CORPORATE AND SECURITIES LAW IN CHINA AND U.S. I. BASIC THEORIES ......................................................................................................... 8 A. MECHANISMS TO ORGANISE PRODUCTION ............................................................................................... 8 B. COSTS OF MARKET ...................................................................................................................................... 8 1. TRANSACTION COSTS .............................................................................................................................. 8 a) SEARCHING/DISCOVERING ............................................................................................................... 8 b) NEGOTIATION ................................................................................................................................... 8 c) ENFORCEMENT ................................................................................................................................. 8 2. INCOMPLETE CONTRACTS ...................................................................................................................... 8 3. ASSET SPECIFICITY ................................................................................................................................... 8 4. RESIDUAL CONTROL ................................................................................................................................ 9 C. COST OF FIRM ............................................................................................................................................. 9 1. DIMINISHING RETURNS .......................................................................................................................... 9 2. MULTIPLE SHAREHOLDERS ................................................................................................................... 10 a) HETEROGENEITY IN DECISION-MAKING ......................................................................................... 10 b) SHAREHOLDER APATHY .................................................................................................................. 10 3. D. AGENCY PROBLEM ................................................................................................................................ 10 AGENTS IN FIRMS ..................................................................................................................................... 10 1. WHY USE AGENTS? ............................................................................................................................... 10 2. AGENCY COSTS...................................................................................................................................... 11 a) EQUITY ............................................................................................................................................ 11 b) DEBT ................................................................................................................................................ 11 3. BASIC MODEL OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ...................................................................................... 11 a) CHINA .............................................................................................................................................. 11 b) U.S. .................................................................................................................................................. 11 E. PRINCIPAL IN FIRMS .................................................................................................................................. 11 F. CONTRACTARIAN THEORY OF CORPORATION .......................................................................................... 12 G. CORPORATE LAW AS DEFAULT RULES ...................................................................................................... 12 II. CORPORATE FORMATION AND CAPITAL ISSUANCE ................................................ 12 A. CORPORATE FORMATION IN U.S. ............................................................................................................. 12 1. INTERNAL AFFAIRS DOCTRINE .............................................................................................................. 12 2. PROMOTER’S CONTRACTUAL LIABILITY ................................................................................................ 13 3. PROMOTER’S FIDUCIARY DUTIES .......................................................................................................... 13 a) B. THE OLD DOMINION CONFUSION .................................................................................................. 14 CORPORATE FORMATION IN CHINA ......................................................................................................... 15 1|P a g e 1. C. PROMOTER’S LIABILITIES IN CHINA ...................................................................................................... 15 CAPITAL MATTERS IN U.S. ......................................................................................................................... 15 1. STOCK ISSUANCE IN U.S. ....................................................................................................................... 15 a) AUTHORISED CAPITAL DOCTRINE ................................................................................................... 15 b) ISSUING PRICE AND STOCK DILUTION ............................................................................................ 15 c) D. (1) ANTI-DILUTION PROVISIONS ...................................................................................................... 16 (2) JUDICIAL PROTECTION ................................................................................................................ 16 DIVIDENDS AND BUYBACKS IN U.S. ................................................................................................ 17 CAPITAL MATTERS IN CHINA..................................................................................................................... 17 1. STOCK ISSUANCE IN CHINA ................................................................................................................... 17 a) LEGAL CAPITAL DOCTRINE .............................................................................................................. 17 b) INITIAL CAPITAL CONTRIBUTION .................................................................................................... 17 c) SECONDARY EQUITY OFFERING ...................................................................................................... 18 2. DIVIDEND PAYMENT IN CHINA ............................................................................................................. 18 3. STOCK BUYBACKS IN CHINA .................................................................................................................. 18 III. LIMITED LIABILITY AND BASIC GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE ...................................... 19 A. PROS AND CONS OF LIMITED LIABILITY .................................................................................................... 19 B. PIERCING THE CORPORATE VEIL ............................................................................................................... 19 1. U.S. ........................................................................................................................................................ 20 a) ELEMENTS ....................................................................................................................................... 20 b) DOCTRINE OF INSUFFICIENT CAPITAL REJECTED ............................................................................ 20 2. CHINA .................................................................................................................................................... 20 3. COMPARISON ....................................................................................................................................... 21 4. EVALUATIONS/QUESTIONS TO ASK ...................................................................................................... 21 C. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE FOR WHOM? ................................................................................................ 22 1. BASIC GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE IN U.S. ............................................................................................. 22 a) DIRECTORS ...................................................................................................................................... 22 b) SHAREHOLDERS .............................................................................................................................. 22 2. BASIC GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE IN CHINA ......................................................................................... 22 a) DIRECTORS ...................................................................................................................................... 22 b) SHAREHOLDERS .............................................................................................................................. 22 3. IV. A. COMPARISON ....................................................................................................................................... 23 a) WHY DIRECTOR SUPREMACY? ........................................................................................................ 23 b) WHAT ARE THE PROBLEMS WITH SHAREHOLDER SUPREMACY IN CHINA? ................................... 23 FIDUCIARY DUTIES ................................................................................................ 23 DIRECTOR FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN U.S. ....................................................................................................... 23 2|P a g e 1. GENERAL PRINCIPLES ............................................................................................................................ 23 a) STANDARD OF CONDUCT – INSPIRATIONAL, BEST-PRACTICE, ABSTRACT ...................................... 24 b) STANDARD OF REVIEW – OPERATIONAL, STRIPPED OF IDEALISM ................................................. 24 2. DUTY OF CARE ...................................................................................................................................... 24 3. DUTY OF LOYALTY AND CONFLICT OF INTEREST .................................................................................. 25 B. a) CLEANSING OF CONFLICT................................................................................................................ 25 b) EFFECT OF CLEANSING .................................................................................................................... 25 c) DUTY TO MONITOR ......................................................................................................................... 26 DIRECTOR FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN CHINA ................................................................................................... 26 1. DUTY OF CARE ...................................................................................................................................... 26 2. DUTY OF LOYALTY ................................................................................................................................. 27 C. a) ACTIONS FORBIDDEN FOR DIRECTORS (ART 148) ........................................................................... 27 b) CLEANING DIRECTOR’S CONFLICT OF INTEREST ............................................................................. 27 SHAREHOLDER FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN U.S................................................................................................. 27 1. DEFINITION OF A CONTROLLING SHAREHOLDER ................................................................................. 28 2. DUTY OF LOYALTY ................................................................................................................................. 28 a) CLEANSING OF CONFLICT AND EFFECT ........................................................................................... 28 b) ENTIRE FAIRNESS ............................................................................................................................ 29 3. D. SALE OF CONTROL ................................................................................................................................ 29 a) SELLING CONTROL TO LOOTERS ..................................................................................................... 29 b) NARROWLY DEFINED CONCEPT OF DUTY OF CARE ........................................................................ 29 SHAREHOLDER FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN CHINA ........................................................................................... 30 1. CONTROLLING SHAREHOLDERS ............................................................................................................ 30 2. SALE OF CONTROL ................................................................................................................................ 30 E. COMPARISON OF FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN U.S. CF CHINA ........................................................................... 30 V. SHAREHOLDER RIGHTS .......................................................................................... 30 A. OVERVIEW ................................................................................................................................................ 30 B. SHAREHOLDER VOTING RIGHTS IN U.S. .................................................................................................... 30 1. ELECTION OF DIRECTORS ...................................................................................................................... 30 a) BOARD TENURE .............................................................................................................................. 31 b) ELECTION RULE ............................................................................................................................... 31 c) REMOVAL OF DIRECTORS ............................................................................................................... 31 d) NOMINATION .................................................................................................................................. 31 e) PROTECTION OF SHAREHOLDER FRANCHISE .................................................................................. 31 (1) PRIMARY PURPOSE & COMPELLING JUSTIFICIATION ................................................................. 31 (2) ADVANCE NOTICE BYLAW .......................................................................................................... 32 3|P a g e C. SHAREHOLDER VOTING RIGHTS IN CHINA ................................................................................................ 32 1. D. DIRECTOR NOMINATION AND ELECTION ............................................................................................. 32 a) RIGHT TO NOMINATE (NON-EMPLOYEE) DIRECTORS ..................................................................... 32 b) RIGHT TO NOMINATE IS ABSOLUTE ................................................................................................ 32 SHAREHOLDER PROPOSALS IN U.S. .......................................................................................................... 32 1. OVERVIEW ............................................................................................................................................ 32 a) PROPOSAL TO AMEND ARTICLES/BYLAWS ..................................................................................... 32 b) PROXY VOTING AND SHAREHOLDER PROPOSAL ............................................................................ 32 2. E. FEDERAL PROXY RULE ........................................................................................................................... 33 a) GENERAL REQUIREMENTS FOR MAKING PROPOSALS .................................................................... 33 b) SOURCES OF DISPUTE OVER EXCLUSION ........................................................................................ 33 (1) RELEVANCE EXCLUSION .............................................................................................................. 33 (2) ORDINARY BUSINESS EXCLUSION ............................................................................................... 33 SHAREHOLDER LITIGATIONS IN U.S. ......................................................................................................... 34 1. DIRECT VS DERIVATIVE ......................................................................................................................... 34 a) HOW TO DIFFERENTIATE?............................................................................................................... 34 b) DERIVATIVE SUITS ........................................................................................................................... 34 c) DIRECT SUITS................................................................................................................................... 34 2. DEMAND AND EXCUSE.......................................................................................................................... 35 a) EXCUSE OF DEMAND FOR FUTILITY ................................................................................................ 35 b) UNIVERSAL DEMAND RULE ............................................................................................................. 35 3. F. SPECIAL LITIGATION COMMITTEE ......................................................................................................... 35 SHAREHOLDER LITIGATIONS IN CHINA ..................................................................................................... 35 1. G. PREREQUISITES TO DERIVATIVE SUITS (ART 151) ................................................................................. 35 SHAREHOLDER INSPECTION RIGHTS IN U.S. ............................................................................................. 35 1. WHO CAN INSPECT? ............................................................................................................................. 36 2. WHAT CAN BE INSPECTED? .................................................................................................................. 36 H. SHAREHOLDER INSPECTION RIGHTS IN CHINA ......................................................................................... 36 1. shareholders of llC (ART 33) ................................................................................................................. 36 2. SHAREHOLDERS OF JOINT-STOCK LIMITED COMPANY (ART 97) .......................................................... 36 VI. FINANCING THE CORPORATION ............................................................................. 37 A. SECURITIES IN U.S. .................................................................................................................................... 37 1. INVESTMENT CONTRACTS .................................................................................................................... 37 2. NOTES ................................................................................................................................................... 37 a) REBUTTAL OF PRESUMPTION ......................................................................................................... 37 b) FAMILY RESEMBLANCE TEST ........................................................................................................... 37 4|P a g e 3. EQUITIES ............................................................................................................................................... 38 a) COMMON STOCKS .......................................................................................................................... 38 b) PREFERRED STOCKS ........................................................................................................................ 38 4. 5. DEBTS .................................................................................................................................................... 38 a) TYPES OF DEBT ................................................................................................................................ 38 b) INDENTURE/NOTE AGREEMENTS ................................................................................................... 39 c) DEFAULTS ........................................................................................................................................ 39 CONVERTIBLES ...................................................................................................................................... 39 B. SECURITIES IN CHINA ................................................................................................................................ 40 C. IPO IN THE U.S. ......................................................................................................................................... 40 1. REGISTRATION WITH SEC ...................................................................................................................... 40 2. LISTING AGREEMENTS WITH STOCK EXCHANGES ................................................................................ 41 3. REGISTRATION PROCESS ....................................................................................................................... 41 D. IPO IN CHINA............................................................................................................................................. 42 1. MAIN BOARDS ...................................................................................................................................... 42 2. SSE START MARKET ............................................................................................................................... 42 3. REGULATORY IPO LOCKUPS .................................................................................................................. 42 E. DUAL CLASS LISTING IN U.S. ..................................................................................................................... 43 1. LAW....................................................................................................................................................... 43 2. PRACTICES ............................................................................................................................................. 43 F. DUAL CLASS LISTING IN CHINA ................................................................................................................. 43 G. SHELF REGISTRATION (RULE 415) ............................................................................................................. 44 H. EXEMPTED OFFERING IN U.S. ................................................................................................................... 44 1. REG D .................................................................................................................................................... 44 2. REG A .................................................................................................................................................... 45 3. CROWDFUNDING (REG CF) ................................................................................................................... 46 I. DIRECT LISTING in U.S. .............................................................................................................................. 46 J. SPAC IN U.S. .............................................................................................................................................. 46 1. IPO PHASE ............................................................................................................................................. 47 2. DE-SPAC PHASE ..................................................................................................................................... 47 K. PRIVATE PLACEMENT & RESALE IN CHINA ............................................................................................... 47 VII. DISCLOSURE AND SECURITIES FRAUD .................................................................... 48 A. DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS IN U.S. ....................................................................................................... 48 B. 1. BLOCKHOLDER DISCLOSURE IN U.S. ..................................................................................................... 48 2. SHORT-SWING INSIDER DISCLOSURE AND PROFIT DISGORGEMENT IN U.S. (§16 OF 1934 ACT) ......... 49 DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS IN CHINA ................................................................................................... 49 5|P a g e C. SECURITIES FRAUD IN U.S. ........................................................................................................................ 49 1. MISREPRESENTATION IN REGISTRATION STATEMENT (§11 OF 1933 ACT) .......................................... 49 2. GENERAL ANTI-FRAUD RULE (§10(B) OF 1934 ACT) ............................................................................. 51 3. SECURITIES CLASS ACTIONS .................................................................................................................. 51 D. SECURITIES FRAUD IN CHINA .................................................................................................................... 52 1. SECURITIES CLASS ACTION .................................................................................................................... 52 E. SECURITIES FRAUD: A COMPARISON ........................................................................................................ 