Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach P. Abell MN3127 2013 Undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences This subject guide is for a 300 course offered as part of the University of London International Programmes in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences. This is equivalent to Level 6 within the Framework for Higher Education Qualifications in England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ). For more information about the University of London International Programmes undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences, see: www.londoninternational.ac.uk This guide was prepared for the University of London International Programmes by: P. Abell, Emeritus Professor of Management, Managerial Economics and Strategy Group, The London School of Economics and Political Science and Professor of Social Research Methods, Copenhagen Business School. This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due to pressure of work the author is unable to enter into any correspondence relating to, or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or unfavourable, please use the form at the back of this guide. University of London International Programmes Publications Office Stewart House 32 Russell Square London WC1B 5DN United Kingdom www.londoninternational.ac.uk Published by: University of London © University of London 2013 The University of London asserts copyright over all material in this subject guide except where otherwise indicated. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced in any form, or by any means, without permission in writing from the publisher. We make every effort to respect copyright. If you think we have inadvertently used your copyright material, please let us know. Contents Contents Introduction ............................................................................................................ 1 Aims and objectives ....................................................................................................... 1 Learning outcomes ........................................................................................................ 2 How to use this subject guide ........................................................................................ 2 Reading advice .............................................................................................................. 2 Online study resources ................................................................................................... 5 A note about the appendices ......................................................................................... 6 Syllabus......................................................................................................................... 6 Examination advice........................................................................................................ 8 Chapter 1: Getting started ................................................................................... 11 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 11 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 11 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 11 Further reading............................................................................................................ 11 1.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 11 1.2 Division of labour, specialisation and productivity ................................................... 20 1.3 Coordination: markets and organisations ............................................................... 21 1.4 Coordination and information ................................................................................ 24 1.5 Organisational control and coordination ................................................................ 28 1.6 Hierarchy and the boundaries of the firm/organisation............................................ 29 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 31 Sample examination question ...................................................................................... 32 Chapter 2: Organisational control and coordination: information and knowledge ..................................................................................................... 33 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 33 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 33 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 33 2.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 33 2.2 The psychologists’ and sociologists’ approach ........................................................ 35 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 38 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 38 Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring ................................................ 39 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 39 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 39 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 39 Further reading............................................................................................................ 39 3.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 39 3.2 Taylorism and Fordism............................................................................................ 42 3.3 The de-skilling debate ............................................................................................ 45 3.4 Technology, coordination, control and monitoring ................................................... 46 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 49 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 49 i MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Chapter 4: Coordination and control: incentives and motivation ........................ 51 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 51 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 51 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 51 4.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 51 4.2 The contribution of sociologists and psychologists .................................................. 54 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 56 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 56 Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams ................... 57 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 57 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 57 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 57 Further reading............................................................................................................ 57 5.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 57 5.2 The economists’ contribution ................................................................................. 58 5.3 The contribution of psychologists and sociologists .................................................. 60 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 65 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 65 Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority................................. 67 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 67 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 67 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 67 Further reading............................................................................................................ 67 6.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 67 6.2 Bargaining and power ........................................................................................... 68 6.3 Behavioural theory of the firm ................................................................................ 70 6.4 Sociologists’ and psychologists’ approaches to power and kindred concepts ........... 71 6.5 Contested conceptual matters................................................................................ 72 6.6 Influence, groups and individuals ........................................................................... 75 6.7 Gender and power................................................................................................. 75 6.8 Marxism and power ............................................................................................... 76 6.9 The role of power and allied concepts in organisation theory .................................. 77 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 78 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 78 Chapter 7: Coordination and control: culture ...................................................... 79 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 79 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 79 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 79 Further reading............................................................................................................ 79 7.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 79 7.2 Trust ...................................................................................................................... 81 7.3 Norms, institutions................................................................................................. 84 7.4 Altruism and commitment ...................................................................................... 84 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 85 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 85 Chapter 8: Coordination and control: participation and democracy.................... 87 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 87 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 87 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 87 Further reading............................................................................................................ 87 ii Contents 8.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 87 8.2 Voting theory ......................................................................................................... 89 8.3 Capital, labour and organisational democracy ........................................................ 90 A reminder of your learning outcomes.......................................................................... 93 Sample examination questions ..................................................................................... 93 Chapter 9: Organisation change, evolutionary and adaptive approaches ........... 95 Aim of the chapter....................................................................................................... 95 Learning outcomes ...................................................................................................... 95 Essential reading ......................................................................................................... 95 Further reading............................................................................................................ 95 9.1 Introduction .......................................................................................................... 95 9.2 Creationism ........................................................................................................... 96 9.3 Darwinian evolution .............................................................................................. 97 9.4 Lamarkian evolution .............................................................................................. 99 9.5 Neo-institutionalism .............................................................................................. 99 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................ 100 Sample examination question .................................................................................... 100 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries ......................................................................... 101 Aim of the chapter..................................................................................................... 101 Learning outcomes .................................................................................................... 101 Essential reading ....................................................................................................... 101 Further reading.......................................................................................................... 101 10.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................... 101 10.2 Introducing strategy........................................................................................... 107 10.3 Vertical contracting and strategic choice ............................................................. 109 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................ 111 Sample examination question .................................................................................... 112 Chapter 11: Horizontal boundaries .................................................................... 113 Aim of the chapter..................................................................................................... 113 Learning outcomes .................................................................................................... 113 Essential reading ....................................................................................................... 113 Further reading.......................................................................................................... 113 11.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................... 113 11.2 Diversification.................................................................................................... 113 11.3 Sociological and psychological approaches ......................................................... 115 11.4 The development of diversified companies .......................................................... 117 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................ 118 Sample examination question .................................................................................... 118 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries .................................................................. 119 Aim of the chapter..................................................................................................... 119 Learning outcomes .................................................................................................... 119 Essential reading ....................................................................................................... 119 Further reading.......................................................................................................... 119 12.1 Hierarchies ........................................................................................................ 119 12.2 Some properties of hierarchies ........................................................................... 120 12.3 Constructing a hierarchy .................................................................................... 122 12.4 Empirical relationships ....................................................................................... 125 12.5 Designing organisations .................................................................................... 126 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................ 130 Sample examination questions ................................................................................... 130 iii MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Chapter 13: Is there one best way to organise? ................................................ 131 Aim of the chapter..................................................................................................... 131 Learning outcomes .................................................................................................... 131 Essential reading ....................................................................................................... 131 Further reading.......................................................................................................... 131 13.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................... 131 13.2 Efficiency and effectiveness ................................................................................ 132 13.3 Comparison of models ....................................................................................... 133 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................ 135 Sample examination question .................................................................................... 135 Appendix 1.1: Qualitative causal diagrams ........................................................ 137 Appendix 1.2: Network analysis – an introduction ............................................ 139 Appendix 4.1: A simple principal–agent model.................................................. 141 Appendix 5.1: Introduction to decision theory and game theory ...................... 143 Decision theory.......................................................................................................... 143 Game theory ............................................................................................................. 144 Appendix 5.2: Levels of analysis ........................................................................ 149 Appendix 6.1: A simple model of sequential bargaining ................................... 151 Appendix 6.2: Bargaining failure........................................................................ 153 Appendix 9.1: Introduction to evolutionary game theory ................................. 155 Appendix 9.2: Logistic growth – an introduction ............................................... 159 Appendix 10.1: Transaction cost analysis (Williamson’s analysis) ...................... 161 Appendix 12.1: The nature of hierarchy ............................................................. 163 Appendix 12.2: Administrative costs .................................................................. 165 Appendix 12.3: Horizontal differentiation and size ........................................... 167 Appendix 13: Sample examination paper .......................................................... 169 iv Introduction Introduction Welcome to MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach, which is offered under a number of degree and diploma programmes. This is an interdisciplinary course drawing centrally upon psychology, sociology, economics and, to a lesser extent, management theory. The subject guide is structured around readings from two textbooks. One is written substantially from an economic perspective on organisations or firms (to use the economists’ favoured term). The other adopts a much more psychological and sociological standpoint. You might well ask why I adopt an interdisciplinary approach. For instance, many courses carry the titles ‘organisation theory’ (largely a sociological term) and ‘organisation behaviour’ (largely a psychological term). ‘Organisation theory’ and ‘organisation behaviour’ are more often than not taught independently of each other and both almost completely separately from theories of the firm/organisation deriving from economics. In my view, however, this is wrong. It is no longer intellectually sensible to proceed in this manner. Each discipline has its own contribution to make and one can only begin to understand the structure and functioning of organisations by incorporating insights from each. Sometimes they complement each other, sometimes they invite alternative interpretations and sometimes they are in conflict – though much less often than many suppose. Economists inevitably pay more attention to organisations with a clear economic purpose (firms) whereas the other disciplines take a wider viewpoint embracing any sort of organisation (for example, churches, prisons and so on). Of course these also have their economic aspects. The central difference in emphasis is upon those organisations that are held together by monetary incentives and those that are otherwise coordinated, for example, by cultural norms or power and coercion. As we shall see, however, most organisations use a mixture of mechanisms designed to hold them together. This subject guide will concentrate upon ‘economic’ organisations though both textbooks invite you to think about a more varied menu of organisations. I hope that you enjoy this guide and wish you good luck with your studies. Aims and objectives This course explores the ways in which organisations can be designed (by management or others) in order to achieve their objectives. It will expose you to the ways in which economists, psychologists and sociologists address this and related issues. It is, therefore, an interdisciplinary course, comparing and contrasting the contribution of the core social science disciplines to the study of organisations. The course draws upon both theoretical and empirical materials and you will be encouraged to draw upon your own local knowledge in pursuing your studies. There will be an emphasis (though not exclusively) on organisations set up with an economic objective. 1 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Learning outcomes At the end of this course and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • describe the essential features of organisations • discuss the factors shaping these features • describe the evolution of different organisational designs/types • discuss how managers may build and change organisations • describe how different organisational forms impact on the individual within organisations. How to use this subject guide The aim of this guide is to help you to interpret the syllabus. It outlines what you are expected to know for each area of the syllabus and suggests relevant reading to help you to understand the material. It must be emphasised that this guide is intended to supplement the textbooks, not replace them. It is important to appreciate that the different topics covered are not self-contained. There is a degree of overlap between them and you are guided in this respect by cross-referencing between different chapters. In terms of studying this subject, the chapters of this guide are designed as self-contained units of study, but for examination purposes you need to have an understanding of the subject as a whole. Reading advice Essential reading This subject guide is structured around readings from two textbooks. They are: Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour.(London: Prentice Hall, 2010) seventh edition [ISBN 9780273728597]. Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008) fourth edition [ISBN 9780273681977]. I shall refer to these texts respectively as ‘B and H’ and ‘D and S’ throughout the subject guide. Occasionally I shall refer to other books and papers where I feel that these two Essential reading texts do not adequately cover the requisite material. Unlike many other subject guides, you can, by and large, follow the course from the pages of the two texts. However, they often refer you to copious further reading, so if there is a particular part of the course you find interesting you may wish to follow your own interests. Detailed reading references in this subject guide refer to the editions of the set textbooks listed above. New editions of one or more of these textbooks may have been published by the time you study this course. You can use a more recent edition of any of the books; use the detailed chapter and section headings and the index to identify relevant readings. Also check the virtual learning environment (VLE) regularly for updated guidance on readings. You can study the course perfectly well by restricting your attention to the subject guide, the two essential texts and the occasional additional references provided. I have, though, attempted to keep the latter to a 2 Introduction minimum. The readings from the textbooks are indicated at appropriate points in the text of the subject guide. The guide does not provide a summary of the readings but rather tries to achieve a theoretical synthesis. In respect of learning activities, opportunities to stop and criticise and practical examples or cases, both texts provide these along with summaries. I have provided learning outcomes in this subject guide which complement those provided in the textbooks. In both textbooks, the central concepts are listed in the left-hand margins. Further reading Please note that as long as you read the Essential reading you are then free to read around the subject area in any text, paper or online resource. You will need to support your learning by reading as widely as possible and by thinking about how these principles apply in the real world. To help you read extensively, you have free access to the VLE and University of London Online Library (see below). Other useful texts for this course include: Abell, P. ‘Is rational choice theory a rational choice of theory?’ in Coleman, J.S. and T.J. Fararo Rational choice theory. (Newbury Park, CA; London: Sage, 1992) [ISBN 9780803947610]. Abell, P. ‘A model of informal structure (culture) of organisations’, Rationality and Society 8(4) 1996, pp.433–52. Abell, P. and D. Reyniers ‘The emergence and viability of participating firms’ in Munshi, S. and B.P. Abrahams (eds) Good governance, democratic societies and globalisation. (Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage, 2004) [ISBN 9780761998488]. Alvesson, M. and H. Willmott (eds.) Critical management studies. (London; Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1992) [ISBN 9780803984554]. Arrow, K.J. Social choice and individual values. (New York: Wiley, 1970) second edition [ISBN 9780300013641]. Besanko, D., D. Dranove and M. Shanley Economics of strategy. (Chichester: Wiley, 1996) [ISBN 9780471598497]. Burns, T. and G.M. Stalker The management of innovation. (Oxford: Oxford Unversity Press, 1994) [ISBN 9780198288787]. Campbell, J.L., J.R. Hollingsworth and L.N. Lindberg Governance of the American economy. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991) [ISBN 9780521408271]. Carroll, G.R. and M.T. Hannon The demography of corporations and industries. (Princeton, NJ; Chichester: Princeton University Press, 2004) [ISBN 9780691120153]. Fligstein, N. The transformation of corporate control. (Cambridge, MA; London: Harvard University Press, 1990) [ISBN 9780674903593]. Grossman, S. and O. Hart ‘The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration’, Journal of Political Economy 94(4) 1986, pp.691–719. Guillen, M.F. Models of management: work, authority and organization in comparative perspective. (Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press, 1994) [ISBN 9780226310361]. Industrial Democracy Group Industrial democracy in Europe revisited. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1993) [ISBN 9780198287865]. Kreps, P. ‘Corporate culture and economic theory’ in Alt, J. and K. Shepsle (eds) Perspectives on positive political economy. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990) [ISBN 9780521398510]. Lukes, S. Power: a radical view. (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005) second edition [ISBN 9780333420928]. Milgrom, P. and J.R. Roberts Economics, organization and management. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1992) [ISBN 9780132246507]. 3 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Miller, G.J. Managerial dilemmas. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992) [ISBN 9780521457699]. Mills, A.J. and P. Tancred Gendering organizational analysis. (Oxford: Pergamon Press, 1992) [ISBN 9780803945593]. Muthoo, A. Bargaining theory with applications. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999) [ISBN 9780521576475]. Noble, D.F. Forces of production. (New York; Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986) [ISBN 9780195040463]. Powell, W. and P. DiMaggio (eds) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. (Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1991) [ISBN 9780226677095]. Richardson, G.P. Feedback thought on social science and systems theory. (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1991) [ISBN 9780812213324]. Richerson, P.J. and R. Boyd ‘The evolution of human ultrasociality’ in Eibl-Eibersfeldt, I. and F.K. Slater (eds) Ethnic conflict and indoctrination. (Oxford: Berghahn, 2001) [ISBN 9781571817662]. Scott, W.R. and S. Christensen The institutional construction of organizations. (Thousand Oaks, CA; London: Sage, 1995) [ISBN 9780803970700]. Teece, D. ‘Towards an economic theory of the multiproduct firm’, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization 3(1) 1982, pp.39–63. Tomer, J.F. The human firm. (London: Routledge, 1999) [ISBN 9780415199278]. Vanek, J. The labor-managed economy. (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1977) [ISBN 978081409554]. Wasserman, S. and K. Faust Social network analysis. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994) [ISBN 9780521387071]. Whitley, R. and P. Kristensen (eds) The changing European firm. (London: Routledge, 1996) [ISBN 9780415130004]. Williamson, O.E. ‘The economics of organization: The transaction cost approach’, American Journal of Sociology 87(3) 1981, pp.548–77. Works cited Alchian, A.A. and H. Demsetz ‘Production, information costs and economic organization’, American Economic Review 62(5) 1972, pp.777–95. Blau, P.M. and R.A. Schoenherr The structure of organizations. (New York: Basic Books, 1971) [ISBN 9780465082407]. Braverman, H. Labor and monopoly capital. (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974) [ISBN 9780853459408]. Chandler, A. Strategy and structure. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1962) [ISBN 9780262530095]. Child, J. Organisation: a guide to problems and practice (London: Sage, 1984) [ISBN 9781853960147]. Coase, R.H. ‘The problem of social costs’, Journal of Law and Economics 3 1960, pp.1–44. Elster, J. ‘Social norms and economic theory’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(4) 1989, pp.99–117. Lawrence, P.R. and J.W. Lorsch Organization and environment. (Boston: Division of Research, Harvard University, 1967) [ISBN 9780875840642]. Mintzberg, H. Mintzberg on management. (New York: Free Press, 1989) [ISBN 9780029213711]. Nelson, R.R. and S.G. Winter An evolutionary theory of economic change. (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 1982). Reprinted 2006 [ISBN 9780674272285]. Pugh, D.S. Organization theory. (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1990) [ISBN 9780140250244]. Roberts, J. The modern firm. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007) [ISBN 9780198293750]. 4 Introduction Online study resources In addition to the subject guide and the Essential reading, it is crucial that you take advantage of the study resources that are available online for this course, including the VLE and the Online Library. You can access the VLE, the Online Library and your University of London email account via the Student Portal at: http://my.londoninternational.ac.uk You should have received your login details for the Student Portal with your official offer, which was emailed to the address that you gave on your application form. You have probably already logged in to the Student Portal in order to register! As soon as you registered, you will automatically have been granted access to the VLE, Online Library and your fully functional University of London email account. If you have forgotten these login details, please click on the ‘Forgotten your password’ link on the login page. The VLE The VLE, which complements this subject guide, has been designed to enhance your learning experience, providing additional support and a sense of community. It forms an important part of your study experience with the University of London and you should access it regularly. The VLE provides a range of resources for EMFSS courses: • Self-testing activities: Doing these allows you to test your own understanding of subject material. • Electronic study materials: The printed materials that you receive from the University of London are available to download, including updated reading lists and references. • Past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries: These provide advice on how each examination question might best be answered. • A student discussion forum: This is an open space for you to discuss interests and experiences, seek support from your peers, work collaboratively to solve problems and discuss subject material. • Videos: There are recorded academic introductions to the subject, interviews and debates and, for some courses, audio-visual tutorials and conclusions. • Recorded lectures: For some courses, where appropriate, the sessions from previous years’ Study Weekends have been recorded and made available. • Study skills: Expert advice on preparing for examinations and developing your digital literacy skills. • Feedback forms. Some of these resources are available for certain courses only, but we are expanding our provision all the time and you should check the VLE regularly for updates. Making use of the Online Library The Online Library contains a huge array of journal articles and other resources to help you read widely and extensively. To access the majority of resources via the Online Library you will either need to use your University of London Student Portal login details, or you 5 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach will be required to register and use an Athens login: http://tinyurl.com/ollathens The easiest way to locate relevant content and journal articles in the Online Library is to use the Summon search engine. If you are having trouble finding an article listed in a reading list, try removing any punctuation from the title, such as single quotation marks, question marks and colons. For further advice, please see the online help pages: www.external.shl.lon.ac.uk/summon/about.php A note about the appendices At the end of this guide there is a series of appendices which have been provided to supplement various chapters. I think that it is important for you to have an opportunity to look at the mathematics which supports the theories and arguments, and it also provides you with more detail on some of the theories mentioned in the chapters. I must stress that you do not need to be able to use or apply the mathematics; as I mentioned above, the Essential reading for this course is the two core textbooks. The appendices are purely additional information for those of you who want to understand and explore the subject in more depth. Syllabus 1. Introduction • Attempts to define organisations of differing types and differing objectives. Normative and positive theories. • Division of labour, specialisation, productivity, economies of scale and the problem of coordination (motivations/incentives and information). • Markets and organisations as alternative coordinating mechanisms. Contrasting market and employment contracts (incentives, risk sharing and information assets). • The market–organisational contractual continuum. Competitive markets, ‘real’ markets, long-term contracts (fixed cost to cost plus), joint ventures, alliances, informal networks, franchising, etc. • Coordination and role of: motivation/incentives, communication/ information/knowledge, bargaining power and authority, culture/ norms/trust/commitment, democratic process. • Introduction to the nature of hierarchical organisations. • Vertical boundaries (make-buy). • Horizontal boundaries (divisional, conglomerates, etc.). • Hierarchical structures (size, span, depth). • Ownership/governance. 2. Theories of boundaries • Transaction costs; assumptions, bounded rationality, opportunism, incomplete contracts; transactional characteristics, asset specificity, uncertainty, complexity, frequency. Team production and externalities. • Property rights theory. 6 Introduction • Monopoly power, information knowledge and rents, competitive advantage. • Role of managerial objectives/motivation. • Role of legislation (national variations). • Ideology. 3. The evolution of organisations • Evolution of contracts. • Evolution of organisational types: peer groups, multifunctional; multidivisional, conglomerates, alliances, networks, long-term (relational) contracting. Centralised v decentralised organisation (discretion). 4. Studying organisations • Organisation, group and individual levels of study and their interrelationship. • Contribution of statistical models and case studies. • Contribution of elementary game theory (one-shot and repeated). • Contribution of network (graph theoretic) models. • Critical theories of organisation. 5. Organisations as contractually coordinated mechanisms • Taylor, standardisation, rationalisation and scientific management; ‘Fordism’. • Theories and critiques of bureaucracy. • Centralisation, decentralisation and discretion/incomplete contracts. • Organisation as an algorithm. • Control loss, coordination loss. 6. Organisations as incentive/motivationally coordinated mechanisms • Introduction to principal–agent theory. • Team production and externalities. • Psychological models of motivation: human relations; human resource management; group and team context (production); motivational reactions to organisational design. 7. Organisations as authority/power/coordinated mechanisms • Nature of power. Authority and influence. • Bargaining power. • Sources of power. • Power and participation/decentralisation. 8. Organisations as information/knowledge distributively coordinated mechanisms • Coordination and information (games). • Theory of teams. • Hidden information/action. • Demand for information and participation. 7 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach 9. Organisations as ‘culturally’ coordinated mechanisms • Nature of culture. • Trust, leadership, sacrifice and commitment. • Social capital. • Corporate culture/ambient cultures. • National business systems. 10. Determinants of hierarchal structures (shape) • Contingency theory. • Population ecology/institutional theory. • Hierarchy (or hybrid organisation) as an optimal mechanism – given operating environment – for combining: rules/contracts, incentives, authority, information, culture. 11. Corporate governance • Ownership and control; participation and organisational democracy. Examination advice Important: the information and advice given here are based on the examination structure used at the time this guide was written. Please note that subject guides may be used for several years. Because of this we strongly advise you to always check both the current Regulations for relevant information about the examination, and the VLE where you should be advised of any forthcoming changes. You should also carefully check the rubric/instructions on the paper you actually sit and follow those instructions. Structure of the examination The examination for this subject is a formal three-hour unseen written examination in which you will be required to answer four questions from a choice of 12. A sample examination paper is included at the end of this guide. The Examiners attempt to ensure that all of the topics covered in the syllabus and subject guide are examined. Some questions could cover more than one topic from the syllabus since the different topics are not self-contained. Examination preparation You should ensure that you answer four questions, allowing an approximately equal amount of time for each question. Remember to devote some time prior to answering each question to planning your answer, and please write clearly and legibly. You should ensure that the question answered is the question posed, and not a pre-learnt answer that has little bearing on the question. Take care to structure your answers clearly by the use of paragraphs, and make sure your answers are closed with a summary or conclusion. You might want to illustrate your answers with the use of simple diagrams like the ones that I use throughout this guide. You are welcome to do this but please do not spend a lot of time drawing very precise diagrams with rulers, etc. This is not necessary. A clear hand-drawn diagram is fine. You may also want to refer to writers or theories that you have read about if their work is relevant to the question. Don’t worry about this too much, or waste your time by putting full references but, for example, ‘Powell and 8 Introduction DiMaggio (1991)’ would indicate to the Examiners perfectly adequately who or what you were referring to. Remember, it is important to check the VLE for: • up-to-date information on examination and assessment arrangements for this course • where available, past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries for the course which give advice on how each question might best be answered. 9 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 10 Chapter 1: Getting started Chapter 1: Getting started Aim of the chapter To introduce and compare economic, sociological and psychological approaches to organisations. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • organisations as control/coordination mechanisms • assumptions of rational and self-interested behaviour/action • ideal types • division of labour • transactions/exchanges; control/coordination; governance • motives/incentives • competitive markets • normative and positive theory • market–organisation continuum • di-graphs and graphs • roles/contracts/norms • incomplete information/uncertainty • discretion • vertical, horizontal, hierarchical and financial boundaries. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Milgrom, P. and J.R. Roberts Economics, organization and management. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1992) Chapter 1. Miller, G.J. Managerial dilemmas. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992) Chapter 1. 1.1 Introduction All societies that we know of seem to possess some kinds of organisations; they are probably cultural universals. Organisations are, however, not easy things to define as they are, particularly in modern societies, rather varied in nature. It is, nevertheless, useful to open with a definition, in order to focus our studies. We may start as follows: 11 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Organisations are constructed mechanisms for controlling and coordinating human activities and symbolic and physical resources in order to achieve certain objectives. Activity Now read Section 1.1 in D and S. A great deal of organisation theory is concerned with describing and explaining the occurrence of different sorts of mechanisms for achieving control and coordination. Although there is no settled consensus about the definition of these central concepts, let us start with the following. Control mechanisms are the means by which the actions/behaviour of actors (sometimes individual human beings, sometimes groups or collections of human beings) are motivated in order to achieve the objectives of the organisation. Coordination mechanisms are the means by which the actions/behaviours of actors (again, individual or collective) are brought into alignment with each other in order to achieve the objectives of the organisation. Note here that the terms action and actors are sociological in derivation. Psychologists may refer to behaviour whereas economists may refer to behaviour and agents. Sociologists distinguish between action, which means motivated or intentional behaviour, and behaviour itself. In regard to the above definition of organisation, you should note that: • organisations are usually consciously constructed (but by whom?) with an objective in mind (but whose objective?) • there may be differing opinions within an organisation about what its objectives are or should be • there may be many different mechanisms for controlling and coordinating human activities both within and outside organisations • the objectives of an organisation may change over time • organisations can be more or less effective (efficient) in achieving their objectives. We shall study these issues, among others; you might, however, ponder two fundamental questions at this early stage in your studies: • Why are some human activities coordinated/controlled within organisations whereas others are not? • How are (should) the boundaries of organisations (be) drawn? If you know the answers to these questions, you don’t really need to study this course. If you don’t, then I hope the course will prove helpful and interesting. The study of organisations: a multidisciplinary approach Until quite recently it was largely sociologists and psychologists who studied organisations. Management theorists also made a contribution. They all asked questions about how organisations impacted upon human activities and vice versa. Pugh (1990) defines organisational behaviour (the favoured term of psychologists) as follows: The study of the structure and functioning and performance of organisations and the behaviour of groups and individuals within them. 12 Chapter 1: Getting started Activity Now read Chapter 1, pp.1–5, in B and H. Economists traditionally evidenced little interest in the ‘structure and functioning’ of organisations (or firms as they would call organisations with an economic objective). Firms were almost invariably treated as ‘black boxes’ with the particular objective of maximising profits (often in a competitive market environment; see Section 1.3). Thus, questions were not normally posed as to how their internal arrangements (control and coordination mechanisms) achieved this objective. Indeed, quite often the profit-maximising objective was pictured as being a consequence of competitive evolutionary forces which drive out firms that do not operate according to this particular objective (see Chapter 9). Recently, however, this situation has changed and now, as D and S’s book testifies, we have several economic approaches to organisations. So modern organisation theory increasingly must become a multidisciplinary endeavour, combining ideas from economics, management theory, psychology and sociology. Some other disciplines like anthropology and operations research also have relevant things to say. Unfortunately, multidisciplinarity is not entirely acknowledged in the respective disciplines, with the result that studies of organisations still tend to evolve independently of each other and there are currently no textbooks which straddle the disciplinary boundaries. Indeed, most books carrying the title ‘organisation theory’ are written almost exclusively from a sociological perspective. Psychologists tend to use the phrase ‘organisation behaviour’. Furthermore, the level of sustained rigour, so essential in modern social science, is markedly different across the disciplines. Much economics, but little psychology and sociology, is expressed mathematically. Although mathematics is not essential to rigour, it is very helpful, but – failing mathematical exposition – clear prose is most important. You will, unfortunately, encounter texts which are far from transparent, particularly in the sociological tradition. I shall try to avoid referencing such texts though you will find them referred to in Buchanan and Huczynski’s book – these authors tend to use the term ‘difficult’ to describe them. It is useful to start with a brief overview of the differing perspectives adopted by each discipline when studying organisations. Activity Now read and compare Chapter 1 in D and S with Chapter 1 in B and H. The economists’ approach to the study of organisations Economists integrate their theories of organisation (or firms as they call organisations with an economic objective) into a standard theory of production. You will probably have encountered this theory in your introductory economics. Activity To revise, if necessary, read Section 2.4 in D and S. 1 Economists will almost invariably assume that economic actors (or agents)1 will behave/act rationally. They will usually seek to understand the ‘structure and functioning’ (control and coordination) of organised firms, assuming that those involved are rational optimisers (they may, Be careful: this term is used both generally, as here, and, more specifically, in principal– agent theory; see Chapter 4. 