Early Piast Rule as a "Post-Carolingian" Phenomenon? I'd like to call your attention to a piece of punctuation. The titles of the two papers at this conference that concern East Central Europe both end with a question mark. Lisa Wolverton's title is a straightforward question. Mine is an expression of doubt—about whether the social or political order presided by the dynasty of the dukes, intermittently kings, later called the Piasts was, to any degree, "post-Carolingian"; and, as a corollary, what is meant by Carolingian or post-Carolingian, and how do we track down whatever that is. The project of situating Poland, over its formative period between the mid-tenth and the later twelfth centuries, in the "Carolingian," or "post-Carolingian," world, presents two enormous—almost (?) insurmountable—challenges. One is state of the evidence, of which we have, in writing, quite literally next to none. There is archaeological evidence, but it is quite difficult to interpret, and is today in a state of a rather bizarre reassessment… The second obstacle is the utter absence of any actual presence, either directly of, or plainly related to, the Carolingian empire or its successor kingdoms, in the territories that subsequently comprised Poland. To begin with the obvious: we are geographically and chronologically far, far away from any actual Carolingian network— dynastic, territorial or political, ecclesiastical, economic, or other—cultural, social, material/architectural… Nor is the future or very early Poland one of those polities which interacted with the world ruled by the Carolingians: places situated nearer to, or overlapping with, the empire's "marches," such as Moravia, Bohemia, the Polabian Slavs, or bits and pieces of the Danube region. These (almost?) insurmountable challenges are complicated by two other considerations, different from the "Polish Question." One is a certain fluidity of the meaning of Carolingian (and its derivative, signalled by the prefix post-) among 1 2 medievalists today. This issue is well identified, and constructively embraced, by Marios Costambeys, Matthew Innes, and Simon MacLean in their superb recent synthesis of "the Carolingian world," where they seek to understand that "world," "on"—and these are their own words—"its own terms," rather than as a long transitional phase from one kind of high-level order to another. That goal, thus stated, logically implies some doubt about the current utility of Carolingian and post-Carolingian as stable analytical categories. That doubt, too, is signalled by a question mark placed at the end of a title. "Was there a Carolingian economy?" the authors ask, at the last section of the relevant chapter. I am struck by the absence of a conclusive answer to the question; and thus, by an implication that, at least on this, the economic and the social, dimension of reality, the adjective of Carolingian, understood as a benchmark or a comparative standard, may require further thought. The other complication is raised by Chris Wickham's massive treatment of early postRoman Europe, Framing the Early Middle Ages—an extraordinarily full study of what I like to call comparable phenomena, extended over a significant time and space, regarding several, enormously varied regions comprising the circum-Mediterranean world. The study works as a lovely roster of highly specific similarities and differences. I'd like to say something about those differences. They are—at least many of them—permanent. They need not—and, as a default proposition, they do not—lead to convergence through diffusion, one-sided or mutual... Wickham gives us an image of, and an explanation for, a great, permanent, irreducible diversity. Hence a few pertinent implications. Wickham's book ends in 800—on the cusp of the "Carolingian" period, and so, in one sense, "too early" for us: in this conference in general, let alone for those of us who study Poland. But this is an illusion. Nothing about the book, its method, analysis, or glimpses into the medieval future, says or implies that that diversity somehow ended in 800; or that regions of Europe situated fully outside of the Mediterranean world—east of Denmark, Wickham's least "Mediterranean," but 3 included, polity—may not be understood in similar terms. The implication—left, I think, as an intriguing question—is that that balance, between similarity and irreducible, permanent difference, was, or at least may have been, a permanent legacy of the world Wickham has reconstructed up to 800—later, and elsewhere. Back to Poland. Because direct presence of, or contact with, the actual Carolingians are implausible, these multiple challenges confront us with two potential resolutions. We can look for impact, or for resemblance. A search for impact entails observation, of traits, or characteristics, that can meaningfully be specified as "Carolingian," or "postCarolingian"; and, their placement in a chronological and spatial succession, from the "Carolingian," or "Frankish," "core," outward to, and "through," royal and ducal courts, ecclesiastical communities, significant individuals, networks, social groups, central places or towns—a process that might be called mediated diffusion. Regarding Poland, that process is sometimes schematically imagined as a domino effect—Franks ➞ Ottonians ➞ Moravians ➞ Czechs ➞ Poles—in which the key piece is the successor empire to the Carolingian: the Eastern Frankish kingdom, Germany, the Empire, the Reich… The most specific—that is, the least poorly documented—area, or vector, of impact through these venues is a specific set of attributes pertinent to the highest office, ducal or royal, including: succession; other dynastic phenomena, such as seniority, marriage, or women; rituals related to the assumption and exercise of office; relationships between rulers and the sacred, and between rulers and the clergy; and the relevant ideology. This particular, most fruitful venue into our subject is best exemplified by the work of Zbigniew Dalewski. A search for resemblance entails the observation of such traits or characteristics, but as a comparative exercise, without explicit emphasis on their imitation, transmission, diffusion or the like… This approach involves a somewhat allusive, or impressionistic, identification of specific bits and pieces of early Poland's high-level order that resonate 