53 VIII. INSIDER TRADING AND MARKET MANIPULATION ............................................... 53 IX. M&A: BACKGROUND............................................................................................. 56 A. DRIVING FORCES OF M&A ........................................................................................................................ 56 B. MAJOR PLAYERS........................................................................................................................................ 57 1. PRINCIPALS ........................................................................................................................................... 57 2. PROFESSIONALS .................................................................................................................................... 57 C. M&A FINANCING ...................................................................................................................................... 58 1. DEBT FINANCING .................................................................................................................................. 58 2. EQUITY FINANCING ............................................................................................................................... 58 D. M&A IN U.S. AND CHINA – GENERAL COMPARISON ................................................................................ 58 X. M&A: DEAL STRUCTURE, APPRAISAL RIGHTS ......................................................... 58 A. STATUTORY MERGER IN U.S. .................................................................................................................... 58 1. GENERAL IDEA ...................................................................................................................................... 58 2. CORPORATE LAW PROCESS .................................................................................................................. 59 3. TRIANGULAR MERGER .......................................................................................................................... 59 4. LEGAL EFFECTS ...................................................................................................................................... 59 B. STATUTORY MERGER IN CHINA ................................................................................................................ 60 C. ASSET DEAL IN U.S. ................................................................................................................................... 60 D. TENDER OFFERS IN U.S. ............................................................................................................................ 61 1. GENERAL BACKGROUND ....................................................................................................................... 61 2. SUBSTANTIVE RULES ............................................................................................................................. 61 E. STOCK PURCHASES IN CHINA .................................................................................................................... 62 F. TENDER OFFERS IN CHINA ........................................................................................................................ 62 1. MANDATORY BID RULE ......................................................................................................................... 62 2. SUBSTANTIVE RULES ............................................................................................................................. 63 G. SHORT FORM MERGERS IN U.S. ................................................................................................................ 63 H. APPRAISAL RIGHTS IN U.S. ........................................................................................................................ 63 1. CONDITIONS ......................................................................................................................................... 63 2. VALUATION ........................................................................................................................................... 64 6|P a g e I. APPRAISAL RIGHTS IN CHINA .................................................................................................................... 65 XI. M&A: TAKEOVER DEFENCES AND FIDUCIARY DUTIES ............................................. 65 A. TAKEOVER DEFENSES IN U.S. .................................................................................................................... 65 1. REFUSAL TO SELL .................................................................................................................................. 65 2. SALE TO ALLIES ...................................................................................................................................... 67 B. FIDUCIARY DUTIES OF TARGET BOARD (U.S.) ........................................................................................... 68 1. POISON PILLS UNDER UNOCAL TEST ..................................................................................................... 68 2. REVLON RULE WHEN TARGET UP FOR SALE ......................................................................................... 69 C. REGULATING FREEZEOUT MERGERS IN U.S. ............................................................................................. 69 D. HOSTILE BIDS IN CHINA ............................................................................................................................ 70 E. 1. TRADING HALT IN CHINA ...................................................................................................................... 70 2. ZUIG INVESTMENT V ZHENXING BIOCHEM .......................................................................................... 70 a) FIRST STAGE: NEW BOTTLE, OLD WINE .......................................................................................... 70 b) SECOND STAGE: NOTHING VENTURED, NOTHING GAINED ............................................................ 71 c) THIRD STAGE: FIGHTING FOR THE LAST STRAW ............................................................................. 71 d) FOURTH STAGE: WINNING A BATTLE OR A WAR? .......................................................................... 71 e) FIFTH STAGE: “CROWN JEWEL” WITH CHINESE CHARACTERISTICS................................................ 72 HOSTILE BIDS: A COMPARISON ................................................................................................................ 72 7|P a g e I. BASIC THEORIES A. MECHANISMS TO ORGANISE PRODUCTION There are two mechanisms to organize production – firms (hierarchical, centralized); and markets (decentralized). To this end, the same function is achieved in two different ways. B. COSTS OF MARKET 1. TRANSACTION COSTS Refers to the cost of providing for some good or service through the market rather than having it provided from within the firm. In order to carry out a market transaction it is necessary to discover who it is that one wishes to deal with, to conduct negotiations leading up to a bargain, to draw up the contract, to undertake the inspection needed to make sure that the terms of the contract are being observed, and so on. A) SEARCHING/DISCOVERING The main reason why it is profitable to establish a firm would seem that there is a cost of using the price mechanism. The most obvious cost of “organising” production through the price mechanism is that of discovering what the relevant prices are. This cost may be reduced but it will not be eliminated by the emergence of specialists who will sell this information. B) NEGOTIATION The costs of negotiating and concluding a separate contract for each exchange transaction which takes place on a market must also be taken into account. In certain markets, e.g. produce exchanges, a technique is devised for minimizing these contract costs – however, they are not eliminated. It is true that contracts are not eliminated when there is a firm, but they are greatly reduced. C) 2. ENFORCEMENT INCOMPLETE CONTRACTS It may be desired to make a long-term contract for the supply of some article or service. This may be due to the fact that if one contract is made for a longer period, instead of several shorter ones, then certain costs of making each contract will be avoided. However, owing to the difficulty of forecasting (cognitive limits), the longer the period of the contract, the less possible (and less desirable) it is for the person purchasing to specify (linguistical limit – cannot describe/measure) what the contracting party is expected to do. Information limit – cannot verify compliance/breach 3. ASSET SPECIFICITY Asset specificity is usually defined as the extent to which the investments made to support a particular transaction have a higher value to that transaction than they would have if they were redeployed for any other purpose. 8|P a g e Williamson argued that transaction-specific assets are non-redeployable physical and human investments that are specialized and unique to a task. For example, the production of a certain component may require investment in specialized equipment, the distribution of a certain product may necessitate unique physical facilities, or the delivery of a certain service may be predicated on the existence of an uncommon set of professional know-how and skills. This may encourage opportunism, where a party could produce poor quality goods, deliver products late, or not follow through with the provisions of a contract. Agreement at t0: B produces 100 widgets for A, contract price $350. Each widget costs B $2 + investment in production equipment of $100 B invests in specific equipment at t1 A requests for renegotiation at t2 and lowers the contract price to $201. B will still accept it as the investment by B at t1 is a sunk cost – a rational person will not consider the sunk cost in making a decision. Foreseeing this above problem, B will not enter into an agreement with A at t0, hence efficient outcome falls through. This is the holdup problem, a situation where two parties may be able to work most efficiently by cooperating but refrain from doing so because of concerns that they may give the other party increased bargaining power and thus reduce their own profits. The holdup problem leads to severe economic cost and might also lead to underinvestment. SOLUTION: vertical integration, where A acquires B (or vice versa) so that the contract is replaced with firm 4. RESIDUAL CONTROL Hart and Moore posit that the sole right possessed by the owner of an asset is his ability to exclude others from the use of that asset. They further argue that control over a physical asset in this sense can lead indirectly to control over human assets. For example, if a group of workers require the use of an asset to be productive, then the fact that the owner (“party 1”) has the power to exclude some or all of these workers from the asset later on will cause the workers to act partially in party 1’s interest. The reason is that by doing so the workers put themselves in a stronger bargaining position later on with the person who determines whether they have access to the asset. This should be contrasted with a situation in which party 1 contracts for a service from someone else who owns the asset – under these conditions, the asset’s workers will tend to act in the other person’s interest since it is that person who is the boss they bargain with in the future. Hence, this view of the firm as a collection of physical assets leads to the intuitive conclusion that a person will have more “control” over an asset’s workers if he employs them than if he has an arm’s length contract with another employer of the workers. C. COST OF FIRM 1. DIMINISHING RETURNS The law of diminishing returns is a theory in economics which predicts that after some optimal level of capacity is reached, adding an additional factor of production will actually result in smaller increases in output. 9|P a g e As a firm gets larger, the costs of organising additional transactions within the firm may rise. Naturally, a point must be reached where the costs of organising an extra transaction within the firm are equal to the costs involved in carrying out the transaction in the open market. Moreover, as intra-firm transactions increase, an entrepreneur may fail to place the factors of production in the uses where their value is greatest. Again, a point must be reached where the loss through the waste of resources is equal to the marketing costs of the exchange transaction in the open market. Example: A factory employs workers to manufacture its products, and, at some point, the company operates at an optimal level. With all other production factors constant, adding additional workers beyond this optimal level will result in less efficient operations. 2. MULTIPLE SHAREHOLDERS A) HETEROGENEITY IN DECISION-MAKING Hansmann argues that multi-stakeholdership raises conflict due to the multitude of contrasting interests and causes incoherent strategic focus as members place their own needs and interests above those of the firm, resulting in interest conflicts and excessive monitoring that leads the firm to fail. Moreover, increasing member heterogeneity results in high decision-making costs – different groups of actors are considered to have fundamentally different interests and may be of nature to solve problems and pursue strategic directions to maximize their well-being at the expense of the welfare of the larger group to which they belong. B) SHAREHOLDER APATHY It is often said that shareholders are not interested in voting rights because each individual shareholder has only a small interest in any given company. As a result, the expense of remaining informed about the company exceeds the expected benefit; this is especially true given that any one shareholder’s vote is unlikely to affect the outcome of any election anyway. This leads to the problem of free-riding, where shareholders have little incentive to monitor senior management, because of the cost they bear while others reap benefits. However, it may be argued that it is not that shareholders do not care, but rather that they find it inefficient to over-invest in monitoring behavior. 3. AGENCY PROBLEM An agency problem is a conflict of interest inherent in any relationship where one party is expected to act in another’s best interests. There may be conflicts of interest between different levels of hierarchy. The problem of inducing an “agent” to behave as if he were maximizing the “principal’s” welfare is quite general. It exists in all organisations and all cooperative efforts. Agency Cost = Cost of Controlling Agent + Cost of Agent’s Opportunism D. AGENTS IN FIRMS 1. WHY USE AGENTS? 10 | P a g e 1. 2. Cost reduction in decision-making Specialisation a. Agents may have certain skillsets that shareholders lack (e.g. risk management) 2. AGENCY COSTS A) EQUITY Agency cost of equity refers to the conflict of interest that arises between management and shareholders. When management makes decisions that might not be in the best interest of the firm and that shareholders view as an action that will not increase the value of their shares, an agency cost of equity has arisen. For example, management may believe that a merger would be the best step forward for the business, whereas the shareholders see that the merger would not help grow the business, and the money spent on the merger could be better used in paying dividends and investing in other areas. Other examples include management misfeasance (fail to perform duty correctly) and malfeasance (intentional act of doing harm), and related party transactions. B) DEBT The agency cost of debt is the conflict of interest between shareholders and creditors of a firm based on the decisions made by management. The agency costs of debt would specifically be the actions taken by debtholders in restricting what management can do with their capital if they believe that management favours actions that would help shareholders instead of debtholders. For instance, managers may want to engage in risky actions they hope will benefit shareholders, who seek a high rate of return. Debtholders, who are typically interested in safer investment, may want to place restrictions on the use of their money to reduce risk. Debtholders usually place covenants on the use of capital, such adherence to certain financial metrics, which, if broken, allows the debtholders to call back their capital. 3. BASIC MODEL OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE A) CHINA China adopts a shareholder primacy model. To this end, the Chinese model stipulates that decision control is in the hands of the shareholders + the 2 nd board, whereas decision management is undertaken by the board and officers. B) U.S. On the other hand, the U.S. adopts a board primacy model. In this regard, the board has decision control and the decision management is undertaken by the CEO. E. PRINCIPAL IN FIRMS In both China and the U.S., shareholders are regarded as the principals of the firm. This is largely due to their vulnerability: 1. 2. Infinite relationship makes detailed contract illusory (vs creditors often short-term or project based) Dispersed nature makes bargaining prohibitively costly, and monitoring difficult (collective action problem) 11 | P a g e 3. Lack of organized political clout (vs labour unions, consumer organisations) Question: How to square this with CSR? F. CONTRACTARIAN THEORY OF CORPORATION The contractarian theory posits that the relationship between the managers and shareholders of a public corporation is contractual. As owners of the company, entrepreneurs and other pre-IPO shareholders want their company’s shares to command a high price when sold to the public. The price at which the company’s shares are sold will depend on the “promises” the pre-IPO entrepreneurs and shareholders make to the post-IPO public shareholders regarding governance arrangements the company will adopt once it is publicly held. Corporate contracts that include promises of effective corporate governance arrangements mean greater value to shareholders, which in turn means that investors will pay more for the company’s shares in the IPO and in the secondary market thereafter. Consequently, the contractarian theory implies that corporations will go public with corporate contracts that provide for governance structures that are, in Easterbrook and Fischel’s words, “most beneficial to investors, net of the costs of maintaining the structure.” In the contractarian vision, managers adopt a corporate contact by first incorporating in a state that offers default rules best suited to it, and then by customizing their own governance arrangements to the extent necessary to maximise the firm’s value. This customization appears as “promises in the articles of incorporation.” Shareholders accept the contract by buying shares in the company and implicitly pricing the quality of the firm’s governance commitments. G. CORPORATE LAW AS DEFAULT RULES As Easterbrook and Fischel explain, the role of corporate law follows logically from the contractual nature of the public corporation. That role is to facilitate atomistic contracting. Firms are believed to be heterogenous in their governance needs and are expected to adopt a diverse assortment of governance arrangements. Entrepreneurs, therefore, must be free to customize their corporate contracts. All the law needs to do is provide “off-the-rack” contract terms that can be adopted, or not, to the extent they enhance a firm’s value. The contractarian theory posits that there are no externalities in the contract between pre-IPO entrepreneurs and shareholders on the one hand, and post-IPO shareholders on the other, so there is no need for mandatory rules; market mediated individual choice will lead to socially optimal corporate contracts. II. CORPORATE FORMATION AND CAPITAL ISSUANCE A. CORPORATE FORMATION IN U.S. The promoter leads the process of incorporation in a particular state. There is no federal charter. The four essentials during incorporation are: (1) corporate name (Co or Inc); (2) registered address; (3) number of authorized stocks; and (4) the incorporator’s name and address. The incorporation takes effect upon filing, and directors may be appointed after incorporation. 1. INTERNAL AFFAIRS DOCTRINE The internal affairs doctrine is a choice of law rule in corporations law – simply stated, it provides that the “internal affairs” of a corporation will be governed by corporate statues and case law of the state in which the corporation is incorporated, sometimes referred to as the lex incorporationis. Delaware is the pre-eminent state of incorporation – the courts there have been key to the state’s dominance as they are highly efficient, and incrementally evolve through “situationally-specific” 12 | P a g e discretion. Corporate franchise fees total to $500m a year and accounts for 20% of Delaware’s state income This can be contrasted to California, which has a long-arm statute (i.e. a statute that allows for a court to obtain personal jurisdiction over an out-of-state defendant on the basis of certain acts committed by an out-of-state defendant, provided that the defendant has a sufficient connection with the state). o CGCL §2115: shareholder of 50% + voting rights have CA addresses AND 50% + business in CA measured by corporate assets, sale or payroll; inapplicable to nationally traded corporations o SB 826 and AB 979 of 2020: Board diversity rules, applicable to all corps with executive headquarters in CA The internal affairs doctrine applies to those matters that pertain to the relationships among or between the corporation and its officers, directors, and shareholders. The conflicts practice of both state and federal courts has consistently been to apply the law of the state of incorporation to the entire gamut of internal corporate affairs. The internal affairs doctrine does not apply where the rights of third parties external to the corporation are at issue, for example, contracts and torts (Vantagepoint). The internal affairs doctrine ensures that issues such as voting rights of shareholders, distribution of dividends and corporate property, and the fiduciary obligations of management are all determined in accordance with the law of the state in which the company is incorporated. On the other hand, the “external affairs” of a corporation, such as labor and employment issues and tax liability, are typically governed by the law of the state in which the corporation is doing business. 2. PROMOTER’S CONTRACTUAL LIABILITY A promoter acts on behalf of a corporation before it is formed. The corporation will not be personally liable for any contracts entered into by the promoter on its behalf prior to incorporation unless it adopts the contract, either by direct action of the board of directors, or through implied action, by accepting the benefit of the contract. The promoter remains personally liable for pre-incorporation contracts he enters into, even after corporate adoption, unless and until there has been a novation (i.e. the assumption will not be effective retroactively, so the promoter is still liable for obligations due before assumption + even after assumption the promoter is the pre-incorporation contract binds the promoter – essentially, the promoter is guaranteeing performance by the corporation). A promoter is personally liable on a pre-incorporation contract except when the counterparty knew that the corporation was not in existence at the time of the contract but nevertheless agreed to look solely to the corporation for performance. The counterparty’s knowledge of the nonexistence of the corporation alone will not exempt the promoter from personal liability. On the contrary, this knowledge indicates intention to bind the promoter since he/she cannot be the agent of a non-existing corporation. From a business perspective, if the pre-incorporation contract cannot bind the promoter, it won’t bind the counterparty either. Then, the business purpose of preparing for the operation of a new corporation will fall through. 