13 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach however, relax this assumption in various ways – see Chapter 10). In so doing, they will unfailingly ask us to centre our attention upon the balance of costs and benefits in pursuing different courses of action and, thus, on how to make the best use of resources – namely, the optimal or efficient allocation of resources. Clearly, although this way of thinking is most relevant to firms, economists do invite us to apply it to all organisations. Although the conception of rational action or behaviour is technically quite difficult to tie down (you may have encountered formalisations of expected utility theory in your economics units), practically it implies an assumption whereby individuals (agents) are deemed to seek (i.e. have preferences for) the best outcome they can secure for themselves, given the range of opportunities they face (i.e. their opportunity set). These opportunities and preferences are also often deemed to be given (exogenous). If not, then the factors shaping preferences and opportunities are usually regarded as independent of each other. Furthermore, economists will usually, though not invariably, concentrate upon monetary consequences to measure the success of outcomes. The two key words are ‘best’ and ‘themselves’. Strictly speaking, rationality only implies choosing the best (i.e. optimal) course of action, given the preferences (or utility functions) and opportunities of the actor. However, economists, at least initially, usually assume, in addition, that individuals look out for themselves (i.e. they have self-regarding sentiments). That is to say, they disregard possible altruistic (positive other-regarding) and spiteful (negative other-regarding) sentiments (see Chapter 7). Furthermore, they often assume that actors have identical preferences (homogeneous preferences). Whatever assumptions they may eventually make, they are adamant that any theories of organisation should be derivable from the choices of individual actors. This is sometimes described as methodological individualism, reductionism or getting the micro foundations right. Sociologists, as we shall see, are much less inclined to worry about micro foundations. Indeed, one tradition invites us to take an organisation as the unit of analysis.2 2 See Appendix 5.2. Those of you who have not encountered much economics before may well feel alarmed by this lengthy list of assumptions. You should recognise, however, that most economists do acknowledge that they are theoretical simplifications. Indeed, they are willing to relax most of them, other than optimality (though even this may be weakened: see Chapter 10 on bounded rationality). You will find both sociologists and psychologists criticising economists for making unreal assumptions. Although economists do not often use the term, you might want to interpret self-interested optimisation as an ideal type3 and later compare it with some of the sociologists’ ideal types. The most fundamental question that economists address in respect of organisation theory is why certain exchanges of goods and services (transactions) between actors take place in markets whereas others occur within organisations (firms). As you might expect, they will try to find an answer in terms of self-interested optimisers. In so doing they will make use of another ideal type – perfectly competitive markets. Activity Now read Section 2.6 in D and S. 14 3 You may have come across this in course SC1021 Principles of sociology. Chapter 1: Getting started Although we shall investigate later, in detail, the choice between market and organisational transactions, it is worth commenting here upon the way in which an answer is provided. The following assumptions are made. • The division of labour, which is driven by exogenous (i.e. given or assumed) technological forces, generates a pattern of potential (economic) transactions. • These transactions could be controlled and coordinated (governed) by either the price mechanism in the (competitive) market or by organisation control and coordination. Another way of expressing this divide is between a market contract and an employment contract. You will find that economists think in terms of efficient contracts. Later I shall ask you to compare the economists’ use of the term ‘contracts’ with the sociologists’ term ‘rules’. • There are various costs and benefits attached to each type of ‘governance’. • The governance chosen will/should maximise net benefit. (We will return to the distinction between ‘will’ and ‘should’ below.) In fact, although this is the standard manner in which ‘transaction costs’ economics analyses the problem, one needs to be a little cautious. As we shall see later, what transaction costs show is that, under certain circumstances, an organisational transaction will produce more net benefit than a market transaction. However, it does not follow that an organisation makes an efficient use of resources. All it will show is that organisations, in those circumstances, are better than the market. One would need additional theoretical ideas to show that the organisation is ‘first best’ (i.e. efficient). Let us now assume that an organisation is chosen. The major contribution of economists to organisation theory is principal–agent theory (PA theory). Activity We will study principal–agent theory later but you might now like to look at the beginning of Chapter 7 in D and S. PA theory seeks to answer the question: what sort of incentives (usually monetary ones) must a (rational) principal (which for the moment might be the owner-manager of a firm) set, in order to motivate (i.e. control) their (rational) agent in order to contribute the agent’s efforts to achieve the principal’s objectives (usually profit maximisation)? So PA theory, as formulated, is a theory of optimal incentives that controls the activities of the agent. If we now extend the idea to two or more agents then it is a matter of coordination (see the opening definition of an organisation). It is important to recognise that PA theory is a general theory of how one person or group of persons can get others to work effectively for them. Economists’ theories of organisation can be used positively (i.e. to describe and explain how organisations actually do control and coordinate their constituent activities) and normatively (i.e. to describe and explain how organisations should control and coordinate their activities). You should recognise here that the ‘should’, in the economists’ conception of normative theory, ultimately relates to the efficient allocation of scarce resources. As we shall later find, because neither psychologists nor sociologists start their enquiries from this standpoint, they do not draw a 15 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach sharp distinction between positive and normative theory. Their objectives are more often than not directed at positive theory. But be careful here: the positive use of theory is not the same thing as positivism (i.e. broadly the idea that the physical and social sciences have identical explanatory logics). Activity If you are not familiar with the above issue, you might read pp.19–25 in B and H. The psychologists’ approach to the study of organisations Psychologists, who usually use the term ‘organisational behaviour’, address two main issues. 1. How do organisational features (e.g. their control and coordination systems) impact upon individual and group behaviour within organisations? 2. How (to what extent) does individual and group behaviour contribute to the achievement of organisational objectives (which may be much broader than economic ones)? Activity Now read Chapter 1 in B and H. Psychologists may or may not assume that behaviour (i.e. action) is optimal but, generally, assume (or find evidence for) a much broader range of motivating factors than economists do (for example, status, self-esteem, work satisfaction, personal or group power and so on). Furthermore, they are more likely than economists to assume individual differences in motivations. B and H refer to this as the ‘organisational dilemma’ (p.19). You should eventually ask the question as to whether this picture of diverse heterogeneity among individual human beings (the organisational dilemma) can be made consistent with the economists’ PA model. A principal would have to design incentive systems which acknowledge the more elaborate and diverse preferences (utility functions) of his/ her agents. Furthermore, principals may themselves have non-economic objectives, like a desire (economists’ term: a ‘taste’) for power. Psychologists also explore altruistic motives under the heading of commitment: individuals may be committed to an organisation or part thereof, in the sense that they may make sacrifices for others in the organisation. Whereas economists will usually assume that people arrive at an organisation pre-equipped with clear preferences (constructed from beliefs and values), psychologists study how preferences constructed from beliefs (truth), affects (likes/dislikes) and values (good and bad) are acquired within organisations. Like sociologists (see below) they emphasise learning, socialisation and behavioural modification. Furthermore, since they entertain individual differences, they engage with issues about ‘controlling and coordinating diverse personality types’. Studying and categorising personalities inevitably leads to a consideration of the emotional side of human beings (emotions like openness, hostility, impatience and ambition). There is a marked contrast in how psychologists and economists start thinking about the action/behaviour of individuals in organisations. Economists, as we have seen, will start with a simple ideal-type model of individuals. Psychologists, on the other hand, will often emphasise the ‘organisational dilemma’ in incorporating a wide 16 Chapter 1: Getting started variety of dispositions. Such disputes may undermine at least a simple common-sense notion of rational action. Both economists and psychologists also recognise that organisations are significantly controlled and coordinated by the flow of human communication. Again, whereas economists treat the issue in an abstract way in terms of information distributions – ‘who knows what and will rationally impart or conceal what’ (Chapter 2), psychologists concentrate upon much finer-grained distinctions. They have developed descriptive theories of different sorts of communication (e.g. verbal/non-verbal, impression, management and so on). Finally, whereas economists tend to assume that individuals perceive the world ‘the way it is’ (despite many philosophical reservations about this), psychologists find room for misperception and systematically biased perception. All this might incline you to the view that the two disciplinary approaches are deeply incompatible. But this would, I think, be over-hasty. You must always, in adjudicating between different models of individuals (some more detailed than others), ask the question: ‘What am I trying to explain?’ If, for instance, you are trying to understand the difference in performance between firms then a rather simple model of the individual will probably suffice. If you want to explain the differing experience of church-goers at their place of worship, then a much more detailed model of perception, communication and emotional response will be needed. One of the advantages of theories like PA is that they can be adjusted to incorporate richer models of human beings. Don’t be over-hasty in finding irreconcilable differences (as some practitioners of particular approaches often are) between different intellectual traditions. The sociologists’ approach to the study of organisations Sociologists, while addressing identical questions to those posed by psychologists, have in addition placed their study of organisations in a much wider context. They have asked questions like: what impact do organisations have upon society at large: how do evolved systems of beliefs and values (i.e. culture) and the distribution of power in society influence the ways in which organisations are structured and function (are controlled and coordinated)? Furthermore, while pondering these ‘macro’ questions, they engage with issues about the appropriate way to conceive of social (or organisational) science. The sociological study of organisations has been strongly influenced by Max Weber’s ideal type of bureaucracy.4 Broadly speaking, Weber thought that the control and coordination of activities within modern organisations are achieved by formally specifying the rules of appropriate behaviour or action for most organisation participants (certainly, the organisationally subordinate participants – think of those working on a production line). 4 If you have access to it, you may also like to re-read the section on Weber in course SC1021 Principles of sociology. A bureaucracy is, for Weber, characterised by (among other things): • an exogenously generated division of labour • a hierarchical authority/power structure • formal rules of behaviour/action. A useful way to think about a bureaucracy is as an algorithm specifying the standards (i.e. a set of interrelated rules) of appropriate activity for each organisational participant (compare this with a completely 17 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach automated system). If the appropriately specified rules are followed (a big if!) then control and coordination should be achieved. Clearly there is some similarity between the economists’ concept of employment contract and the sociologists’ concept of rules. You will eventually need to understand how sociologists use and further develop the idea of bureaucracy, but for the moment, note that, in contrast to the economists’ perspective, the concepts of power and authority (see Chapter 6) are brought into prominence. Indeed, Weber spoke of ‘rational bureaucratic authority’ as the mechanism for controlling and coordinating a modern organisation (but note when he was writing). Observe the word rational here. Weber used the term to mean an efficient means to an end; so bureaucracies are conceived as efficient collective mechanisms (means) for achieving a given objective. We now know, however, that this is a very partial picture. Precisely what Weber meant by rational is much disputed, but we can assume that he was pretty much in accord with the economists in his use of the term. So, for the moment, a bureaucracy is a mechanism which is deemed to result in an efficient allocation of resources. Sociologists (and psychologists) also place considerable emphasis upon social norms as a mechanism of achieving, and, indeed sometimes offering resistance to, organisational control and coordination. By ‘social norms’ they mean widely accepted beliefs about appropriate standards of behaviour (action) in specified circumstances. Social norms (which should be contrasted with personal norms) can arise from the wider society (societal norms) or a section of society (e.g. social class norms) or even be generated within organisations. You will need to distinguish between mechanisms that generate social norms and mechanisms that can rely upon, or are indeed needed to defeat, already existing norms. Social norms have a contingent feature: people tend to follow them only as long as others do so. You should draw a distinction (though it is not always done) between rules (after Weber) and social norms. Both enjoin certain sorts of behaviour or action but rules don’t necessarily have to be widely accepted. Sociologists usually see social norms as a component part of culture. This latter concept, as we shall see later, is very difficult to tie down – there are literally scores of different definitions in the literature. It relates, however, to the ‘symbolic and physical resources’ mentioned in our opening definition of organisation. ‘Corporate culture’ (whatever it might mean) is sometimes described as a controlling and coordinating mechanism which is either generated within an organisation or draws upon the ambient culture surrounding the organisation.5 Sociologists (and recently some economists) have come to study how ‘institutions’ impact upon organisation design. The basic idea is that, rather than trying to understand how organisations are structured and function in terms of individual motivations, one starts with a received (exogenous) way of doing things (an institution) which is then copied. Since social norms are also propagated in this manner, it is sometimes a little difficult to know why we need both terms. Institutions are, however, often best interpreted as bundles of norms and ways of looking at the world (social cognition). For instance, institutions have been defined by Powell and DiMaggio as: ‘cognitive, normative and regulative structures and activities that provide stability and meaning to social behaviour’. We shall look at institutional ideas in Chapter 12. The study of organisational change tends to divide economists and sociologists. Since economists usually want to study organisations that are 18 5 See Chapter 7. Chapter 1: Getting started at an efficient equilibrium, change is not placed at the centre of things. Organisations that are not in equilibrium are treated as of little interest. The exceptions to this way of reasoning are evolutionary models, that we shall study in Chapter 9. Sociologists pay more attention to change and we shall distinguish between adaptive and selection-based models. The latter often operate through an understanding of birth and death rates. Finally, sociologists and some economists have taken an interest in how democracy or voting procedures might be used as a control and coordinating mechanism (see Chapter 8). For instance, contrast a firm owned by shareholders on the basis of one share one vote; a consumer cooperative where each member consumer has a vote; and a producer cooperative where the ‘workers’ control and coordinate on the basis of equal voting power. An initial comparison of the three differing perspectives You have encountered, but in outline only, three differing disciplinary perspectives about effecting the control and coordination of human activities within organisations. They suggest the following mechanisms: • rationally designed monetary incentives (employment contracts) • broader incentives (rational or otherwise?) • rules of behaviour/action • power and authority • norms and culture • democratic precepts. You might be troubled at this stage, wondering how economists can apparently ignore much of the complexity in human motivation and relationships which the other two disciplines seem to wish to embrace. Many non-economists voice such complaints about economics. One needs, however, to be careful in making this sort of complaint. In the final analysis, economists are concerned to understand how individuals respond to relative price changes (or, more generally, the balance of benefits and costs). They would argue that, characteristically, human motivations remain unaltered through these changes and, as a consequence, one can isolate the effect of price changes without delving into broader matters. You should think carefully about this as you progress in your studies. Notice that this argument is not exclusive to ‘monetary prices’; it could equally be applied to balance and costs of a non-pecuniary nature. Activity At this early stage in your studies you should try preliminary answers to the following questions: • To what degree are the various approaches of organisation theory compatible with each other? • To what degree are they contradictory? • Do they complement each other? I would not expect you to have clear answers at this stage. Although we have tended to follow the economists and think in terms of firms, you should get into the habit of thinking about organisations in general. For instance, hospitals and churches – do you think the above-identified control and coordination mechanisms apply to these sorts of organisation? 19 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach 1.2 Division of labour, specialisation and productivity Introduction All disciplines are agreed that the need for organisation largely arises because of the division of labour. In a society of self-sufficiency there would be no division of labour between individuals, no need for exchange of goods and services (transactions), nor any organisations except perhaps the family and organisations of social control. But note, even within the family there is usually a division of labour. A division of labour is defined as the splitting of activities into component parts which are then performed separately. Activity Now read ‘The pin factory’ on p.5 in D and S. The division of labour leads to specialisation, and increased specialisation can lead (but see Section 2.2) to increased productivity (i.e. output per unit of input, such as time or effort). Activity Read Sections 1.2 and 1.3 in D and S. It is often useful to express these simple ideas in terms of a diagram, as in Figure 1.1 (also see Appendix 1.1 of this guide). Division of labour (+) Specialisation (+) Productivity Figure 1.1 Economists often consider a division of labour as given (exogenous) and then ask how organisations and markets can be built upon it. Alternatively, they see it as driven by competitive market forces that procure an optimal division of labour, leading to optimal productivity. Some sociologists, on the other hand, study how the division of labour is generated both within organisations and in the wider society. That is to say, they search for explanations of why the division of labour takes a particular direction – the assumption often being that, rather than being optimal in a narrow economic sense, it is shaped by issues pertaining to power and authority.6 Scientific management (Taylorism) Activity Now read Chapter 13 in B and H and compare it with Section 1.2 in D and S. Scientific management and its extension, Fordism, have until recently been extremely influential in ‘work design’ – or what we might term the detailed 20 6 See Chapter 6. Chapter 1: Getting started division of labour. Fordism is sometimes described as ‘Taylorism plus the production line’. The basic idea is that human beings may react negatively to ‘too much’ fragmentation of activities and this may reduce their productivity or increase the difficulties in achieving coordination and control. We shall return to these issues (see Section 3.2) and also to the associated concept of de-skilling. Nevertheless, keeping this potential line of criticism in mind, it is still useful to start our analysis with an exogenous division of labour necessitating some mechanism of control and coordination. 1.3 Coordination: markets and organisations Introduction If we assume that an exogenous division of labour leads to improved efficiency, then we need to pose two strongly interrelated questions: 1. How should (normative theory) and how are (positive theory) activities, generated by the division of labour, controlled/incentivised/ motivated? 2. How should (normative theory) and how are (positive theory) exchanges (transactions), generated as a consequence of the division of labour, coordinated? The questions are interrelated in the sense that individuals need to be controlled/incentivised/motivated to coordinate their activities. However, in this section we concentrate upon coordination. Activity Now re-read Sections 1.4 and 1.5 in D and S. D and S identify two distinct methods for coordinating activities (you may read these as ideal types – later we will complicate the picture): • organisation coordination • competitive market coordination. I call these ‘methods’, not mechanisms, since each (particularly organisation) may involve a number of the mechanisms identified at the end of Section 1.1. We will return to the market/organisation choice in a moment. Coordination and di-graphs At this stage it will prove helpful to develop diagrams which can depict transactions/exchanges. Activity Now read Appendix 1.2 of this guide. Consider a division of labour generating a sequence of activities (a production line would be an example) as in Figure 1.2. Output/Input Activity/Agent 1 Output/Input Activity/Agent 2 Output/Input Activity/Agent 3 Activity/Agent 4 Figure 1.2 21 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach The points (nodes) represent activities performed by distinct agents, where the output of one agent becomes the input of the next one down the line (a sequence of arcs). Figure 1.2 is a di-graph. We shall find that di-graphs or graphs are often constructive in depicting various features of organisations, so you should familiarise yourself with the basic ideas. Note that they can be used at different levels of aggregation. The di-graph in Figure 1.2 could, in principle, be further decomposed in the division of labour so the activities could be disaggregated into a finer picture. At a more aggregate level the di-graph in Figure 1.3 depicts rather aggregate activities. Oil extraction Shipping Refining Wholesaling Figure 1.3 Each of the aggregate activities might be a separate organisation or they may all be integrated into a single organisation embracing oil extraction to retailing of refined products or any other combination. It would be interesting to know which is the most efficient arrangement or, failing this, why one arrangement is found rather than another. Market coordination Activity Read Sections 2.5 and 2.6 in D and S. If transactions are coordinated through the (perfectly competitive) market, then the equilibrium price is a ‘sufficient statistic’ (see D and S) in effecting both control and coordination. Note carefully the conditions necessary for one to be able to say that markets are perfectly competitive. If the four individual activities depicted in Figure 1.2 were to be so coordinated, then agent 1 would sell his/her output to agent 2, 2 to 3 (both at equilibrium prices) and so on down the chain. In Figure 1.3, at a higher level of aggregation, the price mechanism would coordinate the various organisations, though they themselves would presumably have an internal division of labour. You may encounter the term value chain to describe chains of transactions at any level of aggregation. The competitive market at equilibrium also guarantees the optimal (i.e. Pareto efficient) level of trade (exchange or transaction). This is a very neat guarantee, but all is dependent upon the perfect-market assumptions. What would happen if there were not many buyers and sellers and/or the parties to trade were not fully informed? We can’t answer these questions at the moment. But notice that if all (exogenously generated) transactions were to be embedded in perfectly competitive markets then, in theory, all transactions could be controlled and coordinated by market prices. In such a world, there would apparently be no need for any organisations – at least those which coordinate transactions – at all. Organisational coordination If the activities in Figure 1.3 were to be brought into a single organisation, then the flow of inputs and outputs would not normally (though there are exceptions) be coordinated by the price mechanism but rather by an organisational mechanism. This is the subject matter of our future studies. 22 Retailing Chapter 1: Getting started Again a diagram may help to fix ideas. Consider a transaction between A and B, then the choice between coordinating it using a market or an organisation can be depicted as in Figure 1.4. Coordinator/Manager B A A Price mechanism B Figure 1.4 Note that the organisational choice assumes a coordinator/manager with, shall we say, a hierarchical relation to both A and B. We might also assume here that the coordinator will need to motivate/control A and B – perhaps using a variety of those mechanisms we earlier identified. We now have what we might term a hierarchical division of labour. The coordinator/manager can also be described as having span of control of two.7 7 See Section 1.6. One way of describing the adoption of an organisation as in Figure 1.4 is to say that the price mechanism is suppressed in favour of an administered or planned transaction. Another way of describing this situation is to say that the choice is between ‘buy’ (market) and ‘make’ (organisation). Yet a further locution is to contrast a purchasing with an employment contract. You could now imagine putting various types of organisational coordination onto the transactions depicted in Figure 1.3. Although many organisations are constructed by coordinating transactions (the term ‘vertical integration’ is often used), activities can also be brought into an organisation where there is no obvious transaction, as in Figure 1.5 (the term ‘horizontal integration’ is often used). B A Input Output Input Output Figure 1.5 I say ‘obvious transaction’ because, as we shall see later, there may be less obvious transactions relating to the horizontal division of labour. Markets and organisation in economics We can imagine a given (i.e. exogenous) division of labour generating a network (di-graph) of potential transactions. There are then two idealtypical coordination methods: 1. All the transactions in the network (di-graph) are coordinated by markets (no organisations). 2. All the transactions in the network (di-graph) are coordinated by an organisation (a planned economy). 23 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Activity For further reading on this, see Milgrom and Roberts (1992) Chapter 1. This is a very abstract, but nevertheless useful, way of thinking about the choice between a market and a planned economy. Of course all economies (even those described as planned) comprise a mixture of plan (organisation) and market. But I hope you will agree that the intriguing questions are: firstly, where should the boundaries of organisations be drawn on the network (the normative question)? Secondly, where are they actually drawn (the positive question)? And, finally, if the answers to these two questions are different – why so? 1.4 Coordination and information The economic perspective Activity Read Section 1.6 in D and S. Economists tend to interpret the (rational) choice between market and organisational coordination in terms of the information available to the potential contracting parties (e.g. the information required to enter into a purchasing or an employment contract). In the ideal typical world of perfectly competitive markets where all contracting parties are deemed to possess all the information required to make fully informed rational choices (about past, present and future contingencies), they are indifferent between market and organisational coordination. It is when information is incomplete (and in practice it nearly always is) that the choice is pertinent for contracting parties. Note, in passing, that this argument would not work if parties had a taste for power, which, in turn, is only generated inside organisations (see Chapter 6). You might now begin to think in terms of the choice between ‘real’ markets (rather than perfectly well-informed competitive markets) and organisations. Activity Read Section 2.5 in D and S. Economists distinguish between: • complete contracts – where all the relevant information (i.e. all possible contingencies, past, present and future are covered) is available to the contracting parties when the contract is entered into • incomplete contracts – where all the relevant information is not available to at least one party. A diagram might help you to appreciate the possible distribution of relevant information between contracting parties – call them A and B (see Figure 1.6) 24 Chapter 1: Getting started Rectangle: Complete information A A’s private information (asymmetric information) B Common information B’s private information (asymmetric information) Figure 1.6 From Figure 1.6 you should distinguish: • complete information • common information • private information/asymmetric information. We progress, therefore, to the viewpoint whereby the rational choice between organisation and ‘real’ markets is one of information and incomplete contracts. Thus you will later encounter the idea that an organisation is a nexus of (incomplete) contracts, particularly in what I have termed the hierarchical division of labour. Activity You might like to make a preliminary reading of Section 7.5 in D and S, though you will not find it easy at this stage. Organisation theory becomes a search for optimal or efficient non-market contracts. You will find as we progress that whenever economists analyse a situation (normatively or positively) in terms of contracts, they raise issues about: • optimal incentives (see Chapter 4) • the distribution of information – who knows what • the optimal distribution of risk and uncertainty. This is because in a world of incomplete contracting one cannot be certain about the future and therefore the allocation of resources is a risky/ uncertain business. So organisations and markets can, from an economist’s point of view, be studied as the interplay of: • incentive mechanisms • information-revealing mechanisms • insurance or risk/uncertainty sharing mechanisms (who bears the risk/ uncertainty?). The sociological and psychological perspective Activity Read Chapter 6, pp.174–96, in B and H. Chapter 6 in B and H will give you a good idea of how important both psychologists and sociologists view communication to be (i.e. the flow of information between individuals and groups) for the functioning of organisations. They are entirely in accord with economists in this respect. 25 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Psychologists, however, study the process of information transmission in much more detail than economists. For instance, they study nonverbal communication, and link communication into issues surrounding organisational power and manipulation (see Chapter 6) and culture (see Chapter 7). But they agree that information/communication always underpins coordination and control (including markets, of course). We shall see later how economists envision the strategic manipulation of information (in a world of incomplete and asymmetric information) in order to gain advantage. You should eventually seek to link the detailed psychological study of communication to the economists’ approach to information revelation in designing incentive mechanisms. Sociologists, as we have noted, tend to analyse organisations from the standpoint of the operation of rules. Although you will not find the idea addressed in your textbooks, it is useful to find a parallel between sociologists’ use of the term rules and economists’ conception of contracts. Both words are used to describe what – attendant upon the division of labour – actors/agents (should) do in differing circumstances (contingencies). Economists will almost invariably regard employment contracts (complete or incomplete) as coordinating and controlling activities through the use of appropriate financial incentives and monitoring (i.e. observing compliance with the contract). So, information flows and distributions are tied into this way of looking at organisations. Sociologists, on the other hand, are more likely to consider a wider range of mechanisms, but notably power and authority, in enforcing the rules. Note that economists are divided as to whether organisations and employment contracts do or do not involve power relations (see Chapter 6). A lot depends on how we eventually define this difficult concept. But sociologists often regard information asymmetries as indicative of power differentials – those with relevant information are relatively powerful compared to those without it. Weber’s ideal type of bureaucracy may be equated with the economists’ ideal type of complete contracts. Both, of course, serve as exaggerated benchmarks enabling us to reason about what would happen under ‘ideal’ circumstances. But notice that if, as we argued earlier, we have complete contracts then the choice between organisation and market is not determined. So if we choose to equate complete contracts and rules, we are then inevitably held to the idea whereby if a perfect Weberian bureaucracy could be realised (i.e. an algorithm written covering all possible contingencies), then control and coordination could equally be achieved in a market or an organisation. So, the argument for organisation, or shall we say partial bureaucracy, arises only in default, when a complete bureaucracy cannot be so designed. Although not expressing themselves in this manner, a number of sociologists working within the Weberian tradition have suggested that as uncertainties increase, we encounter the limits of bureaucracy. Uncertainty (i.e. incomplete information, particularly about the future) implies that it is not possible to specify in advance the appropriate rules (to complete the contract). So, organisations arise when rules can only partially control and coordinate activities. You will find that many different words are used by sociologists to describe the level of uncertainty – for example, turbulence, unpredictability, noise, and so on. It is best, however, to use the term ‘uncertainty’ as it is common to economics and sociology. 26 Chapter 1: Getting started We might find a common picture as in Figure 1.7. Incomplete information (+) (+) Uncertainty Incomplete rules Figure 1.7 The question now arises as to how organisational control and coordination are to be achieved when the contracts/rules are incomplete (as they always are, but to differing degrees); that is to say, when information about controlling and coordinating activities is incomplete. Sociologists use the terms formalisation and standardisation to describe the degree to which an organisation is bureaucratised or explicitly rule governed (see Chapter 11). It is useful to have a concept for situations where contracts/rules (i.e. pertinent information) are incomplete. Economists use the terms residual or extra-contractual control; sociologists, unfortunately, use many words, but I suggest we use the term discretion. I shall use both terms, depending on context. If the contracts/rules which are designed to achieve the coordination and control of activities are not fully specified, then how should the residual control/discretion be handled? Much of organisation theory is concerned with this issue. All organisations are a mixture of contractual and discretionary mechanisms. Economists will seek to understand the balance between the two in terms of the costs and benefits of gathering additional information to reduce the degree of incompletion. Figure 1.8 summarises our arguments so far. Incomplete information (+) (+) Uncertainty Incomplete rules (+) Discretion Figure 1.8 Note that this way of thinking can still lead to either a market or an organisation. Activity Can uncertainty-generated discretion be best handled within the framework of a market (where price is a sufficient statistic) or an organisation (where employment contracts will operate)? Both psychologists and sociologists recognise that individuals may, in various systematic ways, not perceive things in an entirely ‘objective’ manner, but their perceptions can have real behavioural consequences. (There are some social scientists who even reject the whole notion of an objective reality.) It is important to distinguish between systematic factors affecting perception and random mistakes. Activity Now read Chapter 7 in B and H. You should use the chapter as a resource – it is not necessary to commit its contents to memory. Economists have also recently begun to study systematic cognitive departures from expected utility theory. The ideas are referred to as 27 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach prospect theory. For instance, people are often ‘overconfident’ (underestimate the probability of events that carry negative utility (value)). Economists are currently strongly divided over the extent to which the precepts of prospect theory should be incorporated into mainline theory. 1.5 Organisational control and coordination Introduction Activity Now read Chapter 3 in D and S. In the previous section I urged you to find an intellectual parallel between two ideal types – Weberian bureaucracy and complete contracting. The real world is more complex. Organisations are coordinated and controlled by diverse mechanisms, sometimes complementary, sometimes alternative (substitutes) to each other. D and S, in Section 3.2, review six mechanisms identified by Mintzberg (1989).8 These, in some ways, cut across the two ideal types. Standardisation of work processes, standardisation of outputs, standardisation of skills and standardisation of norms are each finer-grade distinctions of the rules/contract concept. Activity Now read Chapters 14 and 15 in B and H. This subject guide will be organised rather differently from either of your textbooks in order to bring into relief the impact of the three disciplinary approaches. In passing we have identified several major mechanisms for controlling and coordinating activities (and also resources) in the context of incomplete contracts. Let us think of these in the context of a simple principal–agent (PA) relationship. • Formalised rules/contracts: P designs the contract in order to control A’s activity. • Incentives: P designs an incentive mechanism for A. Incentives may involve anything that motivates A. • Monitoring: P observes A. P can observe either A’s input (e.g. effort) or A’s output, or both. • Power and authority: P uses her/his (bargaining) power/authority to shape A’s contract/activity. A uses her/his (bargaining) power in the same manner. • Cultural: P uses or generates beliefs/values in order to achieve A’s compliance (e.g. commitment). • Democratic: P and A use a voting mechanism to shape contracts/ activities. Note that I have not included information in this list as all the mechanisms involve flows of information. Many organisations make use of a mixture of some or all of these mechanisms. You should recognise that there is no settled agreement about how to conceptualise the range of control and coordination mechanisms. You will have to compare different schemes and make your own judgement as to what is most useful. 28 8 Note: the coordination mechanisms are: • mutual adjustment • direct supervison • standardisation: • of work • of outputs • of skills • of norms. (Mintzberg, 1989, p.102). Chapter 1: Getting started Activity For further reading, see Miller (1992) Chapter 1 and Milgrom and Roberts (1992) Chapter 1. The market–organisation continuum So far you have learned to think about whether exchanges/transactions should (or empirically do) take place in a market or an organisation. You have, of course, no answer as yet. But before we begin to fashion one it is essential to realise that the boundary between the two is not clear. Activity Now read Section 3.4 in D and S. Organisations might make use of internal markets – that is to say, they may use a price mechanism, often shadowing (attempting to copy) the price that would operate in an external market to exchange goods, services or capital. They may also be more or less centralised. There are, in addition, many hybrid forms which have some features of markets and organisations. Furthermore, ‘ideal markets’ – or, indeed, markets even closely approximating perfect competition – are rare. Activity Now read Sections 2.5 and 2.6 in D and S. It is useful to think in terms of an organisation–market or contracting continuum as in Figure 1.9. Perfect comp market ‘Real’ market Long-term contracting Hybrid organisations Franchising Decentralised Centralised organisation organisation Figure 1.9 Activity There are some new terms here like long-term contracting and franchising. We shall develop these ideas later, but for the moment think of yourself as a manager/entrepreneur requiring a component to complete your product (e.g. a windscreen for a car); where on the continuum should you locate your acquisition of the component? 1.6 Hierarchy and the boundaries of the firm/ organisation Introduction Activity Now read Section 8.4 in D and S and Chapter 14 in B and H. Four main boundaries of organisations can be recognised: • vertical • horizontal • hierarchical • ownership/financial. 29 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Vertical boundaries It is easiest to introduce the vertical boundary concept by way of an example. Consider the process running from crude oil extraction to retailing of petroleum to the consumer, depicted as a di-graph in Figure 1.3. Each of these sequential vertical transactions can, in principle, be governed at any position on the contractual continuum (Figure 1.9). Note also that Figure 1.3 is constructed at a level of aggregation whereby each node could be further disaggregated to a finer level of vertical transaction or division of labour. But let us simplify for the moment to the extreme poles of the continuum – market and centralised organisation. There are many possible ways of coordinating the transactions lying in between: • all the transactions are markets using the price mechanism (buying and selling) • all the transactions are vertically integrated in one large organisation running from extraction to retailing. If all the transactions are governed by markets, then we have five independent firms, but then these firms could vertically integrate backwards or forwards (except of course oil extraction, which can only forwardly integrate, and retailing, which can only backwardly integrate). The vertical boundaries of the firm/organisation are determined by the pattern of integration down vertical chains (sometimes called value chains). Clearly, what we eventually want to know is: where should/are the boundaries (be) drawn? Horizontal boundaries If an organisation integrates more than one vertical chain of activities, usually as separate departments/divisions, then this is referred to as horizontal integration (see Chapter 11). Hierarchical boundaries When activities are integrated into an organisation then it is usual for the control and coordination to be structured as a hierarchy. We will later study why this is so (Chapter 12). A rather simple hierarchy is depicted in Figure 1.10 below. Figure 1.10 Note that a hierarchy is a graph (see Appendix 1.2 of this guide). There are a number of important associated concepts: • Size of the organisation, N (N = 9 in Figure 1.10). • Size of the bottom level, n (n = 6 in Figure 1.10). • Spans of control, s. The number of immediate subordinates to a superordinate (s = 3 and 2 in Figure 1.10.) 30 Chapter 1: Getting started • The number of levels (sometimes called vertical span), L (L = 3 in Figure 1.10). • The administrative component (N – n). (N – n = 3 in Figure 1.10). • The number of hierarchical relations (N – 1). Note that given n (the exogenous division of labour), as s increases (for whatever reason) then L (the hierarchical division of labour) decreases and vice versa. The hierarchal shape changes. Organisation theory is concerned with explaining why hierarchies take on different shapes in differing circumstances. It is usual to compare hierarchies with non-hierarchical peer groups. Activity Now read Section 8.4 in D and S. Small organisations (up to where n is approximately 15) sometimes adopt a peer group organisation. Peer groups are also sometimes democratically coordinated. Ownership/financial boundaries At this stage we cannot say very much about these issues. The questions are: who should/does provide the capital (debt and equity) and who owns and controls the physical and certain symbolic (e.g. brands) assets of the organisation? These are often the same people, but not necessarily so. You should recognise that we are dealing with complex contractual and principal–agent problems. Activity You might like to read Section 7.2 in D and S. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • organisations as control/coordination mechanisms • assumptions of rational and self-interested behaviour/action • ideal types • division of labour • transactions/exchanges; control/coordination; governance • motives/incentives • competitive markets • normative and positive theory • market–organisation continuum • graphs and di-graphs • roles/contracts/norms • incomplete information/uncertainty • discretion • vertical, horizontal, hierarchical and financial boundaries. 31 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Sample examination question 1. Compare and contrast the assumptions economists and sociologists make when analysing organisations. 32 Chapter 2: Organisational control and coordination: information and knowledge Chapter 2: Organisational control and coordination: information and knowledge Aim of the chapter To introduce how it is that information underpins the various control and coordination mechanisms which an organisation might adopt. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • adverse selection • moral hazard • information and monitoring • information, power and authority • information and culture. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour.(London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). 