bs_bs_banner Review of European Community & International Environmental Law RECIEL 23 (3) 2014. ISSN 2050-0386 DOI: 10.1111/reel.12090 Water Footprint Labelling and WTO Rules Laura Manson and Tracey Epps* A water footprint is a concept that measures the total volume of freshwater used to produce a product, measured over the full supply chain. This article discusses one idea that has been mooted to ameliorate impending freshwater shortages – namely to encourage consumers to purchase products with a low water footprint by using a water footprint label. A label may provide sufficient incentive for consumers, and governments may impose measures such as taxes or import restrictions based on the water footprint. The article explores the international trade law implications of such measures and finds that, as with other areas of environmental regulation, international trade liberalization and the protection of sustainable freshwater resources are not incompatible goals. However, water footprint labelling, and other associated measures, could have inadvertent trade law implications, meaning that it will be important for governments to give careful thought to their design and application. INTRODUCTION International trade in water takes place in various physical guises: in consumable form, either as bottled water, or in other water-based drinks; and in bulk. However, such physical transfers of water occur only on a very small scale.1 Of far greater practical significance is international trade in products with a substantial ‘virtual water’ content. The concept of ‘virtual water’ refers to the amount of water used in the production of a good or service, and trade in ‘virtual water’ has been identified as presenting significant opportunities to enhance water use efficiency, particularly in agriculture, and to address global and regional imbalances in water availability.2 As freshwater *Corresponding author: Tracy Epps. Email: tracey.epps@mfat.govt.nz. 1 This article will not attempt to discuss the trade that does occur, or the related complications, such as whether water can be considered a ‘good’ under international trade rules (e.g., there has been debate as to whether water constitutes a ‘good’ under the North America Free Trade Agreement and is therefore subject to the agreement’s prohibition on export restrictions, or similarly, whether water can be classified as a ‘good’ under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)); or the various instances of bulk water trade between countries (e.g., between Singapore and Malaysia, or – in at least one instance – between France and Spain). 2 The concept of ‘virtual water’ was conceived by Professor Tony Allan. See J.A. Allan, ‘Fortunately There are Substitutes for Water: scarcity becomes an increasingly pressing issue, a key question that arises in considering how to encourage trade and consumption of water-intensive products in the ‘right’ direction is one relating to transparency – namely, how do we know the virtual freshwater content of any given product? An intriguing option that has been mooted is to develop a water footprint label that would assist in facilitating sustainable water use by acting as a signal for the virtual water content of products. Such a label would form the basis for more well-informed consumer purchasing decisions, and also more well-informed governmental policy. Governments could implement water footprint labelling in an attempt to address freshwater scarcity through discouraging trade and consumption of goods with high virtual water content. They may also impose taxes and import restrictions based on the label (i.e., adopt ‘trade-related water measures’). This article will explore the international trade law implications of such measures. It first sets out further background in relation to freshwater scarcity, explaining why it is an issue of no less significance than, for instance, climate change. The article next considers the types of measures that governments might use to change consumer behaviour, before examining such measures in light of international trade rules. FRESHWATER SECURITY, ‘VIRTUAL WATER’ TRADE AND THE ‘WATER FOOTPRINT’ CONCEPT Freshwater security3 is one of the most pressing issues on today’s global agenda. A rapidly growing population, Otherwise Our Hydro-political Futures would be Impossible’, in: Overseas Development Administration (ed.), Priorities for Water Resources Allocation and Management (Overseas Development Administration, 1993), 13; J.A. Allan, ‘Overall Perspectives on Countries and Regions’, in: P. Rogers and P. Lydon (eds.), Water in the Arab World: Perspectives and Prognoses (Harvard University Press, 1994), 65. See also D. Waughray (ed.), Water Security: The WaterFood-Energy-Climate Nexus: The World Economic Forum Water Initiative (Island Press, 2011), at 69; and A. Gowlland Gualtieri, Legal Implications of Trade in ‘Real’ and ‘Virtual’ Water Resources (International Environmental Law Research Centre, 2008), found at: <http://www.ielrc.org/content/w0802.pdf>. 3 ‘Water security’ refers to the capacity of a population to sustainably provide adequate quantities of acceptable quality water for health, livelihoods and development. See D. Grey and C. Sadoff, ‘Sink or Swim? Water Security for Growth and Development’, 9:6 Water © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 329 LAURA MANSON AND TRACEY EPPS large-scale industrialization and urbanization, and the rapid development of technology are all factors placing increasing stress on the availability and quality of freshwater resources.4 In 2007, it was estimated that onethird of the world’s population lived in places that had periodic water shortages, and that this number is only expected to increase.5 In 2009, the United Nations Deputy Secretary-General warned that if current trends continued, two-thirds of the world’s population could face water shortages by 2025.6 Add to this the uncertain effects that climate change will have on freshwater availability, and it becomes clear why commentators are labelling this a looming global freshwater crisis.7 Freshwater is a local resource. It is confined to the boundaries of river basins and demands within a basin must be met with water available from that basin. For this reason, management of water resources has typically been dealt with at a local catchment or river basin level in accordance with the principle of subsidiarity, which requires water issues to be settled at the lowest community level possible.8 Due to its bulky nature, water cannot easily be moved or traded over long distances, and when it is – for example, through international trade in bottled water and other beverages, shipping of bulk water or inter-basin water transfers – the volume of water involved is relatively low on a global scale.9 However, what does occur on a huge scale, and what is contributing to freshwater increasingly being viewed as a global resource, is long-distance transfers of water in ‘virtual’ or ‘embedded’ form.10 This primarily occurs through international trade in goods. Policy (2007), 545; UN-Water Task Force on Water Security, ‘Water Security and the Global Water Agenda: A UN-Water Analytical Brief’ (UN-Water Task Force on Water Security, 2013), found at: <http:// www.unwater.org/downloads/watersecurity_analyticalbrief.pdf>, at vi. 4 See, generally, 2030 Water Resources Group, Charting Our Water Future: Economic Frameworks to Inform Decision-making (2030 Water Resources Group, 2009); C. Nellemann et al. (eds.), The Environmental Food Crisis: The Environment’s Role in Averting Future Food Crises: A UNEP Rapid Response Assessment (United Nations Environment Programme, 2009); and A. Agarwal et al., Integrated Water Resources Management (Global Water Partnership, 2000), found at: <http://www.gwp.org/Global/GWP-CACENA_Files/en/pdf/ tec04.pdf>. 5 See ‘Global Warming Forecasts – 2025’, found at: <http:// www.global-warming-forecasts.com/2025-climate-change-globalwarming-2025.php>. 6 ‘Majority of World Population Faces Water Shortages Unless Action Taken, Warns Migiro’, UN News Centre (5 February 2009). 7 M. Barlow and T. Clarke, Blue Gold: The Battle against Corporate Theft of the World’s Water (Earthscan, 2002), at xii. For discussion of the uncertain effects of climate change on freshwater and other aspects of the natural and human environment, see C. Field et al., (eds.), Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability – Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Cambridge University Press, 2014). 8 See A. Agarwal et al., n. 4 above, at 28. 9 A.Y. Hoekstra, The Water Footprint of Modern Consumer Society (Routledge, 2013), at 25–26. 10 Ibid., at 26. