Uploaded by Tahmeed Jawad

550Lecture7

advertisement
Econometrics
ECON 550
March 1, 2021
Instrumental Variables
W Chapter 15
Drexel University, LeBow College of Business
Outline for Today
Administrative Business:
• Upcoming Assignments
1) Differences-in-Differences (cont.)
2) Panel Estimation Recap – Exercise #5
3) Instrumental Variables
• Instrument Relevance, Exogeneity, and Monotonicity
• IV Estimation
• 2SLS Estimation
• IV Testing
Due Dates
• Due Monday, 3/8, 6:00 p.m.:
1) Presentations
• Due Friday, 3/12, 11:59 p.m.:
1) FINAL DRAFT
2) Peer Review – Presentations
3) Teammates Survey
• FINAL EXAM: Monday, 3/15, 6:00 p.m. – 8:30 p.m.
Recall: DiD as First-Differencing or Fixed Effects
πΊπ‘¦π‘š 𝑣𝑖𝑠𝑖𝑑𝑠
𝛽
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘ π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝛽 π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝑒
• In terms of first differences,
𝐺𝑉
𝐺𝑉
𝛾 π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝛾 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘
π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝑒
• Recognizing that π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
⇒ Δ𝐺𝑉
𝛾
1, π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝛾 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘
𝑒
0:
𝑣
• 𝛾 captures the average change in gym visits between
February and March for the control group.
• 𝛾 captures the DiD treatment effect.
Recall: DiD as First-Differencing or Fixed Effects
πΊπ‘¦π‘š 𝑣𝑖𝑠𝑖𝑑𝑠
𝛽
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘ π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝛽 π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
𝑒
• In terms of fixed effects,
⇒ πΊπ‘¦π‘š 𝑣𝑖𝑠𝑖𝑑𝑠
𝛼
πœ†
π›½π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘
π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž
• Baseline differences in February gym visits between
𝑒
treatment and control groups are absorbed by the entity
fixed effects, 𝛼 , while time fixed effects, πœ† , absorb the
treatment period effect, π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž , for members of the
control group.
• The coefficient on the interaction term, π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘π‘’π‘‘
π‘€π‘Žπ‘Ÿπ‘β„Ž , captures the DiD treatment effect.
Differences-in-Differences (DiD) (cont.)
οƒ˜ Under what assumptions will the DiD estimator capture
the causal effect of the policy change or experimental
treatment?
οƒ˜ A key assumption of the DiD strategy is that of
parallel trends.
οƒ˜ If not for the policy change or experimental intervention,
outcomes would have evolved similarly over time for both
treatment and control groups.
οƒ˜ This is typically reasonable in the case of experiments given
randomization into treatment, but still a potential concern in small
samples.
DiD Parallel Trends Assumption
• A DiD regression compares the trend in the outcome in
the treatment group to the trend in the outcome in the
control group.
• In order for this comparison to yield a good estimate of
the treatment effect, we must rule out any differences in
pre-existing trends among the two groups.
• If the pre-existing trends differ, then any difference in
differences may simply reflect a continuation of these preexisting trends rather than a causal effect.
Checking Parallel Trends
• Using data from the pre-period, create a linear time trend,
π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘›π‘‘
1,2, … 𝑇 ∀𝑑
1,2 … 𝑇
where period T is the last untreated time period.
• Then, interact it with a treatment group dummy and
estimate the model below on pre-treatment data:
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘›π‘‘
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘ 𝛽 π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘Žπ‘‘ π‘‡π‘Ÿπ‘’π‘›π‘‘
π‘Œ 𝛽
𝑒
• If the coefficient on this interaction is different from zero
𝛽 0 , the data flunk the parallel trends assumption and
the DiD estimate is likely to be biased.
Checking Parallel Trends (cont.)
• Researchers typically plot trends in the outcome variable
across treatment and control groups for both the pretreatment and treatment periods with a vertical line at the
time the treatment is applied.
• If you have data from too few observations to run the
regression on the last slide, you can simply plot the time
trend for visual inspection.