2.1 Introduction As we have observed in the previous chapter, there are several different ways of controlling and coordinating an organisation, but underpinning them all is the distribution of information and knowledge – who knows what, who needs to know what, who is willing to reveal what they know and who can use what they know and others don’t know to their own advantage and to others’ disadvantage. Activity Read Sections 4.1 to 4.3 in D and S. In recent years, economists have developed a whole sub-discipline (sometimes called ‘information economics’) and many of its insights are appropriate to organisation analysis – particularly the choice between markets and organisations (see the continuum in Figure 1.9). It is important to understand the information implications inherent in the concept of sufficient statistic implied by the ideal typical perfectly competitive market. At equilibrium, the price signal contains all the information a potential purchaser requires – the competitive forces of the perfectly competitive market have already driven out any substandard purveyors. So the purchaser has only to make a decision about the quantity of a good, which is homogeneous across all potential purveyors, 33 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach which he or she wants to purchase. Furthermore, the purchase will have no appreciable impact upon the price. So, at equilibrium, the heroic assumptions about complete information are no longer required. Putting it another way: the search costs in locating a suitable purveyor and the risks of being deceived are absent. A wonderful result – but how are purchasers to know that they are facing a perfectly competitive market at equilibrium? In practice also, as we have noted, many markets are likely to be neither perfectly competitive nor necessarily at equilibrium. Organisation analysts, while appreciating the important intellectual role that competitive markets play in organising our thoughts, need to understand the significance of unevenly distributed information in less tidy situations. Nevertheless, setting out the assumptions that underpin ideal typical models helps us to be explicit about the implications of progressively relaxing them. You should fully understand the following two concepts: • Adverse selection (sometimes called hidden information, precontractual hazard or an ex ante information problem). Adverse selection arises when one or more parties have private (i.e. not easily observable) information/knowledge relevant to a potential transaction. There is thus information asymmetry before the transaction is entered into. You should recognise that both organisations and real markets can be impacted by adverse selection problems. The question is (ceteris paribus),1 which is the best (least costly to monitor/risky) choice when confronted by adverse selection? 1 Latin: ‘other things being equal’. • Moral hazard (sometimes called hidden action, post-contractual hazard or an ex post information problem). Moral hazard arises when a party to a transaction/contract subsequently has an incentive (postcontract) to use their private information/knowledge to act in a way that is not observable to the other party but is to their own advantage and to the disadvantage of the other party. It is important to recognise that it is the anticipation of adverse selection and moral hazard that can make it difficult for otherwise willing parties to enter into a mutually beneficial transaction/contract (organisation or market or hybrid). So, although moral hazard is post-contractual, its anticipation can be pre-contractual and, unless resolved, can prevent a transaction from being realised. If so, then the outcome will be Pareto inferior. That is, both parties could be better off, or one better off and the other not worse off, if the transaction could be arranged. The information asymmetries inherent in situations where adverse selection and moral hazard occur enable actors to act strategically or opportunistically.2 They can and may take advantage of their private information and available unobservable actions. Clearly an interesting question is whether organisational mechanisms can be put in place that will either induce individuals to reveal their information or make their actions more visible. Activity One – if only a partial – view of the choice between organisation and market coordination is in terms of addressing adverse and moral hazard problems. For instance, would ‘buying’ an input rather than ‘making’ it address the issues more efficiently? You can’t fully answer this question yet – but think about it. 34 I hope the above line of analysis has made you appreciate the idea that information has value. Not surprisingly, economists have developed ways of measuring it. 2 We will cover this in Chapter 10. Chapter 2: Organisational control and coordination: information and knowledge Activity Now read Section 1.4 in D and S. Decision trees Pay attention also to the concept of a decision tree, which is another example of a graph structure (see opening section of Appendix 5.1). Trees of this sort will prove useful when we come to study strategic interaction and game theory (see Appendix 5.1 of this guide). 2.2 The psychologists’ and sociologists’ approach Although traditional organisation theory (i.e. the creation of sociologists and psychologists) refers to neither adverse selection nor moral hazard (the terms do not appear in the subject index in B and H), the idea of taking advantage of private information and knowledge is widespread. You have already studied Chapter 6 in B and H. In Chapter 1 of this guide we identified several control and coordination mechanisms which we shall study in the following chapters. But let us now see how information issues enter into each of them. Organisation monitoring We can interpret an organisational hierarchy as, among other things, a complex monitoring mechanism. It is sometimes said that in a hierarchy, directions flow down and information flows up. The basic building blocks of a hierarchical organisation are, indeed, spans of control. An organisation is the union of a set of spans of control. Spans of control are sub-organisations where a line manager (P) supervises a number of ‘subordinates’ (agents A, B,…). Note that it is useful to think of hierarchically structured spans as a cascade of principal– agent relationships. We noted earlier that monitoring can be achieved by gathering information (observing) on an agent’s input (effort, application, etc.) or output (some measure of performance). If these are deterministically related, it does not matter which. The difficult issue arises when it is difficult/costly to observe either of them or when the relationship is not deterministic (see Chapter 4). Imagine, for instance, you are supervising a number of research scientists in a Research and Development department where it is difficult to observe either the effort put in or who is responsible for the scientific discovery. No amount of information gathering is going to make this an easy monitoring problem. But monitoring usually takes place in the context of incentives. Assuming for the moment that P’s objectives are the ones that matter, is it possible to design incentives for A… which obviate the need for close monitoring? Note that, in effect, the perfectly competitive market, with its attendant concept of sufficient statistic, achieves precisely this. One way of interpreting perfect markets is as a control and coordination mechanism which requires minimal or no monitoring and thus flows of information. Alternatively, an organisation will also usually meld monitoring and incentives. But observe that the incentives may be much broader than economic ones. Activity Consider how a church or army might control and coordinate its activities. (Not many people advocate markets in these contexts!) 35 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Let us assume a simple organisation where P spans A and B which is structured, following Weber, as a rule/contract-governed bureaucracy. P then designs the algorithm which specifies, as far as possible, A and B’s activities. In general, as we have seen, the rules, because of inherent uncertainties, will not cover all conceivable future contingencies (incomplete contracting) so situations will arise where there will be potential discretionary activities. In this context it is analytically useful to distinguish between monitoring (and information flows) which are: • designed to understand whether the contract/rules are followed • designed to control and coordinate discretionary activities. Monitoring is subject to adverse selection and moral hazard problems, which now (once we are inside an organisation) will concern not only the relationship between A and B but also their hierarchical relationships with P. Will A and B reveal to P, and P to A and B, appropriate ex ante and ex post private information? We shall need some game theory to address these problems. Activity Now read Chapter 9 in B and H. Pay particular attention to the pages which cover the famous ‘Hawthorne experiments’. Pay particular attention to ‘chiselling’, ‘squealing’ and ‘rate busting’. These are all, from the standpoint of organisational design, examples of information asymmetry. Organisation power and authority Many sociologists urge that ‘information is power’. This would perhaps be better expressed as ‘asymmetric information confers power’. We shall discuss these difficult issues in much more detail in Chapter 6. The central question which arises now is how the distribution of information/ knowledge in an organisation determines the way it is controlled and coordinated and, thus, perhaps also its objectives. If people have different objectives (e.g. workers and managers, or prison supervisors and inmates), it is not unreasonable to assume that they will use their private information to their advantage. Adverse selection and moral hazard can influence people’s bargaining power. However, the hierarchical division of labour is usually based upon a division of knowledge (expertise), which also can be seen as a source of legitimation. Those in hierarchically superior positions with relevant knowledge are accepted as being appropriately qualified to exert power (i.e. give directions). Weber’s concept of rational bureaucratic authority is so constructed: experts have specialised knowledge which others respect and which leads them to confer authority upon the experts. More generally, the mechanisms which transmute power into authority are, according to many psychologists and sociologists, central to the functioning of organisations. Sociologists raise far more fundamental issues about the connection between knowledge and power. They detect power relations to the degree that one actor (individual or collective) can, in some manner, affect the beliefs, affects and values of another actor. Sociologists often express this as determining the discourse. So you will encounter expressions like ‘dominant discourse’ or ‘hegemonic discourse’. We might refer to this as the ‘thought control’ conception of power. If I want to control you, can I ‘make you’ want/believe/like what I want (e.g. follow the dictates of my rules/contract – perhaps even without further incentives)? These sorts of control mechanism are highly complex and difficult to study. This does not mean, of course, that they are not important. Since beliefs, values and 36 Chapter 2: Organisational control and coordination: information and knowledge affects are also conceptually part of another difficult concept – culture – there is a connection to be drawn between the concepts of power and culture. There is a significant divide between those who see cultural control and coordination mechanisms as part of the story about power (many sociologists) and those who don’t (many of those small number of economists who think about these issues). Activity Now read pp.57–58 in B and H. We might ask here how an economist would address these issues. We noted earlier that economists usually start with individuals blessed with (exogenous) often homogeneous preferences (utilities) and options. These options are believed to lead, often probabilistically, to consequences upon which the actor places value (utility). The actor then chooses the best option. This picture can be quite difficult to establish, but eventually we finish with the maximisation of expected utility. This appears to be very different from the sociological approach. But one way of beginning to reconcile them, which we shall study later, is to make either or both of the preferences and opportunities endogenous. This can, under certain assumptions, open up the economists’ picture to the idea that this endogenisation is a species of power relationship. Reading this way can also link into issues of perception. Can one actor constrain the perceptions of another and, thus, limit the second’s recognition of available options? This is a very tricky problem to study. Many Marxist scholars favour this interpretation of power relations between capital/management and labour. They will refer to ‘hegemonic culture’, meaning, at least in part, that one group in society exerts ‘power’ over another by limiting its perception/cognition about what is possible or feasible (see Chapter 6). Organisation and culture We have just noted that there can be a close theoretical alliance between coordination and control through power and authority and by cultural means. If either society or a section of society or, indeed, an organisation itself can in some way inculcate beliefs (i.e. knowledge), then this can impact upon control and coordination – sometimes making it easier, sometimes harder. Particularly important components of cultural control and coordination are trust and commitment. If A and B both believe they can productively transact with each other, but are diffident because a complete contract cannot be signed (adverse selection issue), they may resolve their diffidence if they can trust each other not to take advantage of the postcontractual situation (moral hazard issue). Commitment can play a similar role. So trust relations in the wider society can alter the relative costs and benefits of transacting in markets and organisations and can supplant power mechanisms. Organisation and democracy People can choose to control and coordinate their joint activities by various democratic procedures. Small peer groups sometimes use a form of direct participatory democracy based upon the principle of one person one vote. Larger groups, even when adopting a democratic procedure, usually develop a hierarchical division of labour and are more likely to adopt some form of representative democracy. Different forms of enfranchisement 37 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach can arise. Representative organs can be seen as agents of their electorate (principal). Whereas a Weberian bureaucracy usually attempts to legitimate a hierarchical power distribution in terms of competence (rational bureaucratic authority), a democratic organisation may resort to what we might term rational democratic authority. People see unequal power as legitimate because of the underlying democratic principles. Whatever structure is adopted, members of the organisation need information to enable them to participate as well-informed organisational citizens. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • adverse selection • moral hazard • information and monitoring • information, power and authority • information and culture. Sample examination questions 1. Explain how asymmetric information may influence the control and coordination mechanisms in an organisation. 2. What, if any, is the relationship between organisational culture and authority? 38 Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring Aim of the chapter To provide an understanding of how an organisation can be conceived as a monitoring mechanism. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • observations of inputs/outputs • role of Taylorism/Fordism • control loss • de-skilling • technology and organisation control. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Further reading Guillen, M.F. Models of management: work, authority and organization in comparative perspective. (Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press, 1994). 3.1 Introduction Activity Now read Chapter 13 in B and H. One way of analysing an organisation is as a monitoring mechanism. The hierarchical division of labour is then viewed as a complex monitoring structure. In practice, of course, monitoring is mingled with the other mechanisms we have identified, particularly incentive mechanisms, but it is analytically insightful to separately consider hierarchies as monitoring mechanisms. By and large, it is sociologists and to a lesser extent psychologists who have studied the variety in these mechanisms. This is why the extensive reading you have just done is found in B and H’s book. Economists have usually linked monitoring with incentives in PA theory, by asking questions about optimal incentives. We shall study their approach in the next chapter. You should nevertheless recognise that monitoring and incentives are inextricably linked: the more effective the latter, the less of the former one needs. As we noted in Chapter 2, there are two fundamentally different ways P can monitor A. For example, a first line manager or supervisor (P) can monitor a worker (A) by observing their output (e.g. product) and by observing their input (e.g. effort). The choice is only relevant when output 39 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach is not a known (by P) deterministic function of input. For the moment let us assume P and A are individuals and that P is A’s hierarchical ‘superior’. So it is P who is monitoring A, who in turn is in P’s span of control. Indeed, for the moment, P has a span of one. All this might sound so obvious as not to be worth saying, but when we come to study power mechanisms we shall see that it is sometimes averred that the hierarchical division of labour is a process of mutual monitoring up and down a hierarchy. Let us put this idea to one side for the moment and take what we might quite naturally term a ‘top-down’ viewpoint. P would, in a conventional sense, be called A’s manager. Some important terminological issues, nevertheless, arise in making economists’ and sociologists’ perspectives on monitoring consistent with each other. When referring to monitoring, economists usually mean ‘costs of observing’ or perhaps even ‘costs of observing and drawing useful conclusions’. So, if P can ‘costlessly’ observe A’s output or input or infer the latter from the former, there is literally no need for monitoring. Perfectly competitive markets at equilibrium prices have this characteristic. Some sociologists, though, assume (often implicitly) that there is no such thing as costless observation so they find that monitoring is universal. But as long as we are aware of this and interpret ‘monitoring mechanisms’ as costly, then no difficulties should arise. Of course, economists have standard ways of talking about the efficiency of monitoring mechanisms which equate benefits and costs at the margin (see Chapter 4). Two further points. First, you will find economists also using the term ‘signalling’, whereby the motive to reveal information for monitoring purposes can be examined. Second, economists sometimes distinguish between verifiable observations/signals which can be described ex ante1 and verified ex post2 to a third party (e.g. a court of law) and can be used to specify a formal contract, from observations which fail this test. The latter are more likely to be associated with what sociologists call informal monitoring. In sum, it is probably useful to distinguish between the following: • ‘Costless’ observation of inputs/outputs (usually some sort of ideal type). • Monitoring costs: the cost of the time and effort devoted to observing inputs/outputs. The costs of the administration component (see Chapter 10) may be partially attributable to monitoring costs, though the administrative hierarchy has many other costly functions. • Monitoring intensity: the time devoted to monitoring, which will, of course, imply monitoring costs. We may formulate the monitoring (and incentive – which we will study in Chapter 4) problem as follows: • Assume the output of A is dependent solely upon A’s ‘effort’. • P knows this to be the case. • P can observe/monitor A’s output and infer the ‘effort’. • In so far as the observation of A’s output is straightforward, P will have to devote few resources to monitoring A. P’s span of control (supervisions of A) can go up. P has no need to monitor A’s input, which we might assume would be more costly (i.e. constantly watching A). If however, either P does not know the relationship between A’s effort and output; or P cannot ‘easily’ observe A’s individual output (e.g. A is a member of a group/team which produces a ‘collective output’ (see Chapter 5)); or A’s output is dependent upon his/her effort and other factors which 40 1 Latin: ‘as a result of something done before’. 2 Latin: ‘after the fact’. Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring are costly to observe by P, then, under any of these conditions, P will face a more difficult monitoring problem. P will have to devote time and effort in attempting to overcome the monitoring problems (monitoring costs and intensity). This will negatively impact the span of control of P. If, furthermore, the performance of various agents in a span of control are interdependent (see Chapter 12) then it will be the span of coordination which is affected. In practice, organisational monitoring combines a mixture of observing inputs and outputs. Sociologists, following Weber, picture a bureaucratic organisation as utilising procedures whereby P both sets the rules for A (implicitly signs the contract with A) and monitors A’s performance. A span of control (remember that a hierarchy is built of spans of control) is thus, on this reading, a mechanism for both directing and monitoring. Your intuition should tell you that, other things being equal, the more time/effort P has to put into these activities, the lower his/her span of control will be (i.e. number of subordinates). If we extend the picture to situations which, because of uncertainty, cannot be entirely covered by rules/contracts (i.e. incomplete contracts) then discretion will arise. This complicates monitoring. The discretion can be either decentralised to A or centralised with P. If it is decentralised then P will monitor, ex post, A’s decisions in handling the discretion. If it is centralised, P will handle the discretion him/herself and issue appropriate directives. We will study these issues in Chapter 12. As you might expect, they will have an impact upon the span of control and thus the hierarchical division of labour. An organisational hierarchy can be viewed as a complex structure (depicted as a graph) designed to coordinate and control human activities through direction and monitoring. Figure 3.1 depicts a simple hierarchy with various spans of control and a depth of four. Ultimately, we shall be interested in what determines this variation (see Chapter 12). Peak coordinator Second line supervisors First line supervisors ‘Production line’ Figure 3.1 It is natural to think of the bottom of the hierarchy as the ‘production line’ – though this might be a rather awkward term if we are talking about, say, a church. As we move up the levels we encounter first line supervisors (with, in Figure 3.1, spans of two and three) and then second line supervisors with spans of two; and so on. Viewed this way, the hierarchy is a structure of cascading P–A relationships devoted to directing and monitoring. This enables us to introduce an important concept – control loss. (Unfortunately neither textbook introduces the concept.) If we continue 41 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach to take a top-down standpoint on the objectives of the organisation then we can envisage it as lines of control running downwards from the peak coordinator. There are as many links in a line as the depth of the hierarchy. The hierarchy depicted in Figure 3.1 has 10 such lines. For a hierarchy to effectively control and coordinate the activities of its constituent members, the activities of ‘production line’ members must contribute to the objectives of the first line supervisor which, in turn, must contribute to the objectives of the second line supervisor, and so on up to the peak coordinator. To the degree that this is not the case then there will be control loss. Since we have incorporated the idea of coordination into our definition of organisation, we might also refer to coordination loss (see Chapter 12). To get an impression of the nature of these important concepts, you might think in the following terms: attach an (independent) probability number to each link in a hierarchical line of control measuring the extent to which the activities of the subordinate member contribute to the objectives of the immediate superior. Then the control loss down the line is computed by multiplying these numbers together and subtracting from 1. If they are all 100 per cent, then there is perfect control or no control loss. If, however, any depart from 100 per cent, then we find control loss. Notice that the longer the line (the depth of the organisation), the more likely it is that we shall find control loss and even small departures from 100 per cent will have a dramatic effect (for example, multiply 0.99 together four times). As your reading will have revealed to you, the balance of scholarly activity has centred upon the direction and monitoring of the ‘workforce’ or bottom layer in organisations. Taylorism (or scientific management) and its development as Fordism have had a profound impact upon the study of direction and monitoring. 3.2 Taylorism and Fordism Taylorism (which we encountered along with its alternative name scientific management in Chapter 1) is a process whereby activities (sometimes called jobs or tasks) are decomposed into simpler components. Taylorism can facilitate the production line, which with the addition of mass consumption is usually referred to as Fordism. The term ‘Fordism’ is thus used to describe a wider socio-economic phenomenon which became pre-eminent in industrialised economies until the 1970s. Taylorism/ Fordism spread from the US to other advanced economies from the decade following the First World War, and though its credentials were called into question in the latter half of the twentieth century it continues to have a hold on the organisation of work and design of organisations. Once again, using a di-graph depiction is helpful. Figure 3.2 illustrates some decompositions. (a) (b) Complex task C D A B B A A B C (Decomposed tasks) Figure 3.2 42 D C D Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring In Figure 3.2a the complex task is decomposed into four simpler tasks which are sequentially organised. The operational procedures for each task are then formulated as relatively simple rules and targets (routinisation). In general the work flow can be depicted as a di-graph, and the other di-graphs in Figure 3.2 are possible examples. Taylorism focused upon the lowest level in the hierarchical division of labour although the ideas also had some impact upon the decomposition of managerial tasks. Decomposing complex tasks into simpler ones reduces the difficulty (costs) of monitoring (unless people resist – see Section 3.3) by increasing the transparency between inputs and outputs. Other things being equal, it should increase the spans of control of first line supervisors and accordingly decrease the administrative costs (overheads). It should increase the capacity of management to control and coordinate labour by making performance more transparent and simplifying the incentive system. It also enables managers to reap the benefits of mass production, economies of scale and increasing plant utilisation rates. Although Taylorism and Fordism were initially applied to manufacture (particularly automobiles), the ideas can be applied to the provision of services and to people servicing and handling organisations. It is generally held that, although Taylorism was devised and proposed as a ‘scientific’ method of organising (controlling and coordinating) human activities, it had wider implications: • It de-skilled some categories of labour (Section 3.3), though the story about de-skilling and re-skilling is a complicated one. • It reduced the bargaining power of labour; in the terminology developed here, Taylorism decreased, by simplifying tasks, the information asymmetry about the nature of work which traditionally benefited skilled labour. It also reduced the degree to which the production process could be held up by units of labour – they became more easily replaceable. However, as the system evolved, labour also was increasingly demotivated to use any residual ‘tacit information’ to improve production. • It increased the bargaining power of management and ultimately the owners of organisations; management’s adverse selection and moral hazard problems in monitoring labour were reduced. • It created a role for two new categories of labour – namely, maintenance and quality control workers – both removed from direct involvement in production but with significant bargaining power. They became essential to the smooth running of particularly the production line (Fordism – see below). A new form of information asymmetry evolved, conferring power with respect to management. These workers, being in relatively small numbers, were able to use their bargaining power to elevate their relative wages. • It facilitated the transition from skills-based to mass trade unions. Activity Much has been written about the causes, consequences and diffusion of Taylorism which falls beyond the boundaries of organisation theory per se. You might, however, in this respect like to read Guillen (1994). 43 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Taylorism was an American invention and it is argued that the particular circumstances of North American society were conducive to its genesis and growth. In this respect the potential of home mass markets and the relative disorganisation of skilled labour and lack of trade unions are often cited. Accordingly those societies (e.g. Germany) where neither or both of these conditions were present proved less hospitable to its spread. It is important to understand what Taylor and those who advocated his ideas had in mind when describing their prescriptions as scientific. Firstly, the label ‘scientific management’ clearly gave a legitimacy to the prescriptions; to describe something as scientific is to imply that it is in some sense correct. But, more importantly, Taylor believed that the precepts of scientific management would, if systematically applied, guarantee improved efficiency and thus both management/owners and labour could share in the fruits of this improvement. The fragmentation of labour and appropriate incentives would, indeed, lead to a Pareto improvement (i.e. all could be better off) though this terminology was not used. When Taylor was promoting his ideas the US was very much in thrall to the ‘progressive movement’, which embraced science and technology as the harbinger of the good society. Taylor tended to see people very much as most economists do: as motivated solely by financial incentives and as effort-shy. He also believed that quality would be improved and monitoring costs reduced with the routinisation of production tasks. The design of the fragmented labour process was clearly, in Taylor’s mind, also the prerogative of management. Though these may have been reasonable assumptions, particularly in North America, in the early part of the twentieth century, they became progressively less convincing as the decades passed (see Chapter 5). Furthermore, in societies with deeply embedded cultural traditions which commit people to the intrinsic value of skilled work, the diffusion fared less well. Fordism may be defined as Taylorism, developed as the production line, along with a strong emphasis on economies of scale (minimising unit costs) and mass consumption. It is thus usually used to describe the period in advanced industrial societies from the development, by Henry Ford, of the production line (1914) up to the 1970s. Since then, the virtues of the production line have increasingly been called into question, but not entirely so, and the phrase ‘post-Fordism’ is sometimes used to characterise this subsequent period. 44 The production line evolved, courtesy of Taylorism, from craft-based production. In craft production, the product (e.g. an early automobile) occupied a fixed position on the factory floor and components were conveyed from stock (inventory) and assembled at this point. The stock might have been produced in-house or bought in (‘make or buy’; see Chapter 10). The information required to effect coordination and control was significantly in the hands of the skilled workforce. Contracts (rules) were not formalised and highly incomplete. Management was accordingly to a degree dependent upon the goodwill of the workforce and inevitably decentralised much discretion to the shop floor. The effort level exerted by individual workers was by no means transparent to management though the group output was. Organisations were relatively small by later twentieth-century standards and had wide spans and few levels. The system was probably reasonably stable as long as the potential power (see Chapter 6) of skilled workers was used for the benefit of the organisation/ management. This absent control loss becomes a serious problem. Taylor very much saw scientific management as undermining the power of skilled workers. Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring The production line, in contrast, conveyed the product to a sequence of fixed production positions (micro-vertical integration). Skilled labour gave way to semi-skilled labour and the amount of buying-in declined. Individual effort levels became more transparent to management and determined by the speed of the production line. Contracts (rules) became formalised and more complete. Discretion was almost eliminated. First line spans of control remained high, reflecting the ease of monitoring. As we have noted, spans were also, in so far as they were formalised, high under skilled labour assembly. This brings out the point that identical spans can originate for quite different reasons. In the case of skilled assembly, decentralised discretion and cooperative labour relations permitted high spans. The assembly line, on the other hand, achieved the same objective by reducing discretion and simplifying the monitoring. Payment systems (see Chapter 4) were rather variable, probably reflecting the increasingly contested nature of the speed of the assembly line. Time pay (wage rates) led to annual disputes about rates whereas payment by results led to continual, often costly, negotiation between management and labour (see Chapter 5). The success of the production line and mass production depended upon mass consumption. Ford facilitated this by boosting the wages of his workers and introducing credit, enabling them to purchase the cars they had produced. As the emphasis upon consumption spread throughout the industrial economies, it is sometimes claimed that this encouraged the state to engage in demand management and paved the way for Keynsian economics. By the 1960s auto workers were among the highest paid in industrial societies and this fuelled a debate about the role of the ‘affluent worker’. Production line technology proved less attractive in those countries (e.g. Germany) where skilled labour persisted, where small companies continued to play a strong role in the economy and where national mass markets were more difficult to establish. As the twentieth century wore on, Fordism became increasingly vulnerable to a number of socio-economic developments both in the advanced and in the industrialising economies: • Low-wage industrialising countries could adopt the assembly line, etc., and undercut the high-wage economies (Japan, Korea, Malaysia…). • Mass consumer markets began to sunder into more specialised markets, which also increasingly placed emphasis upon product quality (sometimes called the ‘BMW effect’). This often required cooperation of labour and increased discretion, particularly in respect of quality. • Flexible technologies were developed. • Resistance to the assembly line de-skilling. 3.3 The de-skilling debate Activity Now read Chapter 13 in B and H. Although the division of labour in the assembly line did increase productivity, it was explicitly designed to reduce worker skills. Work on the production line is tedious (simple repetitive tasks; work rate controlled by the speed of the line; little pride in production or product; no involvement in the design of work; boredom; minimal discretion and power, and so on). The reaction of workers to these conditions was complicated, varying 45 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach with individual characteristics, over time and with cultural context. On the one hand, increased affluence enabled some to take an entirely instrumental attitude to their work, accepting relative affluence as a suitable reward for the unpleasant nature of their work experience. On the other hand, others increasingly showed resistance, which produced a serious monitoring problem. De-skilling was interpreted, particularly by sociologists, as leading to both objective (i.e. via technology) and subjective feelings of alienation from work and to proletarianisation (a homogeneous unskilled labour force). This line of analysis was particularly promoted by those of a Marxist persuasion (see Chapter 5). Braverman’s book (1974) is the most sustained effort to argue that de-skilling was, at that time, a near universal trend in capitalist societies. It is now almost universally held that Braverman’s thesis was over-simple – varying trends in what is often termed by sociologists ‘the labour process’ are now acknowledged. B and H give a well-balanced overview of this debate – the story is one of both up- and down-skilling. The important lessons we can learn for organisation theory from this debate, which was not always prosecuted in a politically detached manner, are as follows: • Developments in technology can have a marked influence upon patterns of monitoring (and also incentive systems) and thus on organisational control and coordination and, ultimately, design. • Sometimes, equally effective alternative technologies are available, each respectively allowing more or less discretion to hierarchical subordinates. This eventuality then creates a choice of technologies. How this choice is resolved may depend on the relative power of managers/owners and subordinates within firms and in wider society (see Chapter 6). It may also depend on prevalent cultural values and trust between management and subordinates (see Chapter 7). 3.4 Technology, coordination, control and monitoring Activity Now read Chapter 3 in B and H. Since Taylorism and Fordism have each had such a significant impact upon control and coordination mechanisms, and thus on the design of organisations, it is quite natural to ask the question as to whether the production technology always has such an impact. The viewpoint which suggests this is the case is sometimes called ‘technological determinism’, which is contrasted with the idea of choice. You should, however, use these terms rather carefully. A better term for the former would be ‘a determinant’; thus technology would then be conceived as one determinant among possible others in shaping the control and coordination mechanisms (namely, monitoring, incentives, power authority, etc.). Unfortunately the literature is not always analytically precise and this comes out in B and H’s chapter (e.g. the concept of social technology). For instance, issues of discretion and power, incentives and monitoring are all run together. Activity Although these concepts are all ultimately interrelated, it is important initially to keep them analytically separate. In this context it might prove useful for you to use the box and arrow models introduced in Appendix 1.1 when reading B and H’s chapter. 46 Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring For the moment, we are interested in the degree to which technology may determine the nature of monitoring. First, however, we need to be clear about the converse term ‘choice’. It is important to distinguish between: the choice of (production) technology and the choice of control and coordination mechanisms (including monitoring) given a particular technology. B and H’s chapter is written from a sociological perspective. It might be useful to consider how economists would address the issues raised. Unfortunately, D and S don’t really discuss these issues. Economists always start from the idea of choice. So firms (i.e. their principals) will choose both a technology and control and coordination mechanisms, but (assumed) competitive forces will constrain them, eventually to adopt the most efficient procedures. So it is in this sense that they are determined. I think this is the best way of interpreting the term ‘determination’ in B and H’s chapter. It is implicit in the adoption of a number of the work design systems they introduce you to but since, as we noted earlier, sociologists and psychologists often fail to set their ideas within the framework of efficient control and coordination, the reasoning is unfortunately not made explicit. The economists’ reasoning can break down under either of two circumstances: firstly, if competitive conditions do not hold; or, secondly, if there is ‘more than one best way’ of achieving efficient outcomes. B and H call this latter possibility ‘equifinality’ but you should be cautious about using technical-sounding terms where there appears to be no analytical advantage in doing so. If either of these conditions obtain then there is scope for ‘choice’ in the sense that B and H use the term. If there is choice in either of the above respects, then other factors will shape the technology chosen, the job design and the control and coordination mechanisms (including monitoring) adopted. It has been suggested that principals and their managerial agents may continue to choose technologies and job designs that minimise the skill and discretion (and thus the bargaining power) of workers. There is, however, no systematic evidence of this. B and H introduce a number of attempts to alter the production line. They include: • job enlargement (reducing the fragmentation in the division of labour) • job enrichment (increasing discretion/autonomy) • job rotation (multiple jobs) • autonomous work groups (increasing the discretion/autonomy given to work teams which self-manage their division of activities) • flexible specialisation • self-management • empowerment • lean production. You should make sure you understand how each of these terms is used and how they are interrelated. All post-Fordist attempts to redesign the organisation of work now acknowledge the importance of conceiving of a social-technical system. This merely means that when adopting a technology and designing jobs, it is imperative to take into account not only the anticipated efficiency of the monitoring mechanism but also people’s reactions to the job design. In 47 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach particular, it is important to know whether the nature of work or the job will influence their level of motivation and willingness to innovate. These issues are, however, best considered under the heading of incentives. Activity Now read the recap and revision section of Chapter 3 in B and H. As we noted at the start of this chapter, from an economist’s perspective, the need to monitor activities within an organisation in theory only arises if the incentive (motivation) mechanism fails to perfectly align agents’ activities with the organisation’s (the principal’s) objectives. This is more likely to occur to the degree to which the organisation faces uncertainties of one sort or another and, thus, to the allocation of discretion. At one extreme the manager (principal) may decentralise discretion to an agent, trust the incentive mechanism, and monitor the output. Alternatively, the manager may centralise the discretion and issue directives as to the appropriate activity. A production system can thus be characterised by a number of key variables: • the degree of environmental uncertainty • the mix of routinisation and discretion depending on the level of uncertainty • the design of the system; determined by P or jointly by P and A • the incentive mechanism; individual or group/team • monitoring individual and group • discretion; centralised with P or decentralised with A • innovation; centralised with P or joint with P and A. It may be useful to distinguish between a number of ideal types which parallel the typology given in B and H. I shall formulate these in terms of principal P and agents As. Type 1 • Uncertainty is ‘low’. • P designs a routinised (rule-intensive) production system (i.e. jobs which may or may not be interdependent). • P contracts with As on an individual incentive basis. • P monitors the output of As. • Discretion is low (absent in the extreme case). • Innovation is low. Type 2 • Uncertainty is ‘moderate’. • P designs a limited routinised (rule-intensive) production system. • P contracts with As on an individual incentive basis. • P monitors the output of As. • P centralises the discretion. • Innovation is determined by P. 48 Chapter 3: Coordination and control: monitoring Type 3 • Uncertainty is ‘high’. • P designs very limited routinisation and the distribution of discretion (centralised with P or decentralised with As). • P contracts with As on an individual basis. • P monitors discretionary performance. • Discretion decentralised to As. • Innovation determined by P. Type 4 • Uncertainty is ‘very high’. • P and A jointly design the production system. • P contracts with As on a team (economists’ term) or group basis. • P monitors group performance. • Discretion decentralised to the group of As. • Innovation jointly determined by P and As. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • observations of inputs/outputs • role of Taylorism/Fordism • control loss • de-skilling • technology and organisation control. Sample examination questions 1. Discuss some mechanisms which you think might reduce the level of control-loss in an organisation. 2. ‘Organisations are mechanisms designed to enable hierarchical superiors to monitor subordinates.’ Discuss. 49 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 50 Chapter 4: Coordination and control: incentives and motivation Chapter 4: Coordination and control: incentives and motivation Aim of the chapter To introduce and contrast principal–agent theory with other motivational theories. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • define and explain the conclusions of simple principal–agent (PA) theory under different assumptions about information and risk • discuss various theories of motivation and evaluate their utility. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). 4.1 Introduction It would be difficult to deny that a prime mechanism which provides control and coordination within many organisations is the incentive system. Individuals and groups carry out activities which contribute to the objectives of the organisation because they are provided with incentives to do so. These incentives might be very varied, though, depending upon the factors which happen to motivate individuals. Economists emphasise financial incentives whereas psychologists and sociologists try to incorporate a much wider range of motivations. All the positions on the market–organisation continuum (Chapters 1 and 10) can be viewed as occasioning different types of incentive mechanisms. At one end, perfectly competitive markets offer incentives for a buyer and seller to trade at an equilibrium price. At the other end, a centralised hierarchical organisation makes use of the employment contract (usually incomplete), specifying a rate of remuneration to control and coordinate activities. The question, though, is what sort of remuneration? Some possibilities are: • pay by ‘effort’ exerted; forcing contract • pay by results (PBR) or by output • pay by time – wage rate • promotion • prizes for the best performance. Economists have developed the most coherent theory of incentives. Principal–agent (PA) theory is the result. 51 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Activity Now read Section 7.1 in D and S. As D and S make clear, PA theory is very general. It can be applied to any situation where one or a number of individuals (agents) pursue activities (take decisions) on behalf of another individual (the principal). PA theory is often introduced in terms of the separation of ownership and control between the owners and managers of an organisation, and D and S follow this procedure. In fact PA theory grew out of the debate over ownership and control. However, the theory can equally be applied to the hierarchical relations within organisations. Indeed a hierarchy can be viewed as a series or cascade of PA relationships operating down the line. For the moment, though, let us follow D and S and motivate the general theory in terms of the specific relationship between owners and managers. Activity Now read Section 7.2 in D and S. The possible misalignment of incentives between owners and managers can be offset by a number of mechanisms: • stock market prices • the market for corporate control • the market for managerial labour • product market competition. You should understand how each of these markets can impact upon managerial behaviour and militate against managers pursuing their own objectives. D and S interpret PA theory as normative – how P and A should behave given appropriate assumptions. It is, however, often used as a positive theory. Activity Now read Section 7.3 in D and S. This section requires a little basic economics (e.g. the shape of the indifference curves; curves of equal utility to the manager) but the argument which is developed from Figures 7.1 to 7.4 is accessible to anybody who can interpret graphs. It should not surprise you at this stage in your studies that economists study PA relationships in terms of both rational calculation and material (financial) incentive/motives. As we shall see later, many other social scientists are sceptical about either or both of these assumptions, particularly in a positive sense, but sometimes in a normative sense also. However, for the moment it is important to understand the basic ideas behind the theory. You should pay particular attention to the role of information – who is assumed to know what – in the reasoning. Many of the interesting analytic conclusions arise when information is not symmetric between P and A and where they have different attitudes to risk (see below). Section 7.3.1 in D and S links incentives into monitoring (see Chapter 3) and bonding. Bonding is often also referred to as credible precommitment. Both monitoring and bonding are costly; under the assumptions of the model the manager bears these costs. 