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 330 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 ‘Virtual’ or ‘embedded’ water does not refer to the volume of water actually contained in the good, but rather the amount of water used in its production. Transfers of ‘virtual water’ occur when water is consumed in one country to produce a good which is then traded into another country.11 When considering the effect of international transfers of ‘virtual water’ through trade in goods, it becomes apparent that ‘virtual water’ flows can dramatically impact the water availability in a country. For example, Hoekstra notes that: ‘Jordan imports about 5 to 7 billion m3 of virtual water per year, which is in sharp contrast with the 1 billion m3 of water withdrawn annually from domestic water sources.’12 More generally, water-scarce countries can address local water shortages by ‘virtually’ importing the water needed to meet demand. To illustrate, rather than using 1,300 litres of water to produce one kilogram of wheat domestically, a water-scarce country can ‘virtually’ import 1,300 litres of water by importing one kilogram of wheat.13 Through international trade, reductions in national water demand (and water savings) will be experienced in countries that import water-intensive goods (i.e., goods with a high virtual water content), and increases in national water demand (and water deficits) will be experienced in countries that export water-intensive goods. When this is examined in the context of traditional trade theory, it appears that international trade presents significant opportunities to increase the efficiency of global water use through countries specializing in the production of goods for which the opportunity costs of the water used to produce the good are relatively low. In fact, a study carried out in 2006 determined that international trade reduced global water use in agriculture by 5%.14 However, while international trade in ‘virtual water’ appears to present significant opportunities to reduce global water usage, it does not represent a complete solution to the issue of water sustainability.15 Perhaps 11 See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at 26. A.Y. Hoekstra, The Relation between International Trade and Freshwater Scarcity (World Trade Organization, 2010), at 1. 13 See <http://www.waterfootprint.org> for case studies and information on the water footprints of selected products and countries. 14 A.K. Chapagain, A.Y. Hoekstra and H.H.G. Savenije, ‘Water Saving through International Trade of Agricultural Products’, 10:3 Hydrology and Earth System Sciences (2006), 455. 15 See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 12 above, at 13–14. Hoekstra notes that the study did not differentiate between the use of green water (rainwater), blue water (ground and surface water) and grey water (water pollution). There is a significant difference between blue and green water savings because blue water resources are generally scarcer and have greater opportunity costs than green water (e.g., blue water is used for irrigation). Furthermore, Hoekstra recognizes, first, that importing products to alleviate water scarcity issues is limited by the need to generate sufficient foreign exchange from exports to afford the imports; second, that relying on imported goods carries the risk of moving away from food self-sufficiency; and third, that promoting imports can have negative impacts for the domestic agricultural sector, and may threaten the livelihoods of subsistence farmers. 12 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 the biggest limitation is that countries have historically been reluctant to create dependencies on others for vital resources.16 Related to ‘virtual water’ is the concept of a ‘water footprint’, which measures the total ‘volume of freshwater used to produce [a] product, measured over the full supply chain’.17 For example, it takes approximately 15,000 litres of water to produce 1 kilogram of beef, and 8,000 litres of water to produce a pair of jeans.18 It has been suggested that the water footprint concept can be used to inform consumers’ behaviour and drive change towards more sustainable water use.19 However, a precondition to encouraging trade and consumption in the ‘right’ direction is product transparency, and – as discussed in the next section – a water footprint label has been mooted as a device to help achieve this.20 One might ask why consumers would even care about the impacts a product has on freshwater resources, especially when the impacts are generally remote from the consumer. This can largely be answered by way of analogy with the problem of climate change. Twenty years ago, climate change was hardly on the radar of the general public. Now we have an international agreement aimed at reducing greenhouse gas emissions,21 many companies are analyzing and reporting their carbon footprints, and some products carry carbon labelling. Such initiatives result from the realization that global warming, like freshwater scarcity, threatens all humankind. However, there are also important differences between climate change and freshwater scarcity. Most significantly, unlike the offsetting of greenhouse gas emissions, freshwater shortages in a particular catchment cannot be offset by freshwater abundance in another catchment.22 This 16 There is a tendency for countries to prioritize their own food security over trade liberalization. This was seen in 2008, when volatility in global food prices led to over 40 countries implementing export bans to improve domestic food security. See ‘Soaring Food Prices Jeopardizing UN’s Ability to Feed the World’s Hungry’, UN News Centre (24 April 2008). 17 A.Y. Hoekstra et al., The Water Footprint Assessment Manual: Setting the Global Standard (Earthscan, 2011), at 2. The ‘water footprint’ concept was introduced by Hoekstra in 2002. See A.Y. Hoekstra (ed.), Virtual Water Trade: Proceedings of the International Expert Meeting on Virtual Water Trade, IHE Delft, The Netherlands, 12–13 December 2002 (Water Footprint Network, 2003), found at: <http://www.waterfootprint.org/Reports/Report12.pdf>. 18 See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at 3. 19 See generally ibid. 20 Ibid., at Chapter 13. 21 Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (Kyoto, 11 December 1997; in force 16 February 2005). 22 See generally A.E. Ercin and A.Y. Hoekstra, Carbon and Water Footprints: Concepts, Methodologies and Policy Responses (UNESCO, 2012), at 1. WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING may lead to a lack of interest in far-off freshwater shortages. However, this would be a very short-sighted perspective given the outlook that two-thirds of the world’s population will face water shortages by 2025. As freshwater scarcity increases, everyone will begin to feel pressure on their water resources as water-scarce nations call upon other nations for further exports, and eventually aid. No one can predict how this freshwater crisis will play out, but it is something with respect to which pressure is likely to be brought to bear on governments to take pre-emptive action. A water footprint label could be one form of such preemptive action. One possible twist on this situation is the possibility that some water-scarce developing countries may nevertheless want to continue to increase exports in order to promote economic growth, even where the products in question have a high water footprint. They may be able to do so without harm in the short to medium term, but the strategy would put their long-term water security at risk. One can imagine frictions arising if a developed country seeking to take a leading position on water management issues introduced a labelling requirement or other trade-related water measures that had a negative impact on developing countries’ exports.23 In such a scenario, or any other scenario where one country takes issue with another’s traderelated water measures, the legality of those measures may be resolved through the World Trade Organization’s dispute settlement mechanism. The likelihood of this happening will depend on a situation arising where a country finds the measures in question to be sufficiently serious to outlay the resources required to bring a complaint. Often, this will require that there be a sufficiently significant economic impact on the country’s commercial interests, but countries sometimes also bring cases in response to a systemic concern, even in the absence of strong commercial impacts, because they want to discourage other countries from implementing the same kinds of measures in the future. If a complaint was brought to the WTO, questions would inevitably arise as to how to balance the goals of trade liberalization and freshwater sustainability. It is therefore important to examine international trade law rules in determining how a water footprint label could best encourage trade and consumption in the ‘right’ direction. These rules will be discussed in detail below. 23 Note that there is no international legally binding agreement on sustainable freshwater use. See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at 182. There are, however, a large number of legally binding agreements in relation to water and water use. See, e.g., S.C. McCaffrey, ‘International Water Cooperation in the 21st Century: Recent Developments in the Law of International Watercourses’, 23:1 Review of European, Comparative and International Environmental Law (2014), 4. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 331 LAURA MANSON AND TRACEY EPPS CHANGING CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR: WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING IN PRACTICE A water footprint label has been proposed by Hoekstra as a potential mechanism to encourage trade and consumption in a direction that aligns with sustainable water use.24 The basic premise of a water footprint label is product transparency.25 Such a label would allow consumers to understand ‘how much they contribute to the water consumption, water pollution, and water scarcity in different places’,26 and would enable them to make informed decisions to discriminate between similar products based on the different impacts the products’ supply chains have on freshwater resources.27 A water footprint label could be as simple as a ‘yes or no’ label based on whether the product met a certain set of freshwater sustainability criteria. This would be akin to the ‘dolphin-friendly’ label at issue in the US-Tuna case.28 However, the label could also provide more detailed information on the product’s precise water footprint, and/or the impact of its production on water quality, regional water scarcity and ecosystems – that is, the sustainability of the product’s water footprint. The label itself could be physical, or digital, requiring consumers to scan a product code to obtain the information.29 In 2009, Raisio, a Finnish food company, was the first company to present a water footprint on a product. On a package of oat flakes, Raisio added a label showing that 101 litres of water were consumed per 100g of oat flakes.30 It also showed that of this consumption, 99.3% was from the cultivation of oats, 0.57% was from manufacturing and 0.16% was from packaging materials. The issue with presenting a water footprint label in this fashion is that it does not indicate whether the footprint is good or sustainable, especially given the absence of a benchmark water footprint for oat flakes. In Hoekstra’s words, this type of label ‘does not offer a basis for conscious product choice’.31 24 See See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at Chapter 13. Other organizations such as the Water Footprint Network and Sustain have also shown consideration of the idea. See <http://www.waterfootprint.org> and <http://www.sustainweb.org>. 