Uploaded by Annett Franklin

Remedies sample

advertisement
Major Outline
Remedies – UVA Law
Prof. Laycock, Fall 2016
Strategy:
 Big Picture: lump claim/parties into groups that can easily be disposed of based on similar facts
 Alternative Grounds: don’t hedge, but be sure to note alternative grounds and ambiguities
 Make sure you address every party and all theories of liability (see liabilities/COA sheet)
 Always evaluate strength of arguments, but don’t hedge and be decisive
 Consider which possibile remedy (if >1 available) will be best for the plaintiff
Themes, Policy, and History:
 Remedy:
 Economic Theory vs. Corrective Justice
o Economic Theory: remedies outcomes should be used to create proper incentives that create
economically efficient outcomes (optimal number of violations)
 Criticism: sometimes leaves those wronged not fully compensated, also morality
o Corrective Justice: Compensate because it is just; reduce violations of law to smallest possible
number
 Criticism: sometimes creates wasteful overdeterrence
o LAYCOCK: everything takes both into account, but one will be primary (often come out the
same way). More judges prioritize justice than law & economics. But see Posner.
 Writ System: old writs (with their own rules) have been replaced with one single civil COA
 Why do we compensate K expectancy rather than just reliance?
o Economy treats future values as present values. You can borrow against a contract.
o Promises rely in ways that are hard to measure and that can approach full value of expectancy.
o Moral or conventional sense of what promises mean.
o Substantive law of contract commits court and parties to situation post-performance, not to
situation pre-contract, and remedies should reflect that. Contracts work better if both sides can
assume they will generally be performed.
o Efficient breach theory does not explain compensating expectancy
 Freedom of Contract vs. Abuse/Efficient Outcomes:
o We want to let sophisticated parties have freedom of contract, but not to the extent that it is
subject to abuse
o See Kearney and limitations on damages cases
 Law/Equity:
 Judicial Discretion:
 Jury Fallibility
The Rightful Position
 Pp. xxiii-xvii, 1-18
Damages
 Rightful Position
o {
o Rightful Position: P is entitled to recovery that puts him in the position he occupied before the
injury.
 Specificity (Hatahley; see also uncertainty Bigelow, Glendale Federal)
 Lesser of Two Rule: P gets lesser of market value or replacement cost. See In re
September 11th Litigation.
 Exception: For special purpose property, replacement cost even if greater.
(Trinity Church real property & King Fisher Marine chattels; rule in In re
September 11th Litigation)
 See also environmental cases for varying views on the rightful position
o Expectancy vs. Reliance:
 Contracts: Expectancy is default rightful position in contract (see UCC section).
 See UCC buyer and seller defaults
 Torts: No expectancy in tort (Smith) EXCEPT in fraud cases (in most states).
o }
o United States v. Hatahley (10th Cir. 1958 p. 11) – Specificity & Standard
 FACTS: government took and killed special Indian horses, Indians didn’t mitigate
because they didn’t have $, lost other livestock. Emotional distress claim.
 D Court:
 Awarded $395 for each horse (replacement cost was $300)
 Awarded $3500 for emotional damages for each plaintiff
 Awarded half of the value of the lost livestock since they couldn’t figure out what
was lost because of killed horses
 Precision/Specificity/Standard: remedy must be grounded in legal standard with
sufficient facts and reasoning to justify the damages amount so as to put P in the rightful
position.
 But see: Excessive precision. At some point it is not economically efficient to
litigate to perfect accuracy.
 E.g., Mass Torts: formulas avoid need for individual damages hearings. D
strategy—destroy class by forcing every individual P to prove their precise
damages, but requires specificity.
 Abstract losses (e.g. anguish): Lower, but still existent, specificity requirements.
Usually go to jury because they can pull a number out of thin air. Judge can’t.
 APPLICATION: horse remedy pulled out of thin air.
 Proximate Cause: must show how the harm lead to each particular claim for damages,
and to what extent
 APPLICATION: Trial court erred in finding 50% of other livestock costs for no
reason (too speculative)
 Mitigation: No compensation for losses after time by which plaintiff could reasonably
have been expected to mitigate.
 APPLICATION: Indians’ damages cut off at time when they should have had
replacement horses.
 But see Alaska Case: fisherman didn’t pay child support because of bad business,
D court said get a real job, AK Supreme Court reversed saying that due to cultural
differences, no proof that it would be better
 Emotional Distress: must be calculated plaintiff by plaintiff, and explain reasoning
(Laycock: medical/psych. fees, missed work, pain normally judged by jury)
 OUTCOME: remand for new trial on damages
o Value as the Measure of Rightful Position