52 Chapter 4: Coordination and control: incentives and motivation Activity Now read Section 7.6 in D and S and Appendix 4.1 to this guide. In the Appendix, I have provided a slightly different approach to PA theory using only elementary mathematics (some would say it is oversimple). This reading brings out the relative role of fixed wage rate (w) and payment by result (PBR) in designing optimal incentive contracts, and introduces you to the flexibility of PA theory. The general lessons you should learn are as follows: • Incentive contracting depends upon the distribution of information between P and A; in particular, can P observe (monitor) A’s effort or not? (It is always, not unreasonably, assumed that A can do so.) • Incentive contracts depend upon the risk-bearing attitudes of both P and A. • PBR gives full marginal returns to A but also imposes risk on A. A fixed wage rate, on the other hand, puts the risk onto P but reduces A’s return. Assumptions of simple PA models • P wants to control (definition of organisation) A’s activities so that A’s effort (input) contributes to P’s goals (assumed to be the objectives of the organisation). Putting it another way, P wants to eliminate control loss (see Chapter 3). • Output depends on A’s effort and other random factors (e.g. the weather in D and S’s example of strawberry production). • A does not like effort (at an increasing marginal rate). • A has an available alternative (outside) reservation income/utility. A therefore enters into the contract with P on a voluntary basis. Thus, for many economists, the contract is not conceived as involving a coercive power relation operating between P and A (see Chapter 5). • Alternative information and risk assumptions: Case (1) P can observe (monitor) A’s effort (so can A) – symmetric information. The optimal contract is then a forcing contract. Case (2) P cannot observe (monitor) A’s effort (A can) – asymmetric information. • Optimal contracts now depend upon risk assumptions: – P and A are both risk-neutral; then a franchising/rent contract is optimal. – A is risk-averse and P is risk-neutral (a reasonable assumption in many situations); then the optimal contract is risk-sharing and A will receive a fixed wage component in her remuneration. Case (3) P can observe a signal (i.e. imperfect or partial monitoring) of A’s effort; then if, and only if, the agent is risk-averse, the contract should reflect the signal. Otherwise the franchising contract is optimal. Unlike D and S, I have not only referred to P ‘observing’ A’s inputs and output but also placed ‘monitoring’ in brackets. Simple PA models assume that observations, if they can be made, are made costlessly but are more complicated (realistic models incorporate costs of observing and drawing conclusions; see Chapter 3). 53 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Activity Now read Section 7.6.4 in D and S. D and S identify two important extensions of the basic PA theory. First, where one principal monitors several independent agents (note that I, unlike D and S, insert the word ‘independent’ here). Thus, P has a span of control over a number of agents each operating independently. If the output of the As are interdependent then we need to think in terms of a span of coordination – an idea we will return to later. It is further assumed that P knows that the random inputs for each of the As are identical (this fits the adjacent strawberry plot example rather well but does not work if the plots are dispersed and experience different climatic conditions). P can now compare the relative effort levels of the As to the average level. Above- and below-average performance can only be attributed to differences in effort level. If P is risk-neutral and the As are risk-averse, then the optimal incentive contract will be proportional to: (1) individual output and (2) average output. The second extension is to many periods, so P repeatedly monitors the performance of A. Again, if P is risk-neutral and A is averse then P contracts upon A’s past performance. If A is also risk-neutral then a franchise contract is optimal. You should note that it is the assumptions about risk which make PA theory particularly interesting. When P contracts with A using a fixed wage rate as opposed to PBR then P is, in effect, insuring A against fluctuations in A’s remuneration. Indeed, the major conclusion of the theory is that in the absence of risk aversion on A’s behalf, the optimal relation is for P to franchise A. Fixed (time) wage rates, which are often seen as closely allied with organisations, arise because of A’s risk aversion. Organisations are thus conceived as insurance mechanisms. Activity Now read Section 7.6.5 in D and S. D and S urge you to be extremely cautious in applying PA theory to realworld problems. The theory furnishes an impressive system of interrelated concepts which is central to modern organisation theory but at the cost of rather extreme simplification. You need to match this intellectual elegance with the much less systematic but empirically detailed approach of sociologists and psychologists. So let us now turn in that direction. 4.2 The contribution of sociologists and psychologists Basic PA theory is driven by certain basic assumptions: • P and A are driven by material incentives/motivations. • A dislikes exerting effort. P’s effort is not explicitly brought into the picture, though designing the optimal mix of incentives and monitoring may be conceived as such. • The distribution of information (knowledge) between P and A. • The relative risk attitudes of P and A. 54 Psychologists and sociologists have made the most significant impact in terms of a richer picture of human motivation. They have also explored the origins of differing risk attitudes and the impact of groups upon risk taking (see Chapter 5). In addition, sociologists have repeatedly emphasised the demotivating aspects of many types of organisations. Chapter 4: Coordination and control: incentives and motivation Activity Now read Chapter 8 in B and H. This chapter in B and H is very detailed and in some places conceptually a little unclear. The landmark ‘theories’ you should become acquainted with are: • Maslow’s hierarchy • equity theory • expectancy theory (which you should contrast with the economist’s expected utility theory; Chapter 2 in D and S) • Herzberg’s theory. Each of these theories offers a list of factors which, it is claimed, may motivate individuals within organisations. B and H argue, however, that the social scientific support for some aspects of most of them is patchy. Furthermore, they may also be culturally specific. There is a good recapitulation section at the end of the chapter. As an organisational theorist you need to ask whether or not these theories are relevant to organisational design. You might pay particular attention to the section ‘The social process of motivating others’. This section starts with Taylorism and introduces some important distinctions: • intrinsic and extrinsic rewards • job enrichment • job enlargement • job diagnostic surveys • empowerment. You will scarcely be able to avoid contrasting the intellectual styles of PA and motivation theories. The former is often mathematically rigorous and highly abstract; the latter is less rigorous but much more detailed and empirically rich. Whether or not some of the broader motivational factors could be incorporated into a more embracing PA theory is an interesting intellectual challenge. But from an organisation theory standpoint one would expect organisation design to take account of a richer set of motives than purely financial ones. They may also vary across individuals, gender, social class, culture nationality thus highlighting the distinction between normative expectations and additional motivators and which may both vary with these individual differences. Activity Study the diagram on p.262 of B and H. With this diagram, it should be possible in principle to incorporate all the various motivating factors instanced in the above motivational theories into an extended PA theory. For instance, if you assume that agents find more empowering work less costly, then the indifference curve (I) in Figure 7.5 in D and S may not curve upwards as steeply as the one indicated. Then W0 would reduce and R0 (the return to P) would increase. The problem is that it is difficult to actually quantify these effects. If we ask the question, ‘what, from a PA perspective, is the optimal mix of empowerment and income?’ the mathematics is easy but the practicalities are immense. But organisation theorists need to ask such questions. 55 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach In order to get a grip on a very detailed and imprecise set of concepts, it is useful to reason as follows. Start with Taylorism and a hierarchical structure designed to control and coordinate the division of labour (tasks), at the base of the hierarchy: • Recombine some of the tasks (i.e. job enlargement), and also decentralize some responsibilities (autonomy) to the ‘labourers’ (i.e. job enrichment/empowerment). • Assume this then increases satisfaction and motivation. This may enable an increase in spans of control of first line supervisors or even the eradication of a layer of management. Thus, the costs of monitoring and control and coordination will accordingly be reduced. A reminder of your learning outcomes On completion of this chapter and the essential reading, you should be able to: • define and explain the conclusions of simple principal–agent (PA) theory under different assumptions about information and risk • discuss various theories of motivation and evaluate their utility. Sample examination questions 1. How, if at all, do you think Maslow’s ‘theory’, if correct, would modify the central conclusions of principal–agent theory? 2. How and why would you expect ‘job enrichment’ and ‘job enlargement’ programmes to influence the shape of organisations? 3. Explain why some organisation theorists conceive of organisations as ‘insurance mechanisms’. Do you believe this to be an important insight? 56 Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams Aim of the chapter To develop frameworks for understanding the role that groups and teams play in organisational analysis. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts and assess their importance for organisational analysis: • basic concepts of game theory • team production • theories of group formation • role theory. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Alchian, A.A. and H. Demsetz ‘Production, information costs and economic organization’, American Economic Review 62(5) 1972, pp.777–95. 5.1 Introduction Activity Now read Appendix 5.1 to this guide, Chapter 5 in D and S (excluding Section 5.4) and Chapter 22 in B and H. I have invited you to start by reading the chapter in D and S and the appendix devoted to game theory. In the previous chapter we studied individuals; now we turn to groups (the sociologists’ and psychologists’ term) and teams (more favoured by economists). Groups/teams often need to be the focus of attention in controlling and coordinating activities in the service of an organisation’s objectives. Sometimes these groups can be regarded as sufficiently ‘cohesive’ to treat them as ‘individuals’, but other times not (see Appendix 5.2 in this subject guide). Game theory, as the pre-eminent theory of strategic interaction, is central to modern organisation theory. I shall assume in what follows that you have thoroughly acquainted yourself with the basic ideas in D and S’s chapter. You don’t need to be familiar with the section on auctions but I would encourage you to read this section. 57 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach As you will see, game theory extends the idea of rational choice to situations where ‘players’ need to take account of what other players have done or might do when making their own decisions. Furthermore, they must assume that the other players are also calculating likewise. It is often useful to picture the different positions on the market–organisation continuum (see Chapter 1, Section 1.5) as involving different strategic calculations. 5.2 The economists’ contribution Activity Now read Section 7.4 in D and S. This section introduces the idea of team production. Note what this formally means: the output of a group of individual agents does not depend solely upon the sum of their individual inputs (e.g. skilled effort). Inputs are not separable but complement each other. Alternatively, there are production externalities (synergies) between the individuals so the output of any one individual depends not only on their own input but also upon the input of other individuals. Contrast this situation with the independent strawberry farmers in Section 7.6.4 in D and S. Team production thus entails for a principal a span of coordination rather than a span of control. Coordination will be achieved when incentives (or other mechanisms) motivate individuals to internalise the production externalities. D and S give us an informal rendition of a famous paper by Alchian and Demsetz (1972) which claims to show why the entrepreneur who is remunerated after all the other claimants have been rewarded should control and coordinate (i.e. manage) enterprises, if the production is based upon team production and the manager needs to be motivated to ‘offset shirking’ (i.e. slacking in Appendix 5.1 of this subject guide). The authors’ argument, if valid, is in effect a justification of the capitalist/ entrepreneurial organisation of the firm. So read this section of D and S very carefully, critically assessing each assumption in the argument. To use a phrase we used earlier, it shows why capital should hire labour rather than the reverse – a workers’ cooperative – where labour hires capital (see also Chapter 8). Note here my use of the normative term ‘should’. You will recognise that the idea of team production and the individual propensity to shirk (free ride) can be characterised as an n-person prisoner’s dilemma game. It will be rational for all individuals not to internalise the synergies (defect) unless some guarantee can be found that others will not do so. If shirking is not easily detectable then the collective effort without coordination will be at the sub-optimal Nash equilibrium rather than at the Pareto optimum. Furthermore, promises not to shirk are not binding as there is no incentive to honour them. There are thus gains to be had for all by finding the requisite coordination mechanism for the team. It may help, to fix these ideas in your mind, to think in terms of a simple two-player prisoner’s dilemma as follows: 58 Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams Co-op Co-op Defect 33 14 4>3>2>1 Defect 41 22 Now how can the players achieve the (3,3) outcome rather than the (2,2) outcome? It is useful to think in terms of a number of alternatives, some of which we will explore in subsequent chapters: • Repeated interactions can achieve a coordinated (Pareto) outcome (see Chapter 7). • Self-managed coordination (i.e. peer group self-management or monitoring). Alchian and Demsetz discount this possibility (see Chapter 8). • Cultural cooperative norms preventing shirking or enjoining credible/ trustworthy pre-commitments not to shirk (see Chapter 7). • A motivated (by residual remuneration) specialised monitor (this is Alchian and Demsetz’s favoured solution) with the ‘power or authority’ to punish shirking. I use quotes here for, as we shall see, these authors are not keen to use these terms (see Chapter 6). • Multilateral bargaining (see Chapter 6). Since the Alchian and Demsetz model claims to detect a reason not only for organisations but also for a particular governance arrangement, it is sensible here to look at the variety of governance systems in the real world. Activity Now read Sections 6.1, 6.2 and 7.7 in D and S. Section 6.2 of D and S makes it clear that some economists have sought to introduce more realism into their models, but often at the expense of rigour. The behavioural theory of the firm pictures organisations as a coalition of participants or stakeholders. It is recognised that the inducements to participate vary across the different stakeholders and each stakeholder may be motivated by multiple factors. D and S aver that introducing a vector of inducements does not invalidate the mathematical ideas underpinning PA theory. This is correct, though only if the different factors can be put on a common scale – usually monetary equivalents. You should ask yourself whether you think this is feasible. The behavioural theory also allows for slow adjustment to alternative opportunities (an information issue) through ‘aspiration levels’. Section 7.7 of D amd S provides a succinct overview of PA theory. 59 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach 5.3 The contribution of psychologists and sociologists Social psychologists have been at the forefront in understanding the process of group formation. Part 3, Chapters 10 to 13, in B and H gives a very comprehensive overview of these achievements. You will, initially, need to read these chapters selectively. Make sure you understand the relevance of the main boxed concepts/ideas running down the left-hand side of the pages. Activity Now read Chapter 10 in B and H. Organisations can often be analysed as a structure of groups and it is these which impact on the performance of the organisation. Whereas economists derive their concept of team from non-separable production functions (above), sociologists and psychologists take a broader view and often use the words ‘team’ and ‘group’ interchangeably. First, they distinguish a group from an aggregate of individuals. Groups are collections of individuals (at least n = 2) who identify with the group and develop various relatively durable relationships with each other. Formal and informal groups are identified. Formal groups are part of an organisation’s design, whereas informal groups evolve through interaction. Informal groups often exhibit a tendency to homophily – that is, people with similar characteristics tend to form such groups. Individuals may be a member of more than one group, with the result that groups intersect. It is often suggested that individuals that fall into more than one group, provide an integrative function between the groups (boundary spanners and information brokers), for example the linking pin model. The control and coordination of an organisation has to acknowledge this sort of complexity. To use D and S’s term, things are rather ‘messy’ and invite a complex interplay of the control and coordination mechanisms we are going to study. You should think of the inter-individual relationships in graph-theoretic terms (see Appendix 1.2 of this guide); a set of different relationships – communication, power, etc. – running over the same point set. If you keep this picture in mind it will enable you to organise much of the material in these chapters. Directed relations like ‘communicates with’, generate a di-graph. Relations like ‘interacts with’ generate graphs with symmetric relations. Alternatively you can conceive of a structure of relations as a matrix: if the relations are binary (only recorded as present/absent), then the entries in the matrix will be 1 and 0; if the relations have values (e.g. intensity or frequency of interaction) then the entries in the matrix are accordingly valued. Concepts such as group cohesion can be derived from the proportion of the possible relations that exist in a group. Many of the standard concepts in graph theory are useful in the analysis of groups and organisations (inand out-degree, centrality and so on). You may find it useful to think of the organisation as a formal hierarchy (a tree of who reports to whom), with many other types of relations running over the same point set. Many of these may be described as informal relations that may impact the way in which the organisation is controlled and coordinated. Types of group tasks are recognised though the definitions given are not terribly rigorous. Additive tasks arise when each individual produces the same output independently of others (economists’ separable production). Conjunctive tasks are equivalent to non-separable 60 Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams production. Conjunctive tasks also invoke the role of the most productive in influencing others in the group. The Hawthorne studies, designed to test the efficacy of Taylorism, have had a remarkable impact, culminating in the ‘human relations’ approach to organisation: • the Hawthorne effect is now widely recognised in social science; it recognises that people’s behaviour (actions) can be significantly altered by observing them. Hawthorn effects can either support or undermine the control and coordination of organisations • informal organisations/groups are also recognised as a universal aspect of attempts to hierarchically control and coordinate human activities (rate busters, chiselers and squealers are widely acknowledged) • informal norms can have a either a positive or negative impact upon efficiency (Chapter 7). That is to say that they can either support or work against effective control and coordination. Since both formal and informal groups are found within all organisations, it is important to have some appreciation of how they evolve. Formal groups usually follow the dictates of the organisation design and task or job interdependencies (see Chapter 10). The informal structure of these groups and those with no formal basis seem to follow certain patterns. There have been many attempts to describe and explain the processes which generate these patterns and B and H outline two – those of Homans and Tuckman – though many others could have been outlined. You should become acquainted especially with Tuckman though I don’t think it is important to learn the various terms used. Notice that the central ideas are best understood in graph theory terms. Chapter 10 in B and H concludes with sections entitled ‘Groups and teams’. Notice that the term ‘team’ here is not necessarily used in the manner of economists – so be careful in your written work to define your terms. The table distinguishing between teams and single leader work groups is useful. Teams are here defined as groups which effectively selfmanage the control and coordination of their activities to fulfil a specific purpose (see Chapter 8). Activity Now read Chapter 11 in B and H, but miss out the sections on power and status structure as these will be covered in Chapter 6. You have a powerful way of thinking about structure using the ideas from graph and di-graph theory (see Appendix 1.2 of this guide). This should enable you to organise the copious material in this chapter much more effectively. Note that group structure is the pattern of (dyadic) relations of differing sorts of power, status, communication, liking, role (expectations, leadership, and so on) operating over the same point set (individuals). Groups can also have external relations to members of other groups. Putting aside for the moment power and status relations, let us concentrate on the remaining types of relations. Clearly both a total organisation, and the formal groups of which it is constituted, require a communication structure in order to maintain control and coordination. The standard interpretation of an organisation in terms of ‘directives down and information (monitoring) up’ immediately suggests a twoway communication structure. A formal hierarchy may be regarded as providing such formal communication channels either between individuals 61 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach or groups. The actual communication structure usually has, though, a much richer network of connections than this. Notice that when we say A communicates in some respect with B, and B with C, then this often implies that A communicates with C without there necessarily being a direct link from A to C. Large groups and teams that are coordinated by a leader often develop a hierarchical structure where communication has this property, not requiring face to face contact. However, smaller peer groups may have a complete face-to-face communication structure (see Chapter 12). You might expect group communication to be incomplete but strongly connected (make sure you understand what this means and why it is likely to be the case). Some of the names of networks produced in B and H are in my view rather confusing. First, it is important in any structural analysis to distinguish directed and symmetric or reciprocated links/relationships. Thus, whether we are dealing with a di-graph or a graph. Second, it is also important to be aware that the position on the page of the points has no meaning from a graph theory point of view, though it is often convenient to consider those points mentioned previously as a superior in the hierarchal sense (therefore a tree can be drawn with the peak coordinator at the top of the page). To avoid confusion it is often important when using graphs to adopt the convention whereby it is made clear whether a hierarchical dimension is implied or not. Communication patterns (who communicates with whom), can of course be disaggregated to various types of communication (e.g. spoken, written). Note that written communications are regarded as important in the concept of Weberian bureaucracy (see Chapter 12). Bales’ interaction process analysis, which is described by B and H, has proved useful in many studies for charting the variety in possible interactions in groups. However, when it comes to understanding the control and coordination of organisations, it is far from clear that this level of disaggregation is needed. Nevertheless, Bales’ distinction between task and maintenance activity is important, as in the latter respect it draws attention to emotionally positive and negative interactions, which provides a good bridge to friendship and enmity relations, and their possible impact upon control and coordination. B and H refer this to ‘liking structures’. Individuals in organisations inevitably form friendships and, usually to a lesser extent, enmities. The structures generated (who chooses whom) have been widely studied and friendship choice tends to produce homophilic patterns way beyond what one would expect if friends were to be randomly chosen. Furthermore, reciprocated (mutual) choices and triads of friendship links also occur disproportionally. These choice patterns often provide the framework in which informal groups evolve with individuals identified, and from which they can derive their attitudes, norms and actions (see below). Groups based on friendship usually facilitate help- and trust-based reciprocation between members (Chapter 7). Groups that also exhibit durability tend to develop role structures. The concept of social role is introduced in B and H as a set of expectations about appropriate activities that others hold of the occupant of a position/ identity in a group or organisation. Most sociologists would add to this definition the idea of ‘normative’, making it normative expectations, emphasising the institutionalised (see Chapter 7) nature of social roles. When norms are stabilised into social roles then they are sometimes referred to as being ‘institutionalised’. 62 Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams Once again, notice that the (normative) expectations can be envisaged as a structure of relations (expectations about appropriate activities) running between a set of positions. The in-degree (see Appendix 1.2 of this guide) of a focal position gives a picture of the expectations by occupants of other positions applied to an occupant of the focal position. The out-degree gives the pattern of expectations the occupants of a given position have of the occupants of other positions. So social roles provide a powerful way of looking at durable groups and organisations. Roles continue to ‘exist’ when a particular incumbent leaves the role and the expectations will be applied to a new incumbent. Role structures can, therefore, outlive a particular population of incumbents as long as not too many leave the group at one time. Role analysis is sometimes suggested as an alternative to rational choice theory1 as a way of explaining why people act in the ways they do. It is proposed that they follow the normative expectations appropriate to the positions they occupy rather than make calculations about prospective outcomes. Indeed, this picture once gained great currency in sociology. All social systems were viewed as a set of positions or identities between which normative expectations determined the appropriate activities. If there happened to be contradictory expectations (e.g. if a father and mother – two positions/identities – have contradictory expectations of their child) then the child, as occupant of that role, experiences intra-role conflict. How occupants of roles solve this sort of conflict then requires additional theories. If a particular incumbent occupies more than one role then the normative expectations across the roles may not be consistent – then we encounter inter-role conflict. Various theories, some of which are outlined in B and H, state that the same incumbent within a group, which can exacerbate inter-role conflict, can hold multiple roles. The advantage of looking at groups in organisations in terms of roles is that, given the stability of a role structure to changes in incumbents, the control and coordination of the group can be, relatively speaking, routinised (Chapter 12). 1 See Chapter 1; or you may like to read about Talcott Parsons in course SC1021 Principles of sociology if you have access to it. This picture of the control and coordination of activities, in the absence of intra- and extra-role conflict, can quite naturally be described as being at an equilibrium. People as occupants of positions merely follow the dictates of the normative expectations of their roles. This picture has inevitably been described by some critics as static and over-socialised. Furthermore, one might also ask how the role structure and its inherent institutionalised norms have evolved in the first place. As we shall see in Chapter 7, some theorists assume that evolutionary stories can be told in terms of rational self-interest, while others deny that this is possible. You should note the connection we made earlier between norms, rules and contracts. Taylorism could be viewed in terms of a role structure in so far as the rules are institutionalised. Next we turn briefly to B and H’s treatment of leadership. From an organisational, control and coordination point of view, identifying the task and emotional leaders of groups (formal and informal) enables managers to treat these individuals as opinion leaders and to gain their compliance is likely to achieve compliance of the other group members. Look at ‘individuals and groups’ in Chapter 12 of B and H. They document the ways in which groups may shape the perceptions, performance, behaviour and attitudes of group members. Putting it more generally, how it is that groups may socialise members? I counted several concepts in this chapter, 63 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach deriving from the study of groups by various social psychologists. Rather than learning all this material, what we need to do is to extract from the welter of detail a framework appropriate to organisation analysis. There are probably a number of ways this can be achieved but I suggest the following: First, recognise that we are ultimately interested in how groups may alter the actions of individuals in such a manner that they may contribute or hinder the control and coordination of an organisation. Also note that this is possibly a two-way process – an individual may also alter the actions of the other group members (conversion). For these socialisation mechanisms to be operative we assume that individuals do not arrive at the organisation already equipped to act in the specified manner as a consequence of an ambient culture (see Chapter 7). I have used the term socialisation here, but unfortunately many different words are used in literature to describe how individuals derive their actions (and the constituents of actions, beliefs, affects and values) from their social (e.g. group) environment; influence, persuasion, learning and compliance are examples among those terms you will encounter in B and H. We shall try and disentangle some of these in Chapter 6. But for the moment, since actions depend upon beliefs (what individuals conceive as true and false), affects (what they like and dislike) and values (what are deemed as good and bad), we can recognise three socialisation mechanisms: cognitive, affective and evaluative. Furthermore, as noted above, actions are often guided by norms. We can often ask how individuals are socialised into accepting group norms (e.g. roles). One advantage of looking at things in this particular manner is that it can be made consistent with the economists’ perspective – in effect socialisation provides a possible route to endogenising preferences and opportunities (Chapter 1). Social psychologists recognise that individuals may be placed somewhere on an identity continuum running from personal identity at one end to group(s) identity at the other. Most individuals achieve, at least in part, their self-esteem by a sense of belonging to (identifying with) groups (e.g. professional groups or departments). The greater the level of identity of group members, then the more cohesion the group will attain. The greater the group cohesion then the stronger the socialisation within the group. The greater the group cohesion then the more likely the group will develop negative sanctions against infraction of group norms. Extreme group identity can lead to de-indivdualisation, group think, group distortion of perceptions (Asch experiments), and group obedience (Milgram experiments). Furthermore, members of highly cohesive groups can generate negative orientations to other out-groups leading to intergroup conflict. As noted above, groups tend to homophilia though the source of homophilia, which can be rather complex (e.g. individuals with similar intellectual orientations). Homophilic groups can enhance intergroup heterophobia. Homophilic groups tend to be less innovative than heterophilic groups. All of these considerations can have implications for how an organisation with formal and informal groups might be controlled and coordinated. Group cohesion can work in favour of, or against, effective control and coordination. A highly cohesive group can lead to loafing (freeriding) or facilitation. The degree to which group processes operate against organisational effectiveness need tends to suggest that simple monetary incentives will not solve the problem, but the other control and coordination mechanisms we have identified take on added importance. 64 Chapter 5: Control and coordination: incentives, groups and teams A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts and assess their importance for organisational analysis: • basic concepts of game theory • team production • theories of group formation • role theory. Sample examination questions 1. Discuss the contribution that ‘role theories’ can play in organisational analysis. 2. Explain what is implied by the term ‘team production’. What implications does the term have for organisational analysis? 65 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 66 Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority Aim of the chapter To conceptualise the role of the highly disputed concepts of ‘power’ and ‘authority’ in controlling and coordinating organisations and quasi-organisations. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • bargaining power, power and impatience, risk aversion, outside options, commitment strategies, asymmetric information • contested concepts, force, power, inducement, influence or persuasion, authority • gender and power, Marxism and power. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Alvesson, M. and H. Willmott (eds) Critical management studies. (London; Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1992). Braverman, H. Labor and monopoly capital: the degration of work in the twentieth century. (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974). Lukes, S. Power: a radical view. (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005). Miller, G.J. Managerial dilemmas. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992) Chapter 2. Mills, A.J. and P. Tancred Gendering organizational analysis. (Oxford: Pergamon Press, 1992). Muthoo, A. Bargaining theory with applications. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999). Noble, D.F. Forces of production. (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986). 6.1 Introduction It is often assumed that organisational activities are controlled and coordinated by the power or authority exerted by one person or group over another. Intuitively power is exerted when one actor is capable of gaining the compliance of a subordinate by issuing threats. It is natural to see organisational hierarchies as embodying distributions of relative power. They are sometimes described as mechanisms for conveying commands/rules from the top to the bottom. If it is deemed that those 67 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach issuing commands are entitled to do so, then the commands are regarded as legitimate and it is usual to define legitimated power as authority. Another way of expressing this is that PA relationships are power/ authority relations, rather than governed by incentives. It turns out, however, that these innocuous-sounding ideas are fraught with conceptual snags. Indeed, some social scientists have labelled the concept of power as fundamentally contested. This is a rather fancy way of saying that no settled definitions, acceptable to all, can be found. Furthermore, it often proves empirically incorrect to regard organisations solely as top-down power structures. An alternative view is to picture organisations as a system of stakeholders (individuals, groups, departments and so on) who bargain procuring outcomes proportional to their relative bargaining power (e.g. the behavioural theory of the firm – see below). Indeed, the realised objectives of the organisation may be the product of bargaining. If so, then the control and coordination mechanisms and objectives of an organisation are codetermined. I should warn you that these are highly controversial issues about which there are no settled viewpoints. Many economists (though not all) are rather reticent about invoking the concept of intra-organisational power in the context of competitive environments. A competitive labour market, they aver, leads to voluntary employment contracts which do not entail any power relationship between, shall we say, P and A. We will return to this argument later. Activity Now read Chapter 6 in D and S. In the context of the behavioural theory of the firm (which, remember, is not the standard neoclassical model), D and S introduce you to the idea of bargaining power. Economists have been at the forefront of developing the concept of bargaining (power), often making use of gametheoretic precepts. Before we delve into some of the deeper issues about organisation power, it is helpful to explore how they do this and then to compare their approach to that of sociologists. 6.2 Bargaining and power Unfortunately D and S do not analyse bargaining power in any depth but I shall provide a non-technical overview in the following paragraphs. If, however, you want to study things more thoroughly (not essential for the course) then you might like to look at the early chapters of Muthoo (1999). Economists note that bargaining is a common relationship, both between and internal to organisations. They want to understand bargaining from the standpoint of rational actors. Let us motivate our analysis in terms of bargaining between management (M) and labour (L) or perhaps trade unions. What might determine the wage rate if there is room for bargaining (i.e. the labour market is not competitive)? Remember, in perfectly competitive labour markets, there is no room for bargaining over wage rates. Assume M has a maximum she is prepared to pay L, P(max), and L has a minimum she is prepared to work for, P(min). If M and L can agree (contract) on a rate anywhere between P(max) and P(min) then both are better off than if they fail to contract (Pareto improvement). Thus, M and L have a common interest in striking a deal but conflicting interests about where, between P(max) and P(min). 68 Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority Bargaining is the process of reaching a voluntary contract which will stick. There are two important aspects of bargaining: • the outcome – the distribution of the ‘bargaining surplus’ (between P(max) and P(min)) • efficiency – minimising the bargaining costs in reaching an outcome. The theory of bargaining suggests factors which determine both the outcome and associated bargaining costs. M has bargaining power to the degree that the outcome is close to P(min) and M’s bargaining costs are low. L has bargaining power to the degree that the outcome is near P(max) and L’s bargaining costs are low. Note that any division of the bargaining surplus is a Nash equilibrium (see Appendix 6.1 of this subject guide). The factors determining bargaining power are: • bargaining time and impatience • risk aversion • outside options • credible commitments • asymmetric information. We shall look at each of these and start with the assumption of complete information. Activity Now read Appendix 6.1 of this subject guide. Bargaining time and impatience Assume both M and L would prefer to contract earlier rather than later: that is, time to agreement constitutes a bargaining cost for both parties. This often seems a very reasonable assumption. Then, other things being equal, if L and M have equal impatience then they will split the bargaining surplus equally (a particular Nash equilibrium). The general principles are that, for both M and L: • bargaining power is proportional relative to patience • bargaining costs are proportional to impatience. Note that to get simple results each party must be assumed to know both the other’s patience and bargaining costs. In the context of sequential bargaining (each making offers and counter offers), then backward induction will indicate a Nash equilibrium at the outset (see Appendix 6.1). Patience Formal results aside, what determines relative patience? • L and M’s available contracting alternatives (see below). • M’s inventories and L’s saved resources or strike fund. Note that the better off will in general have more patience and can therefore distribute the bargaining surplus to their advantage. This picture thus suggests that bargaining will exacerbate inequalities. The strategies for increasing the bargaining power available to either party are: • reduce one’s own bargaining costs by increasing one’s patience • decrease your adversary’s patience by increasing their bargaining costs. 69 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Note, however, that these strategies will also be costly. Therefore, one needs to balance these costs against prospective gains in terms of a favourable outcome. Risk aversion There will always be a risk that bargaining will break down because circumstances change (often described as ‘exogenous shocks’). There is, thus, also an inherent risk in not settling now. So the relatively risk-averse will have higher bargaining costs. Once again, one would expect those with fewer resources to be relatively risk-averse. Outside options Assume M and L have the same patience and risk aversion; then they should split the bargaining surplus in half. The leading idea is that if either party has a credible alternative partner with a better offer then this will increase their bargaining power. The party can use the credible threat to contract elsewhere. Note that in perfectly competitive markets there is no space for credible threats. Commitment strategies If either party can commit (prior to or during bargaining) to a division of the surplus (‘I will not pay more than X’) that favours them and this is seen as costly to abrogate, then they may increase their bargaining power. The commitment is credible to the degree that stepping down is costly to the party concerned. Commitment often works best when a bargainer is bargaining on behalf of others; for example, a trade union leader who would lose credibility with the membership if they stepped down. An adversary will not call your bluff if the commitment is credible. Asymmetric information All the above approaches to the sources of bargaining power assume that each party is fully informed about the opponent’s resources, preferences, risk attitudes, commitment, etc. The underlying games are, as you would expect, ones of complete information. In practice these assumptions are often over-strong and we have to move to games of incomplete information (see Appendix 6.1 of this guide). When information is not complete, bargaining can be a bewildering mixture of processes. First, learning about your opponent; second, communicating information about oneself (perhaps false); and third, achieving an outcome. In general, bargaining will be inefficient – bargainers will use private information to their own advantage and send false signals. For example, in management– labour bargaining M may be ignorant about L’s P(min), resources, patience, risk aversion and outside options. Likewise M may also be similarly misinformed or ignorant about L. This is why the simple model in Appendix 6.1 of this guide is only really useful to gain an appreciation of some basic concepts. In practice, bargaining raises issues about credible threats and promises and haggling. We will return to these issues after studying how sociologists and psychologists approach the idea of power and kindred concepts. 6.3 Behavioural theory of the firm You will have seen in D and S that the behavioural theory of the firm is an attempt to introduce more realism into the theory of the firm than that which is found in the neoclassical conception. The objectives 70 Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority of the firm are interpreted as the bargaining outcome among several stakeholders rather than being determined by the ultimate principal – usually the owners. It provides a way of introducing bargaining power and theory into our understanding of how organisations are controlled and coordinated. It also introduces a richer model of individual motives by suggesting that actual returns are compared with aspirations in determining an individuals’ likelihood of accepting a contract appropriate to the particular stakeholder. If returns (of whatever it is that motivates individuals/stakeholders) are at least as good as aspirations then the contract will stick, if not a search for alternatives will ensue. So, what determines aspirations becomes a central analytical concern. However in this respect, information about alternatives is often difficult to ascertain due to information asymmetries, thus, lags in adjustment of aspirations are likely. All of this is fairly remote from the picture whereby the competitive markets determines the conditions under which stakeholders accept contracts (of the employment, supplier, consumer). One of the important conclusions of the behavioural theory suggests that transactions internal to organisations, where there are inventory costs in maintaining the transaction, cannot be coordinated without inducing conflicts between the transacting parties. D and S consider the transaction between production and sales managers. 