3. PROMOTER’S FIDUCIARY DUTIES The promoter owes a fiduciary duty to (1) the corporation to be formed, (2) its shareholders and (3) other promoters. In effect, this means that the promoter should avoid conflict of interests with the corporation. In 13 | P a g e cases of conflict, full disclosure and consent from disinterested directors, shareholders/subscribers are required, unless the promoter can prove entire fairness to the corporation. To prove entire fairness, need to demonstrate both fair dealing (i.e. process) and fair price (i.e. substance). Fair dealing encompasses questions of process, including how the transaction is timed, initiated, structured, negotiated, and disclosed and how the approvals of the directors and the stockholders are obtained. Fair price relates to the economic and financial terms of the transaction, including any relevant factors that affect the intrinsic or inherent value of a company’s stock, such as the market value and assets of the company, pro forma analysis and other valuation metrics, and a fairness opinion. The fair price and fair dealing components are not viewed in isolation but rather in conjunction. The most frequently seen pattern is that the promoter acquired assets and resold to the corporation after it is incorporated at a higher price. A) THE OLD DOMINION CONFUSION The Old Dominion Copper company cases demonstrate forcibly the lack of harmony in the courts as to the nature of and remedy for promoters’ frauds in the organisation of corporations. Summary of Facts Bigelow (“B”) and Lewisohn (“L”) acquired a copper mine, then organized a corporation under the laws of New Jersey (“NJ”), with an authorized capital stock of $3.75m but with only $1000 paid in (as permitted by the NJ statute). With the latter amount paid in, the organisation was completed, whereupon the directors (the tools of B and L), voted to increase the capital stock to its maximum, to transfer to B and L, in exchange for their mining and other property worth not to exceed $1m, shares of stock in the new company of the par value of $3.25m, and also to offer the balance of $500k to public subscription. The net result was as follows: B and L obtained 13/15 of the entire capital stock and the public 2/15, when, according to the amount of capital respectively contributed, the former should have obtained 10/15 and the latter 5/15 ($1m:$500k = 2:1). Supreme Court of U.S. The Supreme Court of the United States held that inasmuch as B and L were at the time the contract was made the sole shareholders in the company, the latter was bound, and the mere acquisition of new shareholders, even by public subscription, could not change the nature of the transaction, if it was binding at the time it was made. Holmes J laid very great stress in his opinion upon the unchanging identity of the corporate person. The decision here seems sound. It would have been better had Holmes J not expressed himself in a way as to make possible the inference that under no circumstances can a corporation complain of a wrong if all the existing shareholders participated in it. B and L did in fact commit fraud against the original subscribers at par, but Holmes J could not be persuaded that this would entitle a court of equity to treat this as a corporate wrong to be remedied by mulcting them, principally for the benefit of their coconspirators. That a situation sometimes does arise in which to remedy a corporate wrong would benefit some of the wrongdoers, is inevitable, but the B and L cases did not present it. Supreme Court of Massachusetts On the other hand, the Supreme Court of Massachusetts held that by reason of the fact that public subscriptions were contemplated at the very time when the contract was authorized, it did not bind the corporation and because the public paid par for its stock, the court found the value of all the stock to be par, and ordered a 14 | P a g e judgment against B for an amount equal to the difference between $3.25m and $1m. What is more surprising than the court’s method of finding the amount of the fraudulent profit and mulcting B for the whole of it is the fact that if these tortfeasors had only taken all of the stock, and donated $500k to the corporation as treasury stock, to be sold to the public, the transaction would have passed muster. However, something that is not discussed in both decisions is whether the issuance price is fraudulent, or whether it is fair, which is actually (or in fact should be) the main debate here. B. CORPORATE FORMATION IN CHINA Corporate formation in China is also registration based: the requisite details include name, residence, charter, registered capital, legal representative, directors. The filing is done with the Industrial and Commercial Authority (ICA), which conducts a procedural review before issuing a business license. For a limited liability company, the incorporation is by the shareholders (no more than 50 natural or legal person) For a joint stock limited company, the incorporation is by promoters (2-200, half having residence in China); promoters are shareholders as well o In practice, many joint stock limited companies are converted from limited liability companies once the number of shareholders exceeds 50 or planning for IPO It is pertinent to note that in China, the corporate purpose still needs to be enumerated, and directors (of both boards) need to be appointed in advance. 1. PROMOTER’S LIABILITIES IN CHINA Promoters are liable for contracts concluded in their names for the benefit of the corporation in formation, but the corporation will also be liable after being formed. If the promoters enter into the contract in the name of the corporation being formed, the corporation will be liable for these contracts after being formed, unless the corporation can prove these contracts are purely for promoter’s benefit and the counterparty knows the fact. (NOTE THE REVERSAL OF THE BOP CF U.S.) Additionally, unlike the U.S., the promoter’s role as guarantor is not clear, and promoters have no fiduciary duties Where incorporation fails the promoters are liable for the contracts concluded during incorporation, jointly and severally (SPC Interpretation III, art 2-4). C. CAPITAL MATTERS IN U.S. 1. STOCK ISSUANCE IN U.S. A) AUTHORISED CAPITAL DOCTRINE Pursuant to the authorized capital principle, the total number of stocks that can be issued must be approved by shareholders and recorded in the charter (“authorized shares”). The Board of Directors decides when to issue, how many to issue (“outstanding shares”), and at what price to issue, as long as the number of outstanding shares after issuance will not exceed the total number of authorized shares. B) ISSUING PRICE AND STOCK DILUTION 15 | P a g e Stocks can be issued with or without a par value, and the par value can be any amount that is provided in the charter. When the stocks have par value, the price of issuance cannot be below the par value On the other hand, when the stocks have no par value, the price of issuance is the fair value determined by the Board Stock dilution takes place when a company issues additional shares to new individuals joining the company in exchange for capital, services or even professional advice. This, in turn, reduces the ownership of current shareholders. Some common situations of stock dilution include: 1. 2. 3. Conversion by optional security holders – stock options granted to individuals, including board members or employees, may be converted into common shares that eventually increases the total share count. Offering new shares in exchange for services or acquisitions – a company may offer new shares to the shareholders of a firm that it is acquiring. Small business can also provide new shares to people in exchange for the services they offer. This is usually offered to consultants, advisors, key employees and others who offer services to the company. Secondary offerings to raise additional capital – when a company is acquiring capital for growth opportunities, it offsets the investors equity in exchange for funding. (1) ANTI-DILUTION PROVISIONS Anti-dilution provision are clauses built into convertible preferred stocks and some options to help shield investors from their investment potentially losing value. Anti-dilution provisions are also referred to as preemptive rights. These provisions act as a buffer to protect investors against their equity ownership positions becoming diluted or less valuable. This can happen when the percentage of an owner’s stake in a company decreases because of an increase in the total number of shares outstanding. The two common types of anti-dilution clauses are known as “full ratchet” and “weighted average”. With a full ratchet provision, the conversion price of the existing preferred shares is adjusted downward to the price at which new shares are issued in later rounds e.g. if the original conversion price was $5, and in a later round the conversion price is $2.50, the investor’s original conversion price would adjust to $2.50 The weighted average provision uses the following formula to determine new conversion prices: C2 = C1 X (A + B) / (A + C) C2 = new conversion price C1 = old conversion price A = number of outstanding shares before a new issue B = total consideration received by the company for the new issue C = number of new shares issued (2) JUDICIAL PROTECTION The issuing price cannot be below the “fair value” or used to oppress minority shareholders. To this end, directors, being fiduciaries of the corporation, must in issuing new stock, treat existing shareholders fairly. The power to determine the issuing price must be exercised for the benefit of the corporation and in the interest of all the stockholders (Sidler). 16 | P a g e The court also recognised that a shareholder’s preemptive rights may be seriously undermined if the stock offered was worth substantially more than the offering price, since any such purchase would dilute that shareholder’s interest and impair his original holding. On the facts of Sidley, the difference in selling price and book value of the stock was calculated to force the appellant into investing additional sums. The respondents did not offer a valid business justification for the disparity in price and were the sole beneficiaries from it. The price was a tactic to make the failure of the appellant to exercise his preemptive rights costly. However, since the stipulation entitled the appellant to the same compensation as the respondents, the disparity in equity interest case by their purchase did not affect the stockholder income from Sulburn – by permitting the respondents to recover their additional investment before the remaining assets of Sulburn are distributed, all the stockholders will be treated equally. C) DIVIDENDS AND BUYBACKS IN U.S. Dividend payments and buybacks are decided by the Board of Directors – no shareholder interference is allowed. The minimum requirements for dividends or share buy backs are as follows: 1. 2. 3. First, the balance sheet must show a surplus i.e. the net asset value must be > 0 (“statutory surplus”) Second, the company cannot fall be insolvent under statute (balance-sheet) or common law (liquidity) EXCEPTION: However, there is an exception which allows nimble dividends to be paid out – i.e. payment of dividends from retained earnings by a firm which made no profits – provided it is paid out of net earnings in recent two years. “Funds legally available” is not synonymous with “surplus” - the court in SV Investments determined that “funds legally available” contemplates funds (in the sense of cash) that are available (in the sense of on hand or readily accessible through sales or borrowing – i.e. liquidity) and can be deployed legally for redemption without violating the statutory surplus requirements. The court concluded that even if Thoughtworks had sufficient surplus to effect the redemption, it did not have funds legally available to effect the redemption and, therefore, it was not obligated to redeem the preferred stock. D. CAPITAL MATTERS IN CHINA 1. STOCK ISSUANCE IN CHINA A) LEGAL CAPITAL DOCTRINE The “registered capital” must be declared in the charter and registered with the ICA (art 25, 81). The registered capital must be maintained – there is a strict procedure to change (especially reduce) registered capital. There are further strict restrictions on dividend payments and stock buybacks. B) INITIAL CAPITAL CONTRIBUTION The initial capital contribution cannot be lower than the registered capital. The initial shareholders need to subscribe to the stocks at the price provided in the charter. Payments can be made in installments, but shareholders are liable up to their subscription (art 28, 83). In-kind contributions need to be appraised and cannot be less than the declared subscription amount. In case of shortage, all initial shareholders (promoters) are liable jointly and severally to creditors of the corporation (art 30, 93). 17 | P a g e C) SECONDARY EQUITY OFFERING Shareholders of limited liability companies have pro rata preemptive rights (art 34). 2. DIVIDEND PAYMENT IN CHINA There is mandatory capital reserve requirement – capital reserve funds are set aside on the basis of 10% of the after-tax profits. When it accumulates to the level equal to 50% of the registered capital, the company can stop setting aside the capital reserve funds. Note optional reserve according to shareholder resolutions Additionally, the loss of previous years needs to be made up (if the mandatory reserve is insufficient to cover the loss). ***Dividends can only be paid after losses are made up and reserves are allocated. 3. STOCK BUYBACKS IN CHINA In general, stock buybacks are not allowed as there is a prohibition on capital withdrawal (art 35, 91). However, there are six exceptions (art 142): 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Based on shareholder resolution to reduce registered capital a. Proposed by the board (art 46, 108) with 2/3 shareholder approval (art 43, 103) b. Creditors must be notified within 10 days after capital reduction resolution, and newspaper advertisements must be run within 30 days, who have the right to require debt payments or provision of security within 30 days after receiving the notice or within 45 days after newspaper ads (art 177) c. The charter and registration must be changed with the ICA (art 179) d. In Huagong v Yangduan, the court held that PRC Company Law does not prohibit limited liability companies from repurchasing their own shares. Repurchases made in accordance with the statutory requirements will not harm the interests of the company’s shareholders and creditors, nor will it constitute a violation of the company’s obligation to maintain its capital. On the facts of the case, the repurchase agreement did not ostensibly deviate from market practice, including bearing the normal operation costs and achieve normal operational performances. To merge with another company that is a shareholder Based on 2/3 director approval to grant employee stock incentives (no more than 5% of outstanding shares) To provide shares needed for conversion of convertible bonds To protect corporate value or shareholder interests (10% treasury stocks allowed for up to 3 years) – can be used for defence against hostile takeover Due to the request of a dissident shareholder in M&A or spin off (“appraisal right” – right of shareholder to have a judicial proceeding or independent valuator determine a fair stock price and oblige the acquiring corporation to purchase shares at that price) U.S. vs CHINA Does the legal capital doctrine actually provide more protection to creditors than the authorized capital doctrine? 18 | P a g e The legal capital doctrine is primarily associated with creditor protection and seeks to protect creditors by saying that only that portion of the net assets that exceeds the capital and undistributed reserves can be paid out to shareholders. What will creditors consider when making decisions to lend? Creditors consider the credit risk based on a number of factors (“5Cs): 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. III. Capacity a. Lenders must be sure that the borrower has the ability to repay the loan based on the propose amount and terms b. E.g. For business loan applications, the financial institution reviews the company’s past cash flow statements to determine how much income is expected from operations Capital a. Capital for a business-loan application consists of personal investment into the firm, retained earnings, and other assets controlled by the business owner b. Banks prefer a borrower with a lot of capital because that means the borrower has some skin in the game Conditions a. Refers to the terms of the loan itself, as well as any economic conditions that might affect the borrower b. Business lenders review conditions such as strength or weakness of the overall economy and the purpose of the loan Character a. Refers to a borrower’s reputation or record vis-à-vis financial matters Collateral a. Business borrowers may use equipment or AR to secure a loan b. Applications for a secured loan are looked upon more favourably than those for an unsecured loan because the lender can collect the asset should the borrower stop making loan payments LIMITED LIABILITY AND BASIC GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE A. PROS AND CONS OF LIMITED LIABILITY Limited liability reduces investment risk and encourages equity investment. It also facilitates portfolio diversification, thus enabling shareholder passivity. On a related note, it supports separation of ownership from control and promotes specialization (especially in management and risk-taking). However, the flipside to limited liability is that it allows shareholders to externalize business costs to creditors. This is especially problematic where the creditors are non-consensual, hence prices cannot be adjusted ex ante. B. PIERCING THE CORPORATE VEIL ‘Piercing the corporate veil’ is an equitable exception to limited liability. However, the application of this mechanism may differ under the following two dimensions: 1. 2. Whether the corporation is public or private (separation vs concentration of ownership and control) Whether the creditor is consensual or non-consensual (contract vs tort) 19 | P a g e Creditor Type Contract Low externalization; Corporation Type Public High monitoring cost Tort Medium externalization; High monitoring cost Medium externalization; High externalization; Low monitoring cost Low monitoring cost Private 1. U.S. Where a corporation is run purely for personal ends and not for the benefit of the corporation, then there is a basis for piercing the corporate veil and holding the shareholder personally liable. A) ELEMENTS To succeed in an action for piercing the corporate veil, the claimant must prove two things (Sea-Land Services, applying Van Dorn): 1. 2. First, that there is a unity of interest between the individual and the corporation; and Second, that the allowance of a limited liability would sanction a fraud or promote an injustice On the facts of Sea-Land, while the plaintiff was able to prove the first stage, he was unable to adduce enough evidence with respect to the second stage. Hence, the corporate veil was not pierced as the claimant had yet to offer evidence to completely demonstrate that the corporate veil should be pierced. B) DOCTRINE OF INSUFFICIENT CAPITAL REJECTED A corporation with a minimum amount of assets is a valid one and cannot be ignored (Walkovszky v Carlton). It is pertinent to note Judge Keating’s dissent in Walkovsky where he held that Carlton should be liable as the corporation was intentionally undercapitalized in order to avoid liability, which is a clear abuse of the corporate entity. However, this “insufficient capital” rationale has not been widely persuasive with courts, perhaps due to a fear that it would chill entrepreneurial activity. 2. CHINA Pursuant to art 20, s 3 of the Company Law, shareholders who abuse the independent corporate status and limited liability to evade debts and cause serious harm to creditors will be jointly and severally liable for corporate debts. According to the SPC Proceedings of the National Conference on Civil and Commercial Adjudications 2019, “abuse” has the following characteristics (art 10-12): 20 | P a g e 1. 2. 3. Commingling of legal status (“alter ego”) – asset commingling is the focus, whereby the shareholder uses corporate assets without accounting records, or mixes corporate profits and shareholder dividends Undue control (“corporate dummy”) – there are excessive related-party transactions to transfer benefits or shift liabilities Obvious undercapitalization – where there is a mismatch of capital and expected risk of business. However, caution is needed in application due to the ambiguity of capital sufficiency a. Prima facie, the claimant in Walkovsky may succeed here. But it depends on the specific factual matrix, especially what is considered sufficient capital in the context of taxi companies Commingling of Assets The commingling of personnel, business, finance, and other aspects of affiliate companies that leads to the impossibility of separating out properties and the loss of independent personalities constitutes the commingling of properties. If the affiliate companies that comingle personalities seriously harm the interests of their creditors, the affiliate companies bear joint and several liability among themselves for the external debt (XCMG Construction). On the facts of XCMG Construction, the characterization factors of personality (personnel, business, and finance) showed a high degree of commingling, resulting in an inability to distinguish individual property. A company’s independent property is the material guarantee of its independent bearing of responsibilities – when affiliate companies are unable to separate their properties and lose their independent personalities, they lose the basis for bearing responsibilities independently. 3. COMPARISON Insofar as piercing the corporate veil is concerned, China and U.S. have very similar legal doctrines and patterns in practice. For example, the doctrine is only applicable for private companies, and tort creditors are no more likely to be protected than contract creditors. However, a salient difference between the two countries is that China is more willing to pierce the veil. 4. 1. EVALUATIONS/QUESTIONS TO ASK Should contract creditors to be protected the same as, or more than, tort creditors? Many courts have acknowledged a distinction between the justifications for piercing the veil by a tort creditor and those for a contract creditor. Nearly all such courts that have acknowledged such distinction have concluded that tort creditors should have an easier path to piercing the corporation’s veil of limited liability. This is because tort victims should not be required to bear the costs of risky corporate behaviour when they neither chose to deal with the corporation nor had the opportunity to protect themselves from the risk of corporate insolvency. 2. Should public corporations never be pierced? There is no record of a successful piercing of the corporate veil of a publicly traded company because of the large number of shareholders and the extensive mandatory filling entailing in qualifying for listing on an exchange. 3. 4. Why are the Chinese courts more willing to pierce? Is judicial practice in this regard messy? 21 | P a g e C. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE FOR WHOM? In the U.S., business corporation is organized and carried on primarily for the profit of the stockholders. The powers of the directors are to be employed for that end (Dodge v Ford Motor Company), which includes promoting the value of the company for the benefit of stockholders (eBay Domestic Holdings). In this regard, promoting, protecting or pursuing non-stockholder considerations must lead at some point to value for stockholders (eBay Domestic Holdings). On the other hand, art 5 of the PRC Company Law espouses that companies engaged in business activities must, inter alia, abide by social morals and business ethics, be honest and trustworthy, accept the supervision of the government and the public, and assume social responsibility. 1. BASIC GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE IN U.S. Pursuant to §141(a) of the DGCL, the business affairs of every corporation are to be managed by or under the direction of a board of directors (with possible exceptions, which includes provisions that provide otherwise in the company’s certificate of incorporation). A) DIRECTORS The shareholders elect the directors, who in turn elect the corporate officers. The officers are delegated with the power to manage corporations, and the directors monitor the officers and decide strategic issues. B) SHAREHOLDERS Shareholders can only vote on a limited number of issues besides the election of directors. Some of these include bylaw amendments and M&A. Moreover, they usually do not have the power to call special meetings (if not authorized in articles/bylaws – at least in Delaware). Shareholder proposal rights are limited, and they cannot conflict with the management power of the board. Furthermore, shareholder proposals are not binding even if adopted except for bylaw amendments. 2. BASIC GOVERNANCE STRUCTURE IN CHINA On the other hand, China has adopted a shareholder supremacy principle – the shareholder meeting is the organ of corporate power (arts 36, 98), and the board of directors is accountable to the shareholder meeting (art 46). A) DIRECTORS China has adopted the German dual-board structure, where there is a board of directors and a supervisory board. The board of directors is to make proposals for shareholder resolutions, and to decide the operation and investment plans. The board of directors also selects officers. The supervisory board is to monitor the board of directors and officers. 1/3 of the supervisory board must be employees (art 51, 117) B) SHAREHOLDERS Shareholders holding at least 10% shares for more than 90 days can call special shareholder meetings if neither board elects to do so (arts 40, 101). 22 | P a g e Shareholders in listed companies with at least 3% shares can make proposals of unlimited numbers and about anything legitimate (art 101). These proposals are binding upon adoption. 3. COMPARISON A) WHY DIRECTOR SUPREMACY? Shareholder apathy, information asymmetry, conflicts of interests among shareholders Separation of ownership and control: specialization Foundation of governance: authority coupled with accountability Rein in agency problem: judicial oversight, shareholder election right, market force B) WHAT ARE THE SUPREMACY IN CHINA? PROBLEMS WITH SHAREHOLDER Board is fractional, and directors are deeply dependent on majority shareholders o Directors generally do not consider themselves as fiduciaries of all shareholders o Independent directors are few, weak and many are unprofessional Small shareholders are neither mobilized nor represented Do you think shareholders in listed companies should be empowered to oversee corporate business and affairs directly? Many of today’s shareholders have higher expectations relating to engagement with the board and management than shareholders years past. Bebchuk argues that providing shareholders with the power to intervene can significantly address importance governance problems that have long occupied the attention of corporate law scholars and financial economists. In particular, shareholder power to make “rules-of-the-game” decisions – to amend the corporate character or change the state of incorporation – would ensure that corporate governance arrangements change over time in ways that serve shareholder interests. Shareholder power to make “gameending” decisions – to merge, sell all assets, or dissolve – would address managers’ excessive tendency to retain their independence. Finally, shareholder power to make “scaling-down” decisions – to contract the company’s size by ordering a cash or in-kind distribution – would address problems of empire building and free cash flow. What’s your opinion about the dual board structure? While a two-tiered structure offers some advantages over a unitary structure in its roles, representation, and balance, it does have a few drawbacks. Supervisory boards emphasise the appointment of independent directors to supervisory boards. While these directors may be appointed with the best interest of the company in mind, independent directors often stand to benefit – both financially and in their industry reputations – from the success of the company’s stock. While prioritizing stock market performance may be in the company’s best interest, it’s not always in the best interests of its employees. Warping a board member’s “independence” in this way also leads to more risk averse positioning, often liming the company’s growth. IV. FIDUCIARY DUTIES A. DIRECTOR FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN U.S. 1. GENERAL PRINCIPLES 23 | P a g e There are two basic duties – duty of care and duty of loyalty (which encompasses the duty of good faith). A) STANDARD OF PRACTICE, ABSTRACT CONDUCT – INSPIRATIONAL, BEST- With regard to the duty of care, the directors must be well-informed and adequately diligent. For duty of loyalty, the directors must act in the best interest of shareholders. B) STANDARD OF REVIEW – OPERATIONAL, STRIPPED OF IDEALISM With regard to the duty of care, the business judgment rule is the applicable standard. For duty of loyalty, the entire fairness, the intermediate standards in mergers & acquisitions (compelling justification for interfering with shareholder franchise). 