Uploaded by klauskrause2000

How The Economic Machine Works

advertisement
How The Economic Machine Works
One of the things I admire most in people is the ability to
synthesise and convey complex ideas in a manner that are
accessible and relatively easy to understand. Ray Dalio does
this exceptionally well in his 30-minute YouTube video: How
The Economic Machine Works:
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=PHe0bXAIuk0
Although the economic concepts presented by Ray in this video
are oversimplified, it still provides an incredible framework
for beginners wishing to learn more about Economics.
In this blog, I will focus on writing about my passions, one
of which is Economics. Without further adieu, this article
will provide a brief summary of Ray’s video.
Building The Economic Machine
In the same way that atoms are the building blocks of matter,
transactions are the fundamental building blocks of the
economic machine. These transactions are above all else driven
by human nature, and they create three main forces that drive
the economy:
(1.) Productivity Growth
(2.) The Short-Term Debt Cycle
(3.) The Long-Term Debt Cycle
Transactions
Transactions are simply the exchange of money or credit
between a buyer and seller for goods, services, or financial
assets.
Credit simply refers to money that’s been borrowed. If we add
together all the money and credit that’s been spent, that
gives us the total spending. It is this total spending that
drives the economy.
Now that we can see how transactions drive the economy, we
must begin to understand what markets are given that
transactions cannot occur without markets.
Markets, Governments & Central Banks
A market consists of all the buyers and sellers making
transactions for the same thing. For example, there is a wheat
market, a property market, and a stock market among many
others.
An economy consists of all the transactions in all of its
markets. If you add up the total spending and the total
quantity sold in all markets, you have everything you need to
know to understand the economy.
The biggest buyer and seller is the government. You can think
of the government as an entity that collects taxes and spends
money. It is separate and different to a central bank.
A central bank is different from the government because it can
actually control the amount of money and credit circulating in
the economy (also known as the money supply). For this reason,
the central bank plays an integral role in the flow of credit
within the economy.
Credit
We need to pay particularly close attention to credit because
it is the most important and volatile part of the economy.
Credit allows borrowers to buy things in the present that they
otherwise wouldn’t be able to afford. In a similar manner, it
allows lenders to make money since borrowers promise to repay
the amount they borrowed (called the principal) plus interest.
In this way, credit can help both lenders and borrowers get
what they want.
When interest rates are high, there is less borrowing because
it is expensive. Conversely, when interest rates are low,
borrowing increases because it’s cheaper.
As soon as a lender lends money to a borrower, credit is
created. As soon as credit is created, it immediately turns
into debt.
Debt is interesting because it is both an asset to the lender,
and a liability to the borrower. In the future, when the
borrower repays the loan, plus interest, the asset and
liability disappear, and the debt is settled.
I know exactly what you’re thinking, why on earth is credit so
important? Well, credit is very important because when a
borrower receives credit, they are able to increase their
spending, and remember, it is spending that drives the
economy. This is because one person’s spending is another
person’s income.
When someone’s income rises, it makes lenders more willing to
lend them money because they are more creditworthy. A
creditworthy borrower has two things:
(1.) The ability to repay
(2.) Collateral
Having a lot of income in relation to their debt gives the
borrower the ability to repay. In the event that they can’t
repay, they have valuable assets to use as collateral that can
be sold.
This makes lenders feel more comfortable in lending them
money. So increased income allows for increased borrowing
which allows for increased spending, and since one person’s
spending is another person’s income, this leads to more
borrowing and the cycle repeats. This self-reinforcing pattern
leads to economic growth, and this is why we have cycles.
If you’re a seller in a transaction, you have to provide
something in order to get paid, and how much you get depends
not only on what you’re producing, but how much of it you’re
producing i.e it depends on your productivity. In economics,
productivity measures output per unit of input, such as labour
hours or capital.
