Biography for William Swan Chief Economist, Seabury-Airline Planning Group. AGIFORS Senior Fellow. ATRG Senior Fellow. Retired Chief Economist for Boeing Commercial Aircraft 1996-2005 Previous to Boeing, worked at American Airlines in Operations Research and Strategic Planning and United Airlines in Research and Development. Areas of work included Yield Management, Fleet Planning, Aircraft Routing, and Crew Scheduling. Also worked for Hull Trading, a major market maker in stock index options, and on the staff at MIT’s Flight Transportation Lab. Education: Master’s, Engineer’s Degree, and Ph. D. at MIT. Bachelor of Science in Aeronautical Engineering at Princeton. Likes dogs and dark beer. (bill.swan@cyberswans.com) © Scott Adams How Airlines Compete Fighting it out in a City-Pair Market William M. Swan Chief Economist Seabury Airline Planning Group Nov 200 Papers: http://www.seaburyapg.com/company/research.html Contact: bill.swan@cyberswans.com A Stylized Game With Realistic Numbers 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. The Simplest Case, Airlines A & Z Case 2: Airline A is Preferred Peak and Off-peak days Full Spill model version Airline A is “Sometimes” Preferred Time-of-day Games Model the Fundamentals • Capture all relevant characteristics – – – – – – Different passengers pay high and low fares Different passengers like different times of day Different passengers have less or more time flexibility Airlines block space to accommodate higher fares Demand varies from day to day Demand that exceeds capacity spills • to other flights, if possible – Airlines can be preferred, one over another – Passengers have a hierarchy of decisions • Price; Time; Airline – Bigger airplanes are cheaper per seat than smaller ones Example Simple but True • Example here as simple as we could devise – Covers all fundamentals – Uses simplest possible distributions • • • • • Time of day Fares paid Airline choices Demand variations Choice Hierarchy – Means and Standard Deviations are realistic • Each is a “cartoon” – Reflects industry experience with detailed models – Based on best practices at • AA; UA; Boeing; MIT • Other airlines that were Boeing customers • University contacts The Simplest Case: Airlines A & Z • • Identical airlines in simplest case Two passenger types: 1. Discount @ $100, 144 passengers demand 2. Full-fare @ $300, 36 passengers demand - Average fare $140 • Each airline has – – – 100-seat airplane Cost of $126/seat Break-even at 90% load, half the market We Pretend Airline A is Preferred • All 180 passengers prefer airline A – Could be quality of service – Maybe Airline Z paints its planes an ugly color • Airline A demand is all 180 passengers – – – – – – – Keeps all 36 full-fare Fills to 100% load with 64 more discount Leaves 80 discount for airline Z Average A fare $172 Revenue per Seat $172 Cost per seat was $126 Profits: huge Airline Z is not Preferred • • • • • Gets only spilled demand from A Has 80 discount passengers on 100 seats Revenue per seat $80 Cost per seat was $126 Losses: huge “not a good thing” Preferred Carrier Does Not Want to Have Higher Fares • Pretend Airline A charges 20% more – Goes back to splitting market evenly with Z – Profits now 20% – Profits when preferred were 36% • 25% extra revenue from having all of full-fares • 11% extra revenue from having high load factor • Airline Z is better off when A raises prices – Returns to previous break-even condition Major Observations • Average fares look different in matched case: – $172 for A vs. $80 for Z • Preferred Airline gains by matching fares – Premium share of premium traffic – Full loads, even in the off-peak – Even though discount and full-fares match Z More Observations • “Preferred wins” result drives quality matching between airlines • Result is NOT high quality – Everybody knows everybody tries to match – Therefore quality is standardized, not high • Result is arbitrary quality level – add qualities that people value beyond cost? Variations in Demand Modify Answer Matters are Worse for Z • Consider 3 seasons, matched fares case 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. • Off peak at 2/3 of standard demand (120) Standard demand of 180 