2. DUTY OF CARE The level of precaution required when making business decisions is that without gross negligence. Business Judgment Rule To pass the BJR, the following requirements must be met: 1. 2. 3. 4. First, directors have no conflict of interest (i.e. majority of the board is independent), Second, they made a business decision (i.e. they did something rather than taking no action) Third, they made a decision in good faith (i.e. in the best interest of the company, sufficient as long as any rational mind would agree the decision makes some business sense) Directors are well-informed when making the decision. In this regard, meetings are necessary, expert advice often essential. Voting should only be done after adequate discussion a. On voting, it is pertinent to note that directors are not allowed to vote by proxy (unless otherwise provided by the articles or bylaws); no alternate director Without conflict of interest, good faith and well-informed decision are all presumed by law unless the plaintiff can rebut these presumptions. If the plaintiff fails to do so, the court will not second guess a business decision of the board. In Smith v van Gorkom, the majority held that the directors were grossly negligent because they quickly approved the merger without substantial inquiry or any expert advice. As such, the board of directors breached the duty of care that it owed to the corporation’s shareholders and, accordingly, the protection of the BJR was unavailable. Furthermore, the court rejected the defendant’s argument that the substantial premium paid over market price indicated that it was a good deal. In so doing, the court noted the irony that the board stated that the decision to accept the offer was based on their expertise, while at the same time asserting that it was proper because the price offered was a large premium above market value. EV1: However, it is submitted that the case was decided wrongly. As aptly put by the dissenting judge, the application of the BJR on the facts was wrong – an overview of the entire record, rather than the limited view of bits and pieces which the majority exploded like a popcorn, was convincing enough that the directors made an informed business judgment which was buttressed by their test of the market. Furthermore, imposing such 24 | P a g e liability on directors provides a strong disincentive for the best potential directors to serve on the board, which may consequently result in worse corporate governance. The aftermath of this decision is reflective of the poor outcome reached here, as D&O insurance premiums soared by 10 times, in addition to insurers pulling out of the D&O market. EV2: As such, the Delaware legislature took swift action to change the Delaware General Corporation Law, adding §102b(7) which exempts directors from monetary damages for breaches of duty of care. 3. DUTY OF LOYALTY AND CONFLICT OF INTEREST Conflict of interest arises where the director is not (1) disinterested; or (2) independent. On (1), affairs involve the director’s own (or his affiliates’) economic stakes. On (2), the directors are beholden to someone whose economic stakes are involved (shareholder, officer, or even a third-party). The failure to act in good faith is a condition to finding a breach of the fiduciary duty of loyalty and imposing fiduciary liability. However, a failure to act in good faith is not conduct that results, ipso facto, in the direct imposition of fiduciary liability. Failing to act in good faith may result in liability because the requirement to act in good faith is a condition of the duty of loyalty (Stone v Ritter). A) CLEANSING OF CONFLICT To cleanse this conflict, there are two alternative routes that may be adopted: 1. 2. First, through good faith and informed approval by (majority of) the other directors without conflict (“director approval”); or a. Approval is valid even if such directors cannot meet the quorum b. A “special committee” composed fully of independent and disinterested directors often grants the approval Second, through the informed and uncoerced approval by shareholders subject to regular shareholder approval process (quorum + majority of attending shareholders) (“shareholder approval”) Alternatively, directors may be exempted from liabilities of appropriating corporate opportunities through articles or board resolution (DGCL §122(17)). B) EFFECT OF CLEANSING As a result of the cleansing of conflict, transactions with conflict will not be void or voidable solely because of the conflict. However, cleansed transactions are nonetheless subject to judicial review. Director Approval Under this limb, the BJR is applied. Shareholder Approval Under this limb, there are two specific scenarios to consider: Corwin Rule - Where interested directors and shareholders did not vote, the BJR applies even if the majority of the board are interested or lack independence (Corwin v KKR). Where interested directors and shareholders did vote, the entire fairness standard is applicable (Fliegler v Lawrence). 25 | P a g e In Fliegler v Lawrence, the facts were such that the directors composed a majority of the shareholders. In such a situation, shareholder ratification is not legitimate. Hence, the burden of proof that the transaction was fair rests of the defendant-directors. On the facts, this was satisfied. No Approval The transaction must be entirely fair to be effective. C) DUTY TO MONITOR The board breaches this duty when the board takes no action rather than makes some decision. It is pertinent to note, however, that this is the most difficult cause of action for plaintiffs (shareholders) to win a fiduciary case against. In Caremark, the issue of compliance was raised – specifically, the board’s responsibility with respect to the organisation and monitoring of the enterprise to ensure that the corporation functions within the law achieve their purpose. To this end, the court held that most company decisions do not need director supervision – only a sustained or systematic failure of the board to exercise oversight will establish the lack of good faith that is a necessary condition to liability. The point of oversight and liability was expanded upon in the latter case of Stone v Ritter. There, the court stated that the necessary conditions that predicate for director oversight liability are: a) The directors utterly failed to implement any reporting or information system or controls; or b) Having implemented such a system or controls, consciously failed to monitor or oversee its operations thus disabling themselves from being informed of risks or problems requiring their attention. In either case, imposition of liability requires a showing that the directors knew that they were not discharging their fiduciary obligations. Where directors fail to act in the face of a known duty to act, they breach their duty of loyalty by failing to discharge that obligation in good faith (Stone v Ritter). B. DIRECTOR FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN CHINA Pursuant to art 147, a director has two basic fiduciary duties: (a) duty of care; and (b) duty of loyalty. However, there is a lack o a clear standard of review. To this end, judges sometimes look to American cases and legal doctrines for guidance. The cases on fiduciary duties are relatively few – when the rule is applied, the case is often about less complex administrative decisions rather than complex business decisions. 1. DUTY OF CARE The duty of care requires that directs must make decisions in the best interest of the company, without negligence, and with reasonable care – the determination of whether a director has fulfilled his or her duty of care should be made based on three elements: (1) the action was taken in good faith; (2) with the care that an ordinary person in a similar position in similar circumstances would exercise in handling his or her own affairs; and (3) in a manner that is reasonably believed to be in the best interests of the company (Shanghai Chuanliu). It is very risky to be directors of Chinese companies, especially listed companies: There is no business judgment rule explicitly provided by law or stated by the court 26 | P a g e Moreover, breaches of directors’ duty of care are handled like a regular tort negligence case: no gross negligence is required There are no exemptions provided from monetary damages for directors in breach of the duty of care D&O insurance is very limited as well 2. DUTY OF LOYALTY There is no general definition in law, and the courts look to U.S. for a clue. The focus is on conflict of interest, whereby the directors must protect the corporate interest when their own interest is in conflict with corporate interest and must not take advantage of the director’s position in pursuit of their own or third party’s interest at the expense of the corporate interest. A) ACTIONS FORBIDDEN FOR DIRECTORS (ART 148) a) b) c) d) Taking bribes Misappropriate or embezzle corporate assets Deposit corporate funds into individual bank accounts Lending corporate funds to others or provide security interest for others using corporate assets without proper authorization by shareholders or the board e) Self-dealing with the company without shareholder approval f) Taking corporate opportunities g) Competition with the company h) Misappropriate commissions paid to the company i) Breach of confidentiality B) CLEANING DIRECTOR’S CONFLICT OF INTEREST a) For self-dealing, shareholder approval is required (art 148) – question, however, whether interested shareholders should recuse themselves b) For RPTs (in listed companies), approval by a majority of disinterested directors is required. However, if the number of interested directors outnumber those who are disinterested, then shareholder approval is required (art 124) However, monetary damages cannot be exempted based on disclosure and approval by shareholders if the transaction causes loss to shareholders (Interpretation V, art 1). C. SHAREHOLDER FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN U.S. Shareholders do not owe fiduciary duties to the corporation or other shareholders unless they are controlling shareholders. Shareholder fiduciary duty only becomes an issue when certain board decisions are involved. Examples include having a controlling shareholder on both sides of the transaction, or a controlling shareholder competing for (distinct) benefit against other shareholders. In Sinclair Oil, the court held that under the BJR, a court will not interfere with the judgment of a board of directors unless there is a showing of gross and palpable overreaching. A board of directors enjoys a presumption of sound business judgment, and its decisions will not be disturbed if they can be attributed to any rational business purpose. 27 | P a g e On the facts of Sinclair, no self-dealing was found as Sinclair received nothing from Sinven to the exclusion of its minority stockholders. Hence, the applicable standard was not the intrinsic fairness test, rather the business judgment standard should be applied. 1. DEFINITION OF A CONTROLLING SHAREHOLDER A controlling shareholder is one who: 1. 2. Has voting rights > 50%; or Is a minority controller (i.e. one who has sufficient voting power and management authority) – theory of inherent coercion On the second limb, control of the board is key, either through general control or control of board decisions on particular transaction with conflict of interest – in Tesla Motors, the court held that a minority stockholder may as a matter of law be a controlling stockholder if the controller conceivably has the “de facto power of a significant stockholder, which, then coupled with other factors, [such as managerial supremacy], gives that stockholder the ability to dominate the corporate decision-making process.” 2. DUTY OF LOYALTY Controlling shareholders only have a duty of loyalty (i.e. avoiding conflict of interest) but not duty of care or monitoring Exception probably in relation to sale of control A) CLEANSING OF CONFLICT AND EFFECT There are two ways through which controlling shareholders’ conflict of interest can be cleansed: 1. 2. First, through a special (independent) committee approval a. Fully authorized including negotiation with the controlling shareholder, rejection of controller’s proposal and searching for alternatives b. Freedom to choose its advisors at the corporation’s expense c. Sufficient access to information including inquiries of the management d. Proper functioning, adequate deliberation e. Effect: entire fairness standard still applies while shifting burden of proof to the plaintiff Second, via a majority of minority shareholder approval a. Must be a condition of the transaction from the very beginning (start of material negotiation) b. Informed and noncoerced c. Effect: entire fairness standard still applies while shifting the burden of proof to the plaintiff If both conditions are met, the effect is for the BJR to apply instead. As expounded in Kahn v M&F Worldwide Corp, the BJR will only apply if: i. ii. iii. iv. v. vi. the controller conditions the procession of the transaction on the approval of both a special committee and a majority of the minority stockholders the special committee is independent the special committee is empowered to freely select its own advisors and to say no definitively the special committee meets its duty of care in negotiating a fair price the vote of the minority is informed there is no coercion of the minority 28 | P a g e B) ENTIRE FAIRNESS The concept of entire fairness encompasses fair dealing and fair price. Fair dealing embraces questions of when a merger transaction was timed, how it was initiated, structured, negotiated, disclosed to the directors, and how the approvals of the directors and the stockholders were obtained. Fair price relates to the economic and financial considerations of the proposed merger, including all relevant factors: assets, market value, earnings, future prospects, and any other elements that affect the intrinsic or inherent value of a company’s stock (Weinberger v UOP Inc). The test for fairness is not a bifurcated one – all aspects of the issue must be examined as a whole because the question is one of entire fairness. On the facts of Weinberger, the court was of the view that fair dealing was transgressed as the matter of disclosure to the defendant’s directors was wholly flawed by conflicts of interest raised in the feasibility study, and the minority shareholders were denied critical information. Thus, the vote of the minority shareholders was not an informed one. 3. SALE OF CONTROL Generally, there are no restrictions on the sale of control by controlling shareholders. Market forces apply, and there is no mandatory bid requirement. A) SELLING CONTROL TO LOOTERS However, liability may arise when controlling shareholders are selling control to “looters”. Under the looting doctrine, a controlling shareholder violates his fiduciary duties when he negligently sells his controlling stake to an apparent looter who indeed then proceeds to plunder the corporation. As held in Harris v Carter, while a person who transfers corporate control to another is surely not a surety for his buyer, when the circumstances would alter a reasonably prudent person to a risk that his buyer is dishonest or in some material respect not truthful, a duty devolves upon the seller to make such an inquiry as a reasonably prudent person would make, and generally to exercise care so that others who will be affected by his actions should not be injured by wrongful conduct. EV: It is pertinent to note that the duty of care that the court is advocating for in this case is not the one that is understood generally, rather it is specific to the U.S. corporate law. Otherwise, there will be a conceptual dissonance between the requirement of gross negligence for breaches of fiduciary duties, vis-à-vis mere negligence being made out for breaches of duty of care. B) NARROWLY DEFINED CONCEPT OF DUTY OF CARE A narrowly defined duty of care can be justified on efficiency grounds – this is because in looting cases, the controlling shareholder’s incentives may in fact be insufficient to protect the minority shareholders. Typically, the controller does not participate in the downside of selling to a looter, because after the sale, when the looter starts plundering the corporation, the seller is no longer invested in the firm. Accordingly, in the absence of a duty of care, the seller typically has little incentive to screen potential buyers. Even worse, the controller may profit from selling to a looter, because the price that the looter offers for the controlling stake may reflect the acquirer’s expected profits from plundering the corporation at the expense of the minority shareholders. Courts have been very much aware of this problem and have been willing to apply the looting doctrine in scenarios where the controlling shareholder parted with his stake at an obviously excessive price, and thus “sold out” the minority shareholders. There is then, in looting cases, a strong case to be made for a duty of care for controlling shareholders. 29 | P a g e D. SHAREHOLDER FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN CHINA 1. CONTROLLING SHAREHOLDERS There is no provision of fiduciary duties for controlling shareholders in law. However, PRC company law generally prohibits “abuse of rights to harm the company or other shareholders interest” by any shareholder (art 20). Moreover, controlling shareholders or actual controllers of listed companies have a “duty of good faith” to the company and other shareholders (CSRC Corporate Governance Guidelines for Listed Companies, art 63). However, these are extremely vague standards of conduct without a standard of review – hence, shareholder fiduciary duty cases are even rarer in practice. 2. SALE OF CONTROL For listed companies, the mandatory bid rule applies, hence control premium must be shared. For private limited liability companies, other shareholders have a right of first refusal (ROFR), unless opted out of in the articles of association (art 71). E. COMPARISON OF FIDUCIARY DUTIES IN U.S. CF CHINA China seemingly follows the U.S. in both legislative and adjudicative sense, at least in terms of format. However, there are two major differences: 1. 2. In China, there is a lack of protection of directors In China, there is a lack of a clear definition of controlling shareholders’ fiduciary duties Generally speaking, fiduciary duties lawsuits arise infrequently in China. V. SHAREHOLDER RIGHTS A. OVERVIEW There are three major shareholder rights: 1. 2. 3. Right to vote Right to transfer/exit Right to suit Additionally, there are two corollary rights: 1. 2. Right of proposal: prerequisite to vote Right to inspect: essential to voting and litigation In the U.S., the board has primacy hence there is a clear boundary between board power and shareholder rights. Conversely, in China, shareholder primacy is adopted hence shareholders enjoy much broader powers (at least on paper). B. SHAREHOLDER VOTING RIGHTS IN U.S. 1. ELECTION OF DIRECTORS 30 | P a g e A) BOARD TENURE A regular board is subject to election every year. In contrast, where staggered boards are concerned only 1/3 are subject to election every year. B) ELECTION RULE For a valid quorum, at least 50% of the voting rights must be present in person or by proxy at the shareholder meeting, subject to change by articles or bylaws – however, it cannot be below 1/3 (DGCL §216(a)). In principle, plurality voting is applicable. However, majority voting can be adopted by the articles or bylaws in non-contested elections. As a side, cumulative voting is barely used. Plurality voting: whoever has the highest number of votes, even if below 50%, is elected (necessary for contested elections without a run-off/second round) Majority voting: elected only if received 50%+ votes cast at the election (strengthens shareholder voice in non-contested elections; adopted by 90%+ S&P 500 corporations) Cumulative voting: shareholders can cast all votes for one candidate; at least S/(D + 1) + 1 votes needed to elect 1 director in an election of D directors with total S total votes cast (not very helpful in protecting dispersed minority shareholders) C) REMOVAL OF DIRECTORS Directors can be removed with or without cause in regular boards, but only for cause in staggered boards. D) NOMINATION Generally, the board nominates directors. However, shareholders can nominate via “proxy access” – shorthand for the ability of a long-term shareowner (or a group of long-term shareowners) to place a limited number of alternative board candidates on the company’s proxy card (ballot) for the company’s annual shareholder meeting. In order to be eligible, these shareholders must have collectively held at least 3% shareholding (by at most 20 shareholders) for at least 3 years to nominate 20% directors (SEC rule §14a-8 and DGCL §122). The bylaws an also require reimbursement of expenses spent by dissenting shareholders for “proxy contests” if the dissidents at least partially won. E) PROTECTION OF SHAREHOLDER FRANCHISE (1) PRIMARY PURPOSE & COMPELLING JUSTIFICIATION In Blasius Industries v Atlas Corp, Blasius argued that the directors of Atlas did not have authority to act for the primary purpose of thwarting the exercise of a shareholder vote – specifically, Blasius argued that Atlas’ actions were selfishly motivated in order to protect the incumbent board from a perceived threat to its control. Contrarily, Atlas argued that the business judgment rule prevented the courts from looking into the reasons for why the management voted to increase the size of the board of directors. The court held that even when an action is taken in good faith, it could constitute an unintended violation of the duty of loyalty that the directors owe to the shareholders. The directors are in effect agents of the shareholders. If the purpose of an action is to obstruct the shareholders’ reasonable control over their business, that is inequitable – if there is a disagreement between the shareholders and the directors, the directors have to defer to the judgment of the shareholders. 31 | P a g e However, the court also held that there may be some compelling justification for the directors’ actions, so the actions are not forbidden per se: 1. 2. 3. When stockholders are about to reject a third-party merger proposal that the independent directors believe is in their best interests; When information useful to the stockholders’ decision-making process has not yet been considered adequately or not yet been publicly disclosed; and When if the stockholders vote no the opportunity to receive the bid will be irretrievably lost. (2) ADVANCE NOTICE BYLAW This bylaw requires shareholders to submit to board notice and supplementary information before nominating directors or introducing other business at shareholder meeting. The relevant information include the following: a) Nominees’ hedging positions, background and qualifications b) An agreement by the nominee to comply with fiduciary duties and all governance policies and guidelines of the company c) Advance notice is usually 60-120 days, some stretching to 180 days Advance notice bylaws are frequently upheld as valid by Delaware courts, but often construed narrowly (Hill International Inc v Opportunity Partners LP). C. SHAREHOLDER VOTING RIGHTS IN CHINA 1. DIRECTOR NOMINATION AND ELECTION Shareholders who hold 10% shares, individually or in concert, for 90 days, can call for special shareholder meetings when neither board calls a meeting (art 101). A) RIGHT TO NOMINATE (NON-EMPLOYEE) DIRECTORS The right to nominate non-employee directors is considered to belong solely to the shareholders (Jiang Pengnian v Shanghai Shenhua Industries). B) RIGHT TO NOMINATE IS ABSOLUTE Shareholders with 3% stocks individually or in concert can make proposals to shareholder meetings including director nominations with 10 days’ advance notice (art 102; CISC v Haili Biotech). D. SHAREHOLDER PROPOSALS IN U.S. 1. OVERVIEW A) PROPOSAL TO AMEND ARTICLES/BYLAWS Article amendments are reserved for the Board, and shareholders can only dis/approve. With respect to bylaws, only procedural amendments are allowed – substantive amendments are not allowed (CA Inc v AFSCME Employees; DGCL §113). Once adopted, shareholder bylaw amendments are binding. B) PROXY VOTING AND SHAREHOLDER PROPOSAL 32 | P a g e Most shareholders of listed companies vote by proxy. To solicit proxies from other shareholders, disclosure must be made about the agendas to be voted and the rationales for supporting these agenda. Federal proxy rules provide the information to be disclosed (proxy statements) and safeguards its accuracy (SEC Rule 14a). Proxy soliciting can be very costly. The board can always use corporate funds to do so while shareholders need to spend their own money (reimbursement is possible only if the bylaw allows and usually when shareholders are successful). Hence, shareholders want to have their proposals included in board proxies. 