6.4 Sociologists’ and psychologists’ approaches to power and kindred concepts Activity Now read Chapter 22 in B and H. Reading the above will give you a good impression of the conceptual diversity attached to the idea of power On first reading of this, don’t worry if you feel a little dismayed. It is sometimes difficult to understand what is being said and where the differing conceptualisations agree and differ. Unfortunately, some of the writing in this area does not match the requirements of rigour of modern social science. You should be rather wary of grand-sounding terms like ‘field of force relations’ as they are used so broadly and imprecisely as to carry little clear analytical meaning. Giving a name to a complex set of mechanisms (often with grand, apparently legitimising associations from the natural sciences) is not really a contribution to social science. So you will need to exert your own judgement when reading Chapter 22 in B and H (this is not a criticism of B and H but rather of some of the literature they review). As I said at the start of this chapter, many concepts are highly contested. I shall later try to guide you through the maze but you should recognise that it is my route and many would suggest alternatives. Before looking at conceptual matters, let us think about the role of power, however defined, in coordinating and controlling activities within organisations. Let us go back to the basic idea (see Chapter 2) as to whether a transaction should be left to the market or internalised in the (hierarchical) firm. You might now like to think of a third possibility, whereby the partner to the transaction could bargain, thus keeping the transaction outside an organisation but not in the market (see Figure 6.1). In competitive conditions (and equilibrium) there is, of course, no room for bargaining. But in ‘real markets’ there is. However, in ‘real conditions’ the simple bargaining model, in Appendix 6.1, of this guide will not apply. 71 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach If extra-organisational bargaining is adopted as a third alternative, then all the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard will be present, resulting in ‘haggling’ and, thus, bargaining costs. Indeed, these conditions which undermine the market as an appropriate transaction mechanism also undermine bargaining. Competitive markets Real markets Extra organisation bargaining Figure 6.1 Activity Now read Appendix 6.2 of this guide. You might also like to read Miller (1992) Chapter 2. Appendix 6.2 gives you, in outline, reasons why bargaining between organisations is likely to fail as a control and coordinating mechanism. But of course organisations often do bargain. You should recall the point I made in Chapter 1. Positioning a transaction on the continuum depicted in Figure 6.1 is often a matter of ruling out some sorts of ‘governance’ in favour not of the ‘first best’ but just a superior way of doing things. You have already read Chapter 6 in D and S, which shows how advocates of the behavioural theory of the firm introduce the concept of bargaining power. By way of comparison, B and H propose the ‘rational model’ of organisation (broadly speaking, the classical economists’ model) is compared with the ‘political model’ (i.e. the power perspective). The key idea underpinning both the behavioural and political models is that organisations are coalitions of individuals and various groups which through their relative bargaining power determine: 1. the operational objectives of the organisation 2. the coordination and control of activities. Notice how this departs from the incentives standpoint. There the mechanisms which hold people together in pursuit of organisational objectives are voluntarily entered incentive contracts. The political model, on the other hand, puts power in this position. Needless to say, real organisations are usually a bit of both. You will notice when reading B and H that they counterpoise what they term the rational (with an idiosyncratic definition) and the political models of organisations. This nomenclature is, I think, unfortunate. As we have already seen, a rational approach to bargaining is perfectly feasible. I advise you to follow the distinctions used in this guide. Furthermore, people may actually seek power; it may actually enter their utility function/goals/motives, so they can then quite naturally be described as rationally seeking power. Psychologists have studied the ‘need for power’ and related concepts, the need for affiliation and the need for achievement, which reminds us that the motives of individuals can vary (see Chapter 2). 6.5 Contested conceptual matters I fully expect that you will feel somewhat bewildered at this point in your studies. There is a wealth of material to think about, but don’t become discouraged. 72 Organisation Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority Economists study bargaining power from a game-theoretic standpoint, which is sometimes rather technically demanding, and sociologists and psychologists introduce us to a plethora of, often cross-cutting, concepts. As organisation theorists we need a picture which is both consistent with the precepts of bargaining power theory and which slims down the sociologists’ and psychologists’ conceptual diversity. First, it will not have escaped your notice that bargaining power theory detects the presence of power in the ability of actors to determine the division of a bargaining surplus according to their differing interests, whereas sociologists tend to see power as an inter-actor concept, namely the degree to which one actor can gain the compliance of another when the latter has differing objectives/interests to the first. This difference in focus should not cause concern: it is often possible to derive the latter from the former. Consider M and L bargaining over a wage rate once again. They arrive, given their relative bargaining power, at an ‘agreed rate’. Then if M can get L to work at that rate we can quite naturally speak of their relative interpersonal power. Recall that for any of this reasoning to be applicable there must, from an economist’s point of view, be room for bargaining in the first place – that is, some departure from perfectly competitive conditions. So let us look more closely at the inter-actor conception and continue to motivate the argument in terms of the relationship between M and L. How can M gain L’s compliance and, thus, control and coordinate their activities in ways that are distinct from M providing incentives (not only financial ones)? Distinguish the following types of mechanisms: • force • power • inducement • influence/persuasion or manipulation • authority. Force This implies actual physical constraint: M is able to gain L’s compliance using physical means. Note that this is not the same as using threats of physical compulsion. Gaining compliance by force is not usually part of organisational life except perhaps in extreme conditions – in prisons, for instance. Power M is able to gain L’s compliance by the use of credible threats (negative sanctions), including, possibly, the threat of force. Note that the threat to remove rewards is covered by this definition. However, note also that this would not amount to a credible threat if L has an equally good alternative to move. It is this sort of reasoning that allows Alchian and Demsetz (1972, Chapter 5), to aver that employment contracts are not underpinned by power in perfectly competitive labour markets (see below). Nevertheless, the behavioural theory of the firm and uncompetitive markets surely allow for the use of threats (implicit or explicit) to maintain coordination and control. Inducement M is able to gain L’s compliance by the use of rewards (positive sanctions). But this looks like incentives (see Chapter 4), so why should we add this 73 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach term to our vocabulary of mechanisms? The reason is that some scholars regard differential endowment of the assets which can be used to reward L as a source of ‘power’. If this (contested) conceptualisation is followed then transactions between unequally endowed parties always involves a type of power; inducement among equals always embodies a sort of power! Influence/persuasion and manipulation M is able to gain L’s compliance by changing L’s preferences/perception of interests/perception of opportunities. Influence can, conceptually, be subdivided into situations where: (a) M increases or maintains L’s perception of opportunities, etc., and (b) when M restricts L’s perception of opportunities, etc. The latter might be termed coercive compliance or manipulation (or even indoctrination) and is certainly a species of ‘power’ in the generic sense. The former, however, covers learning and socialisation and often group pressure (see Chapter 5). Drawing conceptual boundaries between these various concepts (often named in various ways) causes much philosophical wrangling. The idea that language and discourse can be a source of ‘power’ is closely related to these distinctions, as is the concept of ideology. The Marxist conception (see below) whereby the ruling ideas are the ideas of the ruling class also fits this conceptualisation. Whether one should think in terms of the manipulation of preferences or interests or opportunities or, indeed, beliefs, values and affects which underpin them is a moot point. If you want to chart your way around this conceptual/ philosophical thicket, then the best read is probably still Lukes (2005). Economists show little sympathy for these sorts of debate, usually regarding people as being able to ‘freely’ form preferences, perceive opportunities and recognise their own interests. Authority In so far as L sees it to be legitimate that M has relative power/ influence/inducement over them, then the capacity to gain compliance is defined as authority.1 As we noted earlier, in perfectly competitive conditions, inducements are identical to incentives. Alchian and Demsetz (1972) write as follows: It is common to see the firm characterized by power to settle issues by fiat, by authority or by disciplinary action superior to that available in the conventional market. This is a delusion. The firm does not own all its inputs. It has no power of fiat, no authority, no disciplinary action different in the slightest degree from ordinary market contracting between two people. I can ‘punish’ you only by withdrawing future business or by seeking redress in courts for any failure to honour exchange agreement. This is exactly all that any employer can do. Thus, for these authors (and for many economists), the move from market to organisation/firm is not one that introduces power relations into the process of coordination and control. Can we make this picture consistent with the sociologists’ contrary viewpoint? Note first that if the above conclusion is drawn in the context of complete contracting and perfectly competitive markets then, as we saw in Chapter 1, there is no way of choosing between organisational and market transactions. If, nevertheless, an organisation is chosen then the Alchian and Demsetz conclusion is probably correct. Some sociologists (notably Marxists, see 74 1 You may like to read about Weber here, as presented in course SC1021 Principles of sociology if you have access to it. Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority below) would still draw attention to any inequality in resources brought to the transaction as being indicative of power – be it in a market or an organisation. So for these scholars any position on the market– organisation continuum would involve power unless, in some sense, the resources they bring to the transaction are ‘equal’. Equality here is difficult to define but it would mean that all parties to transactions would have the same purchasing power given equilibrium prices. However, in the world of incomplete contracts and ‘real markets’ (Chapter 1) is there any reason, in opposition to Alchian and Demsetz, to invoke power relations? Most scholars would answer in the affirmative at any point in the market organisation continuum. Various information asymmetries (Chapter 1) and differential endowments enable bargaining and, thus, ‘power’ to enter the picture. 6.6 Influence, groups and individuals Groups – even organisations – can, as we saw in Chapter 5, socialise and thus influence or manipulate individual members. I shall use the term ‘influence’ as defined above. Psychologists have studied these processes more closely. They speak of group pressure and individual leadership but also use many other terms. We have already encountered the Hawthorne effect in Chapter 5. Activity Now read Chapter 11 in B and H. You will need to read this chapter with caution as the authors often refer to power when they are thinking in terms of what I have termed influence (i.e. group processes changing people’s perceptions, beliefs and attitudes). These ideas to a degree overlap the content of the next chapter on culture. Again you are confronted with a cornucopia of overlapping ideas and I would encourage you to try to fit them into a framework like the one I have given you above. Activity As you read Chapter 11 in B and H, ask yourself what are the basic types of mechanisms at work. Attempt to keep the number of concepts that you use to understand the various mechanisms to a minimum. Make sure you cover the highlighted concepts on the lefthand side of the pages in B and H. 6.7 Gender and power It is sometimes suggested that organisational life reflects male dominance, and theory and description are accordingly not gender neutral. This approach to organisations is part of a much broader critique of both society and the social sciences as serving the interest and power of the male gender. This shows up particularly in: (1) job design and (2) unequal opportunities for women. There is also strong statistical evidence that in many societies women earn, on average, less than men – even for the same job; though the disparity is reducing in most countries. But why is this pattern observed? A number of explanations have been proffered for gender disadvantage. First, certain jobs which attract lower incomes are regarded as more appropriate to women – there may be strong norms to this effect. Even women may regard these as legitimate and not aspire to promotion, 75 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach etc. So the query shifts towards the evolution of these norms and their legitimacy (see Chapter 7). Second, because women are often temporarily absent from the labour force for child rearing they may be less attractive to employers. Third, women have different values about cooperation and competition and organisational life with regards to male values (notably more competitive). Women may also not ‘network’ as effectively as men and networking improves prospects. There is recent evidence that mixed gender teams perform better than single gender teams. The question you might ask is – would you expect, if women were to design the control and coordination system of an organisation, that it would be different from male-dominated organisations? Activity Possible additional reading: Mills and Tancred (1992). 6.8 Marxism and power Marxism construes productive organisation structures as a form of domination. In capitalist societies it is capital that dominates labour. The employment contract is objectively exploitative in the sense that, according to the labour theory of value, capital expropriates labour’s value creation (this is a highly contentious idea). In so far as labour fails to recognise its exploited status, it suffers false consciousness or, to use the concept developed in this chapter, it is (ideologically) manipulated by capital. Labour has an objective interest in eradicating exploitation. Thus productive organisations are the source of class dynamics in society whereby labour comes to recognise its exploited status and eventually mobilises to change society. Within the framework of this grand story, organisation theory should chart the micro conflict and bargaining between capital and labour. Scholars working in the Marxist tradition often speak of ‘hegemonic culture’, implying that culture (which for present purposes might be conceived as languages, beliefs and values) plays a coercive role within both organisations and wider society. You have already encountered Braverman’s (1974) Labor and monopoly capital analysis in Chapter 1 suggesting that scientific management/ Fordism, by de-skilling labour, increases the power of capital. Braverman predicted that de-skilling would be extended to white-collar workers and eventually to management. So, organisation theory itself, which interprets these trends as purely in pursuit of efficiency, becomes one ideological means of maintaining the supremacy of capital and we should accordingly search for an alternative radical theory which has the objective of eliminating exploitation and liberating labour. Labour process theory enjoins us to recognise that the attempt to control and coordinate is inherently unstable. For instance, Hyman writes as follows: The function of labour control involves both the direction, surveillance and discipline of subordinates whose enthusiastic commitment to corporate objectives cannot be taken for granted and the mobilisation of discretion, initiative and diligence which coercive supervision far from guaranteeing, is likely to destroy. Empirical evidence does not lend support to Braverman’s Marxist-inspired predictions. First re-skilling often takes place alongside de-skilling and the differentiation in skills among workers is complex and not adequately 76 Chapter 6: Coordination and control: power and authority pictured in any simple model. It is probably true, however, to say that these complex and ill-understood processes are shaped by bargaining and, thus, shifting balances of power between different levels of management and various groups of workers. Activity Possible additional reading: Alvesson and Willmott (1992); Noble (1986). 6.9 The role of power and allied concepts in organisation theory Few, but not all, would deny that organisations are often at least in part hierarchical structures of power and perhaps influence – ‘commands down and information for monitoring up’. Those in a position of power characteristically design the organisation, appoint subordinates and select a mixture of incentives and monitoring, and issue threats where and when appropriate to maintain control and coordination in order to achieve their objectives. But all of these things can be bargained about and the behavioural theory of the firm captures the idea whereby multilateral bargaining (of which, incidentally, there are at the moment no adequate theories) among a wide range of stakeholders determines the outcome. Contrast this picture, once again, with the classical theory of the firm operating in perfectly competitive markets. This theory has very little to say about organisation design; firms are black boxes compelled, if they are to survive, to operate in a manner which benefits their principals. In this abstract world there is no call, according to most economists, to evoke any concept of bargaining or power or any related concepts. However, some scholars even in this rarefied world would demur. They would say that the exogenous assets that people are endowed with and bring to competitive markets are sources of differing power (purchasing power). Indeed, some would go so far as to construe differing genetic endowments – for which we cannot claim any responsibility – that confer power. You need to think about these issues though I suspect they will remain ‘fundamentally contested’. Modern social scientists study the socialising impact (be it influence or manipulation) of social groups upon the individual by studying what they term structural effects. For example, if we expect any individual’s performance to be a function of his/her ability (however measured) and level of motivation. Indeed, we expect these two variables to interact (i.e. multiply) in their impact upon performance since motivation without ability, or the reverse, is unlikely to generate much performance! This however, only takes us part of the way in providing an explanation of individual performance. It turns out that performance is also a function of the performance, ability and motivation of those to whom the individual is connected by, for example, friendship etc. (i.e. the network of connections – Appendix 1.2). In large groups these effects can often be proxied by the average levels of performance motivation and ability in the individual’s group. Indeed, the story is even more complex because the performance of individuals is also sometimes a function of the average performance of the groups to which the individual’s membership group is connected. These average effects are sometimes called endogenous (in the case of performance) and exogenous structural effects. But in addition, as we noted in Chapter 4, individuals can also ‘influence’ the group. Contemporary social science is now enabling us to unpack the two-way process under the rubric of coevolution. The technical problems 77 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach in so doing are, however, quite daunting. Nevertheless developments like this are increasingly enabling us to address the cross level effects discussed in Appendix 5.1. Meanwhile the lesson that organisation theorists can take from these developments is that if we centre attention upon organisation performance (i.e. achievement of objectives) then, in so far as this is a function of individual performance, the networks that individuals construct can have a profound impact. These networks may provide channels for the exercise of power, inducement, influence and manipulation. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • bargaining power, power and impatience, risk aversion, outside options, commitment strategies, asymmetric information • contested concepts, force, power, inducement, influence or persuasion, authority • gender and power, Marxism and power. Sample examination questions 1. Do you think that Alchian and Demsetz are correct in their analysis of the employment contract? 2. Would you expect, if women were to design the control and coordination system of an organisation, that it would be different from male-dominated organisations? 78 Chapter 7: Coordination and control: culture Chapter 7: Coordination and control: culture Aim of the chapter To understand how various components of ‘organisation culture’ can contribute to organisation control and coordination. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • trust, reputations, helping culture, bilateral and multilateral reciprocity, altruism, commitment • norms and institutions. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Abell, P. ‘A model of informal structure (culture) of organisations’, Rationality and Society 8(4) 1996, pp.433–52. Kreps, P. ‘Corporate culture and economic theory’ in Alt, J. and K. Shepsle (eds) Perspectives on positive political economy. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990). Miller, G.J. Managerial dilemmas. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992). Richerson, P.J. and R. Boyd ‘The evolution of human ultrasociality’ in EiblEibersfeldt, I. and F.K. Slater (eds) Ethnic conflict and indoctrination. (Oxford: Berghahn, 2001). 7.1 Introduction It is generally held that what we might broadly term cultural factors can have an impact upon individual motivation and, thus, affect the control and coordination of organisations. A problem, however, is that the idea of culture itself is used to cover so many different phenomena – thus, definitions abound. Sociologists tend to emphasis shared beliefs, values and affects, which become embodied in norms about appropriate activity. Economists have given the term ‘culture’ scant attention but they have developed a remarkable literature on trust, a concept which many would incorporate into a definition of culture. But beyond this it is to sociologists and to a lesser extent psychologists that we have to look for inspiration though, in addition, management theorists have also latched on to the idea whereby corporate culture can have an impact upon corporate performance. I think I should warn you that much of the writing in this 79 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach area is very diffuse; the research upon which it is based sometimes leaves a great deal to be desired and it does not always come up to the standards of modern social science. Activity Now read Chapter 19 in B and H. The literature covered by B and H is rather descriptive but captures well the diversity of conceptualisations. I do not think you should memorise all the terms introduced, but rather try to develop an analytical framework, which can construct ‘culture as a mechanism for control and coordination’. Schein’s tripartite categorisation shows how varied are the phenomena which can be allowed to fall under the rubric of culture. Despite the diversity there is a common theme underlying the various approaches to organisation culture which centres our attention upon the sources of cooperative activity for the purposes of the organisation’s objectives. In the context of our definition of organisation, in terms of the control and coordination of symbolic resources and activities, we can see organisation culture as one mechanism among several others for achieving this objective. You might ask why I have shifted terms from coordination to cooperation. I have done so to signal that the analysis of cultural mechanisms is often best conceived in game theoretic terms where, in the context of coordination games, the term cooperation is widely used. However, the terms cooperate and coordinate are interchangeable. Of course, cultural factors can also create patterns of cooperation which are inimical to organisation objectives. Indeed, in the context of the behavioural theory of the firm (Chapter 6), each stakeholder group could conceivably cooperate in pursuit of its own bargaining power. The cultural differentiation of groups/departments/functions in organisations can impose significant coordination (integration) costs and lead to control-loss (Chapter 12). It will not have escaped your attention that the impact of culture upon an individual is covered by the concepts of socialisation and, thus, influence and manipulation as defined in Chapter 5. The impact of culture denotes a mechanism, which can change peoples’ preferences by adjusting their beliefs, values and affects. As recorded there, the concepts used to denotate ‘power’ relations and cultural socialisation overlap. As a consequence the contested nature of the concepts describing power relations extends to cultural relations. For example, Marxist scholars will interpret control and coordination achieved through cultural mechanisms as variety of manipulation. It is useful to distinguish between cultural factors that are generated (evolve) within an organisation (probably at a cost) and those that derive from the ambient culture(s). Hofstede’s approach to national cultures has gained much prominence as has the Globe study which extends Hofstede’s five dimensions of cultural orientation to nine. It is worth interpreting Hofstede’s dimensions within the framework of control and coordination. • Social orientation: cultural norms can differ in the extent to which they emphasise the individual or the group/organisation (see below, altruism) as the appropriate target in the process of control and coordination. • Power orientation: cultural norms can differ in the extent to which they emphasise the use of power/authority to control and coordinate activities. 80 Chapter 7: Coordination and control: culture • Uncertainty orientation: cultural norms can differ in the extent to which they emphasise grasping opportunities. • Goal orientation: cultural norms which emphasise the use of material rather than wider incentives in control and coordination. • Time orientation: cultural norms emphasising the short rather than long term. Management theorists tend to emphasise commitment to either the objectives of entire organisations or to various groups or departments. This can involve issues of altruism. Sociologists concentrate upon common beliefs (including tacit assumptions), values and affects, often embodied in social norms. They may also refer to institutions. Economists tend to emphasise trust and reputation effects in repeated exchanges with incomplete contracts and, thus, moral hazard (see Chapter 5 in D and S). When trying to synthesise these apparently diverse approaches, cultures should be conceived as mechanisms that increase the probability of cooperative behaviour (activity) among a number of individuals (or perhaps roles if we want to abstract away from specific individuals). The scope of the mechanism then depends upon which individuals/roles are involved – a group, a department, an entire organisation and so on. Applying the ideas to roles rather than specific individuals would facilitate the idea of institutionalised culture. So, on this reading, cultures are mechanisms for handling adverse selection and moral hazard problems. You should note this is a restrictive definition but one which, I think, fits well the purposes of organisation theory. Cultures that undermine cooperation can obviously exist but these would presumably not contribute to the coordination and control of activities. 7.2 Trust Activity Re-read Sections 8.8.2 and 5.5.1 in D and S. The basic idea here is that both the pre-contractual and post-contractual hazards can, in principle, be overcome if the parties can trust each other not to take advantage (behave opportunistically; see Chapter 10). The issues at stake can best be analysed in terms of a simple ‘help’ or ‘trust’ game as depicted in Figure 7.1. Payoffs Help A B A B 1 1 -1 2 0 0 Not help A Help B A Not help B B Not help A Figure 7.1 As you will notice, the game is a truncated form of the prisoner’s dilemma with which you are already familiar. You will be able to see straight away 81 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach that the Nash equilibrium, when the game is played once, is mutual noncooperation/help because the first mover cannot trust the second mover to cooperate when it is his/her turn to move. So the first mover anticipates this and does not cooperate. As a consequence the second mover certainly won’t cooperate. Note, it is immaterial whether the game is played as one of perfect or imperfect information. The game in Figure 7.1 is set up as one of perfect (and also, note, complete) information and I shall favour this interpretation in what follows. Not surprisingly, the Pareto-efficient outcome is not, at this juncture, achievable. You might like to think about this game in rather more general terms than those pertaining to formal contracts. Organisations, for their smooth functioning, we may suppose, often depend upon mutual help. I help you now, believing/hoping you will help me in the future when I need it. If people are self-interested in the way that game theorists start by assuming, then no help will be offered – the reasoning entirely parallels the precepts of the trust game. A helping culture will not evolve although you and I could both be better off if we could find some way of overcoming the hazards and introducing such a culture. The first mover (helper) needs to trust that the second mover will reciprocate by helping when needs be. If they can, then the Pareto-efficient outcome is within reach. Indeed, the problem can be re-described as one of achieving a relationship of bilateral reciprocity. It might be useful to think of the helping culture as an informal mechanism of bilateral reciprocity. How might the first mover trust the second mover to reciprocate? One possibility will no doubt have already occurred to you – if the players are to play the game repeatedly with a reasonable probability, then cooperation can be achieved (TFT – the folk theorem – etc.). It is perhaps a moot point whether the term ‘trust’ is appropriately used in this context. After all, the reasoning underlying the dynamics of an iterated game depends entirely upon the rational self-interest of the players. Some would want to preserve the term ‘trust’ for situations where people will reciprocate even if it is not in their self-interest to do so. We might call this altruistic trust (we will return to altruism below). This is a conception which is closely allied to the psychologists’ use of the term ‘commitment’ (though, be careful – not the economists’ notion of ‘credible commitments’ in D and S). Both trusting and being trustworthy can of course be described as values. Furthermore, the outcome of trust games depends upon the beliefs that the first mover (trustor) has about the trustworthiness of the second mover (the trustee). So the approach we are adopting is inherently compatible with the basic sociological interpretation of culture as cooperative beliefs and values. It is important (though not brought out in either text) to distinguish between being able to trust, on the one hand, another’s motives, and on the other, their ability/skill to realise certain objectives. I can trust that you will intend to reciprocate and quite independently take a view on whether you are capable of doing so. A trusting culture requires both sorts of trust. It can be argued that organisational and some quasi-organisational exchanges like long-term contracts are, unlike market exchanges, constructed to sustain repeated interactions. Organisations can accordingly aspire to fill the gaps in incomplete contracts with trust. If organisations can rely upon recruiting members from an ambient culture where norms of trustworthiness are widespread, then it may be able to operate with a trusting culture even in the absence of long-term relationships. It is sometimes suggested that the success of the Japanese economy a couple of decades ago was so reliant. 82 Chapter 7: Coordination and control: culture Reputations for trustworthiness can also play a role. In a population of individuals it may be important to build a reputation for trustworthiness if third parties can observe others interact. The other way in which cooperation can be sustained in the trust situations is by command or authority. We can envisage one of the parties or a third party enforcing the Pareto-efficient outcome. We would, of course, not regard this as involving trust but a power mechanism (see Chapter 6). The picture I have given you so far only scratches the surface of the complexities of cultural mechanisms. One important transition an organisation can make is from a reliance upon bilateral reciprocity to generalised reciprocity. Thinking in terms of a helping culture once again, bilateral reciprocity can be sub-optimal. If, initially, A helps B, then when subsequently A needs help, B may not be free to help A – it would be better if ‘somebody’ in the organisation helped B. This situation is generalised reciprocity and is depicted in Figure 7.2. S B HA HB HB HB HA S HA HA A HB HA HA S H H Somebody Help Not help B S Figure 7.2 Activity Now put in your own payoffs! Clearly the problem of free-riding is exacerbated in moving from bilateral to generalised reciprocity. Individuals can free ride on the group. But again repeated interaction can find a cooperative equilibrium. Although, as the term ‘corporate culture’ implies, facets of culture have traditionally been interpreted as mechanisms for maintaining cooperation within organisations, it is now recognised that these mechanisms can operate between cooperative organisations at differing positions on the market–organisation continuum. Furthermore, even though corporate culture is largely conceived as a cooperative mechanism, offsetting the problem of incomplete contracts, team production, externalities, and so on, it is also recognised that the performance of organisations can also depend upon intra-organisational competition between individuals (promotion, for instance) and groups and departments. It may be useful consequently to picture corporate culture as a mechanism for maintaining the optimum mixture of cooperation and competition within an organisation or group of organisations. 83 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Activity Since the two textbooks don’t really cover the issues of trust in any depth, you might like to read Abell (1997); Kreps (1990). 7.3 Norms, institutions Cultures are often conceived as comprising social norms which impact upon activities and thus organisational control and coordination. Social norms are rules about appropriate activities – what one should and should not do in specified circumstances – but they are special sorts of rules. They are social in the sense that they are shared by a community. They are institutionalised to the degree that their violation carries negative sanctions. They are internalised to the degree that their violation induces a sense of unease, shame or guilt (internal sanctions). Clearly an organisation’s objectives could be rather easily achieved if the Weberian rules (see Chapter 2) or the algorithm which I referred to earlier were to be internalised. We have encountered the idea of norms earlier, in particular as constituents of social roles attached to social identities. Social norms (or more likely collections of norms) are sometimes referred to as social institutions. All social scientists believe that some human activities, both inside and outside organisations, are shaped by social norms. They differ, however, in their interpretation. Broadly speaking, economists will analyse social norms as ‘rules’ which evolve (see Chapter 9) in situations which are repeatedly encountered, in order to facilitate optimal, self-interested behaviour (or interaction in a game-theoretic sense). They thus interpret them as an extension of the basic precepts of rational choice (see Chapter 2). Sociologists – notably Elster (1989) – find this simple assumption wanting. He argues that the evolution and compliance with many social norms: • cannot be derived from self-interested precepts • are not optimal. This opens the way to a very different interpretation of the role of social norms. They become, using the term introduced in Chapter 6, influence mechanisms. Marxists, in particular, construe social norms as part of the machinery of ‘domination’ whereby one group (capital) maintains its ‘hegemony’ over another (labour). 7.4 Altruism and commitment As we have noticed, most economists and many sociologists and psychologists conduct their analysis assuming that individuals are selfregarding or self-interested. To use the economists’ term, they only gain utility from their own personal welfare. The support of evolutionary biology, which traditionally also figures self-interest, is sometimes evoked to justify this assumption. More recently, biologists have explored the idea that altruism can arise through evolutionary selection. Although still controversial, an affirmative answer is often now given to this question involving an equally controversial idea of group selection. Altruism is a disposition whereby individuals gain welfare from the welfare of others even at a cost to themselves. Sometimes participative altruism, where costs to self are involved, is distinguished from the non-participative version where only a passive welfare from others’ good fortune is recognised. 84 Chapter 7: Coordination and control: culture If we entertain the possibility of altruism in organisational life (e.g. obtaining welfare from the success of the organisation in achieving its objectives, or perhaps more restrictedly, groups or individuals within an organisation) then we might also recognise that ‘spite’ may be involved. That is to say, gaining welfare from the misfortune of the organisation, etc. Notice that in some sense the assumption of self-interest is in a ‘neutral’ position between the extremes of spite and altruism. You might like to think in terms of a motivational continuum running between these extremes with self-interest in the middle. There can be no doubt that the ‘other regarding sentiments’ play an important role in many organisations, though they are rarely incorporated into models of organisational control and coordination. In particular, if altruistic norms can be engendered (perhaps at a cost) then this should reduce control loss, the need for monitoring, power and directives and so on. This, in turn, will increase spans of control and bring down administrative costs. Needless to say, all of these mechanisms could be used to controvert an organisation’s objectives or used by ‘coalitions’, in the behavioural theory, to generate coalition cooperation. Activity If you would like to review these matters, see Richerson and Boyd (2001). There is a branch of game theory – evolutionary game theory – which is analytically useful in understanding the evolution of altruism and commitment (introduced in Chapter 9). A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • trust, reputations, helping culture, bilateral and multilateral reciprocity, altruism, commitment • norms and institutions. Sample examination questions 1. How can ‘corporate culture’ reduce the administrative costs of an organisation? 2. What role can ‘norms’ play in achieving control and coordination in organisations? 85 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 86 Chapter 8: Coordination and control: participation and democracy Chapter 8: Coordination and control: participation and democracy Aim of the chapter To understand the possible role of voting (democracy) in coordinating and controlling organisations. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • labour and capital participation in ownership and management • voting theory. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010) Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Abell, P. and D. Reyniers ‘The emergence and viability of participating firms’ in Munshi, S. and B.P. Abrahams (eds) Good governance, democratic societies and globalisation. (Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage, 2004). Arrow, K.J. Social choice and individual values. (New York: Wiley, 1970). Industrial Democracy Group Industrial democracy in Europe revisited. (Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 1993). Miller, G.J. Managerial dilemmas. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992) Chapters 3 and 4. Vanek, J. The Labor-managed economy. (Ithaca, NY; London: Cornell University Press, 1977). 8.1 Introduction Yet another way we can conceive of controlling and coordinating activities is by voting. Indeed, the traditional capitalist firm adopts voting on the basis of one vote per share (notice: not one vote per person) but only at its uppermost level of shareholders. Much speculation centres around whether voting or more general participation in decision-making should be extended elsewhere in organisations? We can easily imagine a group of individuals coming together and adopting a voting procedure like majority rule (but why not consensus?) in order to determine what should be done. Indeed, professional partnerships are often built around the principle of majority rule. Democracy or voting is sometimes contrasted with hierarchical control and coordination of activities though, as we shall see below, many avowedly democratic ‘organisations’ actually develop hierarchical structures. Conversely, hierarchical organisations often experiment with limited democratic procedures. In this context, the 87 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach terms ‘participation’, ‘power sharing’ or ‘empowerment’ are often used interchangeably. The idea usually being that those with little discretion in strictly hierarchical structures are afforded significant powers over a, usually limited, range of decisions. This is then another way of describing the decentralisation of an organisation (or who should be involved in decisions). Of course, voting (or indeed decentralisation) in order to decide what should be done is – one thing – whether those affected will then comply is another matter altogether. But the leading idea is that those who are involved in decision-making, either individually or collectively, are more likely to be motivated to comply (see below). Thus, if this is correct, then the control and coordination of organisations can be enhanced. But if majority rule is adopted as the voting procedure then, in particular, will the minority accept the dictates of the majority? Those who advocate organisation democracy, participation and so on usually have in mind that democratic procedures will lend some democratic legitimacy (see Chapter 6) to collective decisions and consequently the outvoted will go along with the decision. The argument that participation will induce motivation has been used to justify all sorts of democratic experiments designed to offset the ‘authoritarian nature of hierarchically structured organisations’ (see below) and it is in this more restrictive context that organisational democracy is often discussed. In particular, should/do (i.e. normative and positive questions) organisations allow some degree of participation by workers (e.g. works councils or labour representation on boards)? Indeed, if we choose to think along these lines, what about considering more ambitious ideas like a labour partnership or cooperative? They do exist, but not many – why? Neither of your textbooks cover these issues adequately, so in this chapter I shall offer more additional reading than in most of the others. It may help to gain some overall perspective on these issues by looking at the range of possibilities concerning firms or economic organisations – see Figure 8.1. This figure captures, at a very abstract level, the alternative ways in which capital and labour may be brought together for productive purposes in the context of competitive markets. Labour partnership 100% Labour involvement in profit Equity Ownership/options Profit Sharing Works council Lab. on board Labour involvement in management 100% Neoclassical capitalist firm Figure 8.1 On the vertical axis I have plotted the degree of involvement by labour in profit, running from none to 100 per cent. The converse is, of course, the 88 Chapter 8: Coordination and control: participation and democracy involvement of capital. Here we are thinking in terms of profit sharing and involvement in equity of those working in the organisation. The horizontal axis plots the involvement of labour in the management (designing and running) of organisations. Again this axis runs from no appreciable involvement to full involvement. Notable points on this axis are works councils (with limited power) and labour representation on the board. So the neoclassical capitalist firm is located at the bottom left-hand corner of the diagram – a firm which is both owned and managed by the providers of capital. At the top right-hand corner we find the labour partnership or cooperative, owned and managed by the providers of labour. We will return to the various less complete possibilities below. Activity Now read Chapter 10 in B and H. This chapter gives a comprehensive summary of various approaches to decision-making. Many of the concepts discussed here have been reviewed elsewhere (risk, uncertainty, rationality, prescriptive (normative) and descriptive (positive) and so on), though the definitions given are often rather idiosyncratic to the authors. You need to understand and retain the previously encountered concepts, but a lot of the detail in this chapter should be treated as background reading as the relationship to organisational design is only tangential. The recap section at the end of the chapter provides a good summary. Note especially the summary of group versus individual decision-making and relate this to Chapter 5. The categorisation of decision-making environments in terms of certainty and uncertainty about cause and effect relations, and consensus and disagreement about objectives, might be related to the arguments about information diversity introduced in Chapter 5. You might also like to look at Industrial democracy in Europe revisited (1993) which will give you an impression of how participation in decision making in firms has been handled in varous European countries. As we have seen, the words ‘participation in management’, ‘empowerment’ and ‘participation in decision-making’ are often used almost interchangeably. Furthermore, it is often left implicit that it is labour participation which is being referred to. Participatory organisations can range from labour partnerships (cooperatives) to modest levels of decentralised decision-making autonomy in traditional hierarchies. 