Exercises Lecture 5: Economies of Scale, Trade and Imperfect Competition (From Textbook, Chapter 7 ) 1. Evaluate the relative importance of economies of scale and comparative advantage in causing the following: (a) Most of the world’s aluminum is smelted in Norway or Canada. (b) Half of the world’s large jet aircraft are assembled in Seattle. (c) Most semiconductors are manufactured in either the United States or Japan. (d) Most Scotch whiskey comes from Scotland. (e) Much of the world’s best wine comes from France. 2. Consider a situation similar to that in Figure 7-3 in the textbook (or slide number 30 in the lecture of October 9th), where two countries that produce a good (buttons) are subject to forward-falling supply curves. In this case assume that the two countries have the same costs, so their supply curves are identical. (a) Describe the pattern of international specialization and trade. What would determine who produces the good? (b) Describe the benefits of international trade in this case. Do they accrue only to the country that gets the industry? 1 SOLUTIONS 1. (a) The fact that there are relatively few locations for this kind of production suggests that it is characterized by the presence of external economies of scale. If these operations are large, there may also be large internal economies of scale in production. (b) Since economies of scale are significant in airplane production, it tends to be done by a small number of (imperfectly competitive) firms in a limited number of locations. One of these location is exactly Seattle, where Boeing produces. (c) The same reasoning as answer (b) applies: external economies of scale are significant in semiconductor production, thus semiconductor industries tend to be concentrated in certain geographic locations. Moreover, if, for some historical reason, a semiconductor is established in a specific location, the export of semiconductors by that country is due to economies of scale and not comparative advantage. (d) Scotch whiskey can only come from Scotland because the production requires a particular technique known to skilled distillers who are concentrated in the region. In addition, soil and climactic conditions are favorable for grains used in local scotch production. These arguments reflect comparative advantage rather than the presence of external economies. (e) Similarly to the previous answer, France has a particular blend of climatic conditions and land that is difficult to reproduce elsewhere. This generates its comparative advantage in wine production. 2. To make things simpler, we can assume that the two countries are identical, so they have completely identical curves. (a) If one country starts out as a producer of a good because, say, it has a head start as a consequence of an historical accident, then all production will occur in that country and it will export to the rest of the world. (b) Consumers in both countries will pay a lower price for the good when all production is located in a single country so as to maximize external economies. The second part of the answer is driven by the same (standard) argument explained during the lecture: increased production as a result of trade leads to a price of the good that is lower than the price before trade in either country. The benefits of international trade will therefore not be limited to the country that gets the industry because the consumers in both countries can profit from such lower price. 2 Numerical Example (from KOM, Chapter 8) & Exercise Recall the following equations: – Demand that each firm faces (I eliminate the i for notational purposes): Q=S h1 n i − b(p − p̄) (1) – AC Curve: AC = F nF +c= +c Q S as Q = S/n (2) – PP Curve: P =c+ 1 bn (3) By assuming that b = 1/30, F = 750 and c = 5, we have to find the equilibrium of the model. From eq. (1), we obtain: Q=S h1 n − i 1 (p − p̄) 30 and from eq. (2): AC = 750 750 n +5= = 750 Q (S/n) S as Q = S/n, while from eq. (3): P =5+ 30 n The solution can be computed both algebraically and graphically. Algebraically, from P = AC (the intersection of CC and P P ), obtain: AC = 750 n 30 +5=5+ =P S n Hence: 3 750 n 30 + 5 = 5 + =P S n ⇒ ⇒ 750 r 30 S n = 750 2 ⇒ n= n 30 = S n 30 S 750 which is the expression that gives us the number of firms. Assume now that there are 2 countries, H and F , which are identical in everything, except for the size S of their markets. Sizes are given, respectively, by: SH = 900 