Pp. 18-35; Supp. Preface, 1-3
In re September 11th Litigation (S.D.N.Y 2008 p. 18)
 Lesser of Two Rule: Plaintiff is awarded lesser of market value or replacement
cost (alternatively, the easier one to calculate).
 POLICY: P is made whole in least expensive way
 Exception: Special Purpose Property (NY): you get replacement costs
even if they are greater. See also Trinity Church. Requires:
 (1) The improvement must be unique and must be specially built
for the specific purpose for which it was designed
 (2) There must be a specific use for which the improvement is
designed and the improvement must be so specially used
 (3* Most Important) There must be no market for the type of
property and no sales of property for such use; and
 LAYCOCK: WTC had a market, even if it was a limited
one (few could afford it)
 In practice, if this is satisfied, courts will find other ones
satisfied as well
 (4) The improvement must be an appropriate improvement at the
time of the taking and its use must be economically feasible and
reasonably expected to be replaced
 Market Value: “Price at which property would change hands between willing
buyer/seller, neither under compulsion to buy/sell, and both having reasonable
knowledge of relevant facts.” US v. Cartwright (SCOTUS, p. 22).
 If total loss: Market value with interest includes every stream of income.
No additional recovery for lost rent, etc., even if MV+interest is less than
MV+lost rent.
 Laycock thinks this is undercompensatory
 If temporary loss: Market value calculated by loss of use for time period
of loss.
 Property of Fluctuating Value (e.g. oil, soybeans): Apply the New York
Rule of highest market value between date of loss and date by which P
should have replaced.
 Replacement Cost: cost to replace. Can depend on P’s subjective situation (see
Hatahley)
 FACTS: WTC 40 years old, sold just before 9/11 for $2.8B, spent $16B to
replace. Insurance pay? Also had lease of property for 99 years to obtain rents.
Now only capable of getting rents for 86 years.
 APPLICATION: Owner gets MV, anything else would be windfall. 1960’s
buildings not worth the money it took to build state of art new WTC. Court said
$2.8B included value for rents discount to PV. Also gets interest (should, but
doesn’t really, compensate for rent)
 Trinity Church v. John Hancock Mutual Life Insurance Co.
(Mass. 1987 p. 28) – Special Purpose Real Property
 FACTS: Zero MV because landmark status restricts use, high replacement cost.
 Outcome: Replacement value minus depreciation awarded.
 Special Purpose Property (MA): Lesser of two does not apply when proven
value to owner is unjustly far from MV OR where there’s no way to determine
market value
 See also: New York test from 9/11 case.
 Reasonable Replacement Costs: Remedy: replacement cost minus depreciation
IF (1) replacement occurs AND (2) replacement is reasonable.
APPLICATION: here, reasonable replacement was done by reasonable
repairing
 King Fisher Marine v. NP Sunbonnet (5th Cir 1984 p. 27) –
Special Purpose Chattle
FACTS: P bought barge for $30k, was going to convert into drydock. Negligence
sunk it. 1/6 similar to it in the world. Expert testimony that it was ideally situated
for conversion
RULE: Where P can convince a trial that there was non-speculative value to him,
they can recover replacement cost (here $233k)
 Environmental/Land Restoration Cases: compare…
Sunburst School District No. 2 (MT 2007): benzene contamination of
school/homes. Court awarded $15 mil to restore properties even though property
was only worth $2 mil (avoid giving power akin to private right of eminent
domain)
Poffenbarger (AL 2007, p. 33): oil spill reduced value of land by $6k, remediation
costs were between $15k-$2.6million. Awarded reduction in market value.
Peevyhouse (OK 1963, p. 33): Restoration costs after coal mining were grossly
excessive to reduction in MV, so court only awarded MV reduction despite term
in K requiring D to restore land (not “principal purpose” of K).
o Expectancy or Reliance as the Measure of Rightful Position
 Torts: (Smith)
FEDERAL RULE: No expectancy in tort – only out of pocket loss. Comes up
often in securities fraud cases.
MAJORITY OF STATES: you can recover beyond out of pocket losses for fraud.
 UCC Default Remedies for Breach of K
Seller (p. 37)
 If buyer repudiates K or refuses to accept goods (Neri)
 Difference between contract price and market value
 If goods resold, difference between contract price and
resale price
 If buyer keeps goods and fails to pay
 Contract price
 Return of goods: if buyer is insolvent
 Incidentals less (cost of covering) expenses saved by buyer’s breach
 Lost volume profits: when seller covers, but would have able to sell even
more if not for breach
 Cannot get consequential damages or specific performance
Buyer (p. 47)
 If not delivered:
 K price less (market value OR cover price)
 AND incidentals (cost of covering); consequential damages
 OR Specific Performance: only if goods not readily available
elsewhere
 If good not delivered as warranted:
 Value of goods as warranted less value of goods received (UCC 2714(2)) at time of acceptance (Chatlos)
 AND incidentals and consequential damages (UCC 2-714(3))
 Neri v. Retail Marine Corp (N.Y. 1972 p. 35) Reliance v.
Expectancy for Retail Sales
FACTS: buyer breaches K (bargained away option to cancel for expedited
delivery on consideration of deposit) for sale of boat bc disabled and needs
