25 Ibid. 26 Ibid., at 188. 27 See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 12 above, at 14. 28 See WTO AB 16 May 2012, United States – Measures Concerning the Importation, Marketing and Sale of Tuna and Tuna Products, WT/DS381/AB/R (‘US-Tuna II’). 29 See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at 197. 30 See <http://www.raisio.com>. See also A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at 197. 31 Ibid., at 198. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 332 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 One way in which the ‘Raisio’-type label might be adapted and improved for use by governments (which would then make it subject to the disciplines of international trade rules)32 would be to disaggregate the water footprint into the three different types of water consumed as follows: (i) Blue water footprint, showing consumption33 of surface and groundwater along a product’s supply chain;34 (ii) Green water footprint, showing consumption of rain water (to the extent that it does not become run-off) that occurs during the production of the good;35 and (iii) Grey water footprint, showing the freshwater pollution resulting from the good’s production.36 A label presenting these three different water footprints would be more effective in terms of achieving freshwater sustainability goals than one showing simply the aggregate water footprint, as it would allow consumers to take into account the relative values of the water consumed or polluted during production. Blue water is the most valuable type of water as it has the highest opportunity costs.37 It is conceivable that two products could have the same aggregate water footprint, but starkly different blue water footprints. Therefore, rather than a ‘Raisio’-type label that would result in consumers being indifferent between the two products, the goal of water sustainability could be enhanced by a disaggregated label which allowed consumers to discriminate against the product with a higher blue water footprint. So far, the two alternative labels discussed have only presented the quantity of water (or types of water) consumed and/or polluted during the good’s production. 32 Private standards are, in the great majority of cases and absent government direction or involvement, not subject to the disciplines of international trade agreements, including the rules in the WTO agreements. See T. Epps, ‘Demanding Perfection: Private Food Standards and the SPS Agreement’, in: M.K. Lewis and S. Frankel (eds.), International Economic Law and National Autonomy (Cambridge University Press, 2010), 73. For a discussion of water footprints as private standards, see P. Szwedo, ‘Water Footprint and the Law of WTO’, 47:6 Journal of World Trade (2013), 1259. 33 Here, ‘consumption’ refers to the ‘loss of water from the available ground-surface water body in a catchment area’ and ‘losses occur when water evaporates, returns to another catchment area or the sea or is incorporated into a product’. See A.Y. Hoekstra et al., n. 17 above, at 2. 34 Ibid., at 2. 35 Ibid. 36 ‘Grey water’ is defined as ‘the volume of freshwater that is required to assimilate the load of pollutants given natural background concentrations and existing ambient water quality standards’. Ibid., at 2. 37 A.K. Chapagain, A.Y. Hoekstra and H.H.G. Savenije, Saving Water through Global Trade (UNESCO-IHE, 2005), at 9. The authors point out that ‘green water is the productive use of rainfall in crop production, which, in general, has a lower opportunity cost compared to blue water use (i.e. irrigation)’. RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 The issue with this is that such labels fail to reveal other important information about the sustainability of the water footprint. This includes information such as where the water footprint is located, the impacts of the freshwater use on downstream users and ecosystems, and whether it contributes to freshwater scarcity or pollution in excess of allowable limits in that area.38 For example, a low water footprint could simply be the result of limited water availability in the area where the good was produced as opposed to efficient use of freshwater. Similarly, two products with the same grey water footprints might appear to have the same impact on freshwater resources. However, further information could reveal that the grey water footprint of one of the products occurred in an area where freshwater bodies were already polluted beyond acceptable limits. Consumers theoretically should care about this additional information because it is important to actual freshwater sustainability. Therefore, a third type of label that would better serve the goal of encouraging sustainable freshwater use would be one that incorporates both the quantitative water footprint and additional information about the sustainability of this water footprint. However, the issue with such a label is that presenting so much information would likely overwhelm and confuse consumers. A way to capture all of this information and present it in an accessible way to consumers would be with what Hoekstra refers to as a ‘water stewardship’ label.39 Of course, the full set of detailed information could be available by other means – for instance, online through scanning a QR code. A ‘water stewardship’ label would be an overall judgment of the performance of the product.40 It could be a simple ‘yes or no’ label, which in this case would be a ‘water stewardship’ stamp meaning the product was produced based on good water stewardship, or it could be a label that ranked the degree of water stewardship into one of several categories. The background information about the blue, green and grey water footprints of the product and the sustainability of the footprints based on where they occurred, and who or what they affected, would be taken into account in determining the appropriate label for the product. Hoekstra also suggests that as part of a ‘water stewardship’ label, we should consider the targets or plans by the producers to make future improvements to the water footprints of their products.41 Given the many different ways a water footprint label could be formulated, a key challenge that arises is developing a standardized methodology for the labelling, and in particular, for calculating the water footprint. In calculating a water footprint, an initial 38 See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 9 above, at Chapter 13. Ibid., at 197. 40 Ibid. 41 Ibid. 39 WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING question is: How far back along the supply chain one should go in the analysis? A general rule that has emerged in this field of study so far is to include the water footprint of all processes that ‘significantly contribute’ to the total water footprint.42 This then raises the question as to what is ‘significant’. Globalization has also led to the complication of many products being made up of components from several different locations with different freshwater circumstances. However, as long as sufficient accounting takes place throughout the supply chain, this complication is not impossible to overcome. In any case, Hoekstra has suggested that a water footprint label should first be introduced for relatively water-intensive products, such as agricultural commodities including rice, cotton, paper and cane sugar.43 These goods are produced in a unique location and their water footprint is much easier to calculate than goods made up of several components. Another issue that must be addressed is how often, and over which time period a water footprint should be calculated. Water availability fluctuates over time, and the time period selected could have a large effect on the water footprint of a product – for example, in a dry year, more irrigation is needed for crop growth thus leading to higher water footprints.44 Taking an average water footprint over a number of years might seem like a practical way to smooth out these fluctuations, but this discounts improvements in technology that have led to greater efficiency in water use in more recent years. We do not propose a solution to any of these issues; rather we seek to illustrate the difficulties inherent in even formulating a calculation methodology, let alone actually applying it in practice. In an attempt to address this challenge, the International Standards Organization (ISO) is currently developing ISO Standard 14046 with the stated purpose of providing decision makers in industry, government and nongovernmental organizations ‘with a means to estimate the potential impact of water use and pollution, based on a life-cycle assessment’.45 ISO 14046 is aiming to present a standardized framework and scientific basis for calculating and reporting water footprints. Because ISO standards are strictly voluntary, there is no guarantee that the standard would be taken up on a wide enough scale to achieve the consistency of approach desired. However, in mitigation of this is Article 2.4 of the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT Agreement), which directs WTO members to use ‘relevant international standards’ as a basis for technical regulations, where they are required, unless such standards would be ‘an 42 See A.Y. Hoekstra et al., n. 17 above, at 10. See A.Y. Hoekstra, n. 12 above, at 19. 