferences from historical data assume a stationary distribution, but the motivations of economic actors are intrinsically nonstationary. As with strict materialism, it’s metaphysically unsound; the premises have to be assumed, but determining their validity is outside the scope of the system. Quants, in other words, engage in abstract and accidental mimesis. They mine historical data to find out what sorts of investments good investors would have made, and they build systems to automatically copy these abstracted, hypothetical investors. They’ve systematized the approach that retail investors used ad hoc when they discovered in the early 2000s that Peter Lynch filed the occasional 13G on a microcap stock. But, unlike these retail investors, the algorithms don’t read the Journal and see Lynch warning them not to ride his coattails.17 Since quants are mining data for signals that predict outperformance, there are three possible endgames: 1. We reach an equilibrium, where fundamental analysis produces some excess returns, and quants are able to harvest a portion of it; 2. As quantitative strategies get more nuanced, and incorporate more data, they become de facto fundamental strategies, driven less by backwards-looking models than by forward-looking interpretations of fundamentals; 3. They overshoot: instead of quants reading 100% of the signal represented by raw data, they read more signal than actually exists. In the short term, this leads to outperformance: higher asset allocation to quantitative strategies means the same trades are made in greater size. But in the long term, these trades push prices further and further out of equilibrium. Eventually, companies either issue or buy back stock to take advantage of these mispricings, which causes quantitative strategies to underperform, lose assets, and explosively unwind. There are many quantitative signals—you can count the big four (value, momentum, carry, short-volatility), or you can enumerate millions.18 But the single biggest quant signal is the invisible one: the idea that a basket of assets that share similar characteristics can be traded as a single unit. Quants who buy the highest-carry decile of the market, and short the lowest-carry decile, accept that they’re facing adverse selection. Some of the stocks they buy will cut their dividends, some of the ones they short will get taken private. But they can measure the average performance of the basket, and with sufficient diversification the individual lead to a larger financial sector and more returns for branded products. But Lynch and Buffett didn’t start with a macro thesis and then rush to implement it; the thesis is something you can extract from asking what ties their various trades together. 17 https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB109779511066146071 18 https://bloom.bg/2NUWbgz 27 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 deviations within the basket will largely net out. Short one stock that doubles, and you’re broke; short two hundred stocks, and the cost of a double is measured in basis points. In a multi-factor model, the return of a given security is the sum of risk free return plus the returns of various factors weighted by the security’s exposure to those factors, plus a random error represented by epsilon. The temptation is to use diversification to make this epsilon equivalent to its use in calculus, as a number so small it’s arbitrarily close to zero. Embedded in this practice is the single biggest signal every quant trades on: that the cost of active security selection exceeds the cost of adverse selection from poor security selection. This is the element of factor-based investing that can be subject to bubble dynamics. While it’s possible that active management was overpriced (and fee compression across the industry certainly lends credence to this thesis), it’s impossible to be overpriced at any price. Quantitative investors are not, in fact, the biggest bettors in this trade: quants represent around 20% of the $3 trillion hedge fund industry. According to Morningstar, passive strategies represented almost $4 trillion of US equities at year-end 2018. All of the investors in these strategies are crowded into a single trade: the betagainst-stock-selection trade. When these assets are a small share of the market, it’s irrelevant, just as a handful of individual investors replicating a major investor’s holdings won’t make a difference. But as money flows from active funds to passive funds, it produces a toxic dynamic: historically, active investors have outperformed before fees and underperformed after fees. This means that their underlying portfolios outperform the broader market, and the set of stocks under-owned by active investors underperform. If assets shift from active to passive, this requires a net purchase of stocks that are likely to underperform, and a net sale of stocks that are likely to outperform. If we imagine this as a factor—call it the “stocks pitched at idea dinners” factor—being long the factor was a tailwind to returns through most of history, and has become a large and growing headwind as passive funds have grown in importance. This means active investors face a painful dilemma: they can either mitigate their underperformance by cutting fees and hugging close to the index, or they can attempt to make their portfolios as un-market-like as possible. There are examples of both; some equity managers move into private company investing, or return outside money to run more concentrated portfolios with their own assets. But others try to keep up with the market by behaving as much like a passive fund as possible: zero cash allocation, approximately the same sector biases as their benchmark indices, with either a tilt towards or away from riskier companies depending on their near-term view of the market. Ultimately, the near-term result of this trend is a steepening of the power-law distribution of returns. The very best investors have an infinitely stupid but infinitely well-funded counterparty to trade against. Everyone else sees diminishing relative returns, and thus diminishing compensation. 