4 with what we know from, or about, its "Carolingian" counterpart. Examples include: Poland's "administrative" framework, above all the comites, and the designation, with the word comes ("companion"), of the highest agent of the ruler's power; that agent's base in a "town" or "city" subject to the ruler; the earliest documented landed estates; coinage, specifically the use of the denarius, a small silver penny, and of its higher units for expression of value, the solidus ("shilling") and the mark; and, political etymology: the presumed derivation of the Western Slavic word for king—król in Polish—from the presumed vernacular name Charles—in Polish, Karol. Right here, I would like to consider an entirely different subject: estates, the villae, in the language of Carolingian documents, but, regardless of their name—and, of the time and place in the earlier Middle Ages—meant here bundles of material resources, consisting of people, the environment, and its useable goods, and of nodes, processes, and revenues of exchange, possessed, exploited, and (to a degree) shaped or modified by a small, highly privileged population—the lords, who, to return Wickham, included two generic protagonists: the ruler and the aristocracy. Specifically regarding Poland, we run into yet another complication posed by the evidence: the relative invisibility in the written sources of anything that can be called an "aristocracy" until at the earliest the twelfth century. To be sure, right from even the earliest bits of evidence, we do have glimpses of people other than the ruler in positions of high(est) power—people who were, for example, in a position to affect succession to ducal or royal office. In that sense, we can be sure that some such population existed, but we know very, very little—I would say, nothing, zip—about that population in depth, including the ways in which it supported itself economically; that is, the nature, and the base, of its resources… So, by a kind of gigantic empirical default, in Poland's earliest history, our attention is necessarily, irreducibly, focused on the ruler—in a wide range of roles, including lordship, that is to say: as the sole visible, or apparent, or at least empirically accessible, possessor of estates. 5 This tilt in the evidence may explain why Polish historians have adopted a highly specific model of the political and economic framework of very early medieval Poland. That model hinges—absolutely turns—on material resources, available to the ruler in his capacity of lord, accessed by him directly—without mediation by intermediate lords or other agents—and including, at their core, the mass of the rural population. That population comprised a whole network of estates. The crux of the model concerns the creation, use, and logical purpose of those estates. This is explained by the ruler's extraordinary degree and type of power. In what might be called a primeval act of power, he was the creator of the resources comprising these estates—what we might call the dux auctor. In particular, he created the labor force. He subjected part of the rural population to specialized, high-intensity obligations, resulting in the emergence, in the midst of that population, of workshops—village-based complexes of specialized production— purposefully geared to the ruler's needs. The network of such localities sufficed to furnish the ducal court with the resources it needed, for warfare, and other roles. The basis, or reason, for this construction is a historiographically generated conundrum: namely, just what enabled, around the mid-tenth century, the emergence of an early-medieval polity that was powerful enough, at least over a stretch of several decades, to challenge militarily the Empire, the Rus', or the Czech Kingdom, and that was worthy of attention from Ibrahim Ibn-Ya'qub, Thietmar of Merseburg, or Bruno of Querfurt… The model serves as a logical "answer" to that conundrum. Generated in its broad contours as long ago as 1964, by Karol Modzelewski, it has enjoyed an astonishing longevity, despite an enormous degree of subsequent reconsideration. It is now undergoing a strong revival, back toward its original formulation—ironically, largely on the basis of archaeological evidence. I've always seen two major flaws with the model. First, it posits a political order that is, right on its face, exceedingly unusual—anomalous—and so doubly difficult to place in a meaningfully comparative perspective. In light of Wickham's work, two anomalies 6 strike me as especially pronounced, and conceptually unfixable. First, the logical disregard for the presence, and significance, of an aristocracy—to Wickham, an absolutely essential element of the existence, and effective power, of any earlier medieval polity—one that, almost by definition, rests on the possession and use of estates. The second anomaly is the model's apparently axiomatic denial of exchange (across its range of meanings), as a factor in the formation, work, and structure of those rural estates, or of the bundles of resources comprising them—above all, the intensively specialized components, the rural populations grouped and engaged in nodes of non-agricultural production. To Wickham, a ubiquitous, almost logically necessary, corollary of intensive economic specialization within a rural labor force is the simultaneous existence of exchange—again, let me add, across its range of meanings. Second—at the risk of sounding really dull—the model is extremely difficult to demonstrate with evidence. This is because, at the time to which the model pertains, there is none. Now, evidence of ducal interaction with lucrative resources certainly does arise in the course of the twelfth and early thirteenth centuries. This may seem "late" for our purposes, but there is no reason to think that, at the time when we can actually discern them, such interactions were new. However, because it is "late," historians have always processed this evidence as a marker of a decline—of that primeval, centrally imposed, duke-created order—and not on its own terms. When it is considered on its own terms, the interaction between the Piast ruler and estates in that (later) period is certainly important, and visible, but it reflects patterns that are different from the model I've just presented—patterns that are complicated and eclectic. They do not