Why has the Nordic electricity market worked so well? Elforsk rapport 05:25 Lars Bergman June 2005 Why has the Nordic electricity market worked so well? Elforsk rapport 05:25 Lars Bergman June 2005 Why has the Nordic electricity market worked so well? Elforsk rapport 05:25 ELFORSK Foreword The development of liberalized electricity markets around the world is, partly, an experiment of applied market theory with uncertain outcome. For this new paradigm to benefit customers thru efficient supply of electricity, we need increased and better knowledge on how competitive electricity markets really work and how to solve the problems that might occur. The study documented in this report was carried out by Professor Lars Bergman of Handelshögskolan in Stockholm, who also presented it at a seminar in San Francisco earlier this year. It is a brief summary of the experiences and the functioning of the Nordic electricity market. In essence, Mr. Bergman’s study proves that the Nordic market seems to have worked fairly well during its’ first ten years of operation. The need for further fine-tuning of the market design is still there though and that is also one of the reasons that Elforsk will continue its’ efforts for improving and exploring different issues related to market design in the program carrying that very same name. Another reason to keep studying the Nordic market is that various reforms are continuously proposed on an international and EU-level. In the midst of this, it is our opinion that we must keep building on the fundamentals that have worked well and also disseminate knowledge on this to the rest of Europe and the world. Elforsk is owned by the Swedish electrical utilities. Its’ business idea is to conduct research and development considered appropriate by its’ owners and carry out this R&D jointly and together with other parties. In 2000, Elforsk initiated the Market Designprogram for the purpose of supporting research on the functioning of competitive electricity markets. The program is financed by Swedish utilities, EBL-Kompetanse in Norway as well as the Swedish Energy Agency. More information about the program, finished reports and conference documentation can be found at www.marketdesign.se. Stockholm, June 2005 Peter Fritz Secretary of the Market Design-program Elforsk AB iv ELFORSK Table of contents 1 INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................. 1 2 CONSUMPTION, PRODUCTION AND MARKET STRUCTURE ................................ 2 3 REGULATORY FRAMEWORK AND MARKET DESIGN ........................................... 4 4 PRICES IN 2002-03: SIGNS OF MARKET POWER? ............................................... 6 5 WHY HAS THE NORDIC MARKET WORKED SO WELL? ........................................ 9 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 MARKET DESIGN AND HYDRO POWER ......................................................................... 9 DILUTION OF MARKET POWER .................................................................................. 9 POLITICAL SUPPORT ............................................................................................ 10 COMMITMENT TO PUBLIC SERVICE........................................................................... 10 6 CONCLUDING REMARKS .................................................................................. 11 7 REFERENCES ................................................................................................... 12 v ELFORSK 1 Introduction Between 1991 and 2000 the electricity markets in Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden were opened up for competition in generation and retailing, and the four national markets were integrated into a single Nordic electricity market. To a large extent this development was induced by the first EU electricity market directive1 that came into force in 19972. It also was inspired by the electricity market reform in England & Wales in 1989, as well as by widely held beliefs that increased competition would raise power industry efficiency to the benefit of consumers. But there were also doubts about the blessing of electricity market reform. One fairly common claim was that traditional vertical integration of generation and transmission facilitated a high level of security of supply and gave rise to economies of scope that were likely to exceed the efficiency increases resulting from competition in generation and retailing. Another claim was that the major power companies were large enough to be able to exercise market power and thus prevent much of the potential gains of competition to be realized. By now the general opinion among power industry representatives and electricity market analysts is that the Nordic electricity market has worked well. The “lights have stayed on” in spite of several adverse supply and demand “shocks”, and according to available data power industry productivity has increased. Seemingly as a result of increased competition both wholesale and retail profit margins have been squeezed. However, very high wholesale prices in late 2002 and early 2003 may indicate the exercise of market power. As will be discussed below, however, a careful analysis of the developments in 2002 and 2003 does not support that view. Yet the picture is not entirely rosy. In spite of the positive developments in terms of continuous market clearing and increased power industry productivity the public at large is less enthusiastic about the results of electricity market reform. Thus there are frequent complaints about bills that are difficult to understand and administrative