28 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Figure 8: Total Value of Exchange-Traded Smart Beta Products. Source: Morningstar To most asset managers, the best risk-adjusted decision is to run a passive portfolio that charges like an active fund. But this leads to further problems down the road: as fees get compressed, managers lose the revenue necessary to support deep research, and they have less room to hire. This leads to a demographic pinch: the industry shrinks headcount slowly through attrition, but doesn’t acquire new talent. Just as in the period from the 1930s through the 1950s, we can expect the active management industry to slowly age, and to have an accordingly lower risk tolerance. To a passive investor or a quantitative investor, this looks like vindication. Systematic investors start with the assumption that active security selection is insufficiently rigorous, and see stock-pickers underperform. Passive investors believe that management fees are too high, and they see those fees drop. But the implicit mimesis of passive and systematic investing means that these investors are slavishly copying the exact people they’re mocking—more and more money is following investors less and less worthy of emulation. It’s the fate of passive and systematic investors to end up like Ted Haggard’s congregation listening to a sermon on the importance of family values, or Bernie Sanders supporters applauding a millionaire who rails against billionaires: faithfully absorbing a message from someone who no longer believes it. 29 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 4 A Mimetic Model of Bubbles: Catalyst, Differentiation, Bifurcation, Crisis, Resolution Every bubble begins with something real, which inspires entirely too much fakery. It begins with Da Vinci but gets dominated by Peter Paul Biros19 , because while genius is rare, the demand of the credulous will always be met by a healthy supply of fraud. In each of the case studies we’ve looked at, the bubble began with a fundamental change in the economy, often a profitable one. Railroads were efficient as a means of conveyance and a generator of dividends, as the 1830s boomlet showed. Electricity did in fact change the world, and lower dividend payouts did, too, by putting more power in the hands of entrepreneurs relative to financiers.20 The conglomerateurs were broadly right in 1960: American management was too old, too hidebound, unaware of better management practices, and generally under-levered. You wouldn’t be reading this if the dot-com bubble didn’t have something to it. In the case of Bitcoin, it’s too early to say for sure, but 99.9% of its price appreciation has occurred subsequent to the first Slashdot thread calling it a bubble in 2012. Factor-based investing has given investors a better way to think about performance and returns, albeit one that behaves differently once acted upon. The beginning of every bubble is a series of triumphs over skeptics. In fact, in most cases the peak of a bubble is a peak of absolute hype, while the start of a bubble is the peak of hype relative to reality. Forming a company is hard, and the more novel the company the harder it is. Broadly speaking, it’s a poor risk-adjusted decision, and requires some bad decision-making to get going. (Be suspicious of founders who seem mentally well-adjusted; they’re probably sociopathic mercenaries cynically riding a trend. Their startups are a good risk-adjusted bet, at least for them.) The cycle of a startup might look like this: 1. Someone has an obviously insane idea, like selling Basic to computer hobbyists in 1975 or selling books on the Internet in 1994. 2. They wildly oversell this idea to investors and early employees—it’s quite common for startups produce sales projections in their early stages, but rare for them to hit their initial numbers. 3. The combination of investor money and talent makes the idea a little less crazy, albeit still ambitious. 4. On the basis of this track record, the founder raises more money and recruits more talent. 5. Over time, either reality converges on these wild expectations, as the expectations get toned down and reality catches up—or exaggeration becomes the only possible 19 https://www.newyorker.com/magazine/2010/07/12/the-mark-of-a-masterpiece In countries where business is more reliant on debt than equity, and on bank loans rather than bonds, financiers have more power. And since they’re more concentrated, it’s easier for government to exercise power over them. When regulators are prudent, that can be a useful way to coordinate different parts of a complex supply chain, but when they’re corrupt, or incompetent but not corrupt, it’s a disaster. 