add up to that, or to any one, simple model. And, they are entirely compatible with various agents, or dynamics, behind the creation, maintenance, and disposal of resources and estates. Such agents certainly included the ruler, but they may have included other actors. The dynamics certainly included impersonal economic 7 phenomena, such as the market, and other types, or aspects, of exchange. So let me propose a lightly alternative model. The Piast duke, as glimpsed through the evidence, performed (simultaneously) several economic roles. I present them here in no specific order or importance, or any kind of developmental sequence; I emphasize simultaneity. One role was creation of a record, by means of a list: of personal names, place-names, and other designations for people and groups; of units of arable and other spaces; of nodes of specialized production and exchange, especially markets and taverns; and of environmental phenomena: animals, fish, forest, park, water, and minerals. Another role was a more detailed reflection upon those itemized components. Here, the lists "balloon" into short narrations, or close descriptions of how a component worked, or was expected to work, as a source of revenue. The third role was permissive, or enabling, or protective, whereby the ruler promised the recipient, and significant others, specified access to resources. The promise could be made in general terms, and apply to the estate in its entirety, or it could be quite detailed, and "balloon" into one of those fuller, more textured economic or demographic reflections. An example of this role is the charter of liberty extended in 1212 by Duke Henry the Bearded, over a market space possessed by the Cistercian women's convent in Trzebnica: "[T]he market of Lubiąż shall be exempt from every Polish exaction," so that "the moneyer shall not levy the pomot from anyone, and shall have no right there, other than to carry out an exchange of coin[age], by selling salt and exchanging pennies during [no more than] three markets," over a specified amount of time. In this case, ducal intervention in the economy consisted in a withdrawal, by the duke and his agents, from the following range of underlying economic phenomena: a social demand for market activity; the use of coin; and the use of salt as a medium of exchange in recoinages. The fourth role was the identification by the duke of some specific area of demand, and some equally specific source for the satisfaction of that demand. The demanded 8 goods included, variously: cattle, meat, wax, tallow, mead, fish, salt, coin, wheels, pottery, wooden vessels, and grain. The sources for procuring such commodities—that is, for satisfying such demand—included: taverns, market spaces, pre-existing horse or cattle herds, butcher stalls, apiaries, bodies of water, mineral deposits, forest, meadow, park, and arable land; and people. The duke associated, in a kind of one-to-one correspondence, one or more components and flows of revenue, goods, or labor, with one or more specific areas of demand, which that component, or those components, was or were meant to satisfy. Finally, the ruler sometimes actively reshaped, modified, or more thoroughly, in a meaningful sense of that word, "created," "organized," or "reorganized," resources. This role is perhaps best illustrated by another example. In a diploma for the Trzebnica nuns issued in 1202 or 1203, Duke Henry recalled: [T]hat my grandfather transferred the market which had once existed in Trzebnica to Cerekwica, for the use[s] of the Wrocław [cathedral]. But because, as a result, the [new convent] is hardly able to have a market nearby for its usual needs..., I have established a market in Trzebnica, without any diminution of the revenue of the market of Cerekwica. But since the populace [plebs] [wishing to attend any one market] is divided by many markets [in]to single [persons], I expect that, because of the very close proximity [of the two markets to one another], the market of Trzebnica will be a source of harm to the market of the canons [of the chapter]. In order to avoid this, and forever to secure for the canons the fullness of their revenues, I have allayed the [canons'] fear of loss, by [a subsidy of] 7 silver marks, accruing from toll, annually. The duke here reported a sequence of his own, and his father's, interventions, anticipating, modifying, and responding to, specific economic phenomena: market spaces; demand, by the possessors of those market spaces, and by the broader, open- 9 ended population, the plebs; and coin, assigned from yet another source of revenue, In order to offset the anticipated complications arising from the above mix. Ducal documents contemporary with these two proliferate with such provisions, falling somewhere within the above typology of ducal intervention, and reflecting a wide range of economic phenomena and processes, with which the ruler interacted and which he affected. And that, to me, is the alternative model. And now, the crunch. Where, uhm, does all this get us in terms of the "Carolingian" or "post-Carolingian" problematic? Apart from some very, very specific elements of rulership, we cannot meaningfully discern influence or impact. So, regarding that approach to our subject, I reluctantly give up… What we can do is observe resemblance: a close comparison of meaningfully comparable phenomena. One such phenomenon is the economy, and the ruler's engagement with it: a resemblance between the Piast ducal "policy" toward the earliest estates in Poland, and the interactions by the Carolingian kings with the varied economic realities, as reflected by Charlemagne's capitulary De Villis. Another meaningfully comparable phenomenon is big systemic transition. The early Polish documents, of which I've noted two in this paper, mark a moment in a long-term process of standardization, and intensification, of peasant status, peasant subjection to the aristocracy, obligations, above all, rent; and, of the range of interactions between the Piast rulers and all of it. Likewise, the decades on either side of 800 were a time when the Frankish peasantry, and the estates that framed rural resources, underwent a series of transitions of the same general kind. By which, I do not mean similar, in process, outcome, or detail, but—in the sense in which I like to use that word—comparable.