Continuous DiD
E.g. Airline Full-Fare Advertising Regulations (FFAR)
π‘‡π‘–π‘π‘˜π‘’π‘‘π‘ƒπ‘Ÿπ‘–π‘π‘’
𝛽
δ π‘‡π‘Žπ‘₯
𝛿 𝐼 π‘ƒπ‘œπ‘ π‘‘πΉπΉπ΄π‘…
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Žπ‘₯
𝐼 π‘ƒπ‘œπ‘ π‘‘πΉπΉπ΄π‘…
𝑒
• In a continuous DiD set-up, all observations are “treated,”
albeit to varying degrees (depending on size of π‘‡π‘Žπ‘₯ ).
• 𝛽 measures average pre-FFAR price where π‘‡π‘Žπ‘₯
0
• 𝛿 measures average price differences pre- versus post-FFAR
• 𝛽 measures the baseline (pre-FFAR) rate of tax pass-through
• 𝛿 captures changes in the rate of tax pass-through post-FFAR
Continuous DiD (cont.)
π‘‡π‘–π‘π‘˜π‘’π‘‘π‘ƒπ‘Ÿπ‘–π‘π‘’
𝛽
δ π‘‡π‘Žπ‘₯
𝛿 𝐼 π‘ƒπ‘œπ‘ π‘‘πΉπΉπ΄π‘…
𝛽 π‘‡π‘Žπ‘₯
𝐼 π‘ƒπ‘œπ‘ π‘‘πΉπΉπ΄π‘…
𝑒
οƒ˜ 𝜹𝟏 is the (continuous) differences-in-differences
estimator of the effect of FFAR on the rate of tax
pass-through.
οƒ˜ Under what conditions will 𝜹𝟏 capture the causal
effect of the policy change?
Difference in Differences in Differences
(Triple-Differencing, a.k.a., DDD)
• Conceptually, the DDD estimator captures the difference
between two DiD results in one regression.
• Triple differencing helps strengthen the credibility of the
parallel trends assumption.
• The first difference is the one we have already studied.
• The second difference is relative to a group that was
exposed to the treatment but should not be affected by it.
• E.g., Outbound vs. Inbound (not subject to FFAR) flights
Why Instrumental Variables?
• We have discussed many scenarios in which different
sources of bias will prevent us from identifying causal
effects of X on Y through violation of the OLS zero
conditional mean independence assumption:
1) Omitted Variables
2) Functional Form Misspecification
3) Measurement Error (Errors-in-Variables)
4) Simultaneity (Simultaneous Causality)
5) Sample Selection
Why Instrumental Variables? (cont.)
• When more direct solutions are not available (e.g. explicit
controls or fixed effects), instrumental variables (IV)
regression offers a possible method for mitigating bias
due to omitted variables, simultaneity, or measurement
error.
• IV may thereby allow us to estimate causal effects.
Intuition for Instrumental Variables
• The problem we want to avoid is having our regressor(s)
of interest, X, being correlated with the error term, u.
• When π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑋, 𝑒
0, one can think of separating the
variation in X into two parts:
1) Variation that is correlated with the error term
( = Endogenous variation)
2) Variation that is uncorrelated with the error term
( = Exogenous variation)
Intuition for Instrumental Variables (cont.)
In other words, the effect of X on Y can be decomposed
into a causal and a non-causal component.
IV allows us to decompose this variation in X and
estimate only the effect of the variation in X that is
uncorrelated with the error term, i.e. the causal effect.
E.g. Concealed Gun Laws and Crime
• Even after accounting for various sources of bias through the
inclusion of fixed effects, one might still worry that our
estimates of the effect of “shall issue” laws on violent crime will
be biased due to the fact that states can choose if and when to
implement these laws (simultaneity).
• Variation in shall therefore consists of two parts:
1)
2)
Endogenous variation in the timing and geographic distribution of
shall issue laws due to state’s intentional responses to crime rates.
Exogenous variation due to factors having nothing to do with crime
rates, such as changes in political representation (driven by voter
preferences over other issues).
• We would like to be able to discard the endogenous variation in
shall and extract only the variation that is truly exogenous to
crime (e.g. as if these laws were randomly assigned) to
measure the causal effect of these laws on crime.