8.2 Voting theory An essential feature of any democratic system is voting of some sort; for example, majority rule, consensus or two-thirds majority. Introducing voting theory will enable you to understand why coordination and control on a democratic basis are rather difficult. The classical statement is by Arrow (1963). He derived ‘the impossibility theorem’, the discussion of which has dominated debates ever since he proved it. Rather than referring to Arrow’s book, you might like to read a more accessible and informal introduction, for instance, Chapter 3 in Miller (1992). Arrow and those who followed his lead posed the problem as to how well-behaved individual preferences (i.e. transitive rankings – see below) over a set of options should be aggregated to a collective preference. The aggregation rule (the social choice function) should produce a clear prescription over all possible combinations of individual preferences (universal domain). The impossibility theorem shows that it is not possible to define such a rule if we impose upon it a number of rather reasonable additional requirements. First, the collective preference should be 89 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach transitive; so if A is collectively preferred to B and B to C then A should also be collectively preferred to C. Second, the preference of A over B should not depend upon which other options happen to be available (independence of irrelevant alternatives). Third, if all the individuals (the electorate) prefer A to B then B should not be the collective choice (Pareto efficiency). You should be aware that this proof also assumes one of the central tenets of economic thinking, namely that it is not possible to compare the utilities of individuals. The problem falls away if we can compute the comparative gains and losses to individuals. The conclusion of this line of reasoning is that even if individuals do feel bound by the outcome of democratic procedures (democratic legitimation), they will not in general be able to find a decision rule to effectively coordinate and control their joint activities. To use Arrow’s picturesque term, they need to find a dictator; thus do we encounter yet another apparent justification of a hierarchical organisation and ‘the right to manage’? In particular, in the presence of team production technologies (see Chapter 5) it is argued that it is difficult to see how a peer group could solve the shirking problem using democratic procedures. They would, it is urged, rapidly find the need for an authority figure who can impose decisions. Of course, if this is so, could such a figure be elected? Nevertheless, we do find many experiments with participatory democracy in organisations, even occasionally labour partnerships based upon majority rule and one member one vote. You should ask yourself how relevant you feel the impossibility theorem is to organisation design. After all, much of your reading has suggested that decentralisation of discretion, participation, empowerment and so on might have a beneficial effect upon motivation and commitment. Referring back to Figure 8.1, many economists, while conceding that most modern economies have drifted somewhat from the bottom left corner towards labour participation in both management and profit/equity, find this reprehensible (efficiency reducing). On the other hand, sociologists have tended to take the opposing view. So, let us now examine some of these arguments more closely. 8.3 Capital, labour and organisational democracy Look again at Figure 8.1. It is useful to compare the two extreme corners, standing respectively for the classical capitalist firm and the labour partnership or cooperative. We can then regard these as ideal types and think in terms of the continuum of possibilities running between them. By this point you should have become familiar in the preceding chapters with the capitalist firm and it is possible to show that such firms operating in perfectly competitive markets achieve a Pareto-efficient, so-called general equilibrium. This result is regarded as one of the great achievements of social science (economics) and is often used, not uncontroversially, to justify competitive capitalism as the best way of organising an economy and its constituent firms. It can, however, also be shown that a system of labour partnerships operating in perfectly competitive conditions will also reach an efficient equilibrium. So we might ask why, historically speaking, there have been so few labour partnerships. One answer is that labour is relatively risk-averse (see Chapter 4) compared with the providers of capital and therefore prefers not to be residually remunerated. Capitalists can spread their portfolio of investments across lots of firms whereas labour cannot in practice spread their labour likewise (recall the findings of principal–agent theory). Most economists suggest that in the competitive evolution of economic 90 Chapter 8: Coordination and control: participation and democracy systems, labour partnerships have been found wanting as a mechanism for controlling and coordinating activities. Of course many non-economic voluntary organisations are coordinated by various democratic procedures among their members. Nevertheless, notable and partially successful examples of labour partnerships are the Mondragon cooperatives in Spain, the kibbutzim in Israel and, for a period, the labour-managed market economy in the former Yugoslavia. Activity If you are interested you might read Vanek (1977). Despite the rather negative press which economists have afforded ‘labour participation’, there is copious international evidence that various forms of participation are popular. Some, however, is introduced by statute, like co-determination in Germany, or works councils in many European countries, and tax breaks for employee share option schemes in the USA. We can again ask the question as to whether these institutions would evolve as efficiency-enhancing mechanisms in the absence of the law. If so, then why the law? We could even ask whether there might be factors preventing the evolution of efficient forms – perhaps management as an interest group distinct from labour resist what they see as an incursion on ‘the right to manage’. I don’t think anybody knows the answers to these questions. What is clear, however, is that many sociologists and psychologists believe that they have evidence for the impact of ‘participation’ upon motivation. Indeed, a mantra of human resource management is that participation leads to commitment (see Chapter 7), with motivational consequences. Given Figure 8.1, we can obviously distinguish between: • participation in financial returns – profit-sharing and share options, etc. • participation in management – designing, controlling and coordinating an organisation. Financial participation is often promoted as a mechanism for improving motivation, though you will recognise that one must be cautious about this proposition. Since the individual efforts (assumed costly) can scarcely be measured and related to profit on an individual basis, profit is a collective good in the organisation and consequently we encounter a prisoner’s dilemma situation. Each ‘rational’ individual will attempt to free ride, giving the inefficient Nash equilibrium. Of course, various cultural factors (see Chapter 7) may, in turn, also undermine this conclusion. In respect of participation in management or decision-making, it is important to recognise that the proposal is that individuals have a taste or preference for participation which, if satisfied, will show up in commitment and motivation. The empirical evidence on these matters is very mixed and much of the research fails to separate the effects of financial and managerial participatory variables. Activity You might like to read Abell and Reyniers (2004). The most general conclusion we might draw from the research suggests that there is a modest impact upon performance of the interaction between financial and participatory variables. In other words, both must 91 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach be present to have any impact upon performance. This effect may arise for two reasons: • an impact upon motivation • an impact upon information sharing. Let us now look at this latter argument. If markets and bargaining fail and the organisational coordination and control of activities is resorted to, then should the organisation be centralised or decentralised? Abstract voting theory apparently favours centralised dictatorial mechanisms. The ideal type would be rather like our earlier-encountered Taylor algorithm. The subordinates would be akin to robots. This assumes that the central authority is omniscient and omnipotent, signing complete contracts. In the world of uncertainty, incomplete contracts and discretion (Chapter 2), the question arises as to whether the discretion should be addressed centrally or in a decentralised (i.e. participatory) manner. Decentralisation is favoured by the argument that subordinates will possess relevant information which the central authority will not also possess (asymmetric information). You should, however, distinguish between two different ways of addressing this question (unfortunately, they are often not clearly distinguished in the literature). First, what we might term the economists’ stance – decentralisation with suitable incentives in place will bring forth the optimal provision of asymmetric information – we will refer to this in Chapter 12 as local knowledge. Second, and more of a sociological argument, decentralisation may satisfy a preference for autonomy and thus enhance the probability that the subordinate will reveal the information. The latter argument can suggest more decentralisation than the former. Even though decentralisation might reveal important information, it always carries the risk that the granted autonomy it will be used by the agent to pursue her or his own objectives which are inimical to those of the principal – the likelihood of so-called control loss (see Chapter 12). Activity You might like to read Miller (1992) Chapter 4. Miller discusses these issues under the auspices of the Sen paradox, which is rather like the Arrow impossibility theorem. Sen shows that when, within the boundaries of an organisation, there are at least two agents that are each decisive over a particular decision, then it is impossible to guarantee universal domain, transitivity and Pareto efficiency. Miller’s way of addressing this paradox is to suggest that organisations reduce universal domain by personnel selection – that is, by making sure agents don’t have diverse preferences. But this in turn raises adverse selection problems for the principal. Perhaps the principal might decentralise the selection of personnel – local knowledge again? But this might lead back to diversity and interdepartmental conflict, etc. (Lawrence and Lorsch (1967) Chapter 11). The role that democratic procedure and, more modestly, participation/ power sharing/decentralisation should be allowed to play alongside other mechanisms to achieve control and coordination of organisations, does not attract a consensual standpoint neither among scholars nor practitioners. Some have advocated power sharing/democracy for firms as a matter of principle, pretty much as political democracy is usually advocated, while others have sought to find the optimal role in terms of efficiency. It is the latter perspective that has motivated social scientists of various sorts, but it is difficult to find strong evidence-based policy promoting the optimal level of participation versus what we might deem the standard hierarchical 92 Chapter 8: Coordination and control: participation and democracy procedures in achieving control and coordination. Indeed, it is likely that the impact of participation varies strongly with the cultural environment in which it is introduced (Chapters 7 and 9). Of course, we are limiting our perspective to firms, many voluntary organisations adopt extensive democratic procedures. We shall return to the issue of decentralisation in Chapter 12. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • labour and capital participation in ownership and management • voting theory. Sample examination questions 1. Contrast and compare organisations where capital hires labour and where labour hires capital. 2. What are the limits, if any, of democratic organisation of work groups? 93 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 94 Chapter 9: Organisation change, evolutionary and adaptive approaches Chapter 9: Organisation change, evolutionary and adaptive approaches Aim of the chapter To understand how we can conceptualise the ways in which organisations can evolve and change. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • organisational demography and density dependence • evolutionary approach to organisational change. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Besanko, D., D. Dranove and M. Shanley Economics of strategy. (New York: Wiley, 1996). Carroll, G.R. and M.T. Hannon The demography of corporations and industries. (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2004). Nelson, R.R and S.G. Winter An evolutionary theory of economic change. (Cambridge, MA; London: Belknap Press, 1982). Powell, W. and P. DiMaggio (eds) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. (Chicago, IL; London: University of Chicago Press, 1991). 9.1 Introduction Activity Start this chapter by reading Sections 10.1 to 10.4 in D and S. Organisations are established (born); can develop (adapt); are eventually disestablished (die); can combine with one or more other organisations; and, sometimes, split into two or more organisations. In developing or adapting they can change any aspect of their structure or objectives. It is useful to distinguish between kinematics, which only describe changes, and dynamics, which explain changes. D and S distinguish these approaches to dynamics: • creationist • Darwinian (evolution) • Lamarkian (evolution). 95 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach It is important for you to understand the assumptions of these differing approaches to organisational change. 9.2 Creationism Given everything that we have studied so far, ‘creationism’ is probably the natural starting point. Our opening definition of an organisation as a ‘constructed’ mechanism designed to coordinate and control human actions and physical and symbolic resources would appear to invite the study of change in terms of: • an exogenous change occurring in the external or internal environment of the organisation • those who design the organisation calculating how to adapt the organisation • the adaptation being implemented (more or less successfully). Neoclassical economists will explain this adaptation process by incorporating the precepts of rational deliberation and choice (Chapter 1). If the implementation is successful, the organisation will quickly attain a new, efficient (cost-minimising) equilibrium. The study of off-equilibrium organisations (which in a competitive environment will, in any case, go to the wall) is regarded as being of little significance. This picture can be somewhat tempered by introducing ‘search costs’ in finding the appropriate adaptation and/or introducing satisficing solutions, especially with complex and rapid environmental changes. Those economists favouring the behavioural theory of the firm will study the design and implementation process in terms of the bargaining power of differing (satisficing) stakeholders. Satisficing may of course not only lead to a ‘second best’ implementation. Much of the sociological and psychological study of organisational change (adaptation) is consistent with the approach adapted by economists, in the sense that each discipline emphasises the adaptations constructed by human actors. However, a central issue raised, particularly by psychologists, is the reaction of humans to change. In adapting an organisation, those involved (principals or stakeholders) must take account of these reactions. Activity Now read Chapter 18 in B and H. You might also read Chapter 17 though the content of this chapter is less central. Chapter 18 of B and H will give you a very detailed understanding of the reactions of humans to change. It may be worthwhile reading first the ‘recap’ to give yourself an overview. You should pose the question as to how the mix of control and coordination mechanisms we have studied could be used to address some of the human responses to change. At various points in the previous chapters we have encountered sociological conceptions of organisation change which concern wrangles over the implementation of differing technologies. It is claimed that the dynamics of technological change are not solely determined by efficiency criteria, but rather by the outcome of disputes over retaining control (power), in particular between labour and management. This picture is consistent with the behavioural theory of the firm. There is very extensive, often sociologically inspired, literature examining the 96 Chapter 9: Organisation change, evolutionary and adaptive approaches development of organisational strategies in order to maintain ‘sustained competitive advantages’ (see Chapter 3 in D and S; and see Besanko et al. (1996)). Although the details of this literature fall beyond the boundaries of organisation theory per se, you should recognise that the art of sustaining competitive advantage is usually a dynamic process as competitors tend to compete away any current advantages a particular firm/organisation might possess. You should, however, contrast this approach with the dynamics of industries and markets with that advocated by many economists outlined above. There we saw how the details of what happened out of equilibrium (i.e. before competitive forces have eroded any competitive advantage) are not deemed terribly important. The ‘theory’ of sustained competitive advantage, however, studies processes whereby organisations (or their management) try to create, protect and sustain a ‘non-equilibrium situation’. Managers are always driving for, and protecting, some form of monopoly. When it comes to comparing the ‘creationist’ with the evolutionary approaches, it is assumed that all change is as a consequence of more or less efficiency-improving choices. There is normally no mechanism whereby one organisation imitates or ‘inherits’ characteristics from others. Nevertheless, it is possible to build on such a mechanism (indeed, the undermining of competitive advantage often takes the form of emulating successful competitors). Imitation can be construed as rational when others are clearly successful and search costs are high. Since imitation is one of the basic mechanisms postulated by evolutionary models, the line between creation and evolutionary models becomes a little blurred. Activity Now read Appendix 9.1 of this subject guide. 9.3 Darwinian evolution Darwinian evolutionary mechanisms explaining the dynamics of populations of ‘species of organisms’ take the following form: • A population of a species of organisms is born. • Each inherits at birth various characteristics (genes) determined by the characteristics of the parent(s) and some random variation. • Certain characteristics (or combinations of characteristics) give their possessors an advantage in a (possibly changing) competitive environment (e.g. competition for food or sexual partners). • The advantageous characteristics are more effectively transferred to subsequent generations (e.g. the current generation has more sexual partners or drives out less ‘fit’ individuals). • Eventually the advantageous characteristics come to dominate the population of organisms. Could ‘organisations’ replace ‘organisms’ in this scheme of things? Some problems are: • What constitutes a ‘species’? • Which characteristics are inherited at birth? • What is the source of random variation? • What is the nature of the competitive process(es)? • What is the inheritance mechanism? 97 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach The approach which attempts to answer these queries is largely due to Carroll and Hannan (2004), which is reviewed in D and S. The important assumption of organisation demography is that the growth of a number of types of organisation (i.e. a species) is determined by the impact of variables upon the birth and death rates. Furthermore, these variables are in turn caused by the number of the types in existence (so-called ‘density dependence’). We can use the idea set out in Appendix 1.1 of this guide to picture these mechanisms (see Figure 9.1). (+) (+) (+/0) Legitimation Birth rate (–) Number of orgs. (–) (+) Competition Death rate (–) Figure 9.1 Equilibrium will be achieved when the birth rate is equal to the death rate. Because of the particular non-linear assumptions that are made by organisational demographers, the birth and death rates can be plotted as in Figure 9.2. Figure 9.2 Notice that above N≠ the death rate is greater than the birth rate and the population will begin to decline. Many populations of organisations initially grow in an S-shaped manner over time (so-called logistically) and then eventually decline. In Appendix 9.2, I have shown you how a logistic curve can be derived from simple density-dependence reasoning. 98 Chapter 9: Organisation change, evolutionary and adaptive approaches 9.4 Lamarkian evolution Activity Now read Sections 10.5 to 10.9 in D and S. Whereas Darwinian models picture organisations as adopting a particular ‘form’ at birth and maintaining that form (until death), Lamarkian models allow the organisation to adapt to a (changing) environment. D and S use Nelson and Winter, An evolutionary theory of economic change (1982) to introduce Lamarkian ideas. The key idea is that organisations are bundles of routines that can adapt when put to use. D and S review this line of thinking extremely well, so I encourage you to read the appropriate sections closely. Activity Try to construct a qualitative causal diagram to cover Nelson and Winter’s central ideas. 9.5 Neo-institutionalism Activity Neo-institutionalism is not adequately covered in either textbook. So read, for instance, Powell and DiMaggio (1991). Both Darwinian and Lamarkian models of organisational evolution assume that organisations operate in a more or less competitive environment. Indeed, they exhibit inertia and competition and may not find an efficient equilibrium, but, ultimately, environmental selection plays a role. But many organisations operate in environments where there is no clear mechanism for driving out ‘poor’ organisations. Examples might be schools, hospitals and civic organisations in the public sector. Neoinstitutionalists introduce the idea of an institutional environment which can determine, at least in part, the ‘structure’ of organisations. As we saw in Chapter 7, institutions can be conceived as bundles of rules. According to institutionalists, such (exogenous) institutions can partially determine the division of labour (along with ‘technology’) and the ‘legitimate’ governance of transactions. We might picture the ideas as in Figure 9.3. Technology Divison of Labour Governance Structure Institutional Environment Figure 9.3 Institutionalists go on to distinguish various mechanisms which account for the impact of the institutional environment upon the governance/ structure of an organisation. DiMaggio calls them isomorphisms and distinguishes them as: • coercive, that is, the power of external agents to enforce arrangements • mimetic, that is, inter-organisational copying • normative, that is, the incorporation of various stakeholder ideologies. 99 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach As with the organisational demographers, institutionalists also tend to picture organisations as adopting a governance/structure. Thus, according to the model, unless the institutional environment happens to enjoin ‘optimal structures’ there is no drive towards efficient arrangements. Activity To what extent do you think institutionalism is consistent with a rational-choice interpretation of organisational arrangements? A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • organisational demography and density dependence • evolutionary approach to organisational change. Sample examination question 1. Contrast the assumptions of Darwinian and Lamarkian models of organisational evolution. Give examples of how different social science theories have developed these. 100 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries Aim of the chapter To understand the factors that influence the ways in which transactions on a vertical chain (value chain) should be/are located on the market– organisation continuum. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • transaction cost economics • strategic calculation. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Besanko, D., D. Dranove and M. Shanley Economics of strategy. (New York: Wiley, 1996). Coase, R.H. ‘The problem of social cost’, Journal of Law and Economics 3 1960, pp.1–44. Grossman, S. and O. Hart ‘The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration’, Journal of Political Economy 94(4) 1986, pp.691–719. Williamson, O.E. ‘The economics of organization: the transaction cost approach’, American Journal of Sociology 87(3) 1981, pp.548–77. 10.1 Introduction As noted in Chapter 1, we may regard the basic unit in organisation analysis as an exchange or transaction generated in the division of labour. The division of labour (exogenous/endogenous – Chapter 3) creates a value or vertical chain; for example as shown in Figure 10.1(a) running from crude oil extraction to the retailing of petroleum products. In so doing, we operate at the level of organisations or firms (recognising that at a greater level of disaggregation the points in the chain are also based on chains at a finer-grained division of labour) and pose the question as to where their boundaries should be located on the value chain. In fact the picture is usually more complex than the one depicted in Figure 10.1(a). Activities usually depend on inputs at all points down the vertical chain, as depicted in Figure 10.1(b). So organisations or market exchanges could control and coordinate each of these transactions. Furthermore, some of these inputs may be common to the points on the main chain (see Appendix 1.2 in this guide), like accounting services, in which case the picture looks more like Figure 10.1(c). Note the use of di-graphs once again (see Appendix 1.2). 101 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Oil extraction (a) Refining Retailing Shipping or pipe Distribution (b) (c) Accounting Figure 10.1 In general we are asking the question as to whether a particular transaction should be internalised (make) or left in the market (buy), as depicted in Figure 10.2; that is, should any point on the chain be a department/function/division or remain as an independent organisation. For the moment we restrict our attention to this simple choice rather than the more elaborate positioning on the market–organisation continuum (Chapter 1). We shall return to the more elaborate issue later on. Market (price mechanism) Organisation Figure 10.2 Start by asking what the benefits and costs of using the market might be. The benefits could include: • Independent firms may be able to reap the benefits of economies of scale (i.e. operate at an output that minimises unit costs) whereas internal departments may not. Unless the firm itself can absorb all the efficient output of the department, it must either operate below the optimal output level or sell on to another firm. This might compromise any information advantages of the purchasing firm (see below). • Independent firms are more subject to market disciplines than departments and may hold down those costs they can control more effectively. Costs may be difficult to identify in departments. 102 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries Firms might, though, attempt to replicate market incentives inside organisations (internal markets). Tapered integration refers to a situation where a firm is supplied partially by an independent firm and partially by its own department. This allows their relative cost structures to be compared. • Independent firms (i.e. their managers) may have stronger incentives to innovate when compared with managers of departments. The costs of using the market might include the following: • Private information may be leaked to independent firms – particularly if there is a need to share technical information. • The focal firm becomes to a degree dependent upon an independent supplier (depending upon switching costs). Thus the latter has a power resource (see Chapter 6) and may use it to hold up the focal firm. • It may prove difficult to control and coordinate flows of goods and services down a vertical chain of independent firms. This may be particularly so where there is a need to fit the products closely. ‘Just-intime’ methods seek to overcome this problem and permit independent firms often with long-term relational contracts (see below). The way most economists (following Coase and Williamson) think about the choice between a market and organisational exchange/transaction is entirely predictable – choose the arrangement that minimises costs. The innovation here is to introduce the idea of transaction costs – the costs involved in making (controlling and coordinating) the transaction. They are sometimes referred to as agency costs, and agency efficiency is found where they are minimised. So, if both production costs (which relate to technical efficiency) and transaction costs vary between organisational transactions and market transactions, then the total costs should be minimised. Activity Now read Chapter 8 in D and S. If you would like to read a slightly more comprehensive economic approach to vertical integration, then read Besanko et al. (1996). In a world of fully informed, rational actors where contracting is complete, there are no transaction costs and the choice between market and organisational exchange is of no consequence (at least as conceived within this framework) unless production costs vary (which, again, they should not under the same assumptions). It is because we relax both the assumptions of full rationality and full information in the context of ‘real markets’ (Figure 1.9) that transaction costs arise and the choice between market and organisational transaction is pertinent. Transaction costs theory is used both in a normative and positive sense (see Chapter 1). The new assumptions are as follows: • Individual bounded rationality: people are intentionally rational but limitedly so. Individuals are neither able to make very complex calculations nor to assimilate large amounts of information. As you might expect, sociologists tend to like this assumption; they see it as more realistic than the full assumptions of rationality. • Opportunism: individuals are not only self-interested but behave with guile. For example, in the context of game theory, individuals will issue promises which are not credible, make use of asymmetric information and they cannot be trusted. 103 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach • Contracting about transactions is incomplete because of inherent uncertainty and incomplete information. • Contracting can thus lead to ex ante opportunism (namely, adverse selection) and ex post opportunism (namely, moral hazard). • These hazards will be exacerbated to the degree that there is little choice of transacting partners and therefore reputations (see Chapter 7) in respect of third parties will not constrain opportunism – small numbers exchange. • Anticipated repeated interaction will make reputations important to both parties but if in the process there is learning by doing, it is then costly to later switch exchange partner. Williamson (1981) calls this the ‘fundamental transformation’ – it ties the parties into the relationship. • Williamson also observes that parties to a transaction might have a preference for a certain type of transaction in addition to the costs and benefits. He calls this ‘atmosphere’. In effect Williamson is introducing wider motives/utilities. Although the vocabulary introduced by Williamson is rather daunting at first sight, it has the advantage that it should enable you to link your thoughts into many of the ideas you have already encountered. Activity Think of transactions as a prisoner’s dilemma or trust game. Both parties would like to contract to achieve Pareto efficiency but each is wary of the other and in the absence of some mechanism to offset this wariness, the exchange does not materialise – the Nash equilibrium. So what mechanisms are available? The mechanisms can be derived as follows. Competitive market – the price as a sufficient statistic; here the prisoner’s dilemma does not model the situation. Organisation – three possible mechanisms which can produce the Pareto-efficient outcome rather than the Nash equilibrium are: 1. Authority and power. 2. Trust (cultural mechanisms). 3. Repeated transaction and reputation effects. As we have seen in earlier chapters, alongside monitoring and employment contracts (incentives), we expect organisations to avail themselves of a mixture of these mechanisms. But note, if we think in terms of ‘real markets’ rather than the ideal type of perfect markets, then the price mechanism is not sufficient and perhaps these mechanisms might also apply at different positions on the market–organisation continuum (see Figure 1.9). We shall return to these matters later. Transaction cost economics embraces not only an unorthodox model of the individual but characteristic aspects (‘dimensions’, to use D and S’s terminology) of transactions themselves that impact upon the transaction costs. Activity Now re-read Chapter 8 in D and S. The argument is that asset specificity (sometimes called ‘relation-specific assets’), uncertainty/complexity of the transaction and frequency of exchange all increase the likelihood that a transaction will be placed (governed) inside an organisation (that is, make) rather than left to the market (that is, buy). Asset specificity comes in different forms: 104 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries • site specificity – adjacent sites, usually in order to economise on transport and communication costs • physical asset specificity – e.g. a pipeline delivering crude oil • dedicated assets – assets of a particular buyer dedicated to a particular relationship • human asset specificity – skills dedicated to a particular relationship which would be less valuable elsewhere. So, we now have a predictive theory about vertical integration alternatively labelled contracting out. By and large, empirical evidence has supported transaction cost theory – particularly the impact of complexity in the context of uncertainty – though one should bear in mind what Williamson terms ‘atmosphere’. If there are widespread specific preferences for organisation – for instance, managers might prefer the power implied by organisation – this would complicate the picture. Furthermore, other factors might influence the choice between market and organisation. Regulation and taxation can confer advantages in deciding where profits are generated. For instance, taxation might favour small firms, and firms operating across different national tax regimes may find it an advantage to contract out. An organisation might vertically integrate to gain a monopoly or acquire information or to limit the flow of information to competitors (see below). Given all these possibilities, it is perhaps surprising that such strong empirical support for transaction cost theory is found. Appendix 10.1 in this guide gives a slightly more formal approach to Williamson’s reasoning. The transaction costs approach still leaves open two questions: 1. Will the integration, if appropriate, be backwards or forwards? 2. What type of organisation will be preferred – e.g. a centralised or decentralised hierarchy? (I leave an answer to this question to Chapter 12.) An extension of transaction costs theory called property rights theory (which is not covered in D and S) provides an answer to the first question. When a transaction is internalised within an organisation, then ownership should (note the normative word) go to the party with the greatest impact upon the post-contractual rents. Activity Although this theory falls beyond this course, you might like to read Grossman and Hart (1986). Property rights theory is essentially a theory of bargaining power (see Chapter 6). Incomplete contracts mean that residual extra-contractual control of assets is important. Ownership confers bargaining power over operational decisions when enforceable contracts break down. Anticipation of post-contractual hazards determines earlier investment decisions. We now need to complicate the picture by reintroducing the market– organisation continuum, as in Figure 10.3. I use the term ‘continuum’ with a certain amount of licence as the alternative positions on it vary in a number of respects and could be reordered. The continuum runs from spot markets with perfect competition, at one end, to integration or organisation, at the other. 105 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach The question now is where should a given transaction be placed on the continuum? Figure 10.3 First, look at what I have termed ‘real markets’. Here we recognise that in the real world the market environment is often far from perfectly competitive. If the transaction is left to the price mechanism, then various market distortions may undermine the price as a sufficient statistic. If, for instance, a supplier holds a monopoly, then backwards vertical integration may look attractive to a buyer. Likewise, a buyer might be tempted to vertically integrate backwards in order to acquire information or to reap benefits of vertical synergies (externalities). Bargaining was discussed in Chapter 6. Organisations bargain using their respective sources of ‘power’ though haggling costs usually demote bargaining to an initial role before a contract is signed. Franchising was also discussed in Chapter 4. Long-term contracts (which will inevitably be incomplete) enable organisations to engage in a protracted relationship. They often occur between buyers and suppliers in a vertical chain. D and S introduced the idea of ‘relational contracting’ (an equivalent term). Remember, whenever you think in terms of contracts you need to think of the incentive, risksharing and information aspects (Chapter 2). Fixed-term contracts put the risk of, say, increases in input prices to the supplier on the supplier’s back. Cost plus contracts reverse the situation so that the costs can be passed to the purchaser. Between these two extremes, various risk-sharing contracts can be designed. If the buyer and supplier have differing risk preferences then, other things being equal, an optimal contract can be found apportioning the risk appropriately. Tapered organisations allow an input to be provided partially by an internal ‘department’ and partially by an independent supplier (see below). Alliances are usually based upon long-term contracts and require a level of mutual trust and integrating culture (Chapters 7 and 9). Joint ventures take alliances a stage further by establishing a jointly owned and controlled organisation to control and 106 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries coordinate the transaction. Joint ventures imply equity contribution from both the supplier and buyer. So the question where should a particular exogenously generated (by the division of labour) transaction be placed on the market–organisation continuum is the normative question. Alternatively, where is it placed and why? The positive questions. Transaction cost economics claims to be both normative and positive and answers both questions. The first by minimising transaction and production costs! The second by testing whether a given transaction, with certain characteristics (dimensions) is, infact, placed to minimise such costs. But as we have seen, this is only part of the story. In summary, the choice of the position of any vertical transaction on the market–organisation continuum in the presence of uncertainty may be shaped by: • economies of scale • anticipated information leakage • acquiring information • relation-specific assets, complexity • residual property rights • market imperfections • regulation. But how are these various strands to be woven together? Unfortunately there is, as far as I am aware, no embracing theory. Imagine you are managing a company that manufactures widgets. To achieve this you need to call on all sorts of inputs ranging from material components to service functions like accounting, finance and human resource management, as well as research, development and window cleaning. On the output side, you need market research, marketing and after delivery service. Which of these activities should be ‘in house’ and which should you buy in or, indeed, use one of the other possibilities on the market–organisation continuum? One extreme possibility might be to contract out everything and just assemble widgets. Another might be to do everything in house. Which strategy should you adopt? 10.2 Introducing strategy The concept of corporate strategy and what many organisation theorists term strategic choice is deployed to address the complex issues of framing a response to multiple factors. Indeed, strategy is used in any situation where a number of ingredients needs to combine. The idea that organisational arrangements designed to control and coordinate activities are a matter of choice was first introduced by sociologists in reaction to an earlier tradition that spoke of ‘determinism’ – often technological determinism. Economists will always speak of choice where changing (exogenous) technology might either enhance or restrict the opportunity set which rational decision-takers face. We might then like to think of technological determinism when for whatever reason, the opportunity comprises a single option. I encourage you to think in these terms even if you want to question the restrictive notion of rationality (see Chapter 1). B and H introduce you to several authors from Weber and Fayol (whom we have already encountered) to Burns and Stalker, Lawrence and Lorsch and Child (all of whom we shall encounter in Chapters 11 and 12), who 107 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach have debated what determines organisation structure. The intellectual divide is between those who promote ‘one best way to manage’ as against what is termed ‘contingency’. However, in this debate, the missing idea (certainly from an economist’s perspective) is efficiency. The question we should ask from a normative standpoint is: is there one or more than one best way to manage (controlling and coordinating) resources efficiently (i.e. in a cost-minimising manner)? Indeed, one would expect the answer to this question to depend on contingent factors like the environmental uncertainty, the size and the technology of the organisation which, in turn, will impact the optimal mix of control and coordination mechanisms and then ultimately the organisation structure (see Chapter 12). Be this as it may, there may conceivably still be more than one ‘efficient’ way to structure an organisation given its contingent context. If we were to view this issue in game theoretic terms then there may be multiple equilibrium among what one may choose. Also from a positive perspective the appropriate question is whether or not, and perhaps why, an organisation departs from an efficient equilibrium. The debate about ‘strategic choice’ is thus sharpened by invoking some economic thinking. As we have repeatedly observed there is no inconsistency here between the economists and other social scientists’ ways of thinking. It should be noted that Child (1984) interprets strategic choice as a matter of managerial power. Indeed, there is no reason not to invoke the behavioural theory of the firm (Chapter 6 again) in the context of strategic choice. But we should, from a positive perspective, always ask, does the power driven structuring of the organisation produce an efficient structure or does it reflect, for instance, managerial or other preferences (see Chapter 11)? Activity Now read Chapters 9 and 16 in B and H. These chapters cover issues of strategic planning that impinge upon organisation theory but which are more often encountered in courses on management theory. You will benefit from reading the chapters but a detailed analysis of strategic thinking is not central to this course. The central idea in management theory concerns the sources of what is termed sustained competitive advantage (SCA). Why do some firms/organisations manage to sustain a better performance than their competitors, while operating in the same markets? Statistics tend to suggest that this is a common experience in many markets. Firms often earn above-average returns (loosely rents) on their assets over relatively extended periods of time. The assumption is that they have some characteristics (but which?) that their competitors find it difficult to replicate or improve upon, at least during the time in which the advantage is sustained. From an organisational theory point of view the question to ask is – are there ways of organising which can confer SCA? Notice that when an organisation possesses a competitive advantage, for whatever reason, then this implies that perfect competition is not operating. In so far as those running organisations seek SCA, they are trying to undermine competitive forces. The early sections of D and S’s chapter show how game theory is an indispensable tool in studying competitive strategies. So should SCA be derived from a clever approach to vertical contracting? 108 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries 10.3 Vertical contracting and strategic choice Consider a transaction between B and S, as in Figure 10.4. The problem is to design a contractual relationship to gain any possible rents. In terms of competitive advantage this amounts to placing the transaction on the market–organisation continuum more effectively than the competition. Assume that there is need for relation-specific assets and a complete contract cannot be signed because of inherent uncertainties. Suppose now that B would like to persuade S to make the relation-specific investment. S’s ex ante problem is that in the absence of trust and credible promises, they anticipate that, once the investment is made, B will take advantage of the situation. S anticipates that B will always be able, once the contract is entered into, to find contingencies not covered by the contract. By making the investment S, in effect, confers bargaining power upon B – who may even use this power to renegotiate the original contract (attempt to reduce the price of the good or service exchanged). S will then anticipate these moral hazards and accordingly not invest; the transaction will fail and both S and B will be less well off than they could be. Thinking in terms of the (for the moment, one-shot) prisoner’s dilemma, S and B find a Nash equilibrium rather than the Pareto-efficient outcome. So what can be done to achieve the Pareto superior outcome? S B Figure 10.4 Some possibilities (neither exclusive nor exhaustive) are: • B makes the relation-specific investment (but then B confers bargaining power to S) • B and S make a joint investment – an alliance or joint venture • S continues to make the investment but enters into a long-term contract with B (note that relation-specific investments tend to imply long-term relationships in the first place) • forward or backward integration (here non-market incentives/ monitoring/authority/power/culture achieve the move from the Nash equilibrium to the Pareto outcome). But let us continue to assume that B wants to find a non-integration solution and still to encourage S to make the costly upfront relationspecific investment. They might do this in the recognition that S, as an independent organisation, may be relatively small, flexible and focused. Furthermore, S may be driven by a more entrepreneurial spirit than if it were to be a division or department in B’s ‘bureaucracy’. An independent S may be more innovative. Also small organisations tend to have lower labour costs (production costs). If so, then both S and B can benefit. The strategic problem is whether or not the transaction costs (ex ante and ex post) can be kept down while reaping these potential advantages. To offset S’s anticipated moral hazard problems, B needs to search for ways of reducing their own and increasing S’s relative bargaining power. To the degree that this proves possible, the strategy will offset S’s anticipated moral hazards. B needs to make themself more dependent upon S before the contract is signed. One notable way they can secure this is to decentralise some design and innovation responsibilities to S. B now becomes partially dependent upon S. Furthermore, B can commit not only to a long-term contract but also to relatively unconditional contract renewal. These strategies do of course put B at some risk. But since we are 109 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach thinking in terms of incentives to transact, you should by now recognise that risk-sharing is another aspect of the possible contracts between S and B that can be subjected to strategic reasoning. Not unreasonably, I think, assume that S is risk-averse and B is risk-neutral. So, S will accept a reduction in rent in order to reduce their risk and, relatively speaking, B will be prepared to shoulder more risk. So, a risksharing, long-term contract can conceivably lead to a Pareto improvement: think in this respect in terms of post-contractual price negotiation. With a fixed-cost contract any increase in S’s costs will be borne by S. S will be reluctant to sign such a contract. With a cost-plus contract, on the other hand, B will bear all the risks of S’s cost increases. Furthermore, S will have no incentives to hold costs down nor, perhaps more importantly, to innovate in order to reduce costs. Clearly, B wants S both to innovate and, where possible, to hold down costs. It is not in B’s interests to take the risk from S and undermine these incentives. How can they provide appropriate incentives while reducing S’s risks and in so doing make the contract interesting to S? What B needs to do is to accept those risks of cost increases which S cannot control while making S responsible for those they can control – a tricky business. B needs to know the nature of S’s cost structure (an information problem – no problem with full information but with information asymmetry it is another story) before they can achieve this. Of course, integration might dispel this problem but then we encounter the bureaucratic losses mentioned above. What can B do? Go back to your principal–agent model (see Chapter 4). We can regard B as a principal and S as an agent. P (B) can acquire information by having more than one agent (S) operating in the same environment (in practice this is not easy). This is called multiple sourcing. It could be achieved by either multiple external sourcing or having an in-house comparator (tapered sourcing). But, of course, one needs to ask whether B’s sourcing requirements are of sufficient magnitude to reap any economies of scale across the multiple sources. If not, would it be sensible – from an information leakage point of view – to allow the sourcing organisation to sell to other organisations on the open market? If B has decentralised design to S then this might prove hazardous. As we have observed, long-term relationships (see Chapter 8) can invoke trust and reputation effects. Traditionally it was assumed that one of the advantages of integration into an organisation derives from the repeated interaction effects. B and S being in the same organisation, they repeatedly interact and, indeed, they will assume that there is a high enough probability that they will once again interact in the future. Thus prudent calculation can overcome the moral hazards in incomplete contracting. In game-theoretic terms B and S may play TFT (the folk theorem). B may also wish to protect her/his reputation for fair play. In short, an organisation can control and coordinate vertical relations by cultural means. However, long-term contracts with a continuation clause also produce repeated interaction (the Japanese were largely responsible, in the 1980s, for recognising this) and, thus, reputation and trust can be generated at other points on the market–organisation continuum. Cultural mechanisms can operate outside formal organisations. If B and S can trust each other not to behave opportunistically, then the advantages of S’s independence and reduced transaction costs can be realised. Finally, reverting to an extended value chain where S’s suppliers are also brought into the picture, we obtain the situation as in Figure 10.5. 