It is intuitive to think that productivity growth is the most
important factor in determining economic growth, and while
this happens to be true in the long run, credit actually
matters much more in the short run. This is because
productivity growth doesn’t fluctuate much, so it’s not a big
driver of economic swings. By contrast, debt is – because it
allows us to consume more than we produce when we acquire it
(think credit cards) and it forces us to consume less than we
produce when we pay it back.
Debt swings occur in two big cycles:
(1.) The Short-Term Debt Cycle (Approximately 5-8 years long).
(2.) The Long-Term Debt Cycle (Approximately 75-100 years
long).
These cycles along with one other factor:
(3.) Productivity growth
Are what drive the economy.
The chart below shows a picture of long-term productivity
growth over time (as shown by the straight line). The longterm productivity growth line shows us that over time, the
average trend is increased economic growth and living
standards (due to higher productivity over time). However, the
volatile curved line represents the short-term debt cycle.
That line shows us that while economic growth is increasing on
average in the long-term, it fluctuates highly in the shortterm. As mentioned, these swings around the line are not due
to how much innovation or hard work there is in the economy,
but rather, they are due to the availability of credit.
For a second, let’s just imagine an economy without credit. In
this economy, the only way in which you can increase your
7:46
Let's for a second imagine an economy without credit. In this economy, the only way I can
increase my spending
7:53
is to increase my income, which requires me to be more productive and do more work.
7:59
Increased productivity is the only way for growth. Since my spending is another person's
income,
8:05
the economy grows every time I or anyone else is more productive.
8:10
If we follow the transactions and play this out, we see a progression like the productivity
growth line.
8:16
But because we borrow, we have cycles. This isn't due to any laws or regulation,
8:23
it's due to human nature and the way that credit works. Think of borrowing as simply a way
of pulling spending forward.
8:32
In order to buy something you can't afford, you need to spend more than you make.
8:37
To do this, you essentially need to borrow from your future self. In doing so you create a time
in the future
8:44
that you need to spend less than you make in order to pay it back. It very quickly resembles a
cycle.
8:51
Basically, anytime you borrow you create a cycle.? This is as true for an individual as it is for
the economy.
8:59
This is why understanding credit is so important because it sets into motion a mechanical,
predictable series of events that will happen in the future.
9:08
This makes credit different from money. Money is what you settle transactions with.
9:14
When you buy a beer from a bartender with cash, the transaction is settled immediately.
9:20
But when you buy a beer with credit, it's like starting a bar tab. You're saying you promise to
pay in the future.
9:27
Together you and the bartender create an asset and a liability. You just created credit. Out of
thin air.
9:35
It's not until you pay the bar tab later that the asset and liability disappear,
H
6:03
which allows increased spending. And since one person's spending is another person's
income,
6:09
this leads to more increased borrowing and so on. This self-reinforcing pattern leads to
economic growth
6:17
and is why we have Cycles. In a transaction, you have to give something in order to get
something
6:25
and how much you get depends on how much you produce over time we learned
6:31
and that accumulated knowledge raises are living standards we call this productivity growth
6:37
those who were invented and hard-working raise their productivity and their living standards
faster
6:43
than those who are complacent and lazy,
6:48
but that isn't necessarily true over the short run. Productivity matters most in the long run, but
credit matters most in the short run.
6:54
This is because productivity growth doesn't fluctuate much, so it's not a big driver of
economic swings.
7:01
Debt is — because it allows us to consume more than we produce when we acquire it
7:06
and it forces us to consume less than we produce when we pay it back. Debt swings occur in
two big cycles.
7:14
One takes about 5 to 8 years and the other takes about 75 to 100 years.
7:20
While most people feel the swings, they typically don't see them as cycles because they see
them too up close -- day by day, week by week.
7:29
In this chapter we are going to step back and look at these three big forces and how they
interact to make up our experiences.
7:37
As mentioned, swings around the line are not due to how much innovation or hard work there
is, they're primarily due to how much credit there is.