Implementing Instrumental Variables
• In order to implement this desired decomposition of the
variation in X, we need at least one additional variable, Z,
which helps to explain the exogenous variation in X
without having any direct effect on Y.
• This additional variable, Z, then serves as an instrument
for our X of interest.
• E.g. Concealed Gun Laws and Crime
• In our example, a potential instrument for shall issue laws would be
a variable which helps to predict where and when these laws are
implemented without having any direct relationship to crime rates
(i.e. where the only relationship is through the implementation of
shall issue laws).
Requirements for a Valid Instrument
(1) Instrument relevance:
• The instrument, Z, successfully explains variation in the
endogenous regressor, X:
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑋, 𝑍
0
(2) Instrument exogeneity:
• The instrument, Z, is uncorrelated with the error term
from the regression relating X and Y (i.e. Z does not
directly influence Y, except through X):
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
0
Instrumental Variables Estimation
• Consider the following basic regression:
π‘Œ
• If cov X, 𝑒
𝛽
𝛽𝑋
𝑒
0, 𝛽 will be biased and inconsistent and
OLS will be uninformative, or worse—misleading.
Instrumental Variables Estimation (cont.)
• Now, suppose there exists a valid instrument, Z, for our
endogenous regressor such that π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
𝑋
πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍
0 and
𝑣
οƒ˜ How can we test for instrument relevance?
οƒ˜ How can we test for instrument exogeneity?
Instrumental Variables Estimation (cont.)
• Given that π‘Œ
𝛽
𝛽𝑋
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, π‘Œ
𝑒,
𝛽 π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑋
• Hence, provided that π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
0 and π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑋, 𝑍
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, π‘Œ
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑋
𝛽
⇒ 𝛽
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
∑
∑
𝑍
𝑍
𝑍̅ π‘Œ
𝑍̅ 𝑋
π‘Œ
𝑋
0,
Properties of
𝛽
⇒ π‘π‘™π‘–π‘š 𝛽
- Consistency
∑
∑
𝑍
𝑍
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, π‘Œ
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑋
𝑍̅ π‘Œ
𝑍̅ 𝑋
𝛽
π‘Œ
𝑋
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑋
𝛽
Properties of
- Unbiasedness
𝜷
𝒁𝑿
𝒀
⇒𝐸 𝜷
𝑿, 𝒁
οƒ˜ In finite samples, 𝜷
𝜷
π‘Ώπœ·
𝒁𝑿
𝒁 𝒀,
𝒖
𝒁 𝐸 𝒖 𝑿, 𝒁
𝛽
remains generally biased (hence
importance of large samples and consistency result).
Properties of
- Efficiency
• Assuming homoskedasticity,
𝜎
𝑆𝑆𝑇 · 𝑅
π΄π‘£π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
οƒ˜ Unless 𝑅 ,
1 (i.e. 𝑋
π΄π‘£π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
𝑍 ,
π΄π‘£π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
𝑛
1
π‘˜
1
𝑒
,
𝑅 from regression of 𝑋
on Z (including constant)
𝜎
𝑆𝑆𝑇
(Note that this comparison is only sensible if π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑋, 𝑒
0)
Weak Instruments
οƒ˜ Weak correlation between X and the instrument, Z,
implies a small 𝑅
,
, and hence, large standard errors.
οƒ˜ Worse, even a very modest failure of instrument
0 does not hold precisely),
exogeneity (i.e., π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
can lead to severe asymptotic bias and inconsistency if
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑋 is weak:
π‘π‘™π‘–π‘š 𝛽
𝛽
π‘π‘™π‘–π‘š 𝛽
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑒
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍, 𝑋
𝛽
𝛽
π‘π‘œπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ 𝑍, 𝑒 𝜎
·
π‘π‘œπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ 𝑍, 𝑋 𝜎
𝜎
π‘π‘œπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ 𝑋, 𝑒 ·
𝜎
Weak Instruments (cont.)
• Asymptotic bias for the IV estimator will be more severe
than for the OLS estimator if:
π‘π‘œπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ 𝑍, 𝑒
π‘π‘œπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ 𝑍, 𝑋
π‘π‘œπ‘Ÿπ‘Ÿ 𝑋, 𝑒
οƒ˜ Successful application of IV methods depends
critically on having a valid (and strong) instrument
that satisfies both instrument relevance and
instrument exogeneity.