problems in connection with change of retailer. Needless to say an important reason for the limited general popularity of the electricity market reform is that retail electricity taxes have increased to the extent that most households currently pay more for their electricity than they used to do. However, the administrative problems are likely to be temporary, and a political decision to raise electricity taxes is not, after all, a sign of a badly functioning electricity market. In view of this it seems that the Nordic electricity market, particularly the wholesale market and related financial markets, has worked quite well. The purpose of this paper is to explore why this is the case, and to what extent the Nordic experiences are relevant for other countries. In other words, is the Nordic electricity a relevant role model for other countries? 1 2 The first EU electricity market directive and its implementation are discussed in Bergman et.al. (1999). The deadline for transcribing the directive into national legislation was in February 1999. 1 ELFORSK 2 Consumption, production and market structure The total consumption of electricity in the Nordic countries is around 390 TWh per annum, reflecting internationally very high per capita electricity consumption. For a long time electricity consumption grew by more than 5 percent per annum, but after 1990 the rate of growth have been quite low (see Table 1). Thus competition in generation has been introduced during a period when the need for new capacity was low, and the room for entry of new generators thus quite limited. Country Denmark Finland Norway Sweden Total OECD Consumption TWh 35 82 125 151 393 - Annual growth 1990-2001 % 1.1 2.5 1.6 0.7 1.4 - Consumption per capita kWh 6 929 16 264 28 428 17 347 16 997 8 404 Table 2.1 Electricity consumption data for the Nordic countries 20013. Source: The Swedish Energy Administration. Around 50 percent of total power generation in the area is based on hydropower, but the share of hydropower differs significantly between the four countries4. The high share of hydropower, and the fact that electric heating is a major electricity consumption sector, means that variations in climatic conditions may, and frequently do, cause supply or demand “shocks”. Thus, since 1996 the annual variations in potential hydropower production have been quite significant, and there have been spells with extreme loads reflecting unusually cold weather conditions in the entire Nordic area. Another aspect of the supply side of the Nordic electricity market is the number and relative size of the power companies. As can be seen in Table 2 a few major power producers have a dominating position on their respective national markets. At the same time none of them has a share of the Nordic market that exceeds 20 percent. This suggests that the degree of competition to a very large extent depends on the degree of integration of the four national markets, which in turn depends on inter-connector capacities and institutional barriers to trade between the four countries. Company (Country) Vattenfall (Sweden) Fortum (Finland) Statkraft (Norway) Sydkraft (Sweden) Share of national market % 47 29 27 19 Share of Nordic market % 17 14 9 8 Table 2.2 Power producers and market share. Source: The Swedish Energy Administration. 3 International per capita consumption data for a later year are not available. However, in the Nordic countries electricity consumption went down to a total of 380 TWh in 2003. 4 The share of hydropower varies significantly between the four countries, and is close to 100 percent in Norway, around 50 percent in Sweden, around 15 percent in Finland and zero in Denmark. 2 ELFORSK Public ownership is still dominating in the Nordic countries. Thus Vattenfall is owned by the Swedish state and Statkraft by the Norwegian state. Fortum is in the midst of a privatization process, with the Finnish state still being a big minority owner. Sydkraft is owned by the German power company E.ON with the Norwegian state being a big minority owner. 3 ELFORSK 3 Regulatory framework and market design The overall design of an electricity market has three fundamental components: The regulatory framework, the trading arrangements, and the design of transmission tariffs. In this section the Nordic electricity market will be briefly described from these three points of view, beginning with the regulatory framework. In Table 3 the regulatory framework in the Nordic countries is described using the criteria and requirements5 of the first EU electricity market directive. Needless to say the electricity market is regulated in many other ways, but the basic regulations adopted by the EU are crucial for the creation of a competitive electricity market. In particular third party access to the network infrastructure is a key prerequisite for a competitive electricity market. As can be seen in the table the EU directive allowed the individual member states to choose between two or more alternatives. However, the Nordic countries have in general chosen the alternatives that are most likely to foster a competitive electricity market. Thus regulated third party access (rTPA) is likely to foster a competitive electricity market more than a regime with negotiated third party access (nTPA) would do. In the same way an authorization procedure probably stimulates competition in generation more efficiently than a regime with tendering for new generation would do. Table 3. Basic regulatory framework Denmark Finland Norway Sweden EU Directive New generation Unbundling of gene- Third party access Market