20 30 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 way to keep the company alive, and founders ratchet up self- and other-deception until it reaches the breaking point. At each stage, the future looks both brighter and more certain—at least for true believers. Over time, this leads to bifurcation, both among companies and investors: companies can choose to “buy in,” as Barnes & Noble did with barnesandnoble.com, or as Chemical’s board did when they considered diversifying into insurance lest Saul Steinberg’s insurance company diversify them out of a job. Other companies turn their backs on the bubble—they don’t say “Not yet,” they just say “No.” In financial markets, this process leads to steady reinforcement of both theses. When Netflix was a small player in electronics, a Blockbuster investor could ignore them. As Netflix grew, the population of Blockbuster investors evaporatively cooled, as anyone who worried about Netflix sold out. Meanwhile, an investor interested in the “movie rentals” business could have looked at Netflix and Blockbuster as comparable companies in 2004; one a bit more expensive and faster-growing than the other, but both in roughly the same business. A few years later, this was untenable: there was no chance that a Blockbuster investor would switch to Netflix if Netflix dropped 20% on poor earnings; to own Blockbuster was to think that Netflix was overpriced by an order of magnitude. To the Blockbuster investor, owning Netflix is literally incomprehensible, and vice-versa. As Girard notes, quoting Proust: Of such a nature is hatred which compounds from the lives of our enemies a fiction which is wholly false. Instead of thinking of them as ordinary human beings knowing ordinary human happiness and occasionally exposed to the sorrows which afflict all mankind and ought to arouse in us a feeling of kindly sympathy, we attribute to them an attitude of arrogant self-satisfaction which pours oil upon the flames of our anger. For hatred transfigures individuals no less than does desire and like desire sets us thirsting for human blood. On the other hand since it can find satisfaction only in the destruction of the supposed self-satisfaction which so irritates us, we imagine that selfsatisfaction, see it, believe it to be in a perpetual process of disintegration. No more than love does hatred follow the dictates of reason, but goes through life with eyes fixed on an unconquerable hope. This places bubble investors and bubble skeptics in separate worlds. It also introduces artificial stability into the price of legacy companies and artificial volatility into the price of challengers. If no reasonable person could hold a view that would justify owning both the incumbent and the challenger, then there’s a smaller natural constituency of buyers when the challenger has a tough quarter. On the incumbent side, a nearly opposite dynamic holds: at a macro scale, their investors are betting on mean reversion; if Blockbuster loses share to Netflix one quarter, it’s not evidence to a Blockbuster owner that such share losses will accelerate—so they tend to buy the dip, in dip after dip. This bimodal investor population explains why growth companies tend to be more volatile as they peak in value, while value companies tend to drift along quietly until 31 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 they suddenly plummet to zero. These extreme price movements are not just caused by exogenous fundamental factors; they’re caused by investors’ recognition that they’re increasingly alone in their views. As Girard says, “A clear view of the inner workings indicates a crisis in the system; it is a sign of disintegration.” A clear-eyed view of the bubble cycle—an enterprise that starts out fabulously overhyped, and gradually grows into the hype—would lead to collapse, so participants rely on self-reinforcing collective delusions to maintain their esprit. Perhaps the best summary of this bifurcated view, in which a narrative of success necessarily describes the hubristic self-destruction of competitors, comes from Neal Stephenson’s Cryptonomicon, published in 1999 at the peak of the dotcom bubble. In Cryptonomicon, a newly-formed startup presents their business plan: Phase 1: After taking vows of celibacy and abstinence and foregoing all of our material possessions for homespun robes, we (viz. appended resumes) will move into a modest complex of scavenged refrigerator boxes in the central Gobi Desert, where real estate is so cheap that we are actually being paid to occupy it, thereby enhancing shareholder value even before we have actually done anything. On a daily ration consisting of a handful of uncooked rice and a ladleful of water, we will [begin to do stuff]. Phase 2, 3, 4, . . . , n - 1: We will [do more stuff, steadily enhancing shareholder value in the process] unless [the earth is struck by an asteroid a thousand miles in diameter, in which case certain assumptions will have to be readjusted; refer to Spreadsheets 397-413]. Phase n: before the ink on our Nobel Prize certificates is dry, we will confiscate the property of our competitors, including anyone foolish enough to have invested in their pathetic companies. We will sell all of these people into slavery. All proceeds will be redistributed among our shareholders, who will hardly notice, since Spreadsheet 265 demonstrates that, by this time, the company will be larger than the British Empire at its zenith. Stephenson is exaggerating. (Barely. The British Empire was roughly a quarter of world GDP in 