E.g. Instrument Validity
• Suppose that we want to estimate
ln π‘€π‘Žπ‘”π‘’
𝛽
𝛽 𝑒𝑑𝑒𝑐
𝑒
For the many reasons discussed before, 𝑒𝑑𝑒𝑐 is likely
endogenous to wages through unobserved ability, etc.
οƒ˜ Which of the following is likely to serve as a valid
instrument for 𝒆𝒅𝒖𝒄?
οƒ˜ Father’s educational attainment?
οƒ˜ Number of siblings?
οƒ˜ College proximity?
οƒ˜ Quarter of birth?
οƒ˜ Social security numbers?
Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS)
• Thus far, it is not altogether transparent how the
introduction of Z enables the decomposition of X into
endogenous and exogenous components to estimate 𝛽 .
οƒ˜ Two-stage least squares estimation (2SLS) makes this
explicit.
2SLS (cont.)
• Recalling our expression for testing instrument relevance,
𝑋
πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍
𝑣
οƒ˜ Estimating this last relationship, we can decompose
variation in X into exogenous and endogenous parts:
1 π‘Ώπ’Š
π…πŸŽ π…πŸ π’π’Š (exogenous)
2) π’—π’Š (endogenous)
2SLS Estimation (cont.)
• 2SLS regression thus proceeds in two stages:
1) In the first stage, we regress the endogenous regressor, X, on
the instrument(s) and obtain predicted values of the component
of X which is uncorrelated with the error term u from the
regression of Y on X:
πœ‹
𝑋
⇒𝑋
2)
πœ‹ 𝑍
πœ‹
𝑣
πœ‹ 𝑍
In the second stage (i.e. the main or “structural” equation), we
regress Y on these predicted values:
π‘Œ
𝛽
𝛽𝑋
𝑒
Provided Z is a valid instrument, πœ·πŸπ‘Ίπ‘³π‘Ί
will be a
𝟏
consistent estimate of the true causal effect of X on Y.
2SLS Estimation (cont.)
• Note that 𝑋 in the second-stage 2SLS regression is a
generated regressor, and is therefore measured with
some sampling error that depends on 𝑣.
• Performed separately as one stage at a time OLS
will be invalid in that it will fail to
regressions, 𝑆𝐸 𝛽
account for variation in 𝑣.
• Computing valid standard errors therefore requires more
sophisticated adjustments, which ivregress 2sls will
perform automatically in Stata.
Multivariate IV vs. 2SLS Estimation
• In a multivariate regression model with a single
endogenous regressor, 𝑋 , 𝛽 and 𝛽
will each still
consistently estimate the effect of 𝑋 on Y, provided that a
valid instrument exists, and IV and 2SLS are
synonymous.
• With multiple valid instruments, or exclusion
restrictions (i.e. variables that do not appear directly in
the 2nd stage equation and satisfy instrument exogeneity),
2SLS estimation is required.
Multivariate IV vs. 2SLS (cont.)
Proof that 𝛽
𝛽 :
𝑋
πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍 𝑣 (First Stage)
π‘Œ 𝛽
𝛽 𝑋 𝑒 (Second Stage)
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑋 , π‘Œ
⇒𝛽
⇒𝛽
⇒
πœ·πŸπ‘Ίπ‘³π‘Ί
𝟏
π‘π‘œπ‘£ πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍 ,π‘Œ
π‘‰π‘Žπ‘Ÿ πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍
π‘‰π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝑋
πœ‹ π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍 , π‘Œ
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍 , π‘Œ
πœ‹ π‘‰π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝑍
πœ‹ π‘‰π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝑍
𝒄𝒐𝒗 π’π’Š , π’€π’Š
𝒄𝒐𝒗 π’π’Š , π‘Ώπ’Š
· 𝑽𝒂𝒓 π’π’Š
𝑽𝒂𝒓 π’π’Š
𝒄𝒐𝒗 π’π’Š , π’€π’Š
𝒄𝒐𝒗 π’π’Š , π‘Ώπ’Š
πœ·π‘°π‘½
𝟏
Structural (IV/2SLS), Reduced Form, and
First-Stage Equations
The reduced form equation evaluates the effect of the
instrument directly on the outcome.