110 Chapter 10: Vertical boundaries R S B Price and market R S Long-term contracts B R S B Organisation span of coordination = 3 Figure 10.5 Should the whole chain be coordinated by integration (span of coordination) or perhaps coordinated by long-term contracts, etc.? If the latter, should B contract with S and R or should B contract with S and S with R? In either case we have examples of network organisation and even virtual organisation if the relationships are mediated by modern information technology. The strategic complexion of these sorts of organisations is little understood. Why don’t you have a go! Reading B and H (Chapter 17) will give you a slightly different, more descriptive, take on the issues of vertical integration and outsourcing. The chapter in B and H also covers some aspects of the next chapter in this guide – horizontal boundaries. The authors’ categories are, however, entirely consistent with our above analysis. ‘Hollow organisations’ are those which outsource all but their core activities, though it is sometimes difficult to decide what these are. ‘Modular organistions’ rest upon a technology whereby the product can largely be assembled from prefabricated components. These may be fabricated in either internal divisions or external organisations (suppliers). The latter may, however, be located anywhere on the market–organisation continuum depending upon the strategic calculations outlined above. ‘Virtual organisations’ is a rather vague term used to describe the currently evolving possibilities afforded by information technology, enabling quasiindependent organisations to coordinate their activities, usually involving long-term contracts of one sort or another. The emergence in recent years of virtual organisations has prompted the observation that the simple equation of markets with competition and organisations with cooperation is an over-simplification. Groups of semi-autonomous organisations can be partially competitive with each other and partly collaborative (sometimes called coopetition). I hope that this section has given you some appreciation of how to analyse organisation choices from a genuinely strategic point of view. Much of the above reasoning can be underpinned from a game-theoretic standpoint. This further supports my earlier contention that modern organisation theory often requires a knowledge of strategic thinking and game theory. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • transaction cost economics • strategic calculation. 111 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Sample examination question 1. Explain why a transaction should be placed in a market or an organisation. 112 Chapter 11: Horizontal boundaries Chapter 11: Horizontal boundaries Aim of the chapter To understand the factors which lead an organisation to adopt a multidivisional structure. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • related diversification, unrelated diversification and locational diversification • evolution of the multidivisional firm. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour: an introductory text. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Burns, T. and G.M. Stalker The management of innovation. (Oxford: Oxford Unversity Press, 1994). Chandler, A. Strategy and structure. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1962). Lawrence, P.R. and J.W. Lorsch Organization and environment. (Boston: Division of Research, Harvard University, 1967). Teece, D. ‘Towards an economic theory of the multiproduct firm’, Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation 3(1) 1982, pp.39–63. 11.1 Introduction We now turn to an analysis of the control and coordination of horizontal activities, to the so-called horizontal boundaries of the firm. Activities are described as horizontal when organisations/firms produce products/ services for more than one output market. We can still pose the question as to whether two or more activities should be (normative question) or in practice are (positive question) left to the market or brought into a closer relationship. Conglomerates comprising a number of divisions often operating in diverse markets are the prototypical case of horizontal integration. They are described as diversified. Activity Now read once again the section on diversification in Chapter 9 of D and S. 11.2 Diversification It is useful to distinguish between: • related diversification 113 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach • unrelated diversification • locational diversification (D and S refer to ‘multinationalisation’). Diversification A production process exhibits economies of scale if the average cost of a unit of output decreases as the total output increases. The average cost curve usually initially declines with volume of output and then either goes flat or increases. Firms/organisations like to operate at a volume of output which minimises average unit costs. A production process exhibits economies of scope, across two or more products, if the total cost of producing them in a single firm/organisation (or by some hybrid position on the market–organisation continuum) is lower than if they were each produced separately by a single firm/ organisation. Such economies usually arise from spreading indivisible fixed costs across an increasing volume of total output. You can, therefore, see straightaway that economies of scope may provide a rationale for some form of integration. But we still need to know how scope economies can arise in the first place. As D and S show, they can always be traced to a common production input and are, therefore, really based upon vertical relationships of one sort or another. So economies of scope can originate at any position in a production process or, if you prefer, on a value chain – indeed, given Figure 10.1, it might be better to say at any point on the value tree. And remember that these structures (di-graphs) can be depicted at different levels of aggregation. The origin of economies of scope can conveniently be thought of in terms of linking value trees which terminate in two (or more) distinct products (markets), as in Figure 11.1. Note also that the marketing ‘function’ in this figure could also be combined to reap any economies of scope in marketing. Unique input Joint input Unique input Marketing product 1 Marketing product 2 Figure 11.1 Economies of scale and thus, potentially, of scope may be found in production or certain disaggregated aspects of production; or research and development; or marketing; or purchasing, and so on. A given vertical chain/tree (generated by the division of labour) with certain activities which cannot achieve economies of scale is a potential candidate for linking to another chain/tree (perhaps at multiple points) and, thus, for related diversification. Potential economies of scope are sometimes referred to as synergies. 114 Chapter 11: Horizontal boundaries Since related diversification is always a disguised form of vertical integration, some of the motives noted in the previous chapter can affect the situation. One should still ask the question, where synergies exist, why the activity that is to be shared across different products should lead to horizontal integration rather than to some other arrangement on the market–organisation continuum. Again, one should think, as in Chapter 10, in terms of minimising the sum of transaction and production costs. Those activities which produce outputs which are difficult to trade in markets or quasi-markets are clear candidates for internalisation and related diversification. D and S emphasise specialised indivisible physical assets, technological and organisational know-how and brand names (this is sometimes called umbrella branding). Activity You might like to read Teece (1982), p.3. Unrelated diversification Many diversified companies appear to integrate activities where it is difficult to identify any economies of scope. This can arise for two principal reasons. First, as D and S argue, diversified companies may be able to allocate financial resources among different activities more effectively than a capital market. This, once again, is a form of vertical integration finding economies of scope/synergy in financial provision. Second, it may be that diversification is driven by managerial objectives rather than maximising shareholder value. For instance, managers’ returns are often related to the size of the company they run (see Section 11.4). Locational diversification D and S use the term ‘horizontal multinationalisation’. Here the firm produces the same product in different parts of the world. It has geographically distributed divisions. What is the advantage of these divisions being part of the same firm? The obvious answer is in terms of the product they market, but again a licencing arrangement is also a possibility. The important thing to recognise about horizontal integration is that the combination of two or more activities into the same organisation does not arise because there is a direct transaction between them, but rather because there are transactions elsewhere in the vertical chains/trees in which they are embedded. Indeed, many modern organisations are best viewed as complex networks of transactions, which are placed at differing points on the market–organisation continuum. 11.3 Sociological and psychological approaches Sociologists and psychologists have taken a rather different but complementary approach to understanding diversified organisation structures. Activity Now read Chapter 16 in B and H. Like all of the chapters in B and H, this one contains a lot of detail, and it strays into the subject matter of our next chapter. Despite the detail it tells a story of how thinking about large complex organisations (read ‘vertically 115 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach integrated and diversified’) has developed from the early work of Max Weber. We have already encountered Weber’s concept of a bureaucracy and the central role he ascribed to rules (or contracts). A summary follows. How Weber’s concept of a bureaucracy has developed • Weber thought that bureaucratic structures, as he defined them, provided the most efficient way of organising. They were based on formalised rules/contracts and rational bureaucratic authority (Chapter 6). In proposing this to be the case, he lay the foundations for the idea that there is ‘one best way of organising’ (I don’t think he actually used this phrase). Note that the idea that there is one route to success is quite consistent with the economists’ common assumption of a unique equilibrium (see Chapter 10). • Following Weber, early management theorists like Fayol also tended to look for universal organisational principles that would be optimal in all situations. Fayol’s six principles (forcasting, planning, organising, commanding, coordinating and controlling), can clearly be seen as ingredients of control and coordination as we have developed them in the previous chapters. However, they have a strong ‘top-down’ flavour, characteristic of the time that they were penned, which fails to recognise the complexity of the various control and coordination mechanisms we have identified. • However, despite the continued importance of bureaucratic structures even to this day, it became recognised that they can be dysfunctional/ inefficient (read ‘bureaucratic costs’ in D and S). Thus bureaucratic/ classical management procedures may not always provide optimal control and coordination. In addition, the behavioural theory of the firm (Chapter 6) cautions us to recognise that a simple assumption of top-down directives may not reflect the political realities of an organisation. Questions of when this is so and what are the alternatives naturally arise. However, some scholars, such as Robins and Leavitt, have drawn attention to the persistence of underlying bureaucratic procedures, despite the overwhelming advocacy of flexible, decentralised and participatory structures among many theorists. It may be that large organisations tend to be more bureacratic (though recently the average size of organistions has declined), and also modern information technology can be used to bolster centralised bureaucratic control and coordination. Scholars are rather divided in this latter respect, some seeing information technology as facilitating decentralisation. Perhaps it is a matter of power as to how it is used? Furthermore, with the emergence of networks of organisations coordinated along the market–organisation continuum, simple sizemeasurement calculations have to be treated with caution. • Studies by researchers like Woodward, Thompson and Perrow1 suggested that rather than there being one best way to organise, the arrangements depended upon the production technology. Optimal organisation is thus described as contingent upon the production technology. In particular, Thompson pointed to the interdependence between stages in the production process as a ‘determining’ factor. You should link this to vertical integration and economies of scale and scope. Unfortunately, these early researchers were not as explicit as they might have been in specifying that it is in organisations that are optimally organised that the fit between the contingent factor and the type of organisation structure will be found. We will examine 116 1 These are referred to in your Essential reading; please see the list of references in B and H. Chapter 11: Horizontal boundaries alternative organisational structures (hierarchical boundaries) in Chapter 12. • If the production technology partly constrains the choice by successful organisations of their organisation structures, then perhaps there are other factors playing a parallel role. B and H suggest environment, size, diversification and internationalisation (for which read ‘locational diversification’). • Environmental dynamism (many other terms are used, like ‘turbulence’) is seen as a contingent factor which renders bureaucratic structures inappropriate. However, I encourage you, for the sake of conceptual parsimony, to use the standard term uncertainty. In Chapter 1 (Figures 1.7 and 1.8), we noted that as uncertainty increases then rules/contracts become incomplete and discretion increases. Nonbureaucratic structures become appropriate as discretion increases. As we shall see in Chapter 12, organisations (and other positions on the market–organisation continuum), are as much discretion-handling mechanisms as they are rule-bound bureaucracies. • High complexity transactions (recall the use of this term in transaction cost economics in Chapter 10) and uncertainty together tend to favour ‘organic’ non-bureaucratic as opposed to ‘mechanistic’/bureaucratic structures. Again I encourage you not to use any new words (Burns and Stalker, 1994). It is sometimes said that we may distinguish between bureaucratic and non-bureaucratic cultures. If indeed we can, then one would expect less bureaucratic structures to emphasise commitment and trust mechanisms perhaps alongside participation in designing the optimal mix of control and coordination mechanisms. • However, if entire organisations need to adapt to their uncertain and complex operating environments, why not take the story one stage further and recognise that different departments/divisions/functions of any organisation may each separately face environments with differing levels of complexity/uncertainty; for example, production and research and development departments? So some departments will optimally need to be more non-bureaucratic or bureaucratic than others. These departments/divisions will nevertheless need to integrate into a coherent organisation and may encounter difficulties (transaction costs) in so doing (Lawrence and Lorsch (1967)). I suggest that you make a serious effort to synthesise the economic with the sociological and psychological perspectives introduced in this chapter. As you will have appreciated in reading Chapter 16 in B and H, various scholars have provided a plethora of descriptive concepts, all of which have some face-value and probably fit your intuitions about organisations. However, you should not, as with other chapters in this textbook, believe it is important to commit all these to memory. 11.4 The development of diversified companies The evolution of multiproduct horizontally integrated firms from earlier multifunctional firms is beautifully recounted in Chandler (1962). Although you can pick up the threads of this story in the two textbooks for this course, I would encourage you to read Chandler’s book. The centrepiece is the evolution, in the middle of the twentieth century, of the large conglomerates with many divisions (either product or regional), each organised functionally (buying, production, marketing, etc.). At their height, in the 1960s, some of the giant conglomerates had scores of divisions and vertical spans of over 20 layers. Up to that period most 117 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach of the advanced industrial economies shared a pattern of increasing concentration (for instance, GNP/firm increased). After about 1975, however, GNP/firm began to decline in most OECD economies, as conglomerates began to ‘focus’ on a more limited range of products and to vertically ‘contract out’ rather than integrate. Joint ventures and alliances also became much more common. Interestingly, the research on conglomerates, even that conducted in the 1960s and 1970s, tended to suggest that they were by no means efficient. Research compared the performance of divisions of conglomerates with independent firms in the same line of business. So it remains a puzzle as to why conglomerates gained the prominence they did. It appears that the justification used by those who promoted conglomeration was that they could allocate resources and spread risk across divisions. In particular, they could switch resources from divisions/markets with a poor growth potential into those with better prospects (the Boston Consulting Group matrix – see B and H – played a significant role in this thinking). Subsequently, however, the line of thinking has been called into question and it is now generally held that the capital market is a better allocator and risk-bearer than the ‘internal capital allocation’ procedure of large multidivision firms. Hence the concept of focus and the current relative predominance of related diversification where ‘non-financial synergies can be found’. Managerial returns (salaries, bonuses, share options) greatly increase with the size of firms, controlling for profitability. Some analysts have, therefore, seen the drive to large multidivisional firms (e.g. through takeovers and acquisitions) as part of ‘managerial capitalism’ representing the interests of management as opposed to shareholders. Yet others have suggested, in a contrary spirit, that managerial skill is scarce and ‘outstanding’ managers can more effectively spread their impact across a number of integrated divisions rather than separate firms (sometimes called ‘dominant managerial logic’). A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to define and explain the following terms and concepts: • related diversification, unrelated diversification and locational diversification • evolution of the multidivisional firm. Sample examination question 1. What justification can there be for horizontally integrated firms? 118 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries Aim of the chapter To understand why most organisations adopt a hierarchical structure. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to explain the: • nature of hierarchy • factors that determine the shape of hierarchies. Essential reading Detailed section references are provided throughout the chapter. Buchanan, D. and A. Huczynski Organizational behaviour. (London: Prentice Hall, 2010). Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008). Further reading Alchian, A.A. and H. Demsetz ‘Production, information costs and economic organization’, American Economic Review 62(5) 1972, pp.777–95. Blau, P.M. and R.A. Schoenherr The structure of organizations. (New York: Basic Books, 1971). Chandler, A. Strategy and structure. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1962). Williamson, O.E. ‘The economics of organization: the transaction cost approach’, American Journal of Sociology 87(3) 1981, pp.548–77. 12.1 Hierarchies Although the control and coordination of activities within organisations is sometimes achieved by non-hierarchical mechanisms, most organisations – even democratic ones – adopt some sort of hierarchy for these purposes. The answer to the question as to why this should be the case might seem obvious to you, but it is nevertheless worth asking. We might reasonably assume that whatever mechanism is adopted, it should minimise administrative costs (agency costs) while maintaining control and coordination of its constituent activities. But before we consider these issues, it is useful to have an understanding of the nature of a hierarchy itself. A very simple one is pictured in Figure 12.1. Notice that hierarchies are naturally depicted as graphs (see Appendix 1.2 of this guide). Activity You might like to re-read Section 3.3 in D and S at this stage; also read Chapters 15 and 17 in B and H. 119 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Figure 12.1 The quantities defined in Appendix 12.1 are: • the overall size (N) • the spans of control (S) • the depth (sometimes called the vertical span but this can be confusing as the word ‘vertical’ is also used to refer to vertical integration) (L) • the administrative component (A) (see Appendix 12.2 of this guide) • the size of the bottom hierarchical level (n). So in Figure 12.1, N = 8; S = 2 (twice) and 3; L = 3; A = 3; and n = 5. Appendix 12.1 gives an elementary introduction to the mathematical interrelationship of these concepts. Each link (arc) in a hierarchy represents a relationship between a superordinate and a subordinate. The number of the latter to the former is a span of control. It is worth recalling that these relationships are complex amalgams of: • incentives • monitoring • power (directives) • culture • participation. As we have seen, they are sometimes described as providing channels where information flows up and commands flow down. In this respect, the links have directed features and are accordingly depicted as di-graphs. 12.2 Some properties of hierarchies Hierarchies have some useful properties which help to explain their frequent occurrence. First, they always contain (N – 1) links (arcs). Check this for yourself. Second, a hierarchy is connected. That is, there is always a path of arcs between every pair of nodes in any hierarchy. Notice in Figure 12.1 that the far right node is connected to the far left node by a path of four arcs running through the top node. It would seem to be a requirement of an organisational hierarchy that it be connected. If any node were disconnected, then how could it be regarded as part of the organisation? Third, a hierarchy achieves connection using a minimum number of (N – 1) symmetric arcs. In fact, on N nodes there are N(N – 1)/2 possible arcs (see Appendix 1.2 of this guide). Such a complete structure, where every node is connected by a single arc to every other node, is also obviously connected. You will have read in both B and H and D and S that ‘small’ organisations often have a ‘peer group’ structure where everybody is in a face-to-face relationship with everybody else and there is a minimum 120 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries of hierarchical structuring. Perhaps you should think in terms of an evolutionary process as N increases – see Figure 12.2. Number of Arcs (Relationships) N(N-1)/2 Peer group N-1 Hierarchy N Size Figure 12.2 When N is below about 10, then a peer group with very little hierarchical structure is possible and probable. Since there is often likely to be a leader or entrepreneur, we could think in terms of a simple two-level organisation with a span of control of N – 1 and where all these ‘subordinates’ are in symmetric relationships. As the number of relations (arcs) in a peer group increases with N squared, then above about N = 10, hierarchy becomes attractive, maintaining connectivity with only (N – 1) hierarchical relations. As Figure 12.2 indicates, the ‘saving’ in relationships by substituting a hierarchy for a peer group becomes progressively more dramatic as N increases. If you regard relationships designed to control and coordinate activities as costly to maintain (agency costs), then a hierarchy (ceteris paribus) is a cost-minimising structure. It is useful to refer to a hierarchy as the formal structure but, of course, relationships develop between nodes outside the formal hierarchy. You should often regard these as comprising the informal structure, though extra-hierarchical relations can be used in a formal command sense (see below). The relationships may be very varied but extra-hierarchical ‘communication’ is particularly important. Across-span relationships Within-span relationships Across-level relationship Diagonal relationships Figure 12.3 121 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Such relationships may be categorised as in Figure 12.3: • within-span horizontal relationships (these are the source spans of coordination: with a span of s there are a potential s(s–1)/2 symmetric relationships (s(s–1) directed relationships). The span of coordination is the number of actual relationships. So, for instance, a production line will normally have a span of coordination of (s–1) • across-span horizontal relationships: Note that these relationships have at least a common superior at a second level in the hierarchy above the level of the relationship. This procedure in practice often amounts to the coordination of departments (Figure 2.4 below). For instance, in Figure 12.4(b) the ‘second line supervisor’ controls and coordinates two ‘departments’ • across-level hierarchical relationships: Although hierarchies are usually depicted without across-level links appearing, in practice, if A is B’s formal superordinate and B is C’s then we naturally assume that transitivity holds and A is also a superordinate of C (Chapter 6). Thus, when thinking of organisations as controlled and coordinated by power and authority, across-level hierarchical relationships are usually assumed, indeed, running from the top of the hierarchy to its bottom. Needless to say such across-level relationships can prove to be extremely problematic in the politics of organisations. For an organisation to be controlled and coordinated effectively it is probably important that not only is power transitive, but also authority. • across-level diagonal relationships. One would, of course, expect fairly dense (indeed complete) within-span relationships in most organisations. Hierarchies are non-cyclic and each pair of nodes at any level has a least common superior. The absence of cycles prevents ‘commands’ going around in cycles and a least common superior designates a formal superior point at which conflicts among subordinates may be resolved. You should draw a number of simple hierarchies and convince yourself that they always possess the properties I have described. Begin to think of an organisation as a hierarchy of formal command-and-control relationships upon which various other (informal) relationships might develop, some of which may be essential in maintaining functional control and coordination of the activities within the organisation. The phrase ‘informal structure’, you should be warned, is used in many different ways. You might like to think in terms of the degree of bureaucracy or hierarchy of an organisation that would be measured by the proportion of functional relationships (i.e. those that maintain control and coordination) which follow the formal hierarchy in an organisation. Organic or nonbureaucratic organisations introduced in Chapter 11 would no doubt evidence a relatively low level of hierarchy as measured. 12.3 Constructing a hierarchy The way you might think about constructing an organisational hierarchy is as follows: • Assume that the division of labour has generated a vertical chain (value chain) of size n (e.g. the number of workers in a production line) and this is to be located within an organisation or on the market– organisation continuum). • Assume that the organisation is to be controlled and coordinated hierarchically. 122 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries • One possibility then is to construct an organisation of two levels and a span of control of n (Figure 12.4(a)). • An alternative would be three levels with spans of control of n/2 and 2 (Figure 12.4(b)). • Our intuition is that, other things being equal, the former arrangement would involve fewer agency costs (a smaller administrative structure). But would it control and coordinate activities as effectively? • Note that hierarchies are built from spans of control/coordination; they are the basic building blocks. Thus, what determines spans of control is of central interest to us. But remember that this is not going to be an easy question to answer since spans provide the locus for the interplay of control and coordination by incentives, monitoring, power, participation and culture. • Notice also that, given n, the smaller the spans (s), the deeper the organisation (i.e. the greater L) and the higher is N and, thus, the administrative component A = N – n. Conversely, increasing spans will reduce the number of levels, the size of the organisation and the administrative component. (a) (b) n n/2 n/2 Figure 12.4 These simple observations provide a clue to a fundamental problem in organisation design. The way (neoclassical) economists would express it is as follows: Decrease the span of control to the point where the marginal gains in control and coordination equal the marginal costs in so doing. A concise statement but difficult to compute. It is essential to realise that as spans come down, suggesting closer monitoring – which might further suggest greater control and coordination – then depth (levels) goes up. But as depth goes up, the risk of control loss goes up. Let us look at this more closely. Consider Figure 12.5, which depicts a ‘line’ of depth three in a hierarchy. Attach probability numbers to each arc indicating the proportion of the activities of the subordinates which contribute to the superordinate’s objectives (we take a top-down view). Assuming that these probabilities are independent of each other, their product will indicate the proportion of the lowest member’s activity which will contribute to the uppermost member’s objectives. If both proportions are unity then there will be no control loss. But assume now that both are 0.9 – then only 81 per cent of the activities will contribute. The control loss is 19 per cent. Add another layer; then the figure (still assuming that the probabilities are all 0.9) is 72 per cent, with a control loss of 28 per cent. 123 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach P1 P2 Figure 12.5 So, in building an organisational hierarchy one has to balance the gains in control and coordination (attributable to intensity of monitoring resulting from small spans of control) with any potential losses resulting from control loss resulting from the consequential increased depth (L). Add to this the possibility that people might react differently and display different cultural attitudes towards intensity of monitoring, and you begin to appreciate the difficulties of designing an optimal organisational hierarchy. Chapter 15 of B and H provides an extensive list of factors, which they claim determine spans of control. It is worth looking at these and relating them to the way we are, and shall be, analysing the determinants of spans. Remember how important this issue is, as hierarchies are ultimately constructed from spans (‘who reports directly to whom’). The following reasoning will apply (ceteris paribus) to each factor impacting spans in the direction suggested. • Similarities of tasks: clearly, if the tasks (jobs) of subordinates are rather homogeneous then one would expect, other things equal, that the optimal span can increase. This will be attributable to a reduction in the time/effort/attention needed to monitor the activity of each subordinate. • Geographic proximity: again the monitoring costs (time/effort/ attention) will increase with distance and spans will reduce, but modern information technology may be offsetting this problem. • Subordinate characteristics: B and H interpret the characteristics as competence and assume (implicitly) that subordinates can, without impairment of control and coordination, take on decentralised responsibilities. Thus, monitoring costs (time/effort/attention) can drop and favour increased spans. But to draw this conclusion one must assume that control-loss is not exacerbated by decentralisation of responsibilities to skilled subordinates (Chapter 8). • Interaction requirements: This refers to what we have termed ‘span of coordination.’ One might expect the greater the number of relationships/transactions that have to be coordinated, the lower the optimal span. However, this is not quite correct. It is the interaction of the complexity of the structure of interaction links and uncertainty that impacts upon span. If the transactions can be routinised/standardised (i.e. with low uncertainty and relatively complete contracts/rules) then the impact on spans should be small. 124 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries • Standardised procedures: a typical example here is the standardisation incorporated in Taylorism which we have already encountered. Standardisation increases the optimal span (Chapter 2). • New problems: this is best conceived as entailing uncertainty and, thus, discretion (Chapter 1). Thus as uncertainty and discretion increase the optimal span will drop unless control and coordination can be maintained by decentralisation/participation. • Knowledge gap: here once again the time/effort/attention needed to monitor will increase with the magnitude of the gap between the superordinate and subordinate and the optimal span will drop. • Task complexity: the complexity of the subordinate’s task will increase the time/effort/attention in monitoring and thus reduce the span. • Manager’s job: the more time/effort/attention a superordinate spends upon activities other than monitoring lower the optimal span. • Planning and coordination; this is covered by span of coordination. I have rather belaboured B and H’s list of factors to try and demonstrate to you how systematic social science will attempt to transcend the descriptive detail proposed by these authors by coining a small set of concepts to cover the detail. The key concepts and their interrelationships will be developed below. 12.4 Empirical relationships We have already reviewed (Chapter 11) the evolution of large complex organisations, which is best analysed by Chandler in his Strategy and structure (1962). Chandler provides a story of the interplay between economies of scale and scope and the quest for synergies (unrealised economies of scope). The market for corporate control has in many countries supported this quest though it may have be driven, particularly in the period when conglomerates were much in evidence, by managerial interests in running large organisations. Though now, under the impetus of ideas about shareholder value, the emphasis is on focused organisations. Organisation theorists have also studied the connection between the overall size of organisations (usually the number of employees) and various aspects of their internal structure. The most general finding is that as size increases, bureaucratic features increase but at a declining rate. The Aston studies were instrumental in establishing these sorts of results. Furthermore, many other internal features display a rather similar pattern with size. Blau and Schoenherr (1971) is the seminal text. They found empirically that the differentiation of organisations into sub-units (departments, divisions, etc.) increases at a declining rate with size. Others have found that L (the number of levels) is similarly related to N (and n). Figure 12.6 depicts some results from several studies. Note that this result implies that the average span must increase with size. (In Appendix 12.3, I show why these results are found.) 125 Number of levels in the hierarchy MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach 1,000 2,000 3,000 Total number of employees Figure 12.6: Variation in number of levels with size of organisation: trends from three samples. (Studies by D.S. Pugh and colleagues, 46 Midlands organisations of different types, data collected 1962–4; Alfred Kleser, 51 West German manufacturing companies, data collected 1970–1; John Child, 82 British manufacturing and service companies, data collected 1967–9.) Activity Now re-read Chapter 16 in B and H; and Appendix 12.3 in this guide. This basic relationship between size and various organisation characteristics is now so well established that any theory must be capable of explaining why. As we noted in Chapter 11, many of the studies unfortunately failed to incorporate efficiency into the picture. It is not clear whether or not poorly performing and better performing organisations exhibit different patterns of relationships. 12.5 Designing organisations The time has come to try to pull together our reasoning about the design of organisations. We started this subject guide with a definition of organisations as follows: Organisations are constructed mechanisms for controlling and coordinating human activities and symbolic and physical resources in order to achieve certain objectives. Although our studies might persuade us to modify some of the key ingredients of this definition, it has guided us well throughout the preceding pages. I have attempted to draw the threads together in Figure 12.7. I published a version of this many years ago but it still seems to me to serve well. Note that it is an example of the sort of diagram I encourage you to make use of in Appendix 1.1. Such diagrams are, I believe, useful when there are multiple theories about a complex reality which are currently difficult to combine into a grand integrating theory. 126 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries Figure 12.7 Our starting point, in the company of D and S, is the exogenously given division of labour. Lacking this, there is little need for exchanges/ transactions and, thus, markets or organisations of any sort. The division of labour (within limits; see Chapter 2 of the subject guide) increases specialisation and productivity, which, in turn, liberates possible economies of scale. It does seem sensible to take the division of labour as given (exogenous), though organisations could conceivably be designed to generate a particular division of labour (i.e. making the division of labour endogenous, see Chapter 2). Let us assume that the division of labour and economies of scale determine the optimal size of the ‘labour force’ – or n, as we have designated it. So we pose the question – how should the organisation be constructed to coordinate and control the activities and the physical and symbolic resources of these n ‘actors’? Our reasoning at this juncture could be applied to a situation where the n actors are individuals (e.g. a vertically integrated production line), or n vertically related production stages, or n horizontally related divisions. If we are going to find a general perspective (or eventually a general theory), then it should operate in this way. I shall use the phrase ‘n activities’ to cover the various possibilities. We assume that the organisation operates in an uncertain environment and, therefore, inevitably enters into incomplete contracts with its various stakeholders. Again, uncertainty is central. In its absence, the choice between market and organisation is indeterminate. Note, however, that in Figure 12.7 the uncertainty variable is not exogenous; there is a negative feedback link running from the size of the organisation to uncertainty. This captures the idea whereby larger organisations are able to reduce, though not eliminate, the uncertainties in their operating environments. There is good empirical evidence for this. Uncertainty generates discretion – the control and coordination of activities that are not explicitly covered by enforceable contracts/rules. Discretion raises issues of pre-contractual and post-contractual hazards – adverse selection and moral hazard. I shall use the terminology of PA theory (see Chapter 4), though the ideas go well beyond the current achievements of the theory. 127 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach The division of labour generates what I have generically called interdependence. This term covers: • relation-specific assets (Williamson, Chapter 10) • economies of scope (synergies) (Williamson, Chapter 10) • team production externalities (Alchian and Demsetz, Chapter 10). Interdependence is best interpreted as an asymmetric relationship even though the work flow might be directed (Thompson). It is the interaction of discretion, generated by uncertainty, and interdependence which drives organisation design. As discretion and interdependence increase, the use of complete contracts/rules declines. Rules are associated with formalisation and standardisation, namely, routinisation; the classical Weberian bureaucracy (Taylorism/Fordism). So, by derivation, as discretion increases, bureaucracy declines (organic organisations become effective (Burns and Stalker, 1994)). Organisations are thus mechanisms both for allocating and monitoring discretionary activities, and setting and monitoring contracts/rules. The degree to which discretionary activities are determined by the n agents is indicative of decentralisation. The degree to which discretionary activities are determined is directed by a Principal (P) then the organisation is relatively centralised. For the moment, we consider a two-level (L = 2) organisation. The level of decentralisation of discretion is determined by three main variables, as depicted in Figure 12.7. First, the risk of control loss: if discretion is decentralised then there is always a risk that the agent’s activities will not contribute to the objectives of the principal. To use Williamson’s term, there will be an ever-present danger of sub-goal pursuit. Thus, other things being equal, the risk of control loss will induce principals to centralise discretion. Decentralising discretion in the context of interdependence is particularly risky. Consider the situations depicted in Figure 12.8. (a) P μ μ (b) P μ inventory μ = uncertainty Figure 12.8 In Figure 12.8(a) we have a case of unrelated horizontal integration. The uncertainty in supply for each agent is separate (independent) and the risks of control loss to P, on decentralisation, are independent. Contrast situation (b): here, if decentralisation at the left agent leads to control loss, this can be transmitted to the other agent. The risks are accordingly multiplied. If an inventory between the agents can be established then the risks are reduced, though inventories designed to hedge against hold-up are expensive. 128 Chapter 12: Hierarchical boundaries The second variable affecting the level of decentralisation is what I have termed ‘value of local information’: if the risk of control loss suggests centralisation then local knowledge possessed by agents – particularly implicit/tacit knowledge – suggests the reverse. To make optimal use of local knowledge, P will need to decentralise discretion to his/her agents. Think of an operating division geographically remote from a headquarters which has a detailed understanding of local market conditions. There is thus a tension between the risk of control loss and local knowledge. The third variable is time to process at P. Assume P decides to centralise all the extra-contractual discretion generated in their span of control; then P may encounter another problem. The more discretionary issues are passed up the line to P, the slower they may be in processing the information and passing down a solution/directive. This suggests decentralisation which will lead to increased monitoring. The problem can, however, be partially obviated to the degree that P can build ‘staff’ support to enhance their information-processing capacity; though P might in turn encounter control loss problems in respect of the staff function. Note that the ‘staff at P’ cycle in Figure 12.7 provides a stabilising negative feedback cycle (see Appendix 1.1 of this guide). As decentralisation of discretion increases while maintaining control and coordination, we would expect spans of control to increase. It is, however, extremely difficult to predict spans of control. They seem to vary across organisations which otherwise look rather similar. So far we have examined organisations as mechanisms for allocating extra-contractual discretion and procuring effective monitoring such that the activities of agents should contribute to the principal’s objectives. In earlier chapters, however, we saw how incentives, bargaining power and culture are also ingredients in coordinating and controlling activities. It is these factors which make for the variability in spans. Unfortunately we have no theories which integrate all of these considerations. If incentives could be devised to guarantee that decentralised discretion would be used to contribute to the principal’s objectives, then spans could be large and organisations flat. Indeed, as we saw, franchising, which might be regarded as an extreme form of decentralisation, and, ultimately, competitive markets do provide these incentives. Spans can also provide a location for (bargaining) power relations. If P and the agents in P’s span – either immediate span or cascaded span down the line – have resources to bargain about the nature of contracts and the disposition of discretion, this can have a profound impact upon organisation design. Agents may, for instance, resist close monitoring and curtailment of discretion. The consequences of bargaining processes are extremely difficult to anticipate. Devolved power may or may not be used to promote the principal’s objectives. The behavioural theory of the firm becomes an appropriate analytical framework. Finally, what I have generically termed ‘culture’, which covers a number of mechanisms, can impact on spans. If, for instance, a principal can trust both the ability and motivation of agents to utilise decentralised discretion to the principal’s benefit, then spans can be expanded. If norms either external to or generated within an organisation affect agents’ activities, then this can either be supportive of the principal’s objectives or not, with consequent implications for the intensity of monitoring. Altruism and commitment can have similar effects. The basic building blocks of hierarchies, spans of control, cascaded spans and spans of coordination are subject to a bewildering number of 129 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach conflicting constraints. But returning finally to Figure 12.7, whatever it is that shapes spans, they and the optimal size of the lowest level in the hierarchy (n) jointly determine the value of L – the number of levels (this is a mathematical relationship), the administrative component (A) and the size (N) of the organisation. Note that as L increases, we expect control loss to be exacerbated. The negative feedback running from size to uncertainty also delivers (with suitable parameters) the major empirical finding that differentiation or depth increases with size but at a declining rate (see Figure 12.6). A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to explain: • the nature of hierarchy • the factors which determine the shape of hierarchies. Sample examination questions 1. What factors influence the spans of control and coordination in an organisation? 