opening procedure ration, transmission and distribution Authorization Accounting and manrTPA 100% agement separation Authorization Legal separation rTPA 100% Authorization Accounting and manrTPA 100% agement separation Authorization Legal separation rTPA 100% Authorization or Accounting and man- Regulated (rTPA), 30 % Tendering agement separation as Negotiated (nTPA) a minimum or Single Buyer Table 3.1 Basic regulatory framework. The key trading institution in the Nordic electricity market is the Nord Pool power exchange, which is an “energy only” spot market at which hourly “system prices” are determined in single price auctions. As long as transmission capacity is sufficient the system price is equal to the wholesale trading price in all four countries. But whenever lack of transmission capacity prevents cross-border trade the “area prices” differ from the system price. Norway is divided into several “price areas”, while there is only one price area in Finland, Sweden and the two parts of Denmark6, respectively. 5 6 For a detailed discussion of these criteria and requirements see Bergman et.al. (1999). There are two separate electricity supply systems in Denmark, East and West. 4 ELFORSK Nord Pool also operates financial (forwards, futures and options) markets at which generators and major buyer can hedge system price risks. The system operator in each one of the countries operates a real time market in order to continuously balance generation and load at minimum cost. In all the four countries the system operators also manage bottlenecks within the respective country and between the countries by means of a counter-trade system. Transmission tariffs are designed in largely the same way in the four countries. A key feature is that transmission prices are independent of the geographical distance between trading parties. As there are no border tariffs between the Nordic countries, the physical inter-connector capacity constraints are the only remaining barriers to trade across the national borders 5 ELFORSK 4 Prices in 2002-03: Signs of market power? Until the summer of 2002 the Nordic electricity market seemed to be a success (see Bergman (2002)). Since 1996, when the Norwegian and Swedish markets were integrated, security of supply had been maintained7, and wholesale prices had fallen considerably. Both industrial and household customers had benefited from the lower prices, even though Swedish household customers had been faced with higher taxes on electricity. Spot price 05.09.03 20.07.03 03.06.03 17.04.03 01.03.03 13.01.03 27.11.02 11.10.02 25.08.02 09.07.02 23.05.02 06.04.02 18.02.02 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 NOK/MW h 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 02.01.02 Per cent However, between 1997 and 2001 the supply of hydropower was well above normal, particularly in 2000. In 2002 the situation changed, and the second half of that year was an exceptionally dry period, and the inflow to hydro reservoirs was only around 50 percent of average inflow during the last 20 years. As a result the hydro stocks were extremely low at the beginning of the winter season when most precipitation comes in the form of snow and thus does not add to the reservoirs until the spring period. In view of this hydropower producers reduced supply, and spot market prices reached unprecedented levels (see Figure 1). But the high prices “did their job” in the sense that the market continuously cleared8. Hydro stocks Figure 4.1 Spot price and Norwegian hydro stock, 2002-2003. Source: Statistics Norway and Norwegian Water and Energy Authorities. Needless to say continuous market clearing, implying that electricity always can be bought or sold at the prevailing price, is an extremely important feature of a market for electricity. But from a social point of view it is also very important that the market prices reflect the relevant marginal costs. This is the case if external effects are effectively internalised, and if the market is sufficiently competitive. Here we focus on the latter aspect, i.e. whether the observed prices to any significant degree reflect the exercise of market power by major generators. 7 However, the margin between available capacity and peak load has gradually decreased, and concerns for the security of supply have increased. In response to these concerns the system operators in Norway and Sweden have introduced incentives for generators to keep reserve capacity available during peak periods. 8 For a detailed discussion of the market developments in 2002-03 see von der Fehr et.al. (2005). 6 ELFORSK In a system dominated by hydropower exercise of market power is not easy to detect. At any given time a generator has to decide whether to use or continue to store a unit of water in the reservoir. The choice depends on factors such as the expected precipitation before and during the next winter season, the length of the winter season and the expected demand during the period. This means that an outside observer cannot easily judge whether a given reduction of hydropower production reflects exercise of market power or just conservative expectations about climatic conditions during the coming months. One way of getting around this problem is to use a simulation model. In this study a simulation model, PoMo9, of the Nordic electricity supply system has been used. PoMo is a dynamic optimization model that computes weekly equilibrium prices under the assumption the Nordic electricity market is competitive and that generators are risk neutral. In any given week generators are assumed to know the current