𝑋
πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍 𝑣 (First Stage)
π‘Œ 𝛽
𝛽 𝑋 𝑒 (Second Stage Structural Equation)
π‘Œ 𝛼
𝛼 𝑍 𝑒 (Reduced Form Equation)
• Under the assumption that the exclusion restriction is
valid, the reduced form effect of the instrument on Y
must necessarily operate through X (only).
• Hence,
𝛽
·πœ‹
𝛼
Structural (IV/2SLS), Reduced Form, and
First-Stage Equations (cont.)
• By implication,
𝛽
𝛼
πœ‹
π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑍 , π‘Œ
1
≡
·
π‘‰π‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝑍
πœ‹
οƒ˜ The causal effect of X on Y is equal to the reduced form
effect of the instrument scaled by the first stage
coefficient.
E.g. Returns to education and college proximity.
Local Average Treatment Effects (LATE)
πœ·πŸπ‘Ίπ‘³π‘Ί captures a local average treatment effect (LATE).
• To see this, note that you can think of the portion of the
variation in X that is explained by Z as capturing the subset of
the sample that is induced to “comply” with X, the “treatment.”
E.g. Returns to education and college proximity.
• Z = distance to the nearest college
• X = college attendance
οƒ˜2SLS (IV) compares those who were induced to attend college
(treated) due to their proximity to a college to those who chose
not to attend (untreated) due to being far away.
LATE (cont.)
• Students who respond to college proximity are called
“compliers.”
• Those who would go to college regardless of how far they
live from a college are called “always takers.”
• Those who would never go to college, regardless of how
close they live to one, are called “never takers.”
οƒ˜IV estimates are based off a comparison of outcomes
within a subset of the pool of potential college students
(the compliers).
LATE (cont.)
•π›½
is the local effect averaged across the subset of
compliers, hence the name, “local average treatment
effect.”
•π›½
does not address the effect of college attendance on
always takers or what might happen if you forced never
takers to attend college.
• IV estimates are likely to be externally valid for those who
are similar to the compliers but may not apply more
generally.
Multicollinearity and 2SLS Estimation
• In a multivariate model, imperfect multicollinearity can be
even more serious for 2SLS estimation than OLS.
• This comes from the fact that
1) The second stage regressor, 𝑋 , has necessarily less
variation than the original endogenous regressor.
2) The correlation between 𝑋 and the remaining
exogenous regressors (used in the first stage as well)
is generally higher than between 𝑋 and the
covariates.
2SLS w/ Multiple Endogenous Regressors
• With multiple endogenous regressors, the order condition
requires the existence of at least as many valid
instruments as endogenous regressors.
• Each endogenous regressor will require a separate first
stage regression, involving all instruments (exogenous
regressors)
Tests of Endogeneity
(i.e. Do we need IV?)
• Suppose that we wish to estimate
π‘Œ
𝛽
𝛽𝑋
𝛽𝑍
𝑒
𝐸 𝑒 , and 𝑍 is an
where we suspect 𝐸 𝑒|𝑋
exogenous control variable.
• Assuming that we have a valid instrument for π‘ΏπŸ , 𝑍 ,
we can test whether IV estimation is necessary by
comparing OLS and 2SLS estimates.
Tests of Endogeneity (cont.)
οƒ˜ Under the null hypothesis that 𝑋 is exogenous,
𝛽
whereas only 𝛽
𝛽
→𝛽
is consistent under the alternative.
οƒ˜ Moreover, assuming homoskedasticity,
Vπ‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
Vπ‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
Durbin-Wu-Hausman Test:
𝐻
𝛽
𝛽
′ Vπ‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
Vπ‘Žπ‘Ÿ 𝛽
𝐻~πœ’
𝛽
𝛽
Tests of Endogeneity (cont.)
Regression-Based Test:
οƒ˜ Under the null (𝑋 is exogenous), the residual from the
first stage regression should have no statistically
significant effect if included as an extra regressor in the
OLS regression.