total, as before Peak day at 4/3 of standard demand (240) Each season 1/3 of year Same average demand, revenue, etc. Off-peak A gets 24 full-fare, 76 discount – • Z gets only 20 discount Peak A gets 48 full-fare, 52 discount – – • Z gets 100 discount, still below break-even Z is spilling 40 discounts, lost revenues Overall, A at $172/seat and Z at $67 – – Compared to $172 & $80 in simple case Some revenue in the market is “spilled’ – all from Airline Z Full Spill Model Case • Spill model captures normal full variations of seasonal demand – Spill is airline industry standard model* • Spill model exercised 3 times: – Full-fare demand against A capacity • For full-fare spill, which is zero – Total demand against A capacity • Spill will be sum of discount and full-fare – Total demand against A + Z capacity • Spill will be sum of A and Z spills • K-cyclic = 0.36; C-factorA=0.7; C-factorAZ=0.7 • Results – A $11/seat below 3-season case – Z $1/seat better than 3-season case • Qualitatively the same conclusions: A wins big; Z looses. *See Swan, 1997 Airline A is “Sometimes” Preferred • • • • 2/3 of customers prefer airline A 1/3 of customers prefer airline Z Full spill case (full spill model employed) Results: – A has 85% load; $133/seat—15% above avg. – Z has 73% load; $97/seat—15% below avg. • If Z is low-cost by 15%, can break even • This could represent new-entrant case Time-of-Day Games • What if 2/3 preferred case was because Z was at a different time of day? – 1/3 of people prefer Z’s time of day – 1/3 of people prefer A’s time of day – 1/3 of people can take either, prefer Airline A’s quality (or color) • Ground rules: back to simple case – No peak, off-peak spill – Back to 100% maximum load factor – System overall at breakeven revenues and costs • Simple case for clarity of exposition – Spill issues add complication without insight – Spill will merely soften differences Simple Time-of-Day Model Total Demand Only AM Morning Midday Evening 17.5% 17.5% 17.5% 15% PM any 15% 17.5% Both A & Z in Morning Z=0F, 80D A=36F, 64D RAS=$ 80 RAS=$172 Full Fare Morn Mid-ing Day Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% Z “Hides” in Evening A=18.9F, 81.1D Z=17.1F, 62.9D RAS=$138 RAS=$114 Full Fare Morn Mid- Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing Day -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% A Pursues to Midday A=22.5F, 77.5D Z=13.5F, 66.5D RAS=$145 RAS=$107 Full Fare Morn Mid-ing Day Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% Demand Up 50%, A uses 200 seats A=33.7F, 166.3D Z=20.3F, 49.7D RAS=$134, CAS=$95 RAS=$111; CAS=$126 Full Fare Morn Mid-ing Day Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% CAS - Cost per Available Seat $230 Larger Airplanes are Cheaper Per Seat $210 Too Expensive $190 $170 $150 $130 Reasonable Range of Sizes $110 $90 Declining Advantages to Scale $70 $50 0 50 100 150 200 SEATS 250 300 350 400 Demand Up 50%, Z adds Morning A=27F, 73D RAS=$154, CAS=$126 Full Fare Z=27F, 143D RAS=$112; CAS=$126 Morn Mid- Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing Day -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% Demand Up 50%, A adds Morning A=40.5F, 157.4D Z=13.5F, 58.6D RAS=$139, CAS=$126 RAS=$ 99; CAS=$126 Full Fare Morn Mid- Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing Day -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% A adds Evening Instead Z=0F, 70D A=54F, 146D RAS=$154, CAS=$126 Full Fare RAS=$ 70; CAS=$126 Morn Mid- Even Dis- Morn Mid- Even -ing Day -ing count -ing Day -ing Only 25% 25% 25% Only 10% 10% 10% AM PM All 10% 10% 5% AM PM All 20% 20% 30% Summary and Conclusions • Airlines have strong incentives to match – A preferred airline does best matching prices – A non-preferred airline does poorly unless it can match preference. • A preferred airline gains substantial revenue – Higher load factor in the off peak – Higher share of full-fare passengers in the peak – Gains are greater than from higher prices • A less-preferred airline has a difficult time covering costs • Preferred airline’s advantage is reduced by 1. Spill – but not much change 2. Partial preference – some people prefer the other 3. Time-of-day distribution – good time/bad airline