2. FEDERAL PROXY RULE Corporate boards can exclude shareholder proposals for various reasons and seek SEC no-action letter to endorse the exclusion. Shareholders can challenge the decision in federal courts. A) GENERAL REQUIREMENTS FOR MAKING PROPOSALS To make a proposal, the shareholder must continuously hold $2,000 in stocks for 3 years, $15,000 for 2 years or $25,000 for 1 year (SEC Rule 14a-8(a)) The proposal, including any accompanying support statement, may not exceed 500 words (SEC Rule 14a-8(d)) The proposal must be received not less than 120 calendar days before the date of the company’s proxy statement released to shareholders in connection with the previous year’s annual meeting (SEC Rule 14a-8(e)) B) SOURCES OF DISPUTE OVER EXCLUSION Notwithstanding that a shareholder had complied with procedural requirements, the company may rely on other bases to reject their proposal. These include the following: (1) RELEVANCE EXCLUSION Pursuant to SEC Rule 14a-8(b)(i)(5), if the proposal relates to operations which account for less than 5 percent of the company’s total assets at the end of its most recent fiscal year, and for less than 5 percent of its net earnings and gross sales for its most recent fiscal year, and is not otherwise significantly related to the company’s business. However, proxy proposals are includable notwithstanding their failure to reach the specified economic thresholds if a significant relationship to the issuer’s business is demonstrated on the face of the resolution or supporting statement (Lovenheim v Iroquois Brands). (2) ORDINARY BUSINESS EXCLUSION Pursuant to SEC Rule 14a-8b(i)(7), shareholders are not allowed to interfere with the board’s authority of managing business and affairs. There are two main considerations: 1. The first relates to the subject matter of the proposal. Certain tasks are so fundamental to the management’s ability to run a company on a day-to-day basis that they could not, as a practical matter, be subject to direct shareholder oversight. a. Examples of this include the management of the workforce, such as the hiring, promotion and termination of employees, decisions on production quality and quantity, and the retention of suppliers b. HOWEVER, proposals relating to such matters but focusing on significant social policy issues generally would not be considered to be excusable because such issues typically fall outside the scope of the management’s prerogative 33 | P a g e 2. The second consideration relates to the degree to which the proposal seeks to micromanage the company by probing too deeply into matters of a complex nature that shareholders, as a group, would not be qualified to make an informed judgment on, due to their lack of business expertise and lack of intimate knowledge of the company’s business a. It comes into play where the proposal seeks intricate detail, or seeks to impose specific timeframes or methods for implementing complex policies On the facts of Trinity Wall Street v Wal-Mart Stores, the court held that under the ordinary business exclusion, Wal-Mart can exclude in its proxy statement Trinity’s proposal which sought to require the development of standards for determining whether to sell firearms and other products that might pose risks to the public and to the company’s reputation and brand value. According to the court, although Trinity’s proposal addressed a significant social policy issue, it did not transcend Wal-Mart’s ordinary business operations because weighing safety concerns regarding large number of products was a routine business matter for retailers. Moreover, the court opined that consideration of the risk that certain products posed to Wal-Mart’s economic success and reputation for good corporate citizenship was enmeshed with how the company ran its business and the retailerconsumer interaction. E. SHAREHOLDER LITIGATIONS IN U.S. 1. DIRECT VS DERIVATIVE A) HOW TO DIFFERENTIATE? In determining whether a stockholder’s claim is derivative or direct, the issue must turn solely on the following questions: (1) who suffered the alleged harm (the corporation or the suing stockholders, individually); and (2) who would receive the benefit of any recovery or other remedy (the corporation or the suing stockholders, individually) (Tooley v Donaldson). A direct shareholder claim included a duty, breach of that duty, and direct injury to the shareholder (independent of injury to the corporation) (Tooley v Donaldson). Examples Direct – securities frauds (in relation to buy or sale of securities, in proxy solicitation, etc); protection of voting rights or inspection rights; to compel payment of declared dividends; suit based on minority oppression; contract breach or torts against individual shareholders Derivative – waste of corporate assets or usurpation of corporate opportunities; contract breach against the corporation; malpractice of corporate advisors Both – breach of fiduciary duties in M&A, especially where selling a corporation B) DERIVATIVE SUITS Derivative suits are considered as combining two suits: one to enforce the corporation’s obligation (to shareholders) to enforce its claims and one to enforce corporation rights of action against the wrongdoer. C) DIRECT SUITS Direct suits can be brought individually or in class. 34 | P a g e 2. DEMAND AND EXCUSE Shareholders must demand the board to prosecute the cause of action before initiating derivative actions unless the board can be excused. Once a demand is made, the board’s decision whether to bring the suit as demanded is protected by the business judgment rule. A) EXCUSE OF DEMAND FOR FUTILITY Demand is excused for futility. To raise a reasonable doubt that the directors’ actions would be protected under the business judgment rule, the plaintiff must allege specific facts that causes reasonable doubt that (Aronson v Lewis): 1. 2. The directors are disinterested and independent; and The challenged transaction was otherwise the product of a valid exercise of business judgment B) UNIVERSAL DEMAND RULE Under this doctrine, there is no excuse to demand. Once rejected by the board to sue, the plaintiff must show that the majority of the board is not independent or the board did not reject in good faith after reasonable inquiry (MBCA §7.44(d)). 3. SPECIAL LITIGATION COMMITTEE Once the demand is excused and a derivative suit is filed, the board can mobilise independent directors who are not the defendants of the suit to form a special litigation committee. This committee will review the case and decide whether continuation is in the corporation’s interest. If it decides not, a motion to dismiss will be filed on behalf of the corporation. To succeed, the committee must prove its disinterestedness, independence and must act in good faith and with care (Zapata Corp v Maldonado). Moreover, the trial court should conduct its own independent judgment to decide whether continuing the suit is in the corporation’s interest (ibid). Under the MBCA §7.44, instead of a trial court conducting its own independent judgment, a committee of at least 2 members is appointed by a majority independent directors to do the same. F. SHAREHOLDER LITIGATIONS IN CHINA In China, both direct and derivative litigations are allowed (art 151; art 152). Chinese law explicitly allows shareholders to bring derivative suits against third parties that are not corporate insiders – as a side, derivative suits against third parties are rare in the US given the demand rule. 1. PREREQUISITES TO DERIVATIVE SUITS (ART 151) For a shareholder to be entitled to bring a derivative suit, he must continuously hold 1% stocks individually or in concert for 180 days. Furthermore, he must serve a demand on the board in writing (supervisory board) to sue supervisory board members, or third parties. When the demand is refused or no suit is brought within 30 days after demand, the shareholder can bring derivative suits to the court. G. SHAREHOLDER INSPECTION RIGHTS IN U.S. 35 | P a g e 1. WHO CAN INSPECT? In general, there is no requirement of shareholding % (California gives 5% absolute right to inspect). However, proper purpose is needed: e.g. to solicit support on voting issues; to uncover management wrongdoings (crucial to derivative suits). In Security First, the court held that the trial court could rely on all of the evidence presented at trial – the failure of the plaintiffs to articulate certain “magic words” is not fatal to the action. Moreover, the court held that the plaintiff had the burden of proof to demonstrate a proper purpose, but was not required to prove a preponderance of the evidence that waste and mismanagement were actually occurring. 2. WHAT CAN BE INSPECTED? Shareholder list vs other books and records (DGCL §220(c)) Three categories (MBCA §§16.01(e), 16.02(a)(b)) o No proper purpose is required: articles and bylaws; shareholder meeting minutes; names and addresses of directors and officers; latest annual reports; etc o Proof of proper purpose: board meeting minutes; shareholder lists; accounting records o No access: all others H. SHAREHOLDER INSPECTION RIGHTS IN CHINA 1. SHAREHOLDERS OF LLC (ART 33) Shareholders of LLCs have a right to inspect and reproduce charters, shareholders and board meeting minutes, and accounting reports. Moreover, the shareholder has a right to inspect the accounting books with proper purpose – a company can reject in writing within 15 days for improper purpose, and the shareholder can sue against the rejection. Pursuant to Interpretation IV art 8, improper purpose includes (1) where shareholder and the company is in “substantial business competition”; (2) to disclose the information to third parties who may impair corporate interest; (3) shareholder did (2) in the past 3 years. In this regard, the burden of proof is on the company (hence improper purpose is barely found). 2. SHAREHOLDERS OF JOINT-STOCK LIMITED COMPANY (ART 97) Shareholders of JSLCs have a right to inspect charters, shareholder lists, shareholder and board meeting minutes, and accounting reports, bond issuance records. They have no right to inspect accounting books, regardless of the purpose. After inspection, shareholders and their advisors (accountants, lawyers) bear the duty of confidentiality. Shareholder rights: Comparison 1. 2. Differences a. Scope of shareholder rights b. Protection of shareholder rights Which country protects shareholders (especially of listed companies) better? a. To what extent does American “board primacy” compromised shareholder rights? b. How much fulfillment of “shareholder primacy” in China? 36 | P a g e VI. FINANCING THE CORPORATION A. SECURITIES IN U.S. Under the 1934 (Securities Exchange) Act § 3(10), securities have been defined broadly to include “note, stock … bond, debenture … investment contract … or, in general, any interest or instrument commonly known as a ‘security’.” In short, a security is one that is perceived and expected by investors as an instrument of investment. 1. INVESTMENT CONTRACTS To determine whether a transaction qualifies as an “investment contract”, and therefore would bioe considered a security and subject to disclosure and registration requirements under the Act, the Howey test is applied. Pursuant to this test, an investment contract exists if there is an (1) investment of money (2) in a common enterprise (3) with a reasonable expectation of profits (4) to be derived from the efforts of others. “Investment of money” o Money is not required – property or services can suffice as investment “Common enterprise” o Horizontal – pooling of like interests among investors o Vertical – success of investment linking to promoter’s efforts (broad) or fortune (narrow) – not accepted by all courts “Expectation of profit” o Substantial profit motive is needed; can be fixed for variable returns “Efforts of others” o De minimis efforts from others does not suffice *** Note: How an instrument is offered is more important than what is offered. Fraudulent description of an investment opportunity with the above features can be subject to securities regulations even if no securities ever exist at all. 2. NOTES Notes are presumed to be securities, with the exception of short-term notes with a maturity not exceeding 9 months (exempted). However, this presumption may be rebutted by evaluating (Reves v Ernst & Young). A) REBUTTAL OF PRESUMPTION First, the court examines the transaction to assess the motivations that would prompt a reasonable seller and buyer to enter into it (question whether investment or commercial/consumer transaction). Second, the court examines the “plan of distribution” of the instrument to determine whether it is an instrument in which there is common trading for speculation or investment (whether it is broadly sold to a broad segment of public). Third, the court examines the reasonable expectations of the investing public (whether it is generally perceived as investment opportunity). Finally, the court examines whether some factor such as the existence of another regulatory scheme significantly reduces the risk of the instrument, thereby rendering the application of the Act unnecessary. B) FAMILY RESEMBLANCE TEST If the notes are close enough to the following, a. b. Notes for consumer financing Notes secured by home mortgage 37 | P a g e c. d. Short-term notes to small businesses secured by business’ assets Bank loans the notes in question might be deemed not to be securities. 3. EQUITIES A) Cashflow rights + voting rights: at least one class needs to have both Residual claimants: common stocks as a call option with an exercise price equal to the amount of debt Derivative interest of common stocks: stock rights, stock options, warrants, tracing stock B) DEBTS A) PREFERRED STOCKS Issued at par values with designated dividend rates: “5% Series A preferred stock, par value $25 per share” Dividend right: cumulative (by default and most often) or non-cumulative; participation or nonparticipation o Cumulative vs noncumulative: cumulative indicates a class of preferred stock that entitles an investor to dividends that were missed cf noncumulative o Participating vs nonparticipating: participating preferred stock, after receipt of its preferential return, also shares with the common stock (on an as-converted to common stock basis) in any remaining available deal proceeds cf non-participating Preference right: preference in liquidation up to par value (and cumulated dividends); liquidation events (i.e. an acquisition, merger, IPO, or other action that allows founders and early investors in a company to cash out some or all of their ownership shares) Voting right: class voting for director elections, M&A Redemption right (company’s right to redeem): optional (with call protection) and mandatory (change of control) Conversion right (right to convert shares of preferred stock into shares of common stock): conversion price initially set 20-30% above common stock price, adjustment protection in case of stock split/stock dividend as well as M&A that eliminates common stocks; exercisable at any time, but subject to company’s optional redemption (forced conversion) o Forced conversion occurs when the issuer of a convertible security exercises their right to call the issue. In doing so, the issuer forces the holders of the convertible security to convert their securities into a predetermined number of shares 4. COMMON STOCKS TYPES OF DEBT Bond: long-term (maturity in 30+ years), often with collaterals, issued at $1,000 face value (principle) with fixed coupon (interest) rate Debenture: 20-30 years, without collateral o Backed only by the creditworthiness and reputation of the issuer. Both corporations and governments frequently issue debentures to raise capital or funds Note: short-term (1-10 years), with or without collaterals 38 | P a g e o Unsecured notes are corporate debt instruments without any attached collateral. It is merely backed by a promise to pay, making it more speculative and riskier than other types of bond investments (e.g. secured notes, debentures) which are backed by insurance policies Commercial paper: < 9 months, without collaterals o Short-term debt instrument issued by corporations, typically used for the financing of payroll, accounts payable and inventories, and meeting other short-term liabilities B) Affirmative covenants: pay tax, buy insurance, disclose information, etc Negative covenants: restrictions on (1) incurrence of new debts; (2) creating security interests; (3) shareholder payments; (4) M&A or sale of assets; (5) related party transactions; (6) issuance of stock of subsidiaries Financial covenants: requirements on working capital, EBITDA, debt service coverage rate, net worth, etc. C) DEFAULTS Payment defaults: fail to pay interests (within 30-day grace period) or principle (no grace period) – bondholder can sue Non-payment defaults: breach of covenants, bankruptcy (involuntary with 60-day grace period, voluntary no grace period) – only indenture trustee can sue Cross-default: borrower in default if he defaults on another obligation 5. INDENTURE/NOTE AGREEMENTS CONVERTIBLES Convertible preferred stocks o Option for the holder to convert the shares into a fixed number of common shares after a predetermined date Convertible bonds o Investment value (bond value) + conversion value (option value) Bond valuation is a technique for determining the theoretical fair value of a particular bond Conversion value refers to the financial worth of the securities obtained by exchanging a convertible security for its underlying assets o Lower coupon rates than comparable bonds; (20-30%) higher conversion price than stock price Coupon rate refers to the nominal yield (depicted as a percentage, calculated by dividing all the annual interest payments by the par value of the bond) annual coupon payment (i.e. annual interest rate paid on a bond, expressed as a percentage of the face value) paid by the issuer relative to the bond’s par value) o Hybrid security - features of a bond, such as interest payments, while also having the option to own the underlying stock Why issue convertible bonds? Companies issue convertible bonds for two main reasons: (1) to lower the coupon rate on a debt – investors will generally accept a lower coupon rate on a convertible bond, compared with the coupon rate on an otherwise identical regular bond, because of its conversion feature thus enabling the issuer to save on interest expenses; (2) to delay dilution – raising capital through issuing convertible bonds rather than equity allows the issuer to delay dilution to its equity holders. A company may be in a situation wherein it prefers to issue a debt security 39 | P a g e in the medium term – partly since interest expense is tax-deductible – but is comfortable with dilution over the longer term because it expects its net income and share price to grow substantially over this time frame. Related to the second point, a company may issue a convertible bond if it is unable to issue debt/equity at a desirable price (for instance if the credit ratings are too low and the stock is underpriced). Delta hedging using convertible bonds Delta is the ratio that compares the change in the price of an asset to the corresponding change in the price of its derivative. For example, if a stock option has a delta value of 0.65, this means that if the underlying stock increases in price by $1 per share, the option on it will rise by $0.65 per share, ceteris paribus. Delta hedging is an options trading strategy that aims to reduce, or hedge, the directional risk associated with price movements in the underlying asset. The approach uses options to offset the risk to either a single or other option holding or an entire portfolio of holdings. The investor tries to reach a delta neutral state and not have a directional bias in the hedge. Delta hedging can be achieved using convertible bonds via convertible bond arbitrage (arbitrage is the simultaneous purchase and sale of the same asset in different markets in order to profit from tiny differences in the asset’s listed price), a strategy that aims to capitalize on the mispricing between a convertible bond and its underlying stock. The arbitrageur seeks to generate consistent returns through a combination of long and short positions in the convertible bond and the underlying stock. B. SECURITIES IN CHINA Unlike the US, there is no unified definition. However, the State Council has identified stocks, bonds and other instruments. The major types of securities circulated in China include: Listed company stocks Unlisted public company shares (listed on National Equities Exchange and Quotations, commonly known as “New Third Board”): market making system, low liquidity, “selected tier” can switch listing to SSE Star Market or SZSE ChiNext Government bonds Corporate bonds Convertible bonds and exchangeable bonds of listed companies Mutual fund units C. IPO IN THE U.S. 1. REGISTRATION WITH SEC Registration is disclosure based – there are no substantive standards Registration under 1933 Act: Form S-1 (prospectus) o Transaction registration: IPO registration is separate from resale registration Registration under 1934 Act: Form 8-A o Corporation registration: subject to current and periodic reporting o Having securities listed on national securities exchanges o 2,000+ shareholders of any class/500+ non-accredited investors, and $10m+ assets 40 | P a g e 2. LISTING AGREEMENTS WITH STOCK EXCHANGES Substantive listing standard in listing rules o Financial standards (earnings, revenue, market capitalization) o Distribution standards (number of shareholders, public float (i.e. shares of a company that can be publicly traded and are not restricted), minimum price) o Corporate governance standards (voting rights, independence of board) 3. REGISTRATION PROCESS Managed disclosure (1933 Act § 5) o Prefiling period (from understanding with underwriter for IPO, “in registration”, to filing of registration statement) No offer, sale or delivery Communications are permitted 30+ days before filing if proposed offering not mentioned (Rule 163A) Regularly released information can continue (Rule 169) Announce the intention to IPO, securities and amount to be offered, timing, manner and purpose of offering, but underwriter cannot be mentioned (Rule 135) o Waiting period (from filing to registration becoming effective) No sale or delivery Oral offers permitted Identifying information about issuer: security, price, use of proceeds, underwriter names etc with legend advising where to obtain preliminary prospectus (without price or full underwriter information, “red herring”), actual preliminary prospectus can replace legend (Rule 134) Free writing prospectus (FWP) allowed beyond info in prospectus as long as legend included and FWP filed with SEC before first use and preliminary prospectus filed no later than FWP (Rule 164) A FWP is any written communication that is both an offer to sell or a solicitation of an offer to buy SEC-registered securities that is used after the registration statement for an offering is filed Road shows: oral communication or FWP, preliminary prospectus need not be filed if available online and presented by issuer management (Rule 405, 433) o Post-effective period (from registration becoming effective) No delivery of securities unless accompanied by final prospectus (no other prospectus allowed) However, delivery of prospectus can be fulfilled by delivery of a notice (within 2 days after sale) informing the buyer that the sale was made pursuant to a registration statement and buyer has the right to request physical delivery of a final prospectus (Rule 173) Physical delivery of prospectus is satisfied if the issuer has filed or is planning to file a final prospectus with SEC (Rule 172(b): “access equals delivery”) SEC Review Process (1933 Act §8) o Registration statements become effective automatically 20 days after filing, but the clock restarts with every amendment. SEC can accelerate the registration effectiveness o SEC officially has the power to refuse a registration or stop it from taking effect, but this power is rarely used 41 | P a g e o o o D. In practice, SEC gives informal written/oral comments to issuers which issuers will follow, although they are not legally obligated to IPO price is always determined at the last minute and 20-day waiting period is indefeasible, hence SEC’s grant of acceleration indispensable to make registration effective SEC does not review the issuer’s merits, but only requires disclosure Registration statements should be written with ordinary investors in mind (“plain English rule”), but some courts may not agree IPO IN CHINA 1. Main boards: to general public, or to more than 200 (unrelated) parties (penetrating rule) o Approval based: substantive review JSLCs Operated for 3+ years Complying with all laws and regulations Net profits greater than 30m RMB in previous 3 years, net cash flow greater than 50m RMB or total revenue greater than 300m RMB in previous 3 years Registered capital greater than 30m RMB Intangible assets account for no more than 20% of net assets No uncompensated loss in the previous accounting period 25% public float 1 RMB par value, premium issuance, pricing cannot be higher than 125% of industry P/E ratio o CSRC controls the flow of new IPOs o “Gun jumping”: from submission of IPO application to publicizing of prospectus 2. SSE START MARKET Registration-based: supposedly, no merit review and faster, review by stock exchanges instead of CSRC o Expected market cap > 1b RMB and (a) positive net profits in recent two years and sum up to > 50m RMB or (b) positive net profits in recent one year and revenue > 100m RMB o Expected market cap > 1.5b RMB, revenue in recent one year > 200m RMB, and R&D investment in recent 3 years > 15% total revenue o Expected market cap > 2b RMB, revenue in recent one year > 300m RMB and total net cash flow in recent 3 years > 100m RMB o Expected market cap > 3b RMB, revenue in recent one year > 300m RMB; or o Expected market cap > 4b RMB and in approved science and tech industries 3. MAIN BOARDS REGULATORY IPO LOCKUPS Controlling shareholders and family members: 36 months from IPO Directors and officers: 12 months from IPO Without controlling shareholders: 36 months from IPO for largest 51% pre-IPO shareholders Other pre-IPO shareholders not acquired stocked within 12 months before IPO application: 12 months from IPO 42 | P a g e Pre-IPO shareholders acquired stocks within 12 months before IPO application: 36 months from acquisition date E. DUAL CLASS LISTING IN U.S. 1. LAW From 1994 (NYSE Listed Company Manual 313.00; Nasdaq Listing Rule 5640) Dual class listing allowed in all major national stock exchanges at the time of IPO Creation of new classes of common stocks with lower voting rights than existing classes at IPO is allowed, but not new classes with higher voting rights State corporate laws never have restrictions on dual class structures Restriction on dual class structure in corporate articles: sunset clauses Transfer-based: because of transfer or dilution Event-based: because of death or incapacity Time-based: X years after