1) Estimate 𝑋
πœ‹
πœ‹ 𝑍
πœ‹ 𝑍
𝑣⇒ 𝑣
• 𝑣 captures variation in 𝑋 that is orthogonal to 𝑍
and 𝑍 and therefore potentially correlated with 𝑒
2) Estimate π‘Œ
𝛽
𝛽𝑋
𝛽𝑍
𝛿𝑣 𝑒, 𝑒 𝛿𝑣 𝑒
3) Test 𝐻 : 𝛿 0
0 ⇔ π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑒, 𝑣
0⇒𝛿 0
⇒ π‘π‘œπ‘£ 𝑒, 𝑋
Tests of Endogeneity (cont.)
• Rejection of 𝛿
0 implies that 𝑋 is endogenous (through
correlation between 𝑣 and 𝑒).
οƒ˜Use IV!
• Note that the regression-based test of endogeneity
delivers identical point estimates in the second step
regression as 2SLS.
• This shows that instead of the usual IV or 2SLS routine,
you could instead include 𝑣 in a second stage regression
alongside 𝑋 to control explicitly for that part of 𝑋 that is
endogenous.
• This is known as the control function technique to IV
estimation.
Overidentification (OID) Tests
• An IV regression is said to be just identified if there are as
many instruments as endogenous regressors.
• If you have multiple candidate instruments, you can test
whether a subset of these are uncorrelated with the
structural error term in the true regression model (i.e. you
can test whether instrument exogeneity is satisfied for a
subset of instruments).
• Note: For any of these tests to be convincing, you must
assert that at least one of your instruments is valid.
• This is an important shortcoming that limits the usefulness
of these tests. Nevertheless, these are commonly used.
OID Tests (cont.)
• Suppose we have two candidate instruments, 𝑍 and 𝑍 ,
for 𝑋 in π‘Œ
𝛽
𝛽𝑋
𝛽𝑍
𝑒.
• Intuitively, we can obtain 2SLS estimates of 𝛽 using
either instrument singly. Under the null that both
instruments are exogenous, both 2SLS estimators will be
consistent and approximately equal (with differences due
only to sampling error).
• We reject this null if 𝛽
𝛽
is statistically
significant, and conclude that one or both instruments are
invalid.
OID Tests (cont.)
• Note that rejection of the null for the Hausman OID test
gives no guidance as to which instrument is invalid.
• Moreover, the OID test might fail to reject if both
instruments are invalid but nevertheless yield similar
2SLS coefficient estimates.
OID Tests (cont.)
• Furthermore, rejection of the null for the Hausman OID
test might also falsely reject due to heterogeneous
treatment effects.
• In this case, instruments might isolate different sources of
variation in the endogenous X.
E.g. Returns to Education
• One instrument might explain variation in high school education
(e.g. quarter of birth) and another might be for college education
(e.g. distance to the nearest 4-year college).
• If the effects of high school and college education on the outcome
are different (i.e. different LATEs), the OID test could falsely reject
validity of the instruments.
OID Tests (cont.)
• Assuming homoskedasticity, an alternative OID test with q
overidentifying restrictions can be implemented as
follows:
1) Estimate model by 2SLS using all instruments and
obtain the residuals, 𝑒
2) Regress 𝑒 on all exogenous regressors and instruments
and compute the regression 𝑅
3) Under the null that all exogenous regressors and
instruments are uncorrelated with 𝑒, 𝑛𝑅 ~πœ’
οƒ˜If 𝑛𝑅 is large, we reject this null and conclude that at
least one instrument is not exogenous.
Weak Instruments Tests
• In the simplest case, testing for whether an instrument or
collection of instruments for a single endogenous
regressors is “weak” can be accomplished as an F test of
the exclusion restrictions in the first-stage.
• Staiger and Stock (1997) suggest as a rule-of-thumb
needing 𝐹 10 to reject instrument weakness.
• For situations involving multiple endogenous regressors
and adjusted (e.g. robust) errors, Kleibergen-Paap
statistics apply, with critical values drawn from Stock and
Yogo (2005).
Assignment
For our last week of class:
Please read W Ch. 15
PRESENTATIONS due 3/8, beginning of class
FINAL DRAFTS and Presentation Feedback
due 3/12 @ 11:59 p.m. EST
Download