44 See A.Y. Hoekstra et al., n. 17 above, at 13. 45 International Standardization Organization (ISO), ‘Measuring the Impact of Water Use and Promoting Efficiency in Water Management’, ISO 14046 Briefing Note, found at: <http://www.iso.org/iso/ iso14046_briefing_note.pdf>. 43 © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 333 LAURA MANSON AND TRACEY EPPS ineffective or inappropriate means for the fulfilment of the legitimate objectives pursued’.46 ISO Standards (and ISO 14046) would most likely constitute relevant international standards under Article 2.4,47 so on this basis reliance on ISO 14046 by WTO members in formulating their water-related technical regulations would be required by the TBT Agreement (unless a country could show that they would be ineffective or inappropriate). It is not at all clear that the ISO standard, if completed, will be widely relied upon. The exception for when standards are ineffective or inappropriate includes where ‘fundamental technological problems’ would inhibit the application of the standard.48 This would be most conceivable in the case of a developing country which might not have the technology to accurately calculate and report water footprints. Although reliance on ISO standards appears to be consistent with the TBT Agreement, we do note the explicit statement in the briefing note on ISO 14046 that the standard is not intended ‘to be adopted or applied in a manner that results in barriers to trade that conflict with WTO requirements’.49 This implies that reliance on an ISO standard in itself is not enough to comply with WTO requirements, and countries could still fall foul of international trade rules through the way in which they apply the standard. It remains unclear to what extent standards such as ISO 14046 would be adopted, and in the absence of an international agreement on water labelling, it may be virtually impossible to get all countries to adopt a common water footprint label. As a result, it is likely that we will see private and public entities formulating their own water footprint labels just like Raisio did in 2009, and perhaps even their own certification schemes. This would inevitably lead to confusion and scepticism of the credibility of certifications and labelling. It may also have trade law implications. In other contexts, such as carbon labelling, there are a variety of requirements, many of which are generated by the private sector – companies, retail organizations and nongovernmental organizations. The question as to what disciplines might be imposed on private standards is not one that we will address here, other than to note that without some form of governmental involvement such standards will not be covered by the WTO’s disciplines.50 Rather, we will focus here on the possibility of measures implemented by governments. 46 Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (Marrakesh, 15 April 1994; in force 1 January 1995) (‘TBT Agreement’). 47 F. Fontanelli, ‘ISO and Codex Standards and International Trade Law: What Gets Said is not What’s Heard’, 60:4 International and Comparative Law Quarterly (2011), 895, at 908. 48 TBT Agreement, n. 46 above, Article 2.4. 49 See ISO, n. 45 above. 50 See, e.g., T. Epps, n. 32 above, at 73; and P. Szwedo, n. 32 above. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 334 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 Ultimately, the success of any water footprint label (whether a government measure or a private initiative) in encouraging sustainable water use would depend upon its effectiveness in influencing consumer behaviour, which relies both on consumers’ understanding of the label and the value they attach to freshwater sustainability. With regard to consumers’ understanding of a water footprint label, a recent study on EU product labelling found that a common assumption by consumers was that the labels represented the environmental impact (or water usage) of the product while in use.51 The concept of a life-cycle assessment of a product’s environmental impact was not familiar. Therefore, any label would have to be carefully designed, and consumers well educated, for it to have its desired effect. With regard to the value consumers might attach to freshwater sustainability, the same study found that when all other product characteristics were held constant, consumers showed a higher willingness to pay, and a willingness to pay a premium for products that were environmentally preferable.52 However, in reality, products are rarely identical in all respects other than their environmental impact. This means that the success of water footprint labelling in influencing consumer purchase decisions may be limited, unless the water footprint label also affects the product’s price or availability. For example, governments could impose a sales-based tax on products with a high or undesirable water footprint, or impose import restrictions based on a product’s water footprint. The trade law implications of such measures will be examined in detail in the next section. IMPLICATIONS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE RULES FOR THE DESIGN AND IMPLEMENTATION OF WATER-RELATED TRADE MEASURES In this section, we highlight the key obligations in the WTO’s General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and the TBT Agreement that countries must observe if they adopt or maintain water-related trade measures. The GATT’s obligations apply generally in respect of trade in goods, while the TBT Agreement imposes differing obligations in respect of mandatory technical regulations, voluntary standards and conformity assessment procedures.53 Where a measure is not within scope of the TBT Agreement, the obligations of 51 Ipsos MORI, London Economics and AEA, Research on EU Product Label Options: Final Report (Ipsos MORI, 2012), at 7. 52 Ibid., at 5. 53 WTO AB 5 April 2001, European Communities – Measures Affecting Asbestos and Asbestos-containing Products, WT/DS135/AB/R (‘EC-Asbestos’), at paragraph 80. RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 the GATT will still be relevant.54 A trade-related water measure may or may not be within scope of the TBT Agreement, and thus obligations under both agreements are of relevance. Here we discuss the GATT obligations first, because one of the key elements of the non-discrimination obligations is also relevant under the TBT Agreement – namely, the determination of whether products are ‘like’. ‘Likeness’ has been extensively considered under the GATT and the case law will also inform determinations of ‘likeness’ under the TBT Agreement. THE GATT Non-discrimination The non-discrimination principle is the cornerstone of the GATT and is encapsulated in two obligations: national treatment and most-favoured-nation (MFN) treatment. The national treatment obligation (Article III) prohibits the application of measures (both regulatory and tax) to ‘imported or domestic products so as to afford protection to domestic production’.55 Paragraph 4 applies the national treatment obligation to domestic regulations, while paragraph 2 applies it to taxes. Article III.4 will apply to domestic regulations that are not technical regulations under the TBT Agreement, such as a requirement on retailers to only stock products with a water footprint below a certain level. Article III.4 requires WTO members to accord to imported products ‘treatment no less favourable than that accorded to like products of national origin in respect of all laws, regulations and requirements affecting their internal sale, offering for sale, purchase, transportation, distribution or use’. Only ‘like’ products must be accorded national treatment under Article III.4. In determining ‘likeness’, panels and the Appellate Body have taken a case-bycase approach using four criteria: (i) the products’ end uses in a given market; (ii) the products’ properties, nature and quality (including a requirement that the products should share the same physical characteris54 In a dispute where an allegation of a violation of the TBT Agreement is not found, or where a measure is found not to fall within that agreement’s scope, arguments under the GATT will come into play. For example, in the EC-Seal Products case, the Appellate Body found that the EU’s seals regime did not constitute a ‘technical regulation’ as defined in the TBT Agreement. However, it went on to find violations under the GATT, and to examine the applicability of that agreement’s exceptions under Article XX. WTO AB 22 May 2014, European Communities – Measures Prohibiting the Importation and Marketing of Seal Products, WT/DS401/AB/R (‘EC-Seal Products’). See also G. Marceau, ‘A Comment on the AB Report in EC – Seal Products in the Context of the Trade and Environment Debate’, 23:3 Review of European, Comparative and International Environmental Law (2014). 