IPO 2. PRACTICES Dual-class structures give specific shareholders voting control unequal to the amount of equity they hold in the company. This is to satisfy owners who do not want to give up control of their company, but do want to tap the public equity markets for financing. Proponents of dual-class shares say they allow founders to pursue a long-term vision, rather than face pressure to focus on short-term results. o Since stock that provides extra voting rights often cannot be traded, it ensures the company will have a set of loyal investors during rough patches Detractors say dual-class shares creates an entrenched class of shareholder who is free to make bas decision with few consequences o Dual-class creates an inferior class of shareholders and hand over power to a select few, who are then allowed to pass the financial risk onto others F. DUAL CLASS LISTING IN CHINA On SSE Star Market or SZSE ChiNex Only allowed at IPO Super-voting shareholder are individuals with material contributions and serving as directors, or entities controlled by these individuals Super-voting class at least 10% cash flow rights; lower voting class at least 10% voting rights, super:lower < 10:1 Super-voting class not traded at public market Mandatory sunset: death/incapacity, transfer, change of control, below 10% cash flow rights One-share-one-vote on o Charter amendments o Changes to super-voting rights o Hiring or firing of independent directors o Hiring or firing of auditors 43 | P a g e o M&A, spin-off, dissolution, or change corporate form Supervisory board monitors compliance of dual-class listing conditions G. SHELF REGISTRATION (RULE 415) A shelf offering is a provision that allows an equity issuer to register a new issue of securities without having to sell the entire issue at once. The issuer can instead sell portions of the issue over a three-year period without re-registering the security or incurring penalties. Used for continuous offering (offered within 2 days after effectiveness and lasting > 30 days) or delayed offering (without present intention to offer) Usually for seasoned issuers eligible to use Form S-3 (short version of S-1) o Having a class of securities registered under 1934 Act and subject to reporting for 12+ months o No default on dividend or debt payments since the last audited financial statement o Public float > $75m Filing a base prospectus with the material available at the time o SEC will review and declare effective of the base prospects except for the Well-Known Seasoned Issuer (WKSI, a seasonal issuer with $700m public float within 60 days or issued in the past 3 years $1B non-convertible, non-common stock securities) whose base prospectus is automatically effective Take off the shelf: actual offering o File prospectus supplements to update or new prospectus if there are fundamental changes or > 9 months after the effective date H. EXEMPTED OFFERING IN U.S. 1. REG D Reg D governs private placement exemptions. Reg D offerings are advantageous to private companies or entrepreneurs that meet the requirements because funding can be obtained faster and at a lower cost that with a public offering. The regulation allows capital to be raised through the sale of equity or debt securities without the need to register those securities with the SEC. Accredited Investors (13 categories, Rule 501) o Issuer’s directors, executive officers or general partners o Natural person with a net worth of more than $1m o Natural person with annual income of $200k (or joint income with spouse of $300k) o Entity owned solely by accredited investors o Anyone in good standing with professional certifications approved by SEC (e.g. investment advisors) o Institutional investors (banks, insurance companies, mutual funds), trusts or private funds owning $5m in investments, family office Small issues (Rule 504) o Exemption from registration the offer and sale of up to $10m of securities in a 12-month period Private placements safe harbour (Rule 506) o Offer or sale to no more than 35 purchasers, but accreditor investors are not counted toward the 35. o Unaccredited investor purchasers must be knowledgeable in financial and business matters to evaluate the merits and risk of the investment; or 44 | P a g e o Through an appropriate purchaser representative who is not an insider of the issuer and has such knowledge and experience in financial and business matters to evaluate the merits and risks for the investment Conditions for Reg D offerings (Rule 502) o No integration for offers/sales 30+ days before beginning of Reg D offering or 30+ days after completion of Reg D offering o Specified information (similar to registration or periodic reporting) needs to be provided to unaccredited investors o No general solicitation (contacting investors without previous relationship) except to accredited investors o No resale without registration or without an exemption (to accredited investors or under Rule 144) Rule 144 mandates that 5 conditions must be satisfied, including a minimum holding period, quantity restrictions, and disclosure of the transaction 2. REG A Reg A contains rules providing exemptions from the registration requirements, allowing some companies to use equity crowdfunding to offer and sell their securities without having to register the securities with the SEC. Reg A offerings are intended to make access to capital possible for SMEs that could not otherwise bear the costs for a normal SEC registration and to allow nonaccredited investors to participate in the offering. Securities in a Reg A offering can be offered publicly, using general solicitation and advertising. An issuer can choose to use an intermediary broker or offer the securities without one. Companies that use the Reg A exemption can sell their securities utilizing two different tiers, each with its own requirements. However, with both tiers, the issuer must file an offering statement with the SEC, including an offering circular, which serves as the disclosure document for investors. Tier 1 Under Tier 1, a company is permitted to offer a maximum of $20m in a 12-month period. The issuing company must also file offering statements with the SEC, which need to be qualified by state regulators in the states in which the company plans on selling the securities. However, companies issuing offerings under Tier 1 do not have ongoing reporting requirements but are required to issue a report on the final status of the offering. Tier 2 Under Tier 2, companies can offer up to $75m in a 12-month period. Companies offering securities under Tier 2 are required to produce audited financial statements and file continual reports, including its final status. Moreover, Tier 2 offerings have additional requirements such as limitations on the amount of money a nonaccredited investor may invest in a Tier 2 security. 10% of the greater of annual income or net worth (for natural persons); or 10% of the greater of annual revenue, or net assets at fiscal year-end (for non-natural persons) However, Tier 2 issuers are not required to register or qualify their offerings with state securities regulators but still must file their offering with the SEC. Testing the waters 45 | P a g e New rules allow a company that has not yet decided on a particular offering strategy to do a generic solicitation of interest – either publicly or privately – from potential investors to help it decide. The company must keep copies of the testing-the-waters materials; and if it ends up doing a Reg A offering it must file those materials with the SEC. No money can be solicited or accepted while testing the waters. Moreover, specific disclosures must be included in the testing-the-waters materials (e.g. a statement that indications of interest are nonbinding). 3. CROWDFUNDING (REG CF) A ceiling of $5m annually Limits on the amount of money a company may raise from any investor o Investors having annual income or net worth below $107,00: $2,000 or 5% of investor’s annual income or net worth within 12-month period o Investors having annual income or net worth over $107,000: 10% of investor’s annual income or net worth within 12-month period, but may not exceed $100k over the 12-month period Through registered crowdfunding portal or broker-dealer Disclosures about offering purpose, targeted amount, deadline for reaching the target, and information of the company (business, capital structure, financial conditions, directors and officers, major shareholders, etc.) need to be filed (audited financial statements required for offerings over $500k) I. DIRECT LISTING IN U.S. Companies that want to do a public listing may not have the resources to pay underwriters, may not want to dilute existing shares by creating new ones, or may want to avoid lockup agreements (contractual provisions preventing insiders of a company from selling their shares for a specified period of time). Companies with these concerns often choose to proceed by using the direct listing process, rather than an IPO. Selling shareholder direct floor listing o Essentially, a secondary offering by existing shareholders, not the issuer = resale to public investors o Same registration requirement, Form S-1 (resale registration), except no underwriter or proceeds related information o No underwriter-imposed lock up (usually 6 months) Primary direct floor listing o Offering by issuer without underwriting but through direct auction at stock exchange o Extra listing conditions: > $100m market value at opening auction, or > $250m market value at opening auction plus existing value of public float o Investment bank serve as pricing advisor to help set the price range recorded in registration statement Major differences between IPO and DPL No book-building by underwriters No “gatekeeping” by underwriters No price stabilizing by underwriters: no “green-shoe” o Greenshoe is a clause contained in an underwriting agreement of an IPO that allows underwriters to buy up to an additional 15% of company shares at the offering price J. SPAC IN U.S. 46 | P a g e 1. A blank cheque company often sponsored by private equity organisers or celebrities is listed publicly Form S-1 registration requirements, but less disclosure due to lack of business operation, so IPO phase can be faster. No contact with potential acquisition target Almost always offered at $10/unit, which includes one common stock and fractional warrants with strike price of $11.50 per whole warrant o Stock warrants represent the right to purchase a company’s stock at a specific price and at a specific date o A strike price is the set price t which a derivative contract can be bought or sold when it is exercised. For call options, the strike price is where the security can be bought by the option holder; for put options, the strike price is the price at which the security can be sold Sponsors take 20% equity, with same proportion of warrants, in SPAC at a nominal amount ($25k), but usually bear management costs and subsidize underwriting fees Underwriters charge 2% of IPO proceeds at this phase and another 3.5% at closing of de-SPAC IPO proceeds are kept in a trust account and can only be invested in short-term treasury bonds Sponsors and other institutional investors sign forward purchase agreements to commit more funds for acquisition at de-SPAC phase 2. DE-SPAC PHASE Either consummate a business combination or liquidate within a fixed period of time (3 years under listing rules, but almost always 2 years provided by SPAC articles) This combination must spend 80%+ of the proceeds in the trust account IPO shareholder approval required before closing the acquisition IPO shareholders have opportunities to redeem their investments at $10/unit with return from treasury bonds, usually regardless of their votes at approval of the combination Redemptions are often overwhelming, and the law only requires a minimum of $5m in trust account after redemption to continue with the combination. But target will require a high amount available to pay for the acquisition To make up the gap left by redemptions, sponsors usually have to introduce new institutional investors, private investment in public equity (“PIPE”) o PIPE refers to the practice of private investors buying a publicly-traded stock at a price below the current price available to the public. PIPE deals are often offered by companies looking to raise a large amount of capital quickly Normal M&A deal structure will be used to consummate the combination. A “super 8-K” must be filed within 4 business days to detail the business operation and all other information required by Form S-1 in a regular IPO Sponsor lockup usually 1 year after de-SPAC K. IPO PHASE PRIVATE PLACEMENT & RESALE IN CHINA Private placement Approval based (by CSRC) No more than 20% of outstanding No more than 35 purchasers No less than 80% of the average price of previous 20 trading days 47 | P a g e Lockups • Auction-based pricing: 6 mons • Fixed pricing: 36 mons • Strategic investors: 18 mons; however, most cases 36 mons on “voluntary” basis Resale restrictions (post IPO lockup period) Controllers: 1% thereafter (or 2% through block trade) of outstanding very 90 days Directors and officers: less than 25% of holding when in office; 6-month lockup since leaving; 1% (or 2% through block trade) of outstanding very 90 days when allowed Pre-announcements required before selling VII. DISCLOSURE AND SECURITIES FRAUD A. DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS IN U.S. IPO: registration statements Periodic reports o Annual report (Form 10-K) Within 90 days of the close of each fiscal year Itemized disclosures are detailed in SEC instructions: business, risk factors, legal proceedings, management’s discussions, and analysis of financial conditions and the results of operations (MD&A), financial statements (audited), directors and executive officers, corporate governance, executive compensation, related party transactions o Quarterly report (Form 10-Q) Within 45 days of the close of each of the first three quarters Mainly financial statements (unaudited), MD&A, and updated risk factors o Must be certified by CEO and CFO for accuracy of material disclosed information; knowing or willful falsehood of a criminal offense Current Report o Within 4 business days after occurrence of material developments o Material agreements especially M&A (full agreements needed to be disclosed); delisting, sale and trading of securities; change of auditors (PCAOB registered); change in control; change of D&O; amendments to articles or bylaws 1. BLOCKHOLDER DISCLOSURE IN U.S. A blockholder is the owner of a large block of a company’s shares and/or bonds. In terms of shareholding, these owners are often able to influence the company with the voting rights awarded with their holdings. Shareholders must file a Form 13D with the SEC when their ownership block reaches 5% of a company’s outstanding shares. 5% threshold with intent to influence and control (Schedule 13D) o 5% of beneficial ownership (either voting power or investment power) of any class of equity, but non-voting stock excluded o Disclose by filing Schedule 13D within 10 days after reaching the threshold Security, issuer and identity of purchasers Source and amount of funds used in making purchase 48 | P a g e Purpose of transaction Contracts or agreements between multiple purchases (groups) or with the issuer 5% institutional investors or passive investors o Disclose by filing Schedule 13G within 45 days after the end of calendar year or 10 days after acquisition, respectively Security, issuer and purchasers Certifying acquisition in ordinary course of business or without intent to influence control 2. SHORT-SWING INSIDER DISCLOSURE DISGORGEMENT IN U.S. (§16 OF 1934 ACT) PROFIT Insiders o Directors or officers at either the time of sale or purchase o 10% shareholders (beneficial owner of equity) immediately before both transactions Disclosure o Initial report (Form 3) within 10 days after becoming an insider (only purchase matters for 10% shareholders) o Report of any change (Form 4) within 2 business days of the change o Annual position report (Form 5) Profit disgorgement o Profits from any matched transactions (buy and sale, or vice versa) within 6 months disgorged to the issuer B. AND DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS IN CHINA IPO disclosure Continuous disclosure (art 70) o Annual report: within 4 months after fiscal year, financial statements, management shareholding, outstanding shares, controlling shareholder o Semi-annual report: within 2 months after semi-fiscal year, similar to annual report o Quarterly report: within 30 days after 3rd and 9th months of fiscal year, simplified financial statements report Current report (art 80) o Material information likely to affect price such as M&A or transaction involving 30% of total asset value, major litigations, change of controlling shareholder Blockholder disclosure (art 63) o 5% of outstanding, immediate standstill, disclosure within 3 days, disclose each 1% change and repeat standstill for each 5% change thereafter Short-swing profit forfeiture (art 44) o Directors, officers, 5%+ shareholders o Matching purchase and sale within 6 months C. SECURITIES FRAUD IN U.S. 1. MISREPRESENTATION IN REGISTRATION STATEMENT (§11 OF 1933 ACT) 49 | P a g e Plaintiffs: all purchasers of registered securities whose purchases can be traced back to the registration in question Material misinformation or omission o Materiality: a substantial likelihood that a reasonable investor would consider it as altering the total mix of information in deciding whether to buy or sell (TSC Industries v Northway Inc) o Omission is actionable only if the omitted part makes the disclosed part misleading Defendants o Issuer o Signers of registration statements: issuers’ executive officers o Directors at the time of filing o Underwriters o Experts: auditors, credit-rating agencies Strict liability with defenses available to defendants other than the issuer Defenses Expertised portion Nonexpertised portion Expert Actually and reasonably believes after reasonable investigation that information is true (ignorance not OK) – due diligence No liability Nonexpert No reason to believe that information is false (ignorance OK) – reasonable reliance Actually and reasonably believes after reasonable investigation that information is true (ignorance not OK) In Escott v BarChris, it was held that this reliance will not be recognised if the officer, director or underwriter was aware that the accounting report was inaccurate. Outside Directors In BarChris, the court held that although outside directors (i.e. directors who are not employed by the issuer and who normally have other full time occupations) can delegate a duty of investigation, he or she is liable if the person to whom this duty was delegated does not perform it properly. BarChris also held two outside directors with relevant areas of expertise to a higher standard than that of a run-of-the-mill outside director. On the facts, the court judged the two directors (lawyer and investment banker) by the standards applicable to their professions, rather than those that might apply to a director who had no expertise in the registration process and did not undertake to oversee compliance with the requirements. Reliance: unnecessary unless o The plaintiff knew of the falsity of the information; or o The securities were bought after 1 year since effectiveness of the registration statement and an earnings statement had been released Damages o Difference between purchase price and actual value (if not sold) or sale price (if sold) and capped at offering price 50 | P a g e o Joint and several liability except for non-managing underwriters (limited to the amount of their participation in the offering) and outside directors (proportionate to the damages he/she caused) Rescission of purchase o §12(a)(2) creates liability for any person who offers or sells a security through a prospectus or an oral communication containing a material misstatement or omission, is liable to the purchaser for rescission of the purchase or damages, provided that the purchaser did not know about the misstatement or omission at the time of the purchase 2. Plaintiffs: purchasers and sellers, but not offerors Defendants: anyone making false statements and inducing others to trade Materiality Scienter o Awareness of the true state of affairs and appreciation of the propensity of his or her misstatement or omission to mislead o Simple negligence not sufficient, but recklessness is sufficient when circumstantial evidence strongly suggests actual knowledge o Misstatements won’t be excused because they advance certain corporate purpose under the securities law (although they may be excused under corporate law) Reliance (transaction causation) o Fraud-on-the-market theory (Basic Inc v Levinson) o Assumption of reliance can be rebutted by evidence showing plaintiffs would have traded even with knowledge of the truth Causation (loss causation) o Between fraud and loss, plaintiff bears the burden Losses caused by systemic risk or issuer’s normal risk not included o Loss does not have to be a drop in price – can be sustainability of price or price rebound (i.e. price has risen from a lower level) o In practice, “event studies” are often uses to identify causation Event study refers to an empirical analysis that examines the impact of a significant catalyst occurrence or contingent event on the value of a security Damages o Capped at the difference between transacted price and the average of daily prices during the 90-day period after corrective disclosure 3. GENERAL ANTI-FRAUD RULE (§10(B) OF 1934 ACT) SECURITIES CLASS ACTIONS Class actions: to overcome “free-rider” problem o Numerous plaintiffs o Questions of law or facts common to the class o One lead plaintiff whose claims are typical to the class and who can fairly and adequately protect the interest of the class, usually with the largest financial interest in recovery Opt-out system: at class certification/notice, or at settlement Litigation costs are advanced by plaintiff lawyers who are paid on contingent-fee basis Most class actions usually settled o Plaintiff: no cost to settle, may be some small payment o Plaintiff’s lawyer: get money and save effort 51 | P a g e o o o D. Defendant: winding up a case with a big release; D&O insurance usually covers the payments which are not available if defendant loses at trial Courts: settlements rarely disapproved; difficult to reject when both parties want to settle Result: frivolous actions abound SECURITIES FRAUD IN CHINA No difference between misrepresentation in offering documents and post-offering market Plaintiffs, investors (implicitly purchasers or sellers) Defendants o Issuer o Directors, officers, controller (direct or indirect), underwriter (sponsor) (art 85) o Other intermediaries of securities issuance or trading: accountants, lawyers, credit-rating agencies (art 163) Material misrepresentation or omission (not clear what kind of omission included, issuer likely to be responsible to clarify in case of market rumours) Culpability (art 85, 163) o Issuer: strict liability o All others: rebuttable presumption of fault (res ipsa loquitur) Both materiality and culpability in civil litigations heavily rely on prior enforcement actions taken by China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) Reliance: fraud-on-the-market Loss causation: increasingly leaning toward financial models Civil damages o No cap o All defendants and jointly and severally liable But is apportionment of liability needed? (Courts start to say yes, at least when intermediaries are involved) Administrative penalties (art 181, 182, 183) o Issuer and its controller: 10% to 100% of issuance proceeds or RMB 2m to 20m o Directors and its officers: RMB 1m to 10m o Intermediaries: 100% to 1000% of service revenue or RMB 1m to 10m o Intermediary responsible individuals: RMB 0.5m to 5m 1. SECURITIES CLASS ACTION Regular representative action (opt-in) o Multiple plaintiffs start the lawsuit and the court notifies the public to join o Regular civil jurisdiction applies When 50+ plaintiffs request to be represented by CSICS, a special representative action, i.e. opt-out class action, can start (art 95) o Case will be moved to Shanghai Financial Court or Shenzhen Intermediate Court (but this does not happen in reality) o CSISC selected cases to be pursue (an expert committee exists) o In reality, it is CSISC that solicits, with much difficulty, the 50 plaintiffs o Plaintiffs can opt out after notice of special representative action is made and at settlement stage (but can they opt out on appeal?) 