stock of water in the reservoirs, demand, and the output of electricity from nuclear, fossil and wind power plants. They are also assumed to know the probability distribution for the future weekly inflow of water to the reservoirs, as well as for the future weekly demand and non-hydro generation. The time horizon is three years. Altogether these assumptions imply that PoMo to a large extent depicts the situation faced by the generators making production decisions and selling power on the Nord Pool spot market during a given week. Deviations between computed PoMo prices and observed Nord Pool prices for a given week obviously reflect various shortcomings of the model. But as PoMo assumes that the Nordic electricity market is perfectly competitive, the deviations also reflect the impact of market power. In Figure 2 the actual spot market prices (weekly averages) and the corresponding PoMo prices in the second half of 2002 and the first half of 2003 are compared. The “12 TWh” case is a PoMo simulation in which the minimum amount of stored water is allowed to be 12 TWh rather the standard requirement 15 TWh. As the minimum requirement was in fact reduced to 12 TWh the beginning of 2003 this case is the most realistic of the two PoMo cases in the figure. A comparison of the “Nord Pool” and “12 TWh” price paths suggest that real world producers react earlier than the risk neutral PoMo producers. Thus Nord Pool prices increased earlier and exceeded the PoMo prices at the end of 2002, but from the beginning of 2003 the situation was reversed. A possible explanation to this deviation is that real world generators are risk-averse and thus overly fast to reduce hydropower production when the risk of running out of water before the spring period is perceived to be high. 9 PoMo is developed by EME Analys and Tentum, and frequently used by the Swedish National Energy administration. 7 ELFORSK PoMo - NordPool 1200 SEK/MWh 1000 PoMo NordPool 12 TWh min 800 600 400 200 16 13 10 7 4 1 50 47 44 41 38 35 0 Week Figure 4.2. Comparison of actual and simulated prices 2002-2003. However, if the major power companies had been exercising market power, the Nord Pool prices would have exceeded the PoMo prices during the entire period. Thus the simulation results suggest that the Nordic electricity market is quite competitive, with market clearing prices close to the relevant marginal costs. The high prices 2002-03 simply reflected an unusual scarcity of hydropower combined with the usual low elasticity of demand. 8 ELFORSK 5 Why has the Nordic market worked so well? Most consumers expect the electricity market to work well and they pay no attention to the reasons why that is the case. In a somewhat wider context, however, that issue is important. If the relative success of the Nordic market is due to a good design of regulations and market institutions, then the Nordic experiences are useful for other countries. But if the favourable outcome primarily depends on country-specific factors or temporary circumstances, there is not much for other countries to learn. On the basis of my own and other studies of the topic my conclusion is that there are four main factors behind the relatively successful electricity market reform in the Nordic countries, namely: • A simple but sound market design, to a large extent made possible by the large share of hydropower. • Successful dilution of market power, attained by the integration of the four national markets into a single Nordic market. • Strong political support for a market-based electricity supply system. • Voluntary, informal commitment to public service by the power industry. The second and third of these factors are “transferable”, while the first and fourth to a large extent are country-specific. In the following each one of the four factors will be briefly discussed. 5.1 Market design and hydro power Electricity supply systems dominated by hydropower tend to be energy-constrained rather than capacity-constrained. Thus the need for incentives to maintain sufficient peak capacity is much smaller than in systems based on fossil fuelled power plants. Moreover, contrary to fossil fuelled power plants hydropower plants have negligible start-up costs. Thus the cost of production during a particular hour does not depend on the rate of production during adjacent hours. Altogether this means that hourly trading on a power exchange, such as the Nord Pool spot market, to a very large extent provides the right incentives for efficient allocation of resources in the power industry. The designers of the Nordic “model” obviously have benefited from the fact that around 50 percent of Nordic power production is based on hydropower. But they were not just lucky. They also actively contributed to an efficient market design by not imposing price regulations or other regulations that would have increased the transaction costs or financial risks carried by generators, industrial customers and retailers. 