1870, or around $130bn in 1990 international dollars, which is within spitting distance of the annual revenues of several major technology companies. The British Empire did not deliver the same levels of free cash flow conversion as a typical large software company.) Conveniently among investors, loyalty tends not to last past delisting. There may be a few Blockbuster partisans out there who still rail against Reed Hastings and all he represents, but for the most part, investors take their lumps and move on. A corporation is immortal so long as it’s either generating cash flow or on life support (whether from operations or from investors), but dies immediately when the support is withdrawn. Once it dies, its constituency naturally disperses, dramatically reducing the odds of cyclical rivalry. (There are cases of this, like Dodgeball’s founders building the competing Foursquare, Liberty Medical’s founder forming Liberator Medical with the same business model, and 32 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 some serial entrepreneurs are that way because they’re serial failures as operators but serial successes as fundraisers, but it’s very much the exception.) Financial bubbles are, in one sense, the most benign expression of mimesis. Money changes hands, but the world does tend to improve, either through over-investment in technology (in equity bubbles) or through a more detailed mapping of the status quo (in credit bubbles). If Lenin had been alive in 1997, he might have assaulted the capitalist establishment by launching an over-funded B2C play, writing his business plan in Starbucks rather than composing manifestos at Café Central. Cynicism, manipulativeness, narcissistic charisma, sociopathic risk tolerance—all of these can be channeled into merely wasteful behaviors rather than catastrophically destructive ones. Adjacent to financial bubbles are the technology bubbles that are funded by governments, rather than by private actors. Both the Manhattan Project and the Apollo Program were enormous technical risks requiring a single-digit percentage of GDP to be invested in an uncertain outcome. One result of these bubbles was coordination— building a tenth of the Apollo Program would have been a foolish investment for a private or public actor, but given a government commitment to completing the entire project, it made sense for individual participants to build out smaller components. The Apollo Program required advances in rocketry, communications, computation, and simulation; the project wouldn’t have been viable if any of these had failed, but the existence of the project provided the initial shove necessary to get the technological ball rolling. To take an extreme example, when Voyager was launched, it had the ability to encode extremely succinct messages. The technology to decode them did not exist, but the team believed (correctly) that this technology would be developed in time. A clear-eyed view of financial bubbles collapses their originality but reveals their internal structure. Crypto-currency promoters use the same strategies as railway entrepreneurs, passive investors apply the same logic as conglomerateurs, everyone assiduously seeks to be the most original-looking copy of a model they don’t fully understand. When we stand outside the bubble, we can see it as not merely a financial phenomenon, but a sociological and even literary one. Shakespeare, the Brothers Grimm, St. Paul, and Walt Disney all understood this: the best stories to tell are the ones that have been told over and over again, and the stories of competitive mimesis and of deification followed by scapegoating are the oldest and best of all. 5 References Bisonnette, Zac. The Great Beanie Baby Bubble: Mass Delusion and the Dark Side of Cute. Portfolio, 2016. Brooks, John. The Go-Go Years: The Drama and Crashing Finale of Wall Streets Bullish 60s. John Wiley & Sons, 1999. Chancellor, Edward. Devil Take the Hindmost: A History of Financial Speculation. Penguin Group, 1999. Girard, Réne. Violence and the Sacred. Continuum, 2005. 33 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465 Hobart, Byrne, “Good Bubble, Bad Bubble http://www.byrnehobart.com/blog/goodbubble-bad-bubble/,” 2010 Huber, Tobias A. “Bubbles As Innovation Accelerators https://medium.com/newco/innovativeexuberance-ad75ee39f4c,” 2017 Kindelberger, Charles P., and Robert Z. Aliber. Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crisis. Palgrave Macmillan, 2005. Odlyzko, Andrew. “Collective Hallucinations and Inefficient Markets: The British Railway Mania of the 1840s.” University of Minnesota, 2010. Nakamoto, Satoshi. ”Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System.” 2008. Sornette, Didier and Peter Cauwels. “Financial Bubbles: Mechanism, Diagnostic and State of the World. Review of Behavioral Economics. 2015; 2(3): 279–305. Spyrou, Spyros. ”Herding in Financial Markets: A Review of the Literature.” Review of Behavioral Finance. 5 (2): 175 - 194 , 2013. Stephenson, Neal. Cryptonomicon. Random House, 1999. Thiel, Peter A. and Blake Masters. Zero To One: Notes on Startups, or How to Build the Future. Broadway Business, 2014. Wheatley Spencer, Didier Sornette, Tobias Huber, Max Reppen and Robert Gantner. “Are Bitcoin bubbles predictable? Combining a generalized Metcalfe’s Law and the LogPeriodic Power Law Singularity model.” Royal Society Open Science. 2019. 6: 180538. 34 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3469465