52 | P a g e E. VIII. Why (or why not) differentiate misrepresentations in offering and post-offering? Which approach makes more sense, China or U.S., especially when it comes to culpability? o Do you think strict liability or scienter is more appropriate for securities fraud? Scienter is more appropriate – fraud requires knowledge, or wilful blindness, on the part of the defendant. This goes towards the mens rea, hence scienter should be part of the inquiry Compare the judicial reasoning when determining culpability o Compare Escott v BarChris and Wang Feng v Wu Yang o Both are trial decisions, supposed to focus on fact finding including culpability Compare the securities class actions in two countries o Why does China limit the lead plaintiff, essentially to CSISC? o What will be the incentives of various parties to sue and settle in China? INSIDER TRADING AND MARKET MANIPULATION A. WHY FORBID INSIDER TRADING? If we want the stock price to reflect information of the issuer, and insiders have such information, then their trading will bring the price close to the actual information (or value) of the issuer – for instance, in the case of misrepresentation that fraudulently raises the stock price, letting insider sell will quickly bring the price close to the truth (Macey) o Nonpublic information reflected in security’s price, hence making the markets more efficient Fairness o But parity of information is not required Property rights o But what is the loss to the owner of the confidential information, i.e. issuer? Market integrity o Market liquidity providers (market-makers) will lose systematically to insiders and have to increase the bid-ask spread (trading becomes costly) Bid-ask spread is the amount by which the ask price exceeds the bid price for an asset in the market o Investors will discount issuers’ security prices when insider trading is allowed (cost of capital rises) Discount refers to a situation when a security is trading for lower than its fundamental or intrinsic value B. SECURITIES FRAUD: A COMPARISON INSIDER TRADING IN U.S. Who are insiders? o Those who are in fiduciary or confidential relation to issuers or holders of the securities – directors, officers, employees entrusted with confidential information o “Parity of information” rejected in the U.S. (Chiarella) Outsiders deemed as insiders o Those outsiders entrusted with confidential information yet deceives the source of information and trade on the confidential information, which essentially violates the duty of confidentiality – “misappropriation theory” (O’Hagan) o Duty of confidentiality (SEC Rule 10b5-2(b)) Recipient agreed to maintain confidentiality 53 | P a g e Having a history, pattern, or practice of sharing confidential information so that the recipient had reason to know the communicator expected recipient to keep information confidential Communication within family Congress members and legislative employees (STOCK Act of 2012) Outsiders receiving tips from insiders: tipper-tippee liability (Dirks v SEC) o Tipper breached fiduciary duty by obtaining personal benefit o Tippee knew or should have known the breach Misappropriation of tender offer information o Prohibition of anyone other than the bidder to trade on insider information he/she knows from the bidder of the target (SEC Rule 14e-3) o No breach of fiduciary duty or duty of confidentiality needed – parity of information Inside information – material, nonpublic State of mind – trade with “conscious knowledge” of inside information (SEC Rule 10b5-1(b)) C. Forbidding selective disclosure of inside information to some market professionals, in particular sellside analysis, and security holders who are “reasonably foreseeable” to trade on the information o Intentional disclosure: simultaneous to general public and selected analysis or investors o Unintentional disclosure: disclose promptly (within 24 hours) after disclosure to selective disclosure But can it eliminate selective disclosure adequately? D. REGULATION FAIR DISCLOSURE MARKET MANIPULATION IN U.S. Why regulate manipulation? o Market is not symmetric – price can rise more quickly when you buy than it drops when you sell o Market-makers will lose systematically to manipulators, and have to increase the bid-ask spread, which raises the cost of trading and reduces liquidity Essentially, manipulators are insider-traders to market-makers, hence manipulation similar to insider trading What is manipulation? (§9 of 1934 Act and SEC Rule 10b-5) o Any intentional interference with market supply and demand Intent – wilful action (stricter requirement than scienter) Causation: loss (difference between trading price and actual value) is a direct consequence of manipulation o Examples: wash sale, matched order, parking, spoofing, entering limit orders to change published prices (“lit”) Wash sale – a transaction in which an investor seeks to maximise tax benefits by selling a losing security at the end of a calendar year so they can claim a capital loss on taxes that year. Investor’s intent is likely to repurchase the security again after the start of the new year, if possible even lower than when they sold Stock parking – illegal practice of selling share to another party with the understanding that the original owner will buy them back after a short time. The goal of stock parking is to conceal a stock’s real ownership while maintaining the appearance of regulatory compliance 54 | P a g e o E. INSIDER TRADING IN CHINA Insiders o Directors, officers, supervisory committee members, controller (and its D&O), 5%+ shareholders of issuer, others who acquire inside information because of business relationship with the issuer o Tender offeror or material asset acquirer and its D&O and controller o Underwriter, sponsor, and other intermediaries o Regulators and other public servants in charge of securities transactions (art 51) o Those who illegally obtain inside information (art 50, misappropriators and tippees) Information o Material, nonpublic information about the issuer that will impact price Disgorgement of profits + fine up to 10 times of profit or up to RMB 5m (art 191) F. Spoofing – type of scam in which a criminal disguises an email address, display name, phone number, etc to convince a target that they are interacting with a known, trusted source Limit orders – a type of order to purchase or sell a security at a specified price or better. For buy limit orders, the order will be executed only at the limit price or a lower one, while for sell limit orders, the order will be executed only at the limit price or a higher one. This stipulation allows traders to better control the prices they trade Manipulation vs hedging (Sharette v Credit Suisse International) A manipulative act is one that is intended to mislead investors by artificially affecting market activity and requires a determination whether the transaction or series of transactions sends a false pricing signal to the market or otherwise distorts estimates of the underlying economic value of the securities traded Hedging is, by itself, generally not manipulative However, hedging activities can constitute market manipulation under the Act of 1934 if the hedging activity is specifically intended or designed to manipulate the price of a security MARKET MANIPULATION IN CHINA Types (art 55) o Continuous trading to affect prices o Collusion to conduct matched transactions o Wash sale o Spoofing o Using fraudulent or uncertain information to induce transactions o Public evaluation, forecast, or investment advice about issuer coupled with opposite transactions o Manipulation through actions in other related markets Is intent required? o Not clear – “affect or intend to affect securities transaction prices or volumes” (art 55) o But why continuous trading is manipulation if without intent? o Why fraudulent information is regulated as manipulation rather than securities fraud? Why uncertain information is prohibited? G. INSIDE TRADING AND MANIPULATION: A COMPARISON 55 | P a g e IX. Overall o U.S. rules are more principle-based, while China lacks a consistent principle or theory but relies on lists of prohibited situations o In China, the line between legitimate and illegitimate transactions can be blurred, so the rules appear uncertain and overinclusive (selective enforcement a bigger concern) Insider trading o U.S. law differentiates between insiders and outsiders relatively clearly (except perhaps in tipper-tippee cases) o Chinese law essentially adopts parity of information Market manipulation o A difficult issue for both countries: But U.S. law focuses on intent, which alleviates concern about deterring trading, while Chinese law does not seem to underscore intent, which will cause chilling effects on trading o Chinese law does not seem to clearly differentiate between anti-manipulation and anti-fraud while in U.S. the former is likely to be absorbed into the latter when spread of fraudulent information is involved M&A: BACKGROUND A. DRIVING FORCES OF M&A Economic rationales o Reduce transaction costs (Coase, Williamson) Vertical integration to avoid holdup o Strategic acquisitions for synergies Sources of synergy o Operating synergy Revenue enhancement Greater pricing power: increase price, but may face anti-trust challenges Combination of functional strengths: one form good at marketing and the other at R&D – but why must acquire instead of outsourcing? Possibly because of above reason (i.e. greater pricing power) Expansion into fast-growing markets: post-merger integration can be challenging Cost reduction Due to economies of scale: reaching minimum average cost; spreading overhead costs Due to greater pricing power: lower prices paid to suppliers, not necessarily monopolistic o Financial synergy Debt coinsurance (Lewellen 1971): Diversification of risk profiles so as to reduce volatility of cash flow, hence the likelihood of financial distress; cost of debt financing decreases and higher usage of debt brings more tax deductions Tax benefit: taking advantage of Net Operating Loss (NOL) tax deduction o Governance synergy Spillover effects on targets of good governance practices when targets are in jurisdictions of relatively weaker shareholder protection Managerial hubris: empire building by strategic acquirers 56 | P a g e o Acquirers on average lose value after acquisition which means the benefits of synergy, if any, would go to target shareholders o Bad bidders could become good targets (Mitchell & Lehn 1990) Firms that subsequently become takeover targets make acquisitions that significantly reduce their equity value, and firms that do not become takeover targets make acquisitions that raise their equity value o CEOs of bad acquirers are more likely to be replaced (Lehn & Zhao 2006) Tax inversion: acquiring a foreign corporation and reincorporate in that country (e.g. US to Ireland) Demand for M&A as PE/VC exit strategy: M&A is more important that IPO as an exit strategy B. MAJOR PLAYERS 1. Financial investors o Private equity funds looking for underperforming targets or partnering with management in management buyouts (MBO) o Operating synergy is less salient, and targets are often worth the same value to different financial investors. Hence, they are vulnerable to the “Winner’s Curse” (i.e. the tendency for the winning bid in an auction to exceed the intrinsic value of an item) Strategic investors o Operating companies seeking synergies o They often outbid financial investors, either because of synergies or management hubris 2. PRINCIPALS PROFESSIONALS Investment Bankers o Sell-side: informational intermediary (connecting bidders and targets); developing valuation and advising target board in business negotiation; providing fairness opinion to target board on the fairness of the final deal price o Buy-side: mainly to provide financing for the purchase o Conflict of interest Sell-side is usually a one-off client whereas buy-side is often a repeated client. Hence, sell-side bankers unwilling to negotiate vigorously against buyers who may well become their next clients Playing on both sides Advising the target while providing financing to the buyer Advising target while holding equity in the buyer Transaction Attorneys o Provide clients with visions and spot significant issues in the transaction o Design transaction structures to achieve business intentions and lower legal/regulatory hurdles o Negotiate deal terms relying on solid knowledge of “what is market” and lubricate the deal process o Draft documents to comply with regulatory requirements and reduce the risk of ex post disputes o “Quarterbacking” to coordinate with various lawyers in specialized areas (tax, employment, IP, financing, anti-trust, etc.), client’s in-house counsels and other advisors (bankers in particular) 57 | P a g e C. M&A FINANCING Acquisition decision and financing decision can be decoupled so that different types of investors can be attracted to the deal 1. Regular bank loans: term loans or revolving lines of credit, often secured Leveraged bank loans: junior secured (secondary mortgage) or mezzanine (senior unsecured) debts Junk bonds: high risk, high yield (noninvestment grade), usually 4 percentage points higher yield than US Treasury debt or similar maturity Convertible bonds: issued at lower interest rate than regular bonds and convertible at a substantial discount to common stock Bridge loans: short-term (usually 6-9 months) unsecured debt provided by 1-banks or hedge funds Seller financing: essentially deferred payment by the buyer, sometimes to mitigate the risk of acquisition (earn-outs) o Earnout is a contractual provision stating that the seller of a business is to obtain additional compensation in the future if the business achieves certain financial goals, which are usually stated as a percentage of gross sales or earnings 2. X. EQUITY FINANCING Cash raised as equity: PE investment Stocks o Common stocks: often used by listed companies when their stocks are overvalued, can be issued after deal closing to pay off related debts o Preferred stocks: similar to debts as a type of fixed income security D. DEBT FINANCING M&A IN U.S. AND CHINA – GENERAL COMPARISON Biggest difference: Sale of company (US) vs sale of control (China) o US acquirers rarely leave minority (especially public) shareholders in the post-acquisition companies except for key management teams (roll-over) Rollover equity is when a seller reinvests a portion of the proceeds from a sale into equity of the acquisition company that is formed to buy the business o Chinese acquirers almost never buy out public investors 100% although public companies (or PE) do buyout private targets Chinese regulators are more paternalist whereas courts are largely out of the picture o More cautious about high leverage ratio, hence leverage buyouts As a result, Chinese acquirers have few financing channels at their disposal o Seriously concerned about acquisition of private targets by public companies at inflated prices M&A: DEAL STRUCTURE, APPRAISAL RIGHTS A. STATUTORY MERGER IN U.S. 1. GENERAL IDEA A majority driven system 58 | P a g e DGCL §251(a) o Merger: seller/target merged into buyer/acquirer, without involvement of a third entity; both are “constituent corporations”, and the acquirer becomes the “surviving corporation” o Consolidation: two constituent corporations combine to form a new entity, the “resulting corporation” Minority protection o Fiduciary duties in the M&A process o Appraisal right to ensure exit without harm 2. CORPORATE LAW PROCESS Resolutions by both boards to approve the merger agreement and recommend it to shareholders (DGCL §251(b)) Shareholder approval from both constituent corporations, in principle, by majority of outstanding shares entitled to vote (DGCL §251(c)), or if bylaw permits, by written consent (DGCL §228) o However, approval by shareholders of the surviving corporation is not needed if: The surviving corporation’s articles is not amended There is no change in the characteristics of the outstanding stock of the surviving corporation; and The surviving corporation does not issue more than 20% of its outstanding shares in connection with the merger (DGCL §251(f)) o In addition, NYSE and NASDAQ listing rules both require acquirer shareholder approval if acquirer is to issue 20%+ outstanding shares in connection with the merger. But only a majority of the voting shares at a meeting with a valid quorum is required – approval of share issuance instead of merger itself (NYSE Listed Companies Manual Rule 312, NASDAQ Listing Rule 4350(i)) o Filing of proxy statements (Schedule 14A) is required for listed corporations when shareholder approval rights are sought Filing of certificate of merger with the state – making merger officially effective (DGCL §251(c)) 3. TRIANGULAR MERGER In a triangular merger, the acquirer creates a wholly-owned subsidiary, which in turn merges with the selling entity. The selling entity then liquidates. The acquirer is the sole remaining shareholder of the subsidiary. Forward triangular merger: merger sub acquires target, so merger sub survives Reverse triangular merger: merger sub merged into target, so target survives; target shares are cancelled, and merger sub’s shares are converted into newly issued shares of the surviving corporation Why? Target debts separated from the acquirer Acquirer is merger sub’s sole shareholder, hence buyer shareholder voting avoided (unless issuing 20%+ buyer shares) Target maintains its operational independence, easier for post-merger integration Reverse triangular merger keeps target business name, and may not be viewed as assignment of target contractual rights, so avoiding disruption of target relationship with suppliers, lenders, employees (unless there is a change of control clause) 4. LEGAL EFFECTS 59 | P a g e Constituent corporations merged into one By operation of law, all rights, privileges, powers, assets, duties, restrictions, disabilities of the disappearing corporation inherited by the surviving corporation Disappearing corporation’s status in legal proceedings is also inherited by surviving corporation except shareholder plaintiffs’ standing to file derivative suits B. Types o o Merger: one corporation acquires another (absorbing merger) Consolidation: constituent corporations combined to incorporate a new corporation (newestablishing merger) Barely used – when incorporation is not easy and, in particular, when new corporation needs to reacquire all the licenses/approvals for its operation, who will want to establish a new entity? Legal procedure o Proposal by boards and supermajority (2/3) approval by shareholders from both sides o Regulatory approval o Execution of merger agreements o Compiling balance sheets and asset lists o Creditors on both sides should be notified within 10 days after shareholder resolution; ads should be published within 30 days in major newspapers Creditors can then request (within 30 days of notice or 45 days if without notice) for advance repayment or provision of security (art 173) o Filing registration with ICA and tax authorities C. STATUTORY MERGER IN CHINA ASSET DEAL IN U.S. A sale of all or substantially all of the assets of a corporation is functionally equivalent to sale of a corporation, and the buyer of assets is essentially the buyer of the target. o First, target sells all or substantially all assets per DGCL §271 (board resolution + majority outstanding shareholder approval) o Second, target voluntarily dissolves its corporate entity per DGCL §275 (board resolution + majority outstanding shareholder approval + filing) “Substantially all” (Hollinger Inc v Hollinger Int) o Quantitatively vital: necessary to the continuation of the corporation’s life (“half is not substantially all”); and o Qualitatively vital: out of the ordinary for the corporation Effects o Title of each identified assets must be individually transferred o Liabilities left behind The sale proceeds are used to pay off liabilities before distributed to target shareholders as special dividends If target’s creditors are not properly paid, many states, including Delaware, allow creditors to seek repayment from acquirer De facto merger doctrine o Substance over form: merger and asset deals are substantively the same - so should be treated equivalently under the law o Delaware rejects de facto merger doctrine so target shareholders will not have appraisal rights in asset deals; but creditors can still rely on de facto merger doctrine if debts are not repaid 60 | P a g e D. TENDER OFFERS IN U.S. 1. GENERAL BACKGROUND A tender offer is a bid to purchase some or all of the shareholders’ stock in a corporation. Tender offers are typically made public and invite shareholders to sell their shares for a specified price and within a particular window of time. The tender offer typically is set at a higher price per share than the company’s current stock price, providing shareholders a greater incentive to sell their shares. In the case of a takeover attempt, the tender may be conditional on the prospective buyer being able to obtain a certain amount of shares to constitute a controlling interest in the company. Wellman v Dickinson o Active and widespread solicitation of a substantial percentage of the issuer’s securities with a premium in price, on fixed terms, conditional upon the tender of a fixed number of securities, and open for a limited period of time o Pressuring security holders to respond o Involving public announcement of a purchasing program preceding or coinciding with a rapid accumulation of shares Regulated by Securities Exchange Act §14(d) and §14(e) (Williams Act) Why tender offer? o Faster (minimum 20 days vs three months for mergers due to shareholder voting) When concerned about third party interloper, tender offer gives acquirer quicker control of target But speed is not guaranteed if regulatory approvals are required, financing is pending, or securities registrations are needed o Hostile bids Downside o Target shareholders can withdraw until tender offer closes whereas once a merger is approved by shareholder, no vote can be rescinded o Unless 100% target shares are tendered, a second step is needed to buy out remaining shareholders to complete acquisition after a tender offer closes (2-step merger) 2. SUBSTANTIVE RULES Start: filing Schedule TO and publishing summary ads in a national newspaper; offer documents mailed to securities holders Offer period: at least 20 business days (announcement day counted as day 1) Amendments o Changing considerations: offer must remain open for an extra 10 business days from the date of first notification of the change o Other changes: offer must remain open for an extra 10 business days o However, if there are 10 (or 5) business days remaining within the original offer period after the change, then no extension of offer period is required All-holders/best price rule: offer open to all holders of the same class of securities being offered and the price paid to every security holder must be the highest price paid to any security holder o Target’s self-tender cannot exclude hostile bidders Withdrawal: tendered shares can be withdrawn anytime before offer closes; but in practice withdrawal rarely happens because tender happens at the last minute 61 | P a g e Pro rata acquisition from all security holders who tendered if total tendered shares > shares offered to purchase Prohibition of purchases outside the offer during offer period by offeror Target board response: filing Schedule 14D-9 within 10 days after offer starts to publish board’s recommendation o Usually, a “stop, look, and listen” letter comes first from the target board asking shareholders to wait for Schedule 14D-9 E. STOCK PURCHASES IN CHINA This is the most frequently used route for M&A transactions in China Essentially, to buy shares, not corporations, from shareholders through private agreements or public tender offers o Impractical to buy all shares, and unnecessary since the purpose in China is to buy control, not corporations o As a result, minority shareholders will be left in the target If the target is a listed company, then the mandatory bid rule may be triggered o Mandatory bid rule provides that a bidder is required to offer a bid to all remaining shareholders if he acquires a specified percentage of voting shares or interests in voting shares o This rule offers minority shareholders an opportunity to avoid future exploitation by the new controller of the company, when control is transferred When listed companies acquire private targets, Value Adjustment Mechanism (VAM) is often used o VAM refers to an agreement that is designed by investor and financing party when reaching an equity financing agreement to resolve the uncertainty, information asymmetry and agency costs between the two parties to a transaction in relation to the future development of the target company, and such agreement contains the equity repurchase, monetary compensation and other valuation adjustment of the future target company o Setting up performance indicators usually within the next 3 years. If missed, sellers should return merger price (partially) to the listed company Investor’s valuation of the target is usually based on the future performance expectations of the target company. If it fails to meet the expectation, the valuation of the target company needs to be adjusted, that is, to protect the investor’s investment interests by means of performance compensation and/or equity repurchase. o Cf earnouts in the U.S. F. TENDER OFFERS IN CHINA 1. MANDATORY BID RULE Below 30% to above 30% through negotiated purchase or indirect purchase general offer Below 30% to exact 30% through negotiated purchase or indirect purchase general offer or partial offer (5%+) Below 30% to 30% through secondary market standstill, disclose then general offer or partial offer (5%+) At 30% or above, purchasing no more than 2% annually requires no offer At 30% or above, purchasing 5% or more partial or general offer Below 30% to below 30% partial or no offer 62 | P a g e 2. SUBSTANTIVE RULES Starting after submission of official offer documents to CSRC o Preliminary tender offer report first, waiting for regulatory clearances, then definitive tender offer report No shorter than 30 days, no longer than 60 days Price no lower than the highest price paid in 6 months before initial disclosure Offeror cannot withdraw during the offer period, but offeree can withdraw tendered stocks till 3 days before offer expiration Revisions need approval from SCRC and cannot revise within 15 days after offer expiration except due to competing bids Offeror needs to provide assurance (20% cash, 100% stock or commitment letter from banks) Offeror cannot purchase stocks outside offer Target directors cannot resign during offer period Target cannot take actions that can materially affects its assets after initial offer disclosure without approval by shareholder assembly Target boards should investigate offeror, review offer conditions and make recommendations to shareholders within 20 days after the tender offer starts G. SHORT FORM MERGERS IN U.S. A short form merger combines a parent company and a subsidiary that is substantially owned by the parent. Either entity can be designated as the survivor of the merger. The statutes typically mandate that the parent company must own at least 90% of the subsidiary before it can use a short form merger. Cashing out minority without shareholder voting: indeed, the voting result will be pre-ordained since majority voting rights held by the acquirer (parent) DGCL §253 o 90+% shares held by parent o Tender offers usually won’t receive so many shares, so target boards will top-up for the acquirer to reach the threshold, but often still difficult DGCL §251(h) o Allowing short form mergers with (usually) 50%+ shares held by the Parent o Conditions The target must be a public corporation (listed or with 2000+ shareholders) Friendly tender offers for all target shares and reaching an agreement with target board explicitly permitting short form merger under this section Merger to be consummated as soon as practical after the first step tender offer on the same conditions o Amended in 2014 to allow “interested” acquirer (with 15%+ shares) to use this section But if the acquirer is a controlling shareholder, DGCL §251(h) mergers will be subject to entire fairness review H. APPRAISAL RIGHTS IN U.S. An appraisal right is the statutory right of a corporation’s shareholders to have a judicial proceeding or independent valuator determine a fair stock price and oblige the acquiring corporation to purchase shares at that price. 