7:46
Let's for a second imagine an economy without credit. In this economy, the only way I can
increase my spending
7:53
is to increase my income, which requires me to be more productive and do more work.
7:59
Increased productivity is the only way for growth. Since my spending is another person's
income,
8:05
the economy grows every time I or anyone else is more productive.
8:10
If we follow the transactions and play this out, we see a progression like the productivity
growth line.
8:16
But because we borrow, we have cycles. This isn't due to any laws or regulation,
8:23
it's due to human nature and the way that credit works. Think of borrowing as simply a way
of pulling spending forward.
8:32
In order to buy something you can't afford, you need to spend more than you make.
8:37
To do this, you essentially need to borrow from your future self. In doing so you create a time
in the future
8:44
that you need to spend less than you make in order to pay it back. It very quickly resembles a
cycle.
8:51
Basically, anytime you borrow you create a cycle.? This is as true for an individual as it is for
the economy.
8:59
This is why understanding credit is so important because it sets into motion a mechanical,
predictable series of events that will happen in the future.
9:08
This makes credit different from money. Money is what you settle transactions with.
9:14
When you buy a beer from a bartender with cash, the transaction is settled immediately.
9:20
But when you buy a beer with credit, it's like starting a bar tab. You're saying you promise to
pay in the future.
9:27
Together you and the bartender create an asset and a liability. You just created credit. Out of
thin air.
9:35
It's not until you pay the bar tab later that the asset and liability disappear,
Credit
 Credit is the most important part of the economy because it
is the biggest and most volatile part.
 Lenders lend money to make more of it.
 Borrowers borrow money to buy something they can’t afford,
such as a house, a car, a business or stocks.
 Borrowers promise to repay the amount borrowed (the
principal) with interest.
 When interest rates are high, borrowing is low.
 When interest rates are low, borrowing is high.
 When lenders believe borrowers will repay, credit is
created.
 Credit can be created out of thin air.
 When credit is issued it becomes debt. It’s a liability for
the borrower, and an asset for the lender. It disappears when
the transaction is settled.
 Credit is important because it means borrowers can increase
their spending. This is fundamental because one person’s
spending is another person’s income.
 This means that the other person, on the back of an increase
in income and more believability by lenders that they will
repay their principle with interest, can now borrow more money
to increase their own spending, which in turn becomes someone
else’s income.
 This creates a cycle, per the chart below – The chart shows
that short-run economic growth is not primarily driven by
innovation but rather by the availability of credit.
Productivity growth matters more in the long run.
Productivity Growth
 Over time, we learn, we accumulate knowledge, we work and
all of this drives productivity growth. Productivity matters
in long run, but credit matters in the short run.
 Productivity growth doesn’t fluctuate much so it’s not big
driver of economic swings, but debt is.
Debt
 Debt allows us to consume more than we produce when it is
acquired, and forces us to consume less when we have to pay it
back.
 This ‘debt swing’ occurs in two cycles, short-term (5 to 8
years), and long-term (75 to 100 years).
 The thing is that most people don’t really see it because
they are living day by day, week by week.
 If the economy lacks credit, the only way to boost it is by
working harder or smarter. This means more productivity, which
is slower and linear, per the diagonal line in the above
chart.
Debt Cycles
 Every time you borrow, you create a cycle.
 When you borrow, you’re effectively borrowing from future
self — borrowing from a self that will need to spend less than
they make. This is as true for the individual as it is for the
economy at large.
 This sets into motion what Dalio calls a mechanical,
predictable sequence of events.
 Credit isn’t necessarily bad.
 It’s bad when it finances over-consumption that can’t be
paid back (kind of like Greece, Portugal, Italy and Spain
during the 2010s).
 It’s good when it efficiently allocates resources that
produce income so that debts can be paid back.
 For example, buying a consumable such as a television with
debt is bad debt.
 Buying a tractor to harvest fields with, generate income,
pay back debt, and enjoy a better quality of life is good
debt.