55 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994 (Marrakesh, 15 April 1994; in force 1 January 1995) (‘GATT’), Article III.1. WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING tics); (iii) consumers’ tastes and habits; and (iv) tariff classifications.56 A case-by-case examination of the facts is required, and the Appellate Body has noted that interpretation of ‘likeness’ involves ‘an unavoidable element of individual discretionary judgement’.57 An important factor in the ‘likeness’ determination is whether there is a competitive relationship between the domestic and imported products. In EC-Asbestos, the Appellate Body had to determine whether cement made with asbestos fibres was ‘like’ cement made with PCG (polyvinyl alcohol, cellulose and glass) fibres.58 While there was no evidence of a competitive relationship, the Appellate Body said that consumers might view these two cements differently if they understood the different health risks. Howse and Tuerk argue that the Appellate Body in effect adopted a test of whether the products would have been competitive in an idealized market in which consumers had complete information.59 We can ask whether two products with different impacts on water resources could be considered unlike each other. Hoekstra uses the example of a beverage such as cola which contains sugars that can come from various sources – sugar beet, sugar cane or maize. The sugar crop in question might be grown with irrigation water from the ‘overexploited Ogallala Aquifier beneath the Great Plains in the United States.60 Under the Article III.4 ‘likeness’ test, would cola with such sugar be ‘like’ cola containing sugar grown in a region with abundant water sources? He also gives the example of cotton from Uzbekistan and Pakistan, which has a relatively large water footprint on blue water resources and can be associated with the desiccation of the Aral Sea and intensive use and pollution of the Indus River, respectively, compared to cotton produced elsewhere without such deleterious effects.61 In neither case are the physical characteristics, end uses or tariff classifications of the products any different. In order for consumer preferences to play any role in differentiating the products, evidence would be required. Even if 56 The first three of these criteria were set out by the 1970 GATT Working Party Report on Border Tax Adjustments, BSID 18S/97, adopted on 2 December 1970, at paragraph 18. The Appellate Body in Japan-Alcoholic Beverages noted that the final criterion, tariff classification, had been referred to in several earlier cases. See WTO AB 1 November 1996, Japan – Taxes on Alcoholic Beverages, WT/DS8/ AB/R, WT/DS10/AB/R, WT/DS11/AB/R (‘Japan-Alcoholic Beverages’), at section H(1)(a). 57 Ibid. 58 EC-Asbestos, n. 53 above. 59 And where tort liability was available. See R. Howse and E. Tuerk, ‘The WTO Impact on Internal Regulations: A Case Study of the Canada-EC Asbestos Dispute’, in: G. De Burca and J. Scott (eds.), The EU and the WTO: Legal and Constitutional Issues (Hart, 2001), 283. 60 A.Y. Hoekstra, The Relation between International Trade and Freshwater Scarcity (World Trade Organization, 2010), at 14. 61 Ibid. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 335 LAURA MANSON AND TRACEY EPPS consumers in the importing country had complete information, they might still see the products as ‘like’. Would consumers in, say, the United Kingdom care enough about conditions in the Great Plains, the Aral Sea or the Indus River to consider the products ‘unlike’? Would consumers in one state of the United States even care about impacts on water resources in another state? It is not inconceivable, and the background discussed above suggests that things may well come to a point where consumers will care (and certainly should care). The point is that, under GATT rules, strong evidence would be required to find a case of unlikeness such that countries could differentiate between the products with impunity. It is important to note that in this type of ‘likeness’ determination, the difference between the products is the process and production method (PPM). There are two types of PPMs: those that are product-related, and those that are not. Product-related PPMs are those where the PPM actually results in an observable difference in the end product itself, such as an organic apple compared to a non-organic one with pesticide residues on it. On the other hand, a non-product related PPM – such as the amount of water used in production of beef – does not confer any particular observable characteristic on the end product. As suggested in the preceding paragraph, it is plausible that different non-product PPMs can make two products ‘unlike’ each other, but only if it can be shown that consumers actually differentiate between them.62 The trouble is that it may be the very lack of differentiation by consumers that leads a government to regulate in the first place.63 There will only be a violation of Article III.4 if imported products have been accorded ‘less favourable treatment’ than ‘like’ domestic products. This requires that there be ‘effective equality of opportunities for imported products to compete with like domestic products’64 and requires panels to ‘examine whether a measure modifies the conditions of competition in the relevant market to the detriment of imported products’.65 Even in the case of ‘like’ products, the GATT allows governments some room to treat products differently. This is because it is not enough to prove a violation to simply say that imported and domestic 62 The same point can be made in the context of differentiating between products based on the amount of carbon or other greenhouse gases emitted during their production. See T. Epps and A. Green, Reconciling Trade and Climate Change: How the WTO Can Help Address Climate Change (Edward Elgar, 2010), at 75. 63 G. Marceau and J. Trachtman, ‘The Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement, the Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures Agreement, and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade: A Map of the World Trade Organization Law of Domestic Regulation of Goods’, 36:5 Journal of World Trade (2002), 811. 64 EC-Seal Products, n. 54 above, at paragraph 5.101. 65 WTO AB 20 January 2001, Korea – Measures Affecting Imports of Fresh, Chilled and Frozen Beef, WT/DS161/AB/R, WT/DS169/AB/R (‘Korea-Beef’), at paragraph 137. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 336 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 products are being treated differently.66 Rather, the imported product must have suffered some detriment. Discrimination may be either de jure (where country A’s product is treated differently on the face of the measure) or de facto (where the measure is ostensibly the same for domestic and imported products, but the imported product nevertheless receives less favourable treatment). De facto discrimination might be found, for example, where it is easier for the domestic products to meet the measure’s requirements, perhaps because the importing country has better technology to improve efficiency of water usage or because the importing country has for some time required calculation and reporting of water footprints. As a result, domestic producers may be well adapted to such requirements, whereas producers of imported products might have more difficulty because they have not had the same requirements at home. The problem may be exacerbated for producers in developing countries. Is it a defence for the government imposing the measure to say that there is a legitimate regulatory distinction between the imported and domestic products? In other words, is there a violation even though there is a ‘genuine relationship’ between the measure and the adverse impact on competitive opportunities for imported products?67 This issue was recently addressed by the Appellate Body in EC-Seal Products where the EU unsuccessfully argued that a panel must inquire as to whether the detrimental impact on competitive opportunities for ‘like’ imported products stems exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction.68 This finding confirmed that it is unlikely that simply having a legitimate public policy reason for a regulatory distinction will be enough to absolve a country from being in violation of the obligation. Article III.2 applies the national treatment obligation to taxes by setting out two separate tests – one in the first sentence, and the other in the second sentence. The first sentence prohibits imposition on imported products of ‘internal taxes or other internal charges’ in excess of 66 EC-Asbestos, n. 53 above, at paragraph 100; EC-Seal Products, n. 54 above, at paragraph 5.101. 67 EC-Seal Products, n. 54 above, at paragraph 5.101. 