2. Under what circumstances would you expect a ‘bureaucratic structure’ to prove effective? Explain why. 130 Chapter 13: Is there one best way to organise? Chapter 13: Is there one best way to organise? Aim of the chapter To understand whether one can conceive of a general theory of organisation. Learning outcomes By the end of this chapter and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to explain: • the role of efficiency/effectiveness in organisation theory • the significance of differing business systems. Essential reading Douma, S. and H. Schreuder Economic approaches to organizations. (London: Prentice Hall, 2008) Chapter 11. Further reading Campbell, J.L., J.R. Hollingsworth and L.N. Lindberg Governance of the American economy. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991). Roberts, J. The modern firm. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007). Whitley, R. and P. Kristensen (eds) The changing European firm. (London: Routledge, 1996). 13.1 Introduction As we have seen at various points in our studies, organisation theorists see their intellectual quest as one of delivering prescriptions about the best way to organise – some would even say the ‘one’ best way. Organisation theorists are often asked to provide an answer to the question, ‘How should activities be controlled and coordinated?’ with the expectation that the answer will centre upon the best/optimal arrangement. At the outset, we should recognise that the optimal way to organise will be dependent upon the organisational socio-cultural-political and technological environment. Optimal arrangements (if they can be found – see below) will depend, in various ways, upon the values and knowledge that people bring to organisations. Therefore, we should reformulate the opening question as: in a given (exogenous) environment, is there one best way to organise? Furthermore, particularly in the modern world, environments may themselves be rapidly changing. 131 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach 13.2 Efficiency and effectiveness Most economists have a clear way of reasoning about optimal arrangements – efficiency. Organisational resources, they aver, are used efficiently if they are allocated between and within organisations, i.e. on the market–organisation continuum, so that they are put to their most productive use (a given amount of production/output is achieved using a minimum of resources/inputs). If, furthermore, these inputs and outputs can be translated into monetary units, this amounts to finding the leastcost arrangement. Economists also assume that the performance function relating performance to the choice of input in an environment is concave. This almost guarantees that there is a unique maximum, and when the choice is not at the maximum, then any improving moves will always take the organisation in the direction of the maximum. If, however, the assumption does not hold (increasing returns, etc.), then the search for the maximum will not be as straightforward. We have noticed that it is important to distinguish between the normative and positive use of the efficiency criterion. This enables us, in principle, to answer questions about how organisations should be arranged and are, in practice, actually arranged. I say ‘in principle’ for in practice it is often not easy to describe the optimal (i.e. first-best) arrangement within organisations. Although not usually as explicit as (neoclassical) economists about issues of efficiency, Weber, the early management theorists, Taylor and the disciples of scientific management were all engaged in finding productive ways of organising. Economists (with some notable exceptions) also evoke the competitive forces surrounding organisations as an (ultimate) selection mechanism, driving out less efficient and selecting cost-minimising arrangements. There is, however, plenty of room within this framework for organisations to exhibit significant levels of inertia, particularly in highly complex, uncertain and rapidly changing environments. Institutional environments may also apply a brake to the evolution towards efficient arrangements. Furthermore, even if competitive conditions are entirely absent, the quest for efficient arrangements does not disappear. There is, thus, significant common ground amongst the various approaches to ‘organisation theory’, enabling us to interpret the disciplines as a normative and positive search for efficient ways of controlling and coordinating activities with symbolic and physical resources. There are organisations where efficiency constraints do not play a central role – churches, recreation clubs, certain often democratically organised voluntary organisations – but even these usually have a side where costs are central to organising their administration. Many people-processing organisations (churches, hospitals, prisons) may not at first sight appear to invite ideas about efficient (cost-minimising) use of resources. But at a deeper level they do. In effect, the product and consumer are one and the same. So, the organisation (e.g. a hospital) needs to be efficiently organised in order to provide a given level of service/treatment to its patients. Similarly, for a church, mosque, etc., the allocation of pastoral care and other experiences is central in allocating the priest’s time, etc. In my view (and I have to express a personal view here, as in the final analysis, many would disagree with me), the efficient use of resources should be at the centre of organisation theory. Some sociologists, in the recognition that narrow views of economic efficiency ignore some ‘resources’ which cannot be given uncontroversial monetary values, have 132 Chapter 13: Is there one best way to organise? urged that effectiveness be distinguished from efficiency. This seems sensible to me. However, as we have noted at a number of points in the preceding chapters, it is important to acknowledge that when transactions are brought within the boundaries of the firm, it does not follow that such an arrangement is necessarily ‘first-best’ efficient; rather only that the costs are less than those associated with market transactions. It is not at all clear that the competition between organisations procures a firstbest solution. It is relatively easy to specify the market conditions which enhance efficiency but when it comes to the complexity of organisational structures the story is very different. Perhaps all we can say about interorganisational competitive forces is that they will select ‘more efficient’ forms, not necessarily the most efficient – not even ‘ultimately’, whatever that might imply. This makes room for factors other than efficiency in determining organisational arrangements (the mix of control and coordination mechanisms). We will return to these issues below. Activity Now read Chapter 11 in D and S. 13.3 Comparison of models Figure 11.3 in D and S cross-classifies the various economic theories of organisation. You might like to add some of the sociological theories you have encountered. The classification raises an important issue about the nature of differing ways of studying organisations and how they might impinge upon the quest for the best way to organise. Until quite recently, most models of organisation were static in nature. The difference, however, between economics and other disciplines was that economic models were formulated so that factors under study were conceived as being in a steady state or equilibrium. Sociological models, on the other hand, were not so constrained. Consider, for example, the relationship between an organisation’s size (see Chapter 12) and its internal differentiation into units of one sort or another (Figure 12.6). These studies were conducted by sociologists and appear to find an interesting non-linear generalisation which is robust across samples and countries. But two questions arise. First, does the relationship only hold for organisations that are, in some sense, at an efficient equilibrium (profit-maximising, cost-minimising)? Appendix 12.3 of this guide adopts this perspective. Second, does the internal differentiation adapt to size instantaneously? If so, no problem will arise with static cross-sectional studies as long as we record the performance of the organisations and seek the connection between the variables among equilibrated organisations only. This might sound rather trivial, but we find authors arguing (see below) against the proposition that there is a best way to organise on the basis of empirical diversity. But the diversity may represent variables that have not equilibrated or where some organisations are (temporarily) not operating at efficient levels. This seems to me to provide a further justification, as we attempt to construct an interdisciplinary approach, for giving efficient/effective use of resources a pivotal position in our thinking. I want you to think hard about this. The recognition that competitive forces appear not to have driven organisations to a homogenous pattern of control and coordination has led some researchers to look for different national or even regional ‘business systems’. 133 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Activity You might like to read some of the following: Campbell et al. (1991); Whitley and Kristensen (1996). In your earlier reading, you will have encountered descriptions of the Anglo-Saxon, the Japanese, the Italian industrial districts, and so on. Some authors have used rather abstract-sounding terms, but the usual point is that a number of characteristics of these seem to go together, notably: • different types of ownership (banks, equity, states, cooperatives, etc.) • collaboration between firms or lack of it • the role of organised labour (degree of trade union penetration) • the regulation of markets (particularly capital and labour) • production processes (Fordism/post-Fordism/flexible specialisation) • varying labour skills (human capital) • institutional environments. Two important questions arise: • Are the different systems converging, particularly with the advent of globalisation, or will diverse systems persist? • Are certain systems likely to disappear altogether? We would expect more efficient systems to eventually triumph even if inertia and received institutional environments inhibit the process. However, different systems may be nearer to optimal in differing socialpolitical-institutional environments, which may not change quickly. We do not really understand these issues and with rapid technological innovation the future is not predictable in any case. Even if we cannot envisage the future, we can adopt ways of thinking about it which are intellectually productive. The sorts of lists that those who describe ‘business systems’ may hold because the various factors complement each other in delivering levels of performance in a particular cultural/ institutional environment. The idea that successful organisations are bundles of complementary assets (human, physical and symbolic) which are controlled and coordinated should be at the centre of your thinking. I conclude with two alternative production systems (see Figures 13.1 and 13.2) adapted from Roberts (2007), which may well show complex patterns of complementarity. Activity Try to work out how you think the various aspects of organisations depicted in Figures 13.1 and 13.2 complement each other (i.e. the presence of one enhances the productivity of another). Specialised machinery Long production runs Infrequent product changes Narrow product line Mass marketing Low worker skill requirements Specialised skill jobs Central expertise and coordination 134 Chapter 13: Is there one best way to organise? Hierarchic planning and control Vertical internal communication Sequential product development Static optimisation Accent on volume High inventories Supply management Make to stock, limited communication with customers Market dealings with employees and suppliers Vertical integration Figure 13.1: Characteristic features of mass production. Flexible machines, low set-up costs Short production runs Frequent product improvement Broad product lines Targeted markets Highly skilled, cross-trained workers Worker initiative Local information and self-regulation Horizontal communication Cross-functional development teams Continuous improvement Accent on cost and quality Low inventories Demand management Make to order, extensive communications with customers Long-term, trust-based relationships Reliance on outside suppliers Figure 13.2: Characteristic features of modern manufacturing. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to explain: • the role of efficiency/effectiveness in organisation theory • the significance of differing business systems. Sample examination question 1. Will globalisation lead to a single best way of organising? 135 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 136 Appendix 1.1: Qualitative causal diagrams Appendix 1.1: Qualitative causal diagrams You should learn some conventions about diagrams like the one depicted in Figure 1.1 in Chapter 1. They are often useful in summarising the relationships between a number of concepts (variables). In Figure 1.1 there is no arrow coming into the division of labour – which is therefore described as exogenous. We do not ask (at least at this stage of our enquiries, though we may later) how the division of labour is caused/determined – it is given. It is always important in developing theories to be explicit about what is taken as given (i.e. exogenous). Economists are better at observing this injunction than sociologists. The variables ‘specialisation’ and ‘productivity’ are, on the other hand, described as endogenous because we do (if the diagram is correct), at least in part, have an explanation of what determines them. The (+) sign on the arrow between the boxes (variables) means that as the first variable increases (decreases) in value, the value of the second variable increases (decreases). Unless it is otherwise stated, the relationship is assumed to be linear. A (–) sign (there is no such sign in Figure 1.1) implies that as the value of the first variable increases (decreases), the value of the second variable decreases (increases). Note that D and S do not place signs on their diagrams but they are assumed to be positive (+). A (+/–) sign indicates a non-linear relationship initially positive then negative. A (–/+) sign depicts a non-linear relationship first decreasing then increasing, A =/0 depicts a non-linear relationship first positive then a plateau (maximum). You should satisfy yourself that in a chain of arrows the overall relationship (i.e. between the first and last variable) is positive (+) if, either, all the constituent arrows are positive (+) or there is an even number of negative (–) arrows. It is negative otherwise. Whereas much economics is expressed in mathematical equations where it is easy to trace chains of reasoning, you will find that much sociology and psychology is not so expressed. Then it is often useful to construct diagrams depicting the signs and patterns of hypothesised relationships. In complex diagrams it is possible to have more than one path of arrows between a pair of variables. We shall also encounter such diagrams. The diagrams might have cycles (see Appendix 1.2) which are feedback (positive or negative) processes. These sorts of diagram are used in system dynamics and causal path models. Figure 12.7 is a good example of a causal diagram. Further reading If you are interested, you might like to read Richardson (1991). 137 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 138 Appendix 1.2: Network analysis – an introduction Appendix 1.2: Network analysis – an introduction Network theory and graph theory are equivalent terms. Definition of a graph: G = {N; R} Where N = a set of points (nodes) usually finite R = a set of pairs of points (N N). An example: lines below are sometimes called arcs. b a d e c So, N = {a, b, c, d, e} R = {aRb, aRc, bRd, cRd, dRe} • Note that here the relations (R) are always symmetric; (for example, if aRb then bRa). • An example would be ‘who interacts with whom’ on a set of individuals. Notice that not all the points interact (for example, e and b). • Note that the position on the page of the nodes has no significance, but the way a graph is presented may well be visually important. • A graph can always be depicted as a matrix. The above graph would have an (associated) matrix as follows: a a b 1 c 1 d e b c d e 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 1 1 1 where 1 indicates the presence of a relation and 0 its absence. Note that the matrix is symmetric about the main diagonal. This follows from the relationships (for example, interaction) being symmetric. • We can add direction to relations – then we define a di-graph, as in the following examples. 139 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Di-graphs • The left-hand di-graph is in the form of a hierarchy and the arc/ relations may represent ‘has formal authority over’. • The right-hand di-graph might depict who sent a message to whom. • Di-graphs can also be depicted as matrices but, in general, they will not be symmetric. • We could add ‘loops’ to both graphs and di-graphs. That is ‘selfrelationship’. They would appear down the diagonal in the associated matrix. • The above graphs and di-graphs only register the presence or absence of a relationship between a pair of nodes. However, ‘interaction’ or ‘sending a message’ may lend themselves to measures, for example, intensity, duration, frequency, etc. We would then attach the measure to the arc and place it in the appropriate cell in the associated matrix. These are then called valued graphs (or valued di-graphs). Some properties of graphs and di-graphs Further reading All the following properties can be defined precisely and formally. If you want to study these definitions then see Wasserman and Faust (1994). Completion A graph (or di-graph) is complete if all the possible arcs are present. On a graph of N points there will be N(N – 1)/2 symmetric relations. The degree of completion is the proportion of the possible arcs present. Connectivity • A graph is connected if there exists a path of arcs between all pairs or nodes. A path is a sequence of arcs. • A complete graph is connected but a connected graph is not necessarily complete. Connection is important for flows of information. • A di-graph is strongly connected if there exists a directed path (i.e. following the arrows) in both directions between all pairs of nodes. • A di-graph is weakly connected if there exists a directed path in at least one direction between all pairs of nodes. In-degree/Out-degree In-degree in a di-graph is the number of arcs coming into a node. The out-degree is the number of arcs going from a node. Nodes in a graph have the same in- and out-degree. 140 Appendix 4.1: A simple principal–agent model Appendix 4.1: A simple principal–agent model Consider a principal–agent relation. P wants an optimal incentive contract. What should s/he do? A simple way of thinking about the problem is as follows. • Assume P and A are profit/income/utility maximisers, • Assume A’s input is effort (e) • Assume A has an available alternative to contracting with P (outside option/opportunity cost etc), A0 So we are talking of ‘voluntary contracting’. • Assume both P and A are risk-neutral (make sure you know what this means). The agent A’s production function is given by: Q = e + where Q is output e is effort (unobservable by P) is a random variable with expectation of zero. • You may imagine as representing all those factors beyond both A’s and P’s control which impact (sometimes positively, sometimes negatively, on the average zero) upon A’s output. So E(Q) = e (1) • Assume the agent A finds exerting effort as costly to him. Further, that increasing effort is increasingly costly. (Note: some psychologists/ sociologists don’t like this assumption at least for low levels of effort – people ‘like’ exerting effort in certain circumstances.) • Assume (rather unrigorously) that A’s cost function has the following form: CA = e2 (2) (e measured in income equivalents) • P will attempt to motivate through: • a fixed (time) wage rate (W) • a variable commission on output (Q) (presumably with a quality constraint). But what is the optimal combination from P’s and A’s point of view? • Assume P offers a ‘linear contract’ whence: A = W + Q – CA (3) A = W + Q – e 2 (4) So, from (1), A’s expected profit: E(A) = W + e – e2 (5) 141 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach A’s optimal effort level e is then given by: dE (ΠΑ ) = β - 2αe≠ = 0 de (6) so, e = /2 (7) A sets effort level independently of W. (So why W?) A’s effort is proportional to (PBR). But what value of ? P wants optimal effort from A by adjusting W and . The total ‘profit’ (revenue) from the contract (assuming price of Q = 1) is: R = Q – e2 (8) P’s profit p is given by: p = Q – e2 A0 E(p) = e – e2 A0 (9) (10) (from equation (1)). P will maximise E(p) with respect to A’s effort: dE (Πp ) = 1-2 αe = 0 de (11) The effort level which P wants (eP) is: 1 ep = 2 So, eP = e when = 1 (12) (by comparing (12) with (7)) This may be regarded as rather surprising. Optimally P has to give the full residual profit to A. So how will P make a return in this abstract setting? • P will seek a fixed payment for ‘franchising’ the job to A. • P will choose (-W) to make W – e – e2 = A0 when = 1 1 and e = 2 Compare this result with those in D and S. In this framework ‘wage rates’ (W) will arise when A is relatively risk-averse and would prefer a fixed wage rather than a variable return. 142 Appendix 5.1: Introduction to decision theory and game theory Appendix 5.1: Introduction to decision theory and game theory Decision theory Decision theory is one way of analysing decision situations. Game theory extends the idea of decision theory to situations where two or more decision-makers interact. Decision theory usually involves a single decision-maker facing a series of options (actions) each of which leads to outcomes with attached payoffs with certain (subjective) probabilities. We start by analysing a simple decision. The basic idea is to: 1. construct a decision tree 2. attach some value (payoff) to the ‘outcomes’ indicated by decision tree on the 3. estimate the best (expected) outcome. A decision tree is best introduced by an elementary example, as shown in Figure 1. Payoffs of outcomes 0.25 7.0 0.50 10 5 0.25 8 7.0 2.0 0.25 10 0.25 4 0.25 0.25 -2 -4 Figure 1: Decision tree. The decision-maker must choose between Action 1 and Action 2. Some conventions This shape is called a decision (or action) node: This shape is called a probability node: Lines (arcs) from action nodes are actions available at that node. Lines (arcs) from probability nodes are beliefs by the decision-maker about the probability of the outcomes. The probabilities sum to unity at each node. Outcomes are exclusive. Payoffs are the monetary values of the outcomes to the decision-maker. 143 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach The probability nodes are labelled with the respective expected payoffs (see below). Note: The payoffs are those which the decision-maker attaches. Another decision-maker may have different payoffs. In more advanced theory payoffs are often measured in terms of utility. The probabilities may be objective or the subjective estimates of the particular decision-maker. The question that now arises is this: which action, 1 or 2: 1. Should the decision-maker choose (normative theory)? 2. Will the decision-maker choose (positive theory)? If the decision-maker is rational, 1 and 2 should be the same. Use expected value theory as follows: • Expected value of Action 1 = (0.25)(10) + (0.50)(5) + (0.25)(8) = 7.0 • Expected value of Action 2 = (0.25)(10) + (0.25)(4) – (0.25)(2) – (0.25)(4) = 2.0 The decision-maker will/should choose Action 1: that is, it maximises expected payoff. Notes: 1. Could have many actions at the decision node. 2. Two or more actions may have equal expected value (then indifferent between them). 3. The probabilities might be subjective estimates; then maximise subjective payoff. Game theory Game theory extends decision theory to situations where decision-making (by a number of decision-makers) is strategically interdependent. By strategically interdependent we mean: • the outcomes of one player’s decisions are dependent upon the decisions of the other player and vice versa • therefore, players need to take account of others’ decisions in making their own decisions if they have an interest in the outcomes and are to influence them accordingly. The basic elements of a game are: • players (individual/collective), at least two • moves • strategies • outcomes • payoffs. These will become clear as we proceed. Some basic distinctions in game theory Non-cooperative and cooperative theory: • cooperative theory assumes that communication and binding (enforceable) agreements (contracts) can be secured between players. • non-cooperative theory makes no such assumptions. 144 Appendix 5.1: Introduction to decision theory and game theory It is usually accepted that non-cooperative theory is fundamental since cooperative games can be reduced to non-cooperative games (by modelling the establishment of binding agreements). One-shot and repeated games: • in the one-shot situation a game is played once • repeated games are played more than once – perhaps an indefinite number of times. We shall, in this introduction, only consider one-shot situations, though repeated games are central to organisation theory. Assumptions of rationality Game theory usually starts by assuming rationality. By this is meant: • players maximise expected return (utility) • players assume that others playing are also rational • players assume that others assume they are rational, and so on. There are two alternative ways of depicting the structure of a game: • games in extensive form • games in normal (or strategic) form. Extensive-form games We start by introducing the basic idea of games in extensive form. They are best introduced by elementary examples. Consider first a situation where two players, P and A, decide upon a joint venture. Each has two possible actions (moves): 1. to cooperate (involving costs)(c) 2. to slack (reducing costs)(s). We can model an interdependent decision tree, as shown in Figure 2 below. Outcome c c Both cooperate A s P s P cooperates A slacks c A cooperates P slacks s Both slack A Figure 2: Interdependent decision tree. The tree is almost self-explanatory. P is described as the first mover and A as the second mover. Games could be much more complicated with repeated moves and, indeed, more than two players. In this simple model both P and A have two moves (s and c each). It should be clear to you that players could have any number of moves and, indeed, different sorts of moves. The tree gives, as it were, the logically possible combinations of moves and the outcomes are described here in an obvious manner; they derive from tracing the ‘path’ through the tree. As the model stands, however, we can 145 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach make no predictions without some idea of the preferences of P and A over outcomes. So we now assume, not unreasonably, that the outcomes are valued as in Figure 3 (payoffs). c c P A 3 3 1 4 4 1 2 2 A s P c s A 4>3>2>1 s Figure 3: Game 1. This is the same situation as above except that the ranking of the outcomes for both P and A are now included. So, for instance, P’s best outcome (scored 4) is to slack and for A to cooperate. This is known as a non-zero sum (or variable sum) game because the payoffs for any outcome are not such that what one player gains, the other loses (we assume for this idea that the numbers not only rank the outcomes but can be added and subtracted). The question now is, what will happen in this simple situation? The basic idea is to think forwards and reason backwards, although this does not always work. Now A will choose s whichever node he or she is at. This is because s is known as a dominant strategy for A, being the choice at both nodes. P will then choose s because 2 > 1. ss is what is termed the Nash equilibrium. It is the prediction of what rational decision-makers will choose. P can think ahead and note that A will choose s, and will thus also choose s. A Nash equilibrium is a combination of strategies (one for each player) which has the property that no player has an incentive to choose another strategy if the other players also choose their Nash strategies. This game has one unique Nash equilibrium (both slack). Note that the cc combination could make both players ‘better off’. Both would acquire 3 rather than 2 units of value. cc is the Pareto equilibrium, though ss is the Nash equilibrium. Much of organisation theory is concerned with how to move interactions from the Nash to the Pareto equilibrium. This game has a number of noteworthy characteristics. 1. It is a game of complete information. Roughly speaking, this means that both players know the structure of the game (the tree) and each other’s payoffs. Imagine what might happen if the players did not know each other’s payoffs. 2. It is a game of perfect information. This means that the players know what choices have been taken in the past (the history of the game). So A knows whether P has chosen c or s. Note that if P (by mistake, shall we say) chose c, then A would still choose s (and receive 4 units of value). 146 Appendix 5.1: Introduction to decision theory and game theory 3. You should satisfy yourself that the same outcome (Nash equilibrium) will result if A is the first mover rather than P. There is no first-mover advantage. Now consider what might happen if the ranking of the outcomes changed as shown in Figure 4. P A c c 3 3 2 4 4 2 1 1 A s P c s A s 4>3>2>1 Figure 4: Game 2. What will happen now? You should think forwards, reason backwards. A will choose s at the upper node and c at the lower node. P will anticipate this and choose s. (s,c) is the Nash equilibrium. If A moved first, s/he would get the 2,4 result (a Nash equilibrium). There is first-mover advantage. Again, this is a game of: • complete information • perfect information. We will now consider games with imperfect information. Consider Figure 5. c c P A 3 3 1 4 4 1 2 2 A s P c s A s Figure 5: Revert to Game 1 (Game 1a). You should now note the dashed line (called an information set). This is a convention which indicates that A does not know the history of the game (whether P has chosen c or s). Alternatively, A and P may decide at the same time. 147 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach What will happen now? • A will still choose s. • P will still choose s. We obtain the same result as before (the ss Nash equilibrium). Games in strategic form We now turn to the definition of games in normal or strategic form. Consider Game 1a. Both P and A have two strategies, c and s. The normal form is a matrix as follows: A P c s c 3,3 1,4 s 4,1 2,2 Here the rows represent the strategies of P and the columns those of A. In each cell of the matrix the first number (by convention) is the payoff of the row player and the second that of the column player. You should be able to see how to move from the extensive form of Game 1a to the normal form. We know, of course, that the Nash equilibrium is at ss (the bottom righthand corner of the matrix). You can find the Nash equilibrium in the normal form as follows: if A chooses c, then P will choose s (4 > 3) if A chooses s, then P will choose s (2 > 1). Now: • if P chooses c, then A will choose s (4 > 3) • if P chooses s, then A will choose s (2 > 1). Then ss is the Nash equilibrium. Now consider Game 1 again (perfect information). A strategy in a game for a given player is a complete specification of what he or she may do under all possible circumstances. In Game 1, P has two strategies, c and s respectively. A, however, has four strategies: • c if P does c and c if P does s, cc • s if P does c and c if P does s, sc • c if P does c and s if P does s, cs • s if P does c and s if P does s, ss. The game in normal form is given by: A P cc sc cs ss c 33 14 33 14 s 41 41 22 22 You should be clear using the above procedure that s, ss is the unique Nash equilibrium. 148 Appendix 5.2: Levels of analysis Appendix 5.2: Levels of analysis Organisational analysis is sometimes pursued by taking organisations as the unit of analysis; at other times, the units are individuals, groups/teams or departments within an organisation. It is useful to have an analytical framework which enables us to think about the connections between these alternative ‘levels’. The following type of diagram (sometimes attributed to James Coleman (1990))1 is helpful: it considers the relationships between corporate culture and performance. 1 Coleman, J.S. Foundations of social theory. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990) [ISBN 0674312252]. Figure 5.2 Imagine that each arrow depicts a causal mechanism. Then 4’ is a causal relationship at the macro/corporate/organisation level. It would be studied by inspecting relationships (correlations) where organisations are the units of analysis. 3’ and 3 are across-level relationships: how organisations impact on groups and then the latter impact on individuals. These are sometimes called ‘macro-micro’ relations – causal mechanisms, which can be decomposed into macro-meso and meso-micro. 2’ and 2 depict mechanisms operating respectively at the group and individual levels. 1 and 1’ are the mechanisms which translate individual performance to group and ultimately to organisation performance – sometimes called ‘micro-macro’. We may wish to suppress the group level and just consider two levels – the organisation (macro) and the individual (micro). A methodological individualist will maintain that no mechanisms ‘exist’ at levels 4’ and 2’ that are not the conjunction of mechanisms that operate at the lower levels. So, to explain the impact of corporate culture upon corporate performance one would have to reduce the explanation to statements about individual norms and performance and how those produce (perhaps aggregate to) corporate performance. Further reading If you are interested in these issues you might like to read Abell (1992). 149 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 150 Appendix 6.1: A simple model of sequential bargaining Appendix 6.1: A simple model of sequential bargaining Consider a sequential alternating offer ‘game’ between M and L. M and L are bargaining over the division of a unit value. (In a ‘proper’ model, one would make explicit assumptions about M and L’s utility functions, but I abstract from this.) Initially M (first mover) makes an ‘opening offer’ X to L and (1 – X) to self (0 < X < 1). L can either: • accept, or • make a counter-proposal. If L does not accept, the unit value is diminished by a factor (0 < < 1). So the value of the unit declines at some rate (equal for both M and L). (One could easily make it different for M and L.) captures the idea of bargaining costs. If L does not accept M’s opening offer, L makes a counter-offer about how to divide .1. Say L offers X to M and (1 – X) to self. Assume the bargaining can go on indefinitely. So, M (by backward induction) needs to fix the opening offer so that L is indifferent between X and (1 – X) So X = ς 1+ς M gets 1 – L gets ς 1+ς ς 1+ς Then the opening offer is accepted. If = 1 then 50/50 divide. As 0 first mover advantage. Notes: 1. Not realistic – bargaining protracted – why? 2. Irrational? 3. Model too simple? 4. Perhaps information asymmetry? 5. M and L don’t know each other’s . This model leads to games of incomplete information involving haggling, learning and bargaining. See Muthoo (1999). 151 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 152 Appendix 6.2: Bargaining failure Appendix 6.2: Bargaining failure Could bilateral/multilateral bargaining (Appendix 6.1) provide an efficient way of controlling and coordinating activities? If so, could it be an alternative to both markets and organisations? Coase (1960)1 argues that with no bargaining costs and clear property rights, the answer is yes. But the distribution of the bargained outcome will depend upon the prior property rights. In practice, however, if the distribution of the bargained outcome is not deemed legitimate, then players will tend to bargain over the initial property rights. 1 See pp.1–44. But, also, if because of asymmetric information bargaining costs (haggling) increase, then the efficiency of bargaining will decline. It is especially likely that bargaining costs will be high in multilateral bargaining. If asymmetric information about players’ preferences (L(min), M(max)) is the problem, then is it in the interests of bargainers to reveal their preferences? General answer – no. Information revealing has the form of a prisoner’s dilemma (PD) – n-person for multilateral and 2-person for bilateral. Each player/bargainer’s preference is to conceal their own preference at a sub-optimal Nash equilibrium. With multilateral bargaining there will be a tendency to free-ride on the bargaining ‘group’ (see Section 5.5 in D and S). The solution to this PD would be to find incentives which would induce each bargainer to reveal their preferences. This is a so-called incentive compatible system. The general conclusion is that a ‘third party’ with ‘coercive powers’, which the bargainers can ‘voluntarily’ subject themselves to, is required. Thus, bargaining without organisation fails as an alternative to the market. 153 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 154 Appendix 9.1: Introduction to evolutionary game theory Appendix 9.1: Introduction to evolutionary game theory Consider a population of players (N) where randomly chosen pairs play the game: C D C XX YZ D ZY TT where C and D are the strategies available to the players. Let the probability of playing D in the population be h. Then the probability of playing C in the population is (1 – h). In repeated random interactions: • the payoff to playing D is • PD = (1 – h)Z + hT • The payoff to playing C, • PD = (1 – h)X + hY Thus PD = h(T – Z) + Z PC = h(Y – X) + X If Z > X > Y > T (chicken payoff?) Z>X (T – Z) < 0 (Y – X) < 0 We may plot as follows: This shows that at equilibrium we have h≠N playing D and (1 – h≠)N playing C. But how would an off-equilibrium system evolve? 155 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Assume that strategies evolve in proportion to their relative success (payoff). In a fixed population players change strategy in this manner. Thus, when C players do better than D players, the latter will switch from D to C (the right-hand part of the above plot); when D does better than C then the switch will be to D. So the system will evolve to h≠. The equilibrium is stable. Now consider the rankings of the prisoner’s dilemma: Z > X > T > Y. Now Z>X (T – Z ) < 0 (Y – Z ) < 0 T>Y Plotting once again, we have: Now there is no mixed equilibrium. A system will evolve to h = 1 (the Payoff D C z T x 0 Nash equilibrium). Finally, assume: X > Z > T > Y. Now X>Z (T – Z) < 0 (Y – Z) < 0 T>Y 156 h 1 Y Appendix 9.1: Introduction to evolutionary game theory Plotting: Payoff D x C z 0 h=/ h Y 1 The system will evolve to h = 0 if it starts to the left of h≠; and to h = 1 if it starts to the right. h≠ is an unstable equilibrium and the system path is dependent. 157 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 158 Appendix 9.2: Logistic growth – an introduction Appendix 9.2: Logistic growth – an introduction N = number of organisations t = time dN =B–D dt (1) where B is the births per unit time, D is the deaths per unit time. B and D will in general depend upon N. Assume B = bN and D = dN where b = the average birth rate per organisation per unit time, So, d = the average death rate per organisation per unit time dN (2) = (b – d) N dt If b > d, then the population will grow at an increasing rate indefinitely (exponential growth) as follows: Number of organisations t Exponential growth also assumes that b and d are fixed and independent of N (no density dependence). We can regard equation (2) as the basic demographic equation. In the text we noted that Carroll and Hannan assume that both b and d depend on N in a non-linear fashion. Here we assume that the dependence is linear. b = b0 – kbN (3) d = d0 + kdN (4) where b0 and d0 are the values of b and d when N tends to zero. Note that b declines with N and d increases. These are rather standard assumptions in elementary demographic models. So, substituting (3) and (4) in (2), dN dt = ((b0 – kbN) – (d0 – kdN)) N When dN/dt = 0 (that is, when the birth and death rates are equal) 159 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach N≠ = b0 – d0/kb + kd Let r = b0 – d0 Then substituting we have: ≠ dN = rN ( N –≠ N ) N dt This is the slope of the logistic curve, which takes the form: N≠ Number of organisations t Notice that the growth of N is proportional to its departure from equilibrium (where the death and birth rates are equal). N≠ is often designated as K in the literature. You might like to put nonlinear relations between N, b and d into equation (2) and show that the population can decline from N≠. Further reading For further reading, see Carroll and Hannan (2004). 160 Appendix 10.1: Transaction cost analysis (Williamson’s analysis) Appendix 10.1: Transaction cost analysis (Williamson’s analysis) Transaction cost economics implies that a transaction should be placed either in a market or in an organisation so that costs are minimised. The relevant costs are production costs and transaction costs. Both of these costs vary with the asset specificity and uncertainty involved in the transaction. Consider the impact of asset specificity upon costs, for a relevant level of uncertainty and transaction. Production costs will vary as follows: Production costs Or ga nis ati on ket Mar 0 Specificity (Cost of org. Cost of market) 0 Specificity As specificity increases, the market becomes more expensive as outside opportunities decline. At low levels of specificity organisation is costly because outside options offer economies of scale. 161 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Transaction costs will vary as follows: Transaction costs Market Organisation Specificity (Cost of org. Cost of market) Specificity Combining production and transaction costs: Prod. cost (Cost of org. Cost of market) Prod. and Trans. cost x Specificity Trans. costs Market Organisation Thus an organisation transaction is favoured when the asset specificity exceeds x. 162 Appendix 12.1: The nature of hierarchy Appendix 12.1: The nature of hierarchy Let Size = N Spans = S Depth = L Then N = 1 + S + S2 + .... + SL–1, L ∑S N= i–1 i=1 . The size of the bottom layer n, n = SL–1 . The administrative component A, A = 1 + S + S2 + .... + SL-2 L–1 = ∑S i–1 i –1 . Since n = SL–1 , log n = (L – 1)logS = log n +1 log s . 163 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 164 Appendix 12.2: Administrative costs Appendix 12.2: Administrative costs Empirically established relationship. C = CEO income N = size of organisation log C = a log N – k where a, k are constants. Why? Assume n members at bottom S (average) span of control Income at bottom = 1 per person Assume ratio of income in consecutive layers in constant = (empirical results support this). Number at each level n + n + n2 S S .... + nL–1 S Total income 2 n + n β + n2 β .... + nL–1 β L–1 S S S Thus C = nL–1 β L–1 S log C = log n + (L–1)[logβ − logS] n n 2 n l–1 Administrative costs = s β + s2 β .... sl–1 β 165 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 166 Appendix 12.3: Horizontal differentiation and size Appendix 12.3: Horizontal differentiation and size Organisation size = N n1 units (span of CEO?) Each unit has n2 members ∴ N =n1n2 C1 = transaction costs of maintaining inter-unit dependencies Total cost between units = C1n1(n1 – 1) C2 transaction costs of maintaining intra-unit dependencies Total costs inside units = C2n2(n2-1)n1 Total transaction costs TC = C1n1(n1 – 1) + C2n2(n2-1)n1 Choose n1 and n2 to minimise TC Subject to: N – n1n2 = 0 Form a Lagrangian L = TC + (N – n1n2) = C1n1(n1 – 1) + C2n2(n2 – 1)n1 + (N – n1n2) Taking partial derivatives and setting to zero, ∂L = C1 (2n1–1) + C2n2(n2–1) +λ n2 = 0 Sn1 SL = C2 n1(2n2–1) − λ n1 = 0 δ n2 SL = N – n 1n2 = 0 Sλ Cost minimising value of n1: ≠3 ≠2 2n1– n1 = [C2 /C1] N2 We need to determine the signs of: ≠ δ n 1/ δ N and ≠ δ 2 n1/δ N 2 Thus ≠ 2 ≠ ≠ ≠ 6n1 (δ n1/δ N ) – 2 n1 ( δ n1/δ N ) = 2[C2 / C1]N and ≠ ≠2 ≠ δ n1/δ N =[C2 /C1] N/3n1– n1 167 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach So for ≠ n1> 1/3 ≠ δ n/δ N > 0 Similarly, ≠ S2 n1/δ N2 > 0 So the regularity discovered by Blau and Schoenherr is proven.1 Differentiation increases at a declining marginal rate with N (= size). Transaction cost considerations inside the firm explain a major regularity. 168 1 See Blau and Schoenherr (1971). Appendix 13: Sample examination paper Appendix 13: Sample examination paper Important note: This Sample examination paper reflects the examination and assessment arrangements for this course in the academic year 2013–2014. The format and structure of the examination may have changed since the publication of this subject guide. You can find the most recent examination papers on the VLE where all changes to the format of the examination are posted. Time allowed: three hours. Candidates should answer four of the following twelve questions. All questions carry equal marks. 1. Discuss the proposition that firms (organisations with an economic objective) only exist because of incomplete information. 2. How does the division of labour influence the design of organisations? 3. Weber analysed organisations as heavily dependent upon ‘rules’. Economists emphasise the role of ‘incomplete contracts’. Are these concepts compatible? Explain your answer. 4. An organisation is coordinated by a risk-neutral principal (P) who can only observe an agent’s output. The agents are also risk-neutral. What is the optimal contract from P’s point of view? What do you consider to be the advantages and disadvantages of analysing organisations from this standpoint? 5. ‘Corporate culture can be conceptualised as a mechanism whereby inter-personal trust and reciprocity are established.’ Discuss. 6. What do you understand by the term ‘team production’? Show how you would expect team production to influence the spans of control in an organisation. 7. Explain how ‘free-riding’ might arise in a ‘peer group’. What mechanisms could, in your view, overcome the problem? 8. The employment contract does not involve the exertion of ‘power’ of one actor over another. Do you agree? If so, why? If not, why not? 9. ‘Psychologists have demonstrated that it is rarely, if ever, possible to analyse organisations according to the precepts of rational, selfinterested behaviour.’ Discuss. 10. ‘There are many ways of locating a transaction in neither a market nor a hierarchical organisation.’ Outline some of the alternatives and explain what factors might determine their choice. 11. What contribution can evolutionary models make towards an understanding of organisation structures? 12. ‘Organisations are complex strategic systems, which implies that game theory should be at the centre of any attempt to analyse them.’ Discuss. 169 MN3127 Organisation theory: an interdisciplinary approach Notes 170