and SF = 1600. This implies that, for H: n2H = 30 900 = 36 750 ⇒ nH = 6 and PH = ACH = 5 + 30 = 10 6 while for F : n2F = 30 1600 = 64 750 ⇒ nF = 8 and PF = ACF = 5 + 30 = 8.75 8 Graphically, the mkt equilibrium in the absence of trade is shown in Fig. 1 4 CHAPTER 8 Firms in the Global Economy Price per auto, in thousands of dollars 36 34 32 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 1 2 3 4 5 Price per auto, in thousands of dollars 36 34 32 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 1 2 3 4 5 CC PP 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Number of firms, n (a) Home 5 Equilibrium in the Automobile Market PP 6 CC PP 8 (c) Integrated Figure 8-5 CC 7 8 (b) Foreign Price per auto, Figure 1 in thousands of dollars 36 34 32 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 9 167 10 11 12 Number of firms, n 9 10 11 12 Number of firms, n Suppose now that the two countries decide to integrate and to create a free-trade zone. We want to determine how the previous equilibrium modifies and how it would be under this hypothesis. If there is an integrated market, then total market size S is given by: S = SH + SF = 900 + 1600 = 2500 , thus the new equilibrium will be simply given by: n2 = 30 2500 = 100 750 ⇒ n = 10 and P = AC = 5 + which graphically is shown in Fig. 2. 6 30 =8 10 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 CC PP 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Number of firms, n 1 2 3 4 5 (a) Home 7 8 9 1 (b) Foreign Price per auto, in thousands of dollars 36 34 32 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 1 2 3 4 5 8-5 6 CC PP 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Number of firms, n (c) Integrated Figure 2 um in the Automobile Market Home market: With a market size of 900,000 automobiles, Home’s equilibrium, determined by t ion of the PP and CC curves, occurs with six firms and an industry price of $10,000 per auto. (b market: With a market size of 1.6 million automobiles, Foreign’s equilibrium occurs with eight fi try price of $8,750 per auto. (c) The combined market: Integrating the two markets creates a ma on autos. This market supports ten firms, and the price of an auto is only $8,000. 7 Exercise Suppose the two countries previously considered were to integrate their market with a third country Z which has a market size SZ given by SZ = 3125. Find the number of firms, the output per firm and the price in the new integrated market after trade. Solution To find the new equilibrium, it suffice to calculate the market size of the integrated market. In this case, we have: S = SH + SF + SZ = 900 + 1600 + 3125 = 5625 , thus the number of firms is given by: n2 = 30 5625 = 225 750 ⇒ n = 15 Using the price equation and the fact that b = 1/30, c = 5, you can easily find that P = 1 30 +c= +5=7 bn 15 Finally, output per firm can be computed using Q = S/n: Q= 5625 S = = 375. n 15 8 Graphing Problem C, P 6 A A A A A 10 @ @ @ @ @ @ A A A A @ @ @ A A A 8 @ @ @ A A A @ @ @ A A A MC @ @ @ A A A 5 @ @ @ @ @ A A A @ @ A A A @ @ @ @ @ @ A A A A A A A A A A A MR A A D ∗ = M R∗ @ @ @ @ @ @ @D @ @ - 4 5 10 Q Figure 3 1. Consider Fig. 3, which represents the demand and cost functions of a monopolist firm. If it was unable to export and constrained by its domestic market, what quantity would it sell at what price? 9 2. Assume that the monopolist discovers that it can export as much as it likes of its product at the world price P ∗ = 5. How much product will the monopolist produce/sell? At what price? 3. Given the opportunity to sell at world prices, what is the marginal (opportunity) cost of selling one unit of product domestically? 4. While selling exports it would also maximize its domestic sales. Hence, how much product would the firm sell domestically? At what price? Answers 1. Given the intersection of the MC with the MR, the monopolist will sell 5 units of product at the price P = 8. 2. In this case you have to consider that the optimal strategy for the firm is to equate MC and MR on both markets, that is: M R∗ = P ∗ = M C , where ∗ stands for international/foreign. From this condition, you easily obtain that total production is Q = 10, which is sold at the world price P ∗ = 5. 3. The marginal (opportunity) cost is 5. 4. To determine production at Home of the monopolist, you just have to apply the condition M R∗ = M R. From this, it follows that production at Home is Q = 4, which is sold at the price P = 10. 10