68 Ibid., at paragraph 5.117. In this regard, the EU was arguing for a similar approach to be taken to the determination of ‘less favourable treatment’ under GATT, n. 55 above, Article III.4 as under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement, n. 46 above. The issue has also been debated by academics. Regan, for example, has argued that regulatory intent is irrelevant in the determination, and that ‘less favourable treatment’ only covers measures with an objective protectionist intent. D. Regan, ‘Further Thoughts on the Role of Regulatory Purpose under Article III of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade’, 37:4 Journal of World Trade (2003), 737. On the other hand, Porges and Trachtman have argued that it is unclear whether different treatment based on non-protectionist goals is permitted under Article III or whether any ‘less favourable’ treatment would violate Article III.4. See A. Porges and J. Trachtman, ‘Robert Hudec and Domestic Regulation: The Resurrection of Aim and Effects’, 37:4 Journal of World Trade (2003), 783. RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 those applied to ‘like’ domestic products. To violate this sentence, the imported and domestic products must be ‘like’. However, if they are not, there may be a violation of the second sentence where there is competition between an imported product and a ‘directly competitive or substitutable’ domestic product which is ‘not similarly taxed’.69 The threshold for determining less favourable treatment under the first sentence is lower compared to the second sentence. Where imported and domestic products are ‘like’, even a negligible difference between the taxes imposed on them will constitute a violation (e.g., a tax of 5% on a domestic product with a water footprint below a certain level versus a tax of 7.5% on an imported product with a higher footprint). However, if the products do not reach the threshold of being ‘like’, but are ‘directly competitive or substitutable’, then some differences in taxation levels are allowable as there will only be a violation if the products are ‘not similarly taxed’.70 However, such a small difference is unlikely to be sufficient to change consumer behaviour, and so wherever products are ‘like’ or ‘directly competitive or substitutable’, governments will have limited policy space to tax them differently without being found in violation. Panels and the Appellate Body have used the same criteria to determine ‘like products’ under Article III.2 as they have under Article III.4. In the case of Article III.2, panels have construed ‘likeness’ more narrowly. This is because, as the Appellate Body explained in JapanAlcoholic Beverages, the ‘second sentence provides for a separate and distinctive consideration of the protective aspect of a measure in examining its application to a broader category of products that are not like products as contemplated by the first sentence’.71 Only through a narrow interpretation can it be ensured that scope is left for application of the ‘directly competitive or substitutable’ test. An example would be where Country C imposes an additional sales tax on the basis of a product’s water footprint which results in Country A’s milk bearing 10% additional sales tax compared to Country C’s milk. It is going to be even more difficult for Country C to show that imported and domestic milk are not ‘directly competitive or substitutable’ due to their differential water footprints than it would be to show that the milk is not ‘like’. Panels and the Appellate Body have taken an economics-focused approach to determining what is ‘directly competitive or substitutable’, looking at factors such as elasticity of substitution in order to examine 69 Interpretive Note, Ad Article III GATT, n. 55 above. Japan-Alcoholic Beverages, n. 56 above, at section H(2)(b). 71 Ibid., at section H(1)(a). 70 WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING competition in the relevant markets.72 They have said that the required competitive relationship ‘may exist between products that are not, at a given moment, considered by consumers to be substitutes but which are, nonetheless, capable of being substituted for one another’,73 and further, that it is the properties or characteristics of goods that are important because it is from these that consumers derive utility. It is difficult to see how – in the absence of very strong evidence showing that consumers were not prepared to substitute low water footprint milk with high footprint milk – the imported and domestic products would not be found ‘directly competitive or substitutable’. A violation of Article III.2 requires that a tax measure be applied ‘so as to afford protection’. This requires examining how the tax measure is actually applied, and its effects, to see whether the measure actually affords protection to domestic products. The effect is determinative; the intended objective of the measure is irrelevant.74 According to the Appellate Body, the protective application of a measure ‘can most often be discerned from the design, the architecture, and the revealing structure of a measure’.75 In the milk scenario, this would require examining the requirements for application of the additional sales tax to see if it was designed so that domestic milk would be exempt. If so, this may suggest a protective application. The MFN obligation (Article I) requires that a country accord any ‘advantage, favour, privilege or immunity’ to a product from one country to ‘like’ products from other countries. This obligation raises the same question of ‘likeness’ as the national treatment obligation and the Article III cases will be instructive as to the approach to be taken to the determination. An advantage such as a lower sales tax cannot be afforded to a product from one Member and not to a like ‘product’ from another. Quantitative Restrictions GATT Article XI prohibits members from imposing on imports from other countries any ‘prohibitions or restrictions other than duties, taxes or other charges’.76 This obligation would prevent a country from prohibiting or restricting imports of products based on their water footprint, unless such a prohibition could be justified on the grounds of the general exceptions as discussed next. 72 Ibid., at section H(1)(b). WTO AB 17 February 1999, Korea – Taxes on Alcoholic Beverages, WT/DS75/AB/R, WT/DS84/AB/R, at paragraph 114. 74 Panels are required to undertake ‘a comprehensive and objective analysis of the structure and application of the measure in question on domestic as compared to imported products’. Japan-Alcoholic Beverages, n. 56 above, at section H(2)(c). 75 Ibid., at section H(2)(c). 76 Such prohibitions or restrictions include quotas, import or export licences or other measures. 73 © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 337 LAURA MANSON AND TRACEY EPPS General Exceptions The GATT Article XX exceptions allow a member in violation of the agreement’s obligations to justify the offending measure. Relevant exceptions are found in subparagraph (b) (measures ‘necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health’) and (g) (measures ‘relating to the conservation of exhaustible natural resources’ if such measures are made effective in conjunction with restrictions on domestic production and consumption’). Article XX’s chapeau prohibits measures that are ‘applied in a manner which would constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where the same conditions prevail or a disguised restriction on international trade’. The Appellate Body has consistently required that, in examining whether a measure falls within Article XX, it is first necessary to determine whether it falls under one of the exceptions in the subparagraphs and, if so, to assess whether it has been applied in a manner consistent with the chapeau.77 To be justified under Article XX(g), a measure must be ‘related to conservation of exhaustible natural resources’. In US-Shrimp, the Appellate Body said that the term ‘exhaustible natural resources’ is ‘evolutionary’, and must be defined in the light of ‘contemporary concerns of the community of nations about the protection and conservation of the environment’.78 Cases have variously found turtles, gasoline and clean air to be exhaustible natural resources.79 It is difficult to imagine water not being considered an exhaustible natural resource, given the scarcity issues noted above. Under Article XX(g), it is not necessary to show that a measure has achieved, or is likely to achieve, its stated objective. In US-Gasoline, the Appellate Body stated that to be considered as ‘relating to’ conservation, a measure must be ‘primarily aimed at’ the conservation of exhaustible resources.80 As the Appellate Body noted in that case should it become clear that realistically, a specific measure cannot in any possible situation have any positive effect on conservation goals, it would probably be because that measure was not designed as a conservation measure to 77 WTO AB 20 May 1996, United States – Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, WT/DS2/AB/R (‘US-Gasoline’), at 22. 78 WTO AB 6 November 1998, United States – Import Prohibition of Certain Shrimp and Shrimp Products, WT/DS58/AB/RM (‘USShrimp’), at paragraph 130. 79 Regarding gasoline, see WTO DS 11 October 1994, United States – Taxes on Automobiles, WT/DS31/R (‘US-Automobiles’), at 109. Regarding clean air, see WTO DS 20 May 1996, United States – Standards for Reformulated and Conventional Gasoline, WT/DS2/R (unadopted). Other examples cited by the Appellate Body include petroleum and iron ore. US-Shrimp, n. 78 above, at paragraph 128. 80 US-Gasoline, n. 77 above, at 18. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 338 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 begin with. In other words, it would not have been primarily aimed at conservation of natural resources at all.81 In a later case, the Appellate Body softened this requirement, suggesting that the measure need only be ‘reasonably related to the ends’, based on an examination of the ‘general design and structure’ of the measure and its relationship to the objective’.82 Subparagraph (g)’s third requirement is that a measure be made effective in conjunction with restrictions on domestic production or consumption. This requires that there be ‘even-handedness’ in restrictions between domestic and foreign producers.83 Article XX(g) thus appears likely to provide a basis for a country to justify a measure that discriminates between products based on their water footprint, subject to the measure being administered in a manner consistent with the chapeau’s requirements (discussed below). Subparagraph (b) requires that a measure be ‘necessary’ to protect human, animal or plant life or health. Given the importance of water to health, it is plausible that a country might seek to justify its measure under this heading, although Article XX(g) (discussed above) provides the easier test to fulfil. This is due to the concept of necessity in subparagraph (b). In KoreaBeef, the Appellate Body stated that on a continuum with ‘indispensable’ at one end, and simply ‘making a contribution to’ at the other, the term ‘necessary’ is closer to ‘indispensable’.84 The test set out by the Appellate Body in that case made the determination of whether a measure is necessary dependent on the importance of the objective, the measure’s contribution to that objective and the trade impact of the measure.85 While the Appellate Body has included ‘the importance of the objective’ as a relevant factor in determining necessity, it has also emphasized that each WTO Member has the right to set its own public health or environmental objectives and the level of protection related to those objectives.86 In Brazil-Tyres, the Appellate Body said that, in determining necessity, ‘a panel must assess all the relevant 81 Ibid., at 22. See also US-Automobiles, n. 79 above, at paragraph 3.198, where the European Community unsuccessfully argued that an American tax known as the ‘gas guzzler tax’ could not be considered as primarily aimed at the conservation of carbon fuel because it had become a revenue measure designed to fund domestic programmes favoured by the United States Congress and Administration. 82 US-Shrimp’, n. 78 above, at paragraph 141. See also S. Charnovitz, ‘The WTO’s Environmental Progress’, 10:3 Journal of International Economic Law (2007), 685, at 701. 83 US-Gasoline, n. 77 above, at 21. 84 Korea-Beef, n. 65 above, at paragraph 161. 85 Ibid., at paragraph 164. 86 See, e.g., US-Gasoline, n. 77 above; and EC-Asbestos, n. 53 above, at paragraph 168. RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 factors, particularly the extent of the contribution to the achievement of a measure’s objective and its trade restrictiveness, in the light of the importance of the interests or values at stake’.87 This approach treats the importance of the interests or values at stake not as a direct part of the analysis, but as informing the balance of the contribution of the measure and its trade effects.88 In terms of considering the measure’s contribution to the objective, in Brazil-Tyres, the Appellate Body looked for a ‘genuine relationship of ends and means between the objective purposed and the measure at issue’89 and said that ‘when a measure produces restrictive measures on international trade as severe as those resulting from an import ban, it appears to us that it would be difficult for a panel to find that measure necessary unless it is satisfied that the measure is apt to make a material contribution to the achievement of its objective’.90 In EC-Seal Products, the Appellate Body suggested that the Brazil-Tyres case had not set one predetermined standard, but rather that each measure has to be assessed on an individual basis against the degree of contribution, the importance of the value and the level of trade-restrictiveness.91 Much would depend on how the objective of a water-related measure was framed. If it was too broad or ambitious (e.g., reduce water scarcity worldwide) it would be extremely difficult to show a real contribution to the objective’s achievement; if, on the other hand, the objective was more modest (e.g., increase consumers’ awareness of water scarcity issues), then it would be easier to design and structure a technical regulation that would contribute to its achievement. As to evidence, the Appellate Body has taken a fairly liberal approach, suggesting in Brazil-Tyres that the analysis did not have to be quantitative but could be qualitative, and noting that the results of certain actions (e.g., measures to attenuate global warming) can only be evaluated with the benefit of time.92 A final inquiry under Article XX(b) is whether there are other measures that would be equally as effective but less trade restrictive. A panel must ask first, whether the alternative preserves for the responding member ‘its right to achieve its desired level of protection with respect to the objective pursued’.93 Second, whether the WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING alternative is less trade restrictive than the impugned measure.94 And third, even if an alternative measure provides the same benefit and is less trade restrictive than the impugned measure, whether it is ‘reasonably available’.95 Once a measure is found to fall within one of the subparagraphs, the analysis turns to the chapeau, which deals with the manner in which a measure is applied. Specifically, it asks whether a measure is a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries where the same conditions prevail, or is a disguised restriction on trade. In interpreting the requirements of the chapeau, the Appellate Body has favoured flexibility of measures. A country should not require other countries to use exactly the same measures as it imposes but, rather, should focus on similar effects.96 In Brazil-Tyres, the Appellate Body noted that if there is discrimination between countries in the application of the measure, the measure will violate the chapeau ‘when the reasons given for this discrimination bear no rational connection to the objective falling within the purview of a paragraph of Article XX, or would go against that objective’.97 In the case of water-related trade measures, ensuring such a connection may not always be as simple as it sounds, given the many factors that go towards assessing water usage and efficiency; and to be safe from challenge under the chapeau, the country would have to show that they had taken into consideration the differences between their circumstances and those of their trading partners so as to come up with an evenhanded measure. TBT AGREEMENT The TBT Agreement was designed to promote trade liberalization, while maintaining the right of members to take measures that are a legitimate exercise of regulatory autonomy.98 Unlike the GATT, which has a specific exceptions clause, the TBT Agreement contains statements in its preamble indicating that members can address, inter alia, environmental concerns, so long as they do not create ‘unnecessary obstacles to trade and 94 87 WTO AB 17 December 2007, Brazil – Measures Affecting Imports of Retreaded Tyres, WT/DS332/AB/R (‘Brazil-Tyres’), at paragraph 156. 88 See T. Epps and A. Green, n. 62 above, at 147. 89 Brazil-Tyres, n. 87 above, at paragraph 145. 90 Ibid., at paragraph 150. 91 EC-Seal Products, n. 54 above, at paragraph 5.213. 92 Further, the selection of the method for determining the contribution depends on the ‘nature, quantity, and quality of evidence existing at the time the analysis is made’. Brazil-Tyres, n. 87 above, at paragraphs 145–146 and 151. This was confirmed in EC-Seal Products, n. 54 above, at paragraph 5.222. 93 Brazil-Tyres, n. 87 above, at paragraph 156. Ibid. The Appellate Body said that ‘an alternative measure may be found not to be reasonably available . . . where it is merely theoretical in nature . . . or where the measure imposes an undue burden on that Member, such as prohibitive costs or substantial technical difficulties’. Ibid., at para 308. 96 See US-Shrimp’, n. 78 above, where the Appellate Body focused on the nature of international negotiations regarding the environmental concern at issue prior to the imposition of the measure. 97 Brazil-Tyres, n. 87 above, at paragraph 227. 98 M. Cardwell and F. Smith, ‘Contemporary Problems of Climate Change and the TBT Agreement: Moving Beyond Eco-labelling’, in: T. Epps and M. Trebilcock (eds.), Research Handbook on the WTO and Technical Barriers to Trade (Edward Elgar, 2013), 391, at 403. 95 © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 339 LAURA MANSON AND TRACEY EPPS are not applied in a manner which would constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination between countries . . . or a disguised restriction on international trade’.99 In this section, we focus on the obligations that apply to technical regulations.100 Definitions Technical regulations are defined in Annex 1.1 of the TBT Agreement as a: Document which lays down product characteristics or their related processes and production methods, including the applicable administrative provisions, with which compliance is mandatory. It may also include or deal exclusively with terminology, symbols, packaging, marking or labelling requirements as they apply to a product, process or production method. A labelling requirement, as discussed above, might constitute a technical regulation under this definition, which not only covers product-related PPMs, but also covers non-product-related PPMs to the extent that they deal with requirements for ‘terminology, symbols, packaging, marketing or labelling requirements’. Regulations requiring labels have generated concerns under the TBT Agreement in various contexts, including country of origin, carbon footprinting and ‘food miles’.101 A ‘yes or no’ water footprint label would fit within this second category and may also raise concerns. Non-discrimination The TBT Agreement imposes a non-discrimination obligation for technical regulations that requires members to afford both national treatment and MFN treatment to ‘like’ imported products (Article 2.1). The requirement is to accord ‘treatment no less favourable’. In US-Clove Cigarettes, the Appellate Body suggested that ‘likeness’ in the TBT context is to be determined ‘based on the competitive relationship between and among the products’.102 In this finding, the Appellate 99 TBT Agreement, n. 46 above, recitals 5 and 6. Key obligations that apply to technical regulations are nondiscrimination (national treatment and MFN treatment), and that the measure be not more trade-restrictive than necessary. Obligations on members in respect of standards include ensuring that their central government standardizing bodies accept and comply with the Code of Good Practice for the Preparation, Adoption and Application of Standards in Annex 3 of the TBT Agreement, ibid. Standardizing bodies that have accepted and are complying with the Code of Good Practice will be acknowledged as complying with the principles of the Agreement. Conformity assessment procedures are subject to obligations in Articles 5 to 9 of the TBT Agreement. 