 Like most things, when it comes to cycles, what goes up must
eventually come down.
Short-term Debt Cycle
 The first phase of the cycle is an expansion.
 Spending increases which increases incomes and asset values.
and leads to inflation.
 When spending is faster than the production of goods, it
means that we have more demand than supply, which results in
inflation.
 The Central Bank manages inflation by raising interest
rates, which makes credit more expensive and decreases
borrowing, spending and incomes.
 This results in deflation — prices coming back down.
 Economic activity decreases, and if unchecked this can lead
to a recession (zero or negative GDP growth in two successive
quarters).
 At this point, Central Banks decrease interest rates in
order to stimulate borrowing and spending, and boost economic
activity and get the economy out of recession.
 If credit is available it leads to economic expansion. When
it’s not, it leads to recession.
 In the short-term debt cycle, spending is only constrained
by the willingness of lenders and borrowers to provide and
receive credit.
 This short-term debt cycle lasts for about 5 to 8 years and
happens over and over again for decades. The peak and trough
of the cycle end up higher and higher with each subsequent
cycle which means more growth and more debt is accumulated.
This brings us to…
Long-term Debt Cycle
 The long-term debt cycle lasts for about 75–100 years.
 Despite more debt being accumulated through the short-term
debt cycles, lenders keep lending money. This is because of
the short-now view of the world — high incomes, soaring asset
prices, booming stock-markets and so on. Because of this, over
a long period of time, debts rise faster than incomes creating
the long-term debt cycle.
 But as COVID19 and previous crashes reminds us, the recent
past is not always an accurate predictor of the future. This
irrational exuberance is preempts an economic bubble.
The Debt Burden
 This is good.
 When incomes grow in relation to debt, things are kept in
balance
 But a debt burden emerges when debt growth exceeds income
growth.
 This debt to income ratio is the debt burden.
 While people might feel wealthy as the value of their assets
soar, a wise philosopher once said that we shouldn’t conflate
the trappings of success with success in itself.
 People might remain creditworthy to borrow and spend and
feel wealthy, but that’s because of the collateral that
underpins their borrowings.
 But as the debt burden increases, the value of said
collateral can vanish. As the debt burden increases, it
creates larger debt repayments over decades, and eventually it
hits a peak, as was the case with the global financial crisis
in 2008, with Japan in 1989 or during The Great Depression in
1929.
 At this point, spending goes backwards, borrowing stalls,
incomes drop, asset values plummet, stock-markets tank and
social tensions rise — this is called a deleveraging. It’s a
little like what we’re seeing today, although the COVID19
crisis wasn’t brought upon us by the long-term debt cycle
correcting itself, but through a ‘force majeure’ external
event and Government interventions.
 Suddenly the value of the collateral that was used to
securitise loans is gone, and banks find themselves in
trouble. This led to the massive bail-outs of banks like JP
Morgan, Goldman Sachs, Wells Fargo, State Street and others in
a massive US$700 billion bail-out bill in 2008. Lehman
Brothers weren’t so lucky.
 At this point in the long-term debt cycle, interest rates
can no longer be used to stimulate the economy because they
are already at zero.
 The difference between a recession and a deleveraging is
that the debt burden is too big and can’t be relieved by
lowering interest rates.
So what do we do now?
Four Levers to Deleverage the Economy
 There are four levers we can pull to get the economy back on
its feet during a deleveraging.
1 — Cut Spending
 Essentially austerity measures for businesses and
individuals.
 But the thing about this is that. perhaps paradoxically, it
causes incomes to fall because remember, one person’s spending
is another person’s income, so the debt burden gets even
bigger because people can’t afford to repay their debts
anymore.
 Cutting spending is deflationary and painful, and as
businesses further cut costs, it means less jobs and higher
unemployment.
2 — Reduce Debt
 Debt can be reduced through defaults and restructures.