surgery (unsure if disabled and wouldn’t be able to make payments, or disabled
and wouldn’t be able to use boat); seller sells to another after incurring incidental
storage costs.
OUTCOME: Expectancy damages. Seller gets lost profits and incidental costs
(storage/insurance until later sale), and must return deposit that is in excess
thereof (restitution)
 NOTE: reliance damages would have been cost to store boat. (i.e.,
incidentals)
Expectancy Damages (General Rule): Enforcement of D’s promise to move P to
a new position. Can include both what is in contract, and incidentals, etc.
 POPLICY: Right to be paid in the future has value; allows for predictable
contracting; would make credit less available if creditors weren’t entitled
to expectancy.
 EXCEPTION: If damages are excessively large or cannot be proven.
 Criticism: Can lead to overcompensation. See Chatlos.
Reliance Damages: Returns P to his position prior to K as if he had never done
business with D.
Restitution: buyer gets back deposit (minus damages from breach) otherwise it
would be unjust enrichment
LAYCOCK: efficient breach can’t explain this; it’s a distribution case
 Chatlos Systems, Inc. v. National Cash Register Corp. (3d
Cir. 1982 p. 45) Gross Expectancy in Contract
FACTS: Value as warranted ($208K) grossly in excess of purchase price ($46K)
which was grossly in excess of value of goods delivered ($6K), bc machine didn’t
do what was warranted.
MAJORITY: $202K. Value as warranted minus value of goods delivered.
Equivalent to expectancy ($162K, value as warranted minus price) plus
disgorgement of seller’s $40K profit.
DISSENT: Buyer cannot receive more than bargained for, he only bargained for
$46K of product.
LAYCOCK: Case criticized for overcompensating. Example of courts’ strong
preference for expectancy damages.
 Texaco, Inc. v. Pennzoil Co. (Tex. Ct. App. 1987 p. 62)
Lowest Feasible Measure of Chosen Expectancy
FACTS: Tortious interference with right to contract. Pennzoil K’ed with Getty for
3/7 of its stock, which would give it rights to 3/7 of Getty’s oil. Getty reneged on
deal when Texaco offered higher price.
ISSUE: Pennzoil wanted to measure damages in terms of oil (more valuable).
Texaco wanted to measure damages in terms of stock.
Expectancy Choice: Look to the benefit of the bargain. Pennzoil was more
interested in the oil than acquiring minority ownership. Stock is worthless without
oil (Pennzoil was arbitraging). Thus damages measured in terms of oil.
 See below for consequentials and direct damages double dipping
Lesser of Two: Pennzoil may be made whole (i.e., get oil) through difference
between K price and: (1) MV of equivalent amount of stock (to be used to buy oil,
$.5B, Epstein’s idea), (2) replacement cost of finding more oil ($7.5B), or (3)
market value of oil ($23B),
 LAYCOCK: Equivalent stock is cheapest, but no other oil company was
selling this much stock, so replacement costs awarded as they were less
than MV.













Tortious Interference w/ Right to Contract: technically a tort case, but
compensates for expectancy like contract AND allows for consequential and
punitive damages
 Smith v. Bolles (SCOTUS 1889 p. 50) Tort and
Expectancy (Federal Rule)
FACTS: Tort action. Stock worthless, sold for $1.50, seller fraudulently
represented it would soon be worth $10.
FEDERAL RULE: No expectancy in tort – only out of pocket loss. Comes up
often in securities fraud cases.
 MAJORITY OF STATES: you can recover beyond out of pocket losses for
fraud.
 Where victim of breach ends up better off from K – market:
Nobs Chemical v. Koppers (5th Cir 1980 p. 38): Contract to buy at $500, market
price drops to $200, buyer repudiates. Seller had already contracted w/ supplier to
buy at $400 w/ right to cancel. (Simplified)
 K – market = $300
 Seller’s expected profit = $100 (this is K price minus what it paid to obtain
goods)
Courts are split as to whether to limit recovery to lost profit.
Compensatory Damages
o {
o Types:
 Direct Damages
 Consequentials
Must be a normal and proximate result of the breach (Buck)
Not available if they resulted from a failure to pay money (Meinrath)
Framing: benefit of the bargain can make consequentials actually direct damages
(Texaco)
 Direct vs. Consequential:
Direct (general) Damages: Initial impact of wrong; value of what was
taken/destroyed/damages/failed to deliver, etc.
Consequential (special) Damages: Everything that happens as a foreseeable and
inevitable result of the initial impact. difference is based on the
foreseeability/inevitability
o Issues:
 Avoidable Consequences (Mitigation): P is only entitled to
damages that he could not reasonably avoid (mitigate).
(S.J. Groves for contract; Hataley for tort)
 Limits on Damages Contract Only
Liquidated Damages Clause: Fixes fair compensation for breach to avoid
unnecessary litigation. (UCC 2-718(b))
 May be the exclusive remedy, even if it undercompensates. (Northern
Illinois Gas).
 May not be a penalty. TEST: Reasonable and proportional to actual loss
AND damages at time of K difficult to measure. (In Re TWA)
Limitation of Remedy Clause: Permissible unless it fails essential purpose (UCC
2-719). (see failed repair/replace clause but OK consequential damages clause
limitation in Kearney )
 Collateral Source
Download