5.2 Dilution of market power Like in most other European countries the national electricity markets in the Nordic area were all dominated by a publicly owned “national champion”. This was particularly the case in Sweden where the market share of the state owned company Vattenfall was more than 50 percent. Given the new regulatory framework the major companies would be able to exercise considerable market power on their respective home market and thus jeopardize the competitive electricity markets that the reforms were intended to create. The strategy adopted to solve this problem was market integration. Again thanks to the large share of hydropower, in conjunction with the uneven distribution of hydropower 9 ELFORSK resources between the four countries, inter-connector capacities were quite large. Thus the barriers to cross-border trade were institutional rather than physical. By abolishing border tariffs and adopting a system with distance-independent transmission prices the relevant market was significantly enlarged and the market power of the major generators diluted. However, from time to time the physical inter-connector constraints are binding so that the Nordic market becomes two or several regional markets with different prices. With the exception of 2000, when inter-connectors from Norway were congested most of the time, there has been complete price equalisation between 30 and 60 percent of the time and only small price differences during most of the remaining time. The Swedish electricity market has been fully integrated either with the Finnish or the Norwegian market essentially all the time. Thus from a competition point of view the Nordic electricity market is close to a single market in which the combined market share of the four major producers is less than 50 percent (see Table 2). 5.3 Political support Even though electricity market reform came about as a result of political decisions continued political support by no means is guaranteed, particularly if employment in the power industry is reduced as a result of increased competition or supply and demand shocks lead to high electricity prices. In the Nordic countries the development of prices in 2002-03 was a major test of the degree of political support for the market based electricity supply system. Although there were strong demands for political intervention, particularly in Norway, no intervention took place. Thus, instead of blaming the power companies leading politicians stated that electricity prices were high because hydropower was unusually scarce, and that no regulation could change that situation to the better. Apart from the fact that no regulations, temporary or permanent, were imposed the no-intervention policy probably also had long-term effects. Due to annual variations in hydropower supply wholesale electricity prices inevitably will vary between different years. By confirming that prices will be allowed to be high in “dry” years the politicians in effect increased the expected rate of return on investments in new generation capacity. 5.4 Commitment to public service Although the power companies in the Nordic countries have been exposed to competition for quite some time a strong commitment to public service seems to remain. Alternatively there may be expectations that collusion and exploitation of market power will induce new regulations or even a return to the “old” system. In any case an analysis of the development of electricity prices give no indication that there is collusion between generators, or that major power companies exploit the market power that they in fact have. Thus actual wholesale electricity prices have constantly been lower than the prices obtained in simulations with numerical oligopoly models in which Cournot competition is assumed (see Bergman (2002)). 10 ELFORSK 6 Concluding remarks There are two major threats to the success of electricity market reform in the Nordic countries. The first is that security of supply can not be maintained. The second is that market power prevents the potential benefits of competition to be realized. So far security of supply has been maintained, although exceptional storms have created serious problems in electricity distribution. The major power companies have been accused of exercising market power, but convincing proofs are lacking. At the same time power industry productivity has increased, and retail electricity prices (before tax) have become strongly linked to wholesale electricity prices. The situation may change in the future. Thus it remains to be seen that investments in new capacity are carried out when they are needed, and that mergers and capacity expansion do not significantly increase concentration and market power. But the development of the Nordic electricity market so far to a large extent is quite successful. Does this mean that the “Nordic model” should be adopted all over the world? The answer is “no”. In many ways the success of the Nordic model depends on area specific factors such as ample supply of hydropower and significant inter-connector capacities. Yet there are some “universal” lessons that can be learned from the Nordic experiences. In particular the Nordic experiences suggest that a “deregulated” market for electricity works well if: • There are no price regulations and constraints on the development of financial markets • There is continued political support for a market based electricity supply system also when electricity is scarce and prices are high. 11 ELFORSK 7 References Bergman, L., G. Bruunekreft, C. Doyle, N-H M. von der Fehr, D.M. Newbery, M. Pollitt and P.Regibeau (1999) “A European Market for Electricity”. Monitoring European Deregulation 2. London: CEPR and SNS. Bergman, L. (2002), “The Nordic electricity market – continued success or emerging problems?” The Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 9, 11-38. Von der Fehhr, N-H M., E.S. Amundsen and L. Bergman (2005), ”The Nordic Market: Signs of Stress?”, The Energy Journal, Special Issue on European Energy Liberalisation. 12 SVENSKA ELFÖRETAGENS FORSKNINGS- OCH UTVECKLINGS – ELFORSK – AB Elforsk AB, 101 53 Stockholm. Besöksadress: Olof Palmes Gata 31 Telefon: 08-677 25 30. Telefax 08-677 25 35 www.elforsk.se