 When banks are squeezed, businesses can’t repay their loans,
and individuals are lining up to withdraw their money from the
bank for fear of it not being there tomorrow in case of bank
defaults, you’re likely looking at a depression.
Default
 This is essentially a failure to repay. This immediately and
directly impacts the defaulting Government’s bondholders and
has dire downstream consequences for the entire economy and
people of a nation which is why countries like Greece were
bailed out by the deeper-pocketed EU compatriots (even though
the likes of Germany ultimately benefited).
Debt Restructuring
 With restructuring, lenders get paid back less or paid back
over longer period of time, or at a lower interest rate.
Lenders would rather have a little of something than all of
nothing (remember this when renegotiating your interest rates
and repayment terms during this time of COVID19), and
ultimately this serves to decrease debt.
 But debt restructuring also causes income and asset values
to disappear faster, again causing the debt burden gets worse.
We’re not having much luck here…the debt reduction is painful
and deflationary as well!
 The Central Government is impacted, because it is collecting
fewer taxes but needs to spend more because unemployment has
risen!
 It needs to create stimulus plans to increase spending in
the economy.
 The Government’s budget deficit explodes because it now
needs to spend more than it earns in taxes.
 To fund this deficit, it either needs to raise taxes, borrow
money, or both. And with unemployment at a high, where do
those taxes come from? The rich.
3 — Redistribute Wealth from Haves to Have-Nots
 Much like Robin Hood stealing from the rich to give to the
poor, incomes are redistributed. This can result in the
wealthy being squeezed and resenting the have-nots, and vice
versa for the contrast in outcomes.
 If this continues, social disorder and revolution can
follow, both within and between countries, as was the case in
the 1930s when Adolf Hitler came to power due to economic
collapse in Germany.
 Pressure to end the depression mounts, but with no credit in
the market, and with most ‘money’ being credit, as was
mentioned earlier, the only thing left to do is…
4 — Print Money
 With interest rates at zero, the Central Bank is forced to
print money. This is inflationary and stimulative, although it
can decrease the value of a currency, especially if too much
is printed, which can make nations uncompetitive or less
competitive on a global scale.
 By buying financial assets, the Central Bank drives up asset
prices but it only helps people who have financial assets.
 The Central Bank can only buy financial assets, not goods
and services, so in order to support the economy at large, the
Central Bank buys Government bonds which gives the Government
the ability to buy goods and service. This gets money into the
hands of people at large, not just those with financial
assets.
 The Government can now run at a deficit while also spending
on stimulus programs and unemployment benefits. This will
lower the economy’s overall debt burden over time, and
increase spending and incomes.
 However, policy makers need to balance the four levers in
order to lead to what Dalio calls a ‘beautiful deleveraging’.
 When it’s beautiful, debts decline relative to income
growth, real economic growth is positive, and inflation isn’t
a problem. This is because a delicate balance between cutting
spending, reducing debt, transferring wealth and printing
money is maintained.
 Printing money won’t cause inflation providing it offsets
the decrease in credit, but does not exceed it. However, if
too much money is printed it can lead to hyper-inflation, is
what Germany experienced during its deleveraging in the 1920s
when 160 German marks were equivalent to just one US dollar.
 An ugly deleveraging follows if income growth is not higher
than the rate of interest on accumulated debt to cut the debt
burden.
 The ‘reflation’ or recovery phase of the long-term debt
cycle — the time it takes for debt burdens to fall and
economic activity to resume per usual — lasts roughly 7 to 10
(10 years for the Great Depression and seven for the global
financial crisis). This is what’s known as a lost decade.
Three Rules of Thumb For Life
Finally, Dalio leaves us with three rules of thumb with which
to navigate the economy ourselves, be it in our own
businesses, organisations we work at or our personal finances.
1. Don’t have debt rise faster than income (because debt
burdens will eventually crush you).
2. Don’t have income rise faster than productivity — it will
eventually render you uncompetitive.
3. Do all you can to raise productivity — in the long run
that’s what matters most.
Download