101 For a discussion of concerns raised in the TBT Committee, see S. Baddeley, P. Cheng and R. Wolfe, ‘Trade Policy Implications of Carbon Labels on Food’, 13:1 Estey Centre Journal of International Law and Trade Policy (2012), 59. 102 WTO AB 24 April 2012, US – Measures Affecting the Production and Sale of Clove Cigarettes, WT/DS406/AB/R, at paragraphs 111– 113. 100 © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 340 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 Body rejected the Panel’s approach which involved consideration of the measure’s regulatory objectives. The Appellate Body did say that regulatory concerns may play a role in the determination of ‘likeness’ to the extent ‘they have an impact on the competitive relationship between and among the products concerned’ or are otherwise reflected in traditional criteria for assessing likeness such as ‘physical characteristics and consumer preferences’.103 As discussed in the preceding section, a water footprint labelling requirement may be seen as responding to consumer concerns, providing them with the required information to satisfy their preference for environmentally friendly products. Given available evidence, consumer preferences may contribute to a finding that the products are not like.104 Again, however, evidence may also show that labelling requirements influence consumer preferences rather than respond to them.105 There will be ‘less favourable treatment’ under Article 2.1, where the measure modifies the conditions of competition in the relevant market to the detriment of imported products; and the detrimental impact ‘reflects discrimination’ in that it does not ‘stem exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction’.106 The latter requirement incorporates concepts found in the chapeau of GATT Article XX. In US-COOL, the Appellate Body talked about a measure not stemming exclusively from a legitimate regulatory distinction as being one that is ‘designed or applied in a manner that constitutes a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable discrimination’.107 The test for ‘less favourable treatment’ thus provides policy space for governments to respond to water scarcity issues. If an imported product fails to qualify for a label, or if doing so has negative implications for its ability to compete in the market, and the distinction in treatment stems exclusively from a non-discriminatory and legitimate water policy, then the measure may not constitute discriminatory treatment under Article 2.1 of the TBT Agreement. However, the regulating country would need to be careful in the measure’s design so as to avoid any de facto discrimination. Not More Trade-restrictive than Necessary Article 2.2 of the TBT Agreement requires members to ensure that their technical regulations are not 103 Ibid., at paragraph 117. T. Voon, A. Mitchell and C. Gascoigne, ‘Consumer Information, Consumer Preferences and Product Labels under the TBT Agreement’, in: T. Epps and M. Trebilcock, n. 98 above, 454, at 465. 105 Ibid. 106 US-Tuna II, n. 28 above, at paragraph 231. 107 WTO AB 23 July 2012, US – Certain Country of Origin Labelling (COOL) Requirements, WT/DS384/AB/R, WT/DS386/AB/R (‘USCOOL’), at paragraph 271. 104 RECIEL 23 (3) 2014 prepared, adopted or applied with a view to or with the effect of creating unnecessary obstacles to international trade. For this purpose, technical regulations shall not be more traderestrictive than necessary to fulfil a legitimate objective, taking account of the risks non-fulfilment would create. Such legitimate objectives are, inter alia: national security requirements; the prevention of deceptive practices; protection of human health or safety, animal or plant life or health, or the environment. Policies aimed at conserving freshwater or improving efficiency of its use would fall within the concept of ‘legitimate objectives’.108 But even where a legitimate objective has been identified, there may be a violation if the measure in question is more trade-restrictive than necessary. In this regard, the Appellate Body has found that a determination of violation requires panels to consider: (i) The regulation’s trade-restrictiveness;109 (ii) The regulation’s degree of contribution toward achievement of the legitimate objective;110 and (iii) The risks that non-fulfilment would create.111 Various design features of a regulation could contribute to making it more trade-restrictive than necessary if there were alternative ways of designing the regulation that would make it more appropriate for a wider range of producers from different countries and hence less trade-restrictive. An assessment of the regulation’s degree of contribution toward achievement of the legitimate objective raises similar questions as discussed in relation to the GATT Article XX chapeau, including how broadly the objective was framed and whether products that comply with them actually promote freshwater sustainability. If countries were able to base their measures on international standards, such as ISO, this would help support arguments as to a regulation’s degree of contribution.112 For a country imposing water labelling requirements on imported products, it may be difficult to show that there are risks from non-fulfilment of the objective. It is easy to envisage risks from non-compliance by domestic 108 The term has been interpreted generously by the Appellate Body. For a discussion of the concept, see A. Kudryavtsev, ‘The TBT Agreement in Context’, in: T. Epps and M. Trebilcock, n. 98 above, 17, at 59. 109 US-Tuna II, n. 28 above, at paragraph 318; US-COOL, n. 107 above, at paragraph 471. 110 As evidenced by the design, structure and operation of the technical regulation, and also its application. See US-Tuna II, n. 28 above, at paragraph 315; US-COOL, n. 107 above, at paragraph 373. 111 US-Tuna II, n. 28 above, at paragraph 318. 112 This would also be the case under the chapeau of GATT, n. 55 above, Article XX. In the TBT context, however, it is worth noting that Article 2.4 of the TBT Agreement, n. 46 above, actually requires members to use relevant international standards where they exist, ‘except when such international standards or relevant parts would be an ineffective or inappropriate means for the fulfilment of the legitimate objectives pursued’. WATER FOOTPRINT LABELLING producers where the objective is to maximize efficient use of water or minimize water pollution. Nonfulfilment of a broader objective related to use of water internationally would not be likely to carry much of a risk and so this factor would weigh minimally in the overall analysis. CONCLUSION As with other areas of environmental regulation, such as climate change, international trade liberalization and sustainability of freshwater resources do not have to be incompatible goals. WTO rules recognize the importance of such areas of regulation, and panels and the Appellate Body have accorded flexibility in their interpretation of the rules to ensure that members can exercise their rights to pursue such regulation. However, the considerations we have highlighted indicate that water footprint labelling, and other traderelated measures based on a product’s water footprint, could well have inadvertent trade law implications. This may be the case even where the footprint’s calculation is based on sound methodology, in part due to the fact that freshwater usage will have a different impact on the environment and on users in different areas, and in part because capacity to improve efficiency of water use will vary across regions. We have sought in this article to highlight some of the key issues raised by application of WTO rules (there will, inevitably, be others), and in so doing, to highlight the importance of giving careful consideration to how measures are designed and applied. The devil is so often in the detail, and the complications inherent in the very exercise of calculating a product’s water footprint mean that the actual trade implications of any measure can only be assessed with full knowledge of the facts. The complications should not act as a deterrent to governments in moving forward with the development of means such as labels to encourage consumers to take into account freshwater sustainability in their purchasing decisions, but careful design will be required. Laura Manson (BCom/LLB(Hons), University of Otago, New Zealand) is an analyst in Corporate Finance at PwC New Zealand. Tracey Epps (BA/LLB(Hons), LLM, SJD (Tor)) is a Lead Adviser in the Legal Division of the New Zealand Ministry of Foreign Affairs and Trade. © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 341 Copyright of Review of European Comparative & International Environmental Law is the property of Wiley-Blackwell and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.