1. CONDITIONS 63 | P a g e A judicial procedure to determine the fair value for dissenting shareholders’ shares in merger Available in which transactions? (DGCL §262) o Statutory mergers, but not asset deals or tender offers o But not available for any publicly-traded shares or shares of a surviving corporation where shareholders were not required to vote Unless shareholders of constituent corporations are required to accept a merger consideration other than stock of the surviving corporation or publicly traded stock of another corporation (“market out”), which basically means cash “market out”, generally, is a condition precedent in an acquisition agreement or tender offer that allows a buyer to avoid the closing if there is a significant disruption in the financial, banking, or stock markets. Marketout clauses protect a buyer by reducing its additional exposure to marketrelated events that are beyond the control of the parties involved in a particular transaction Not applicable to §253 short form mergers, but applicable to §251(h) short form mergers Who can demand for appraisal? o Record or beneficial owners o Collectively owning 1%+ or $1m worth of stocks o Who made a written demand for appraisal before shareholder meeting o Did not vote “yes” for merger at the meeting (if you made a mistake, you lose the right (In re Appraisal of Dell Inc); and o Remain shareholders from the date of demand, through the pendency of the appraisal action 2. VALUATION Fair value: court discretion o In re Appraisal of Dell Inc, the court held in an appraisal proceeding that the fair value of Dell Inc was 28% higher than the price paid for it. The court concluded that the deal price undervalued Dell because there was a significant “valuation gap” between the long-term value of Dell and the market’s short-term focus, and the agreed-upon price was the product of a competition among like-minded financial bidders who were price-constrained by targeted internal rates of returns in LBO pricing models. Even though the deal price represented a nearly 30% premium to market and was within range of DCF values provided by the Dell special committee’s financial advisors, the court held that a DCF valuation, using the court’s inputs, produced a better approximation of the “fair value” of Dell than the results of the sales process The court here failed to give weight to the result of a full and fair sale process or the market’s expectations for Dell’s future performance and value. While the facts include some unusual circumstances, its reasoning could be applied to any transaction where the public markets and markets for corporate control do not give full credit for a company’s business plans and projections The reasoning of this case calls into question the ability of financial sponsors, and to some extent, all buyers, to reliably estimate their exposure to appraisal claims, undermining the certainty that buyers and sellers need to optimize sales of corporate control. This uncertainty will cause significant issues for parties planning mergers. Stockholders will see appraisal as a potentially valuable option and, by voting against mergers they might otherwise think should be approved, seek to preserve the right to obtain appraisal. Buyers will hold back some amount to deal with potential appraisal claims (or insist on complex corporate structuring to avoid appraisal). The 64 | P a g e economic frictions created may be considerable and will affect even the many transactions where the appraised value likely would not exceed the merger price o Reversed in Dell Inc v Magnetar, where the court held that the court below erred in giving no weight to Dell’s pre-deal stock price or the deal price when determining the fair value in this appraisal proceeding. In the court’s view, the “market-based indicators of value – both Dell’s stock price and the deal price – have substantive probative value” and “deserved heavy, if not dispositive, weight.” Court reaffirmed its decision in DFC Global Corporation not to establish a presumption that the dela price constitutes “fair value” yet joined DFC in strongly suggesting that deal price – assuming a reasonable sale process – merits substantial, and perhaps dispositive weight Several principles o Only target standalone value will be awarded, no synergy can be included o No minority discount although dissenting shareholders are in minority o No liquidity discount although dissenting shareholders will lose liquidity after merger I. XI. APPRAISAL RIGHTS IN CHINA Possible under the company law o Dissenting shareholders in mergers, spin-offs or sale of substantially all assts can demand the company to buy out their shares at a fair price (art 74, 142(4)) However, almost never heard of in practice o Not surprising given that Chinese are acquiring control rather than companies M&A: TAKEOVER DEFENCES AND FIDUCIARY DUTIES A. TAKEOVER DEFENSES IN U.S. 1. REFUSAL TO SELL Shareholder rights plan (“poison pill”) – poison pills allow existing shareholders the right to purchase additional shares at a discount, effectively diluting the ownership interest of a new, hostile party o Mechanism The target board to issue rights through a board resolution without shareholder approval The rights give shareholders the ability to buy stocks of the issuer Initially, the rights are deliberately designed as “out of the money options” (exercise price higher than market price of stocks) Options – for a premium, stock options give the purchaser the right, but not the obligation, to buy or sell the underlying stock at an agreed-upon price before an agreed-upon date. This agreed-upon price is referred to as the strike price and the agreed upon date is known as the expiration date An option to buy an underlying asset is a call option, while an option to sell an underlying asset is called a put option OTM refers to option that has no intrinsic value, only extrinsic value The rights are triggered when someone acquires a specified percentage of target stocks (“acquirer”), usually 10%-20% 65 | P a g e o Once triggered, the rights are re-priced so that, usually, upon exercise, each holder of a right can receive the number of stocks having a market value of twice the original exercise price of a right E.g. original exercise price = $500, current market price of issuer stocks = $50, then once triggered each right can be used to purchase (500 * 2)/50 = 20 shares However, the acquirer cannot exercise the rights, and instead their rights are voided once triggered The outcome is that, once triggered, acquirer’s shareholding in the issuer will be significantly diluted However, before being triggered, rights can be redeemed at a nominal price by the target board, and target board can also decide who can be excluded from the definition of “acquirer” Hence, poison pill creates an incentive for potential acquirers to engage directly with the target board Twists Whose stocks to purchase? Initially, the rights would allow purchase of stocks of the combined corporation (“flip-over pill”) Then the rights evolved to allow purchase of target stocks (“flip-in pill”) Later, the prevailing design included both flip-over and flip-in features Use blank check preferred stocks instead of common stocks – this is a method companies use to simply the process of creating new classes of preferred stock and to raise additional funds from investors without obtaining separate shareholder approval. This kind of stock can also be created by a public company as a takeover defense in the event of a hostile bid for the company Rights are used to purchase preferred stocks which are entitled to vote in the same class as common stocks on mergers (e.g. preferred shares could be given special voting rights or be convertible to common stock) Since preferred stocks are authorized as blank checks, they are even easier than common stocks to be used by the board without shareholder approval o Legal documents Certificate of Designation to the target articles to set forth basic terms of the rights Indenture agreement between the target and a trustee to set forth the terms once the rights are triggered Since no shareholder approval is required and the documents can be prepared in one or two days, essentially every listed company in the U.S. has a poison pill (“shadow pill”) regardless of declaration of a rights plan Shadow pill = the right to adopt a pill at any time o Effect Poison pills are so formidable that they have been triggered only twice since invented Poison pills are considered most effective when combined with a staggered board Empirical evidence disagrees on the impact of poison pills on firm values, some found positive effects, some (small) negative effects. And pills seem to give target board a stronger bargaining position which has led to higher takeover premium Leveraged recapitalization – company changes its capitalization structure by replacing the majority of its equity with a package of debt securities o Borrow money to pay dividends or buy back stocks or even to acquire other companies including the acquirer (“pac man”) 66 | P a g e o The main purpose is to exhaust the amount of money that can be borrowed against target assets so that the acquirer cannot borrow additional money against the same assets to finance its acquisition Structural defenses (“shark repellents”) o Dual class structure – two or more classes of share with different voting rights. Typically, insiders are given access to a class of shares that provide greater control and voting rights, while the general public is offered a class of shares with little or no voting rights o Staggered board – a board that consists of directors grouped into classes who serve terms of different lengths o Supermajority vote requirements 80% of outstanding shares and a majority of shares not owned by the acquirer o Golden parachute – lucrative severance packages inked into the contracts of top executives that compensate them when they are terminated. In addition to large bonuses and stock compensation, golden parachutes may include ongoing insurance and pension benefits o Advance notice bylaw – require a stockholder to provide prior notice to a corporation of a stockholder’s director nominees or business to be brought before a stockholder meeting Embedded defense o Embedded in the terms of contracts reached between the target and a third party Poison put: accelerated debt repayment upon change of control A poison put is a takeover defense strategy in which the target company issues a bond that investors can redeem before its maturity date i.e. bondholders can redeem their bond before the maturity date and receive full payment in the event there is a takeover of the company. Thus, the poison put is an added expense the acquiring company must pay if it wishes to acquire the target company 2. SALE TO ALLIES “White knight” o A “white knight” is usually a friend of the target board/management so they can keep their positions after the sale o Deal protections (lock ups) in favour of “white knights” – deal protection mechanisms are essentially contractual agreements between the preferred bidder and the target that are designed to discourage competing bids and to protect the preferred bidder if a competing bid emerges Break-up fee (termination fee) – used in takeover agreements as leverage on the seller against backing out of the deal to sell to the purchaser. A breakup fee is required to compensate the prospective purchaser for the time and resources used to facilitate the deal Empirical evidence found it can also be used to attract bids and bring higher acquisition premiums for target shareholders Cf reverse break-up fee (paid by the offering entity) Stock lockup – a device to prevent large shareholders from selling their shares too quickly and causing a sudden change in stock prices after a company goes public Crown jewel (asset lockup option) – stock option offered by a target company to a white knight for additional equity or the purchase of a portion of a company (e.g. some of target’s best assets i.e. crown jewel) o Risks Deal protection terms are subject to judicial review and may be voided 67 | P a g e Putting target up for sale will subject board to a duty to sell to the highest bidder (Revlon rule) who may be unfriendly “White squire” – target board selling a block of shares to a friendly shareholder o Purchase a partial stake cf white knight that purchases the entire company B. FIDUCIARY DUTIES OF TARGET BOARD (U.S.) Unocal intermediate standard of judicial review of takeover defenses o Under Unocal standard, business judgment rule is applied in the context of a hostile battle for control where board action is taken to the exclusion of, or in limitation upon, a valid stockholder vote. However, the board must carry its own initial two-part burden: first, a reasonableness test which is satisfied by demonstration that the board of directors had reasonable grounds for believing that a danger to corporate policy or effectiveness existed; second, a proportionality test, which is satisfied by a demonstration that the board of directors’ defensive response was reasonable in relation to the threat posed. o First prong: target board must show reasonable grounds for believing that a danger to corporate policy or effectiveness existed Threats: opportunity loss, structural coercion, substantive coercion (shareholders mistakenly accepted underpriced hostile bid due to insufficient information) Good faith response to perceived threat, not for the purpose of entrenching themselves Reasonable investigation: target directors well informed in making responses o Second prong: target board needs to further prove that the defense was reasonable in relation to the threat posed by the hostile bid (proportionality) o Unocal test recharacterized in Unitrin. Respond with 2 qns: Is it draconian (coercive or preclusive)? Reasonable within a “range of reasonableness”? o Business judgment rule is reinstated if both prongs are satisfied 1. POISON PILLS UNDER UNOCAL TEST Generally okay - in Moran v Household International, court found that the adoption of poison pill was a legitimate exercise of business judgment. To this end, the defensive tactics adopted by the board need not have been in anticipation of any specific threat and the adoption of a preemptive plan developed before the pressure of a crisis increased the likelihood that the board was acting out of a business judgment Exceptions o “Dead-hand poison pill” – issue new shares to everyone but the hostile bidder seeking to buy the company. It serves to dilute the value of the shares the acquirer already purchased, reducing its percentage of ownership and making it more costly to seize control. Dead hand provisions may only be rescinded by the directors who adopted them (intention is to close the proxy contest/redemption loophole in standard poison pills by precluding newly elected directors from redeeming the pill) Outlawed in Delaware and many other states Both preclusive and coercive preclusive, as the added deterrent effect of the provision made a takeover prohibitively expensive and effectively impossible coercive, as the pill effectively forced shareholders to re-elect the incumbent directors if they wished to be represented by a board entitled to exercise its full statutory powers 68 | P a g e o o “Slow-hand/No-hand poison pill” – pill nonredeemable for a fixed period of time In Quickturn Design Systems, court held that no hand pill limited a newly elected board’s authority by precluding redemption of the pill – and thereby precluding an acquisition of the corporation – for six months Consequently, the no-hand pill tended to “limit in a substantial way the freedom of [newly elected] directors’ decision on matters of management policy.” Accordingly, it violated “the duty of each [newly elected] director to exercise his own best judgment on matters coming before the board’ Anti-activist pills during Covid-19 – use of poison pills against activists in corporate governance contests (as distinguished from corporate control contests) excessively low triggering point: 5% including options and warrants; overbroad definition of “act in concert” including a “daisy chain” (A & C are imputed as acting in concert if A & B and B & C are acting in concert respectively); narrowing the definition of passive investors excluded from “acquirer” the particular features of a pill, most importantly the threshold and what ownership interests count toward it, are highly significant for activists. 2. REVLON RULE WHEN TARGET UP FOR SALE The Revlon rule is the legal principle stating that a company’s board of directors shall make a reasonable effort to obtain the highest value for a company, when a hostile takeover is imminent When target board put the company up for sale, its duty “changed from preservation of” target “as a corporate entity to the maximization of the company’s value at a sale for the stockholders’ benefit” The directors’ role changed from defenders of the corporate bastion to auctioneers charged with getting the best price for the stockholders at a sale of the company” No single roadmap board must follow in Revlon-land, but practices often involve either bidding before reaching an agreement (no-shop approach) or solicitation after reaching an agreement (go-shop approach) Best deal: mainly about price and certainty, other considerations including form of consideration, tax consequences, timing of the deal, antitrust issues Applicability o Paramount Communications v Time Inc Target initiates active bidding to sell itself or effect a reorganization Target absconds its long-term strategy and seeks a break-up in response to a bid o Paramount Communications v QVC Network Inc Sale of control: cash out or sale to an acquirer with a controller C. REGULATING FREEZEOUT MERGERS IN U.S. A cash out merger (i.e. freezeout merger) results from a merger of two entities in which the shareholders of the target company do not want to be involved with the new company. In the case of a freeze out merger, the shareholders of the target company are often forced to sell their shares as part of the acquisition or merger deal. Freezeout mergers can be structured either in 1 step (statutory mergers) or 2 steps (tender offer + short form merger) Either way, for public corporations, Schedule 13E-3 needs to be filed with SEC, in addition to regular disclosures required for the particular deal structure, detailing the process of and rationales for conducting the freezeout merger (or going private) 69 | P a g e When initiated by controlling shareholders, entire fairness test is applicable unless structured with double protection: special committee approval + majority of minority shareholder approval (In re MFW Shareholders Litigation), and then business judgment rule applies o 2-step freezeouts may be subject to a similar rule (In re CNX Gas Corp Shareholders Litigation) o Previously, however, In re Siliconix Inc Shareholders Litigation, the first step tender offer was not subject to entire fairness review if without “actual coercion or disclosure violations”, and in Glassman v Unocal Exploration Corp, the second step short form merger was not subject to entire fairness review either D. HOSTILE BIDS IN CHINA Quite active since 2018, somehow slower in recent years o A good number of Chinese listed companies have dispersed ownership structure – controlling shareholders have about 20%-30% shares o Baoneng’s bid for Vanke was a highly visible case, which accumulated target shared from the secondary market and allegedly involved some regulatory violations o As blockholder disclosure rules tightened, fewer toeholds used in hostile bids, and the new generation of bids rely more on public tender offers and even creeping acquisition China’s law does not have clear guidance about takeover defenses o The overall regulatory environment evolves in the pro-bid direction o E.g. CSISC in recent years has been active in fighting against “shark repellents” o Trading halt was a powerful defense frequently used 1. TRADING HALT IN CHINA A unique Chinese practice o Issuer can apply voluntarily o Due to a variety of (often unverifiable) reasons, e.g. asset restructuring (or recapitalization), acquisition, private placement o For as long as 6 months or maybe even longer Both stock exchanges revised trading halt rules in 2016 and 2018, after Vanke’s long-term halt as a defense against Baoneng (halted for 6+ months), mainly to restrict the length of the halt o Material asset restructuring, usually 10 trading days, extendable up to 25 trading days for special regulatory reasons (SSE) o Other important matters: tender offer or change of control, up to 10 trading days 2. ZUIG INVESTMENT V ZHENXING BIOCHEM A) FIRST STAGE: NEW BOTTLE, OLD WINE Zuig informed Zhenxing of its intention to bid for control and requested Zhenxing to disclose its intention on June 21, 2017, but Zhenzing delayed for a week and filed Zuig’s preliminary tender offer report on June 28, 2017 A partial tender offer of 27.49% of Zhenxing’s outstanding common stocks at a price of ¥36 per share (about 16% premium relative to last available trading price and 28% premium relative to previous 30day VWAP) Zuig’s “new bottle” – tender offer: before the tender offer, Zuig only held 2.51% of Zhenxing’s stocks, and never bought Zhenxing’s stocks within 6 months before the preliminary report Zhenxing’s “old wine” – trading halt: Zhenxing’s stock trading halted from Jun 21, claiming plan for recapitalization 70 | P a g e B) Barbarian’s around the corner o Zuig’s tender offer pan matured after 60 days’ waiting so it could launch an official tender anytime from Aug 28, 2017 o Zhenxing’s trading halt was approaching a mandatory end on Sept 21, 2017 based on the new regulation on trading halt Imaginative lawsuit – Zhenxing’s largest shareholder at the time filed lawsuit in Shanxi High Court against both Zuig and Zhenxing on Sept 13, 2017 o Against Zuig: Nondisclosure of purchase by alleged parties acting in concert (even true, only accumulated 4.74% stocks): insider trading by Zuig’s employees (who are really outsiders); price manipulation before announcing preliminary tender offer plan – price fell from ¥33.48 to ¥25.58 (evidence? causality?) o Against Zhenxing: Failure to discover and stop Zuig’s alleged misbehaviours (issuer should play regulator’s role?) Regulator weighed in: SZSE issued inquiry letter to Zhenxing on Oct 11, requesting for specific facts indicating Zuig’s alleged misbehaviour C) THIRD STAGE: FIGHTING FOR THE LAST STRAW Zuig started the formal tender offer on Nov 3, 2017 at ¥36 per share, and the offer would close on Dec 5, 2017 The offer went smoothly until Nov 29 when Zhenxing’s largest shareholder at that time announced reaching an agreement to sell its stocks to Kaisa Group, an HK listed real estate developer, at ¥43 per share (closing price on Nov 28 at ¥33.54) o What’s behind the sale? Stirring up shareholders’ suspicion about the sufficiency of Zuig’s offer price o Why on Nov 29? Offer terms cannot be changed within the last 15 days of the offer Regulator weighed in again – SZSE issued another inquiry letter asking about the validity of the transfer (e.g. of pledged stocks) at mid-night on Nov 29 On Nov 30, Zuig held a press conference explaining the meaning and risks of Kaisa’s deal to public investors On Dec 1, SZSE issued still another inquiry letter questioning the capital structure of Kaisa and the source of its purchase money D) SECOND STAGE: NOTHING VENTURED, NOTHING GAINED FOURTH STAGE: WINNING A BATTLE OR A WAR? Zuig successfully completed its tender offer on Dec 5, 2017 with more than 140m Zhenxing stocks tendered (about 55% of outstanding stocks, and 75.5% of circulating stocks), doubling the amount in the offer Being the first hostile bidder that successfully acquired the control block of a public company through tender offers, Zuig made history in Chinese capital markets. It “opened a new chapter in corporate governance of Chinese listed companies” However, the former controlling, now the 2nd largest, shareholder did not give up o On Jan 8, 2018, Shi Family reported to former CBRC (now CBIRC) that Minsheng Bank, Zuig’s debt financier, violated regulatory rules forbidding lending to parties in pending litigations o On Jan 17, 2018, one of Shi brothers resigned from CEO and CFO positions, and representatives from Kaisa took over these offices 71 | P a g e E) FIFTH STAGE: CHARACTERISTICS JEWEL” WITH CHINESE On Jan 3, 2018, shortly after Zuig completed the tender offer, but before it could join the board, Zhenxing’s original largest shareholder reshuffled the board of Shuanglin Bio-Pharmacy Co, Zhenxing’s wholly-owned subsidiary. In fact, Shuang Lin contributes to Zhenxing’s 99% revenue – “crown jewel” To entrench Shuanglin’s incumbent board, on Jan 5, 2018, Shuanglin’s articles of incorporation was amended to require 2/3 of its shareholders’ approval for board election or future amendment of articles On Dec 14, 2018, Shuanglin’s board held an emergency meeting to fire its CEO, potentially a Zuig ally – then Zuig controlled Zhengxing’s board, but not Shuanglin’s board On Jan 5, 2019, Zhengxing’s board held an emergency meeting to revoke Shuanglin’s articles amended on Jan 5, 2018, reshuffle Shuanglin’s board, and reinstate its expelled CEO Zhengxin’s original largest shareholder sued again on Jan 15, 2019 to invalidate Zhenxing’s board resolution adopted on Jan 5, 2019 which was eventually withdrawn E. “CROWN HOSTILE BIDS: A COMPARISON China started with a very unfriendly environment for hostile bidders o Liu Shiyu, CSRC Chairman: acquisition funds making hostile bids are “barbarians”, “robbers of the industry”, “challenging the bottom line of financial laws and regulations of the state” However, China has pivoted toward a more bidder-friendly environment in a short period of time, especially due to the changes in trading halt rules by the stock exchanges and the anti-takeover stance taken by CSISC o Except “poison pills” which is not available due to the legal capital doctrine, the takeover defenses in China are heavily borrowed from the American playbooks o Similarly, the anti-defense campaign in China also follows American theories and practices 72 | P a g e