Can nontradables generate substantial home bias? Technical Appendix Paolo Pesenti and Eric van Wincoop Federal Reserve Bank of New York November 1999 1 A model of international portfolio choice with nontradables: extensions In this Appendix we focus on the technical aspects of the model presented in the main text. Domestic residents receive an endowment stream of nontradables S(t), whose stochastic rate of growth is given by dS(t) = ¹dt + ¾X d»(t) S(t) (A.1) where ¹ and ¾X are constant parameters and » is a standard Wiener process. The instantaneously stochastic returns on domestic and foreign assets are: dR(t) = ´dt + ¾R d!(t) dR¤ (t) = ´dt + ¾R¤ d! ¤(t) (A.2) (A.3) Here R is the cumulative return on the domestic asset, R¤ the cumulative return on the foreign asset, and ´ the expected return per unit time, assumed to be equal across countries and constant over time. The instantaneous correlation between the returns is denoted ½ ´ [E (d!d!¤)] =dt. The correlations between the growth rate of nontradables consumption and the two asset returns are denoted ½RX ´ [E (d!d»)] =dt and ½R¤ X ´ [E (d!¤d»)] =dt. The stochastic process for domestic ¯nancial wealth W (measured in terms of traded goods) is dW (t) = [n (t) dR (t) + (1 ¡ n (t)) dR¤ (t)] W (t) +p (t) S (t) dt ¡ C (t) dt ¡ p (t) X (t) dt (A.4) where C(t) is domestic consumption of tradables, X (t) consumption of nontradables, n(t) is the fraction of wealth invested at home and p (t) is the relative price of nontradables. The value function V [W (t); X(t)] is de¯ned as: V [W (t); X(t)] ´ max Et C(t);n(t) Z 1 t e¡±(s¡t)U[C (s); X(s)]ds where ± is the rate of time preference. In equilibrium we have: S (t) = X (t) ; dS (t) dX (t) = S (t) X (t) 1 (A.5) and the relative price of nontradables p(t) is determined as the ratio of the marginal utilities UX =UC . Optimal consumption/portfolio choice C(t) and n(t) solves the Bellman equation: ±V [W (t); X(t)] = max U [C (t) ; X (t)] + (Et dV [W (t) ; X (t)]) =dt (A.6) C(t);n(t) subject to (A.1)-(A.4) and the appropriate boundary conditions. Applying Ito's Lemma to the value function, we obtain 1 1 dV = VX dX + VW dW + VXX dX 2 + VWW dW 2 + VXW dXdW: 2 2 (A.7) Substituting dX and dW with their expressions (A.1) and (A.4), after taking the conditional expectation of (A.7) we can rewrite (A.6) as follows: 1 ±V [W; X] = max U[C; X] + VX X¹ + VW (W ´ ¡ C) + V XXX 2¾2X C;n 2 h i 1 2 2 2 2 2 + V WW W n ¾R + (1 ¡ n) ¾R¤ + 2n (1 ¡ n) ½¾R¾R¤ 2 +V WX WX ¾X [n½RX ¾R + (1 ¡ n) ½R¤ X ¾R¤ ] Optimal portfolio shares are obtained by taking the ¯rst-order condition for a maximum with respect to n. Di®erentiating the previous expression yields: h 0 = VWW W n¾R2 ¡ (1 ¡ n) ¾R2 ¤ + (1 ¡ 2n) ½¾R¾R¤ +VWX X¾X [½RX¾R ¡ ½R¤X ¾R¤ ] i (A.8) from which we derive the expressions for n and bias in the main text. The model can be generalized in several respects. Consider ¯rst the case in which expected returns are not constant over time, but rather exhibit mean reversion around a constant steady-state mean. Speci¯cally, replace (A.2) and (A.3) with dR(t) = ´ (t) dt + ¾Rd!(t) dR¤(t) = ´ ¤ (t) dt + ¾R¤ d!¤ (t) where d´ (t) = ¡k (´ (t) ¡ ¹́) dt + Ád!(t) d´¤ (t) = ¡k (´¤ (t) ¡ ¹́) dt + Á¤d!¤ (t) 2 (A.9) (A.10) are two Ornstein-Uhlenbeck processes, with ¹́, Á and Á¤ constant positive parameters. Intuitively, a shock d! pushes upward the current return and the future expected return on domestic assets. If the expected return ´ is currently above its long-run average ¹́, it is expected to decline; if ´ < ¹́ instead, ´ is expected to raise. In the long run, the distribution for the expected return ´ is stationary, and ´ is normally distributed with asymptotic mean ¹́ and asymptotic variance Á 2=2k. Similar considerations hold for ¹́¤. Under these new assumptions, the value function includes now ´ and ´¤ as arguments, and the modi¯ed Bellman equation is now: ±V [W; X; ´; ´¤] = max U[C; X] + VX X¹ + VW [W [n´ + (1 ¡ n) ´¤] ¡ C] C;n 1 ¡V´ k (´ ¡ ¹́) ¡ V´¤ k (´¤ ¡ ¹́) + VXX X 2 ¾2X 2 h i 1 + VWW W 2 n2 ¾R2 + (1 ¡ n)2 ¾R2 ¤ + 2n (1 ¡ n) ½¾R¾R¤ 2 1 1 + V´´Á 2 + V´¤ ´¤ (Á¤ )2 + VW XW X ¾X [n½RX ¾R + (1 ¡ n) ½R¤ X ¾R¤ ] 2 2 +VW´ WÁ [n¾R + (1 ¡ n) ½¾R¤ ] + VW ´¤ W Á¤ [n½¾R + (1 ¡ n) ¾R¤ ] +VX´X ¾XÁ½RX + VX´¤ X¾X Á¤½R¤ X + V´´¤ ÁÁ¤½ The ¯rst order condition with respect to n now yields h 0 = VW (´ ¡ ´ ¤) + VW W W n¾2R ¡ (1 ¡ n) ¾2R¤ + (1 ¡ 2n) ½¾R¾R¤ i +VWX X¾X [½RX¾R ¡ ½R¤X ¾R¤ ] + VW´ Á [¾R ¡ ½¾R¤ ] + VW´¤ Á¤ [½¾R ¡ ¾R¤ ] so that the portfolio share invested in domestic assets is equal to n = ¾2R¤ ¡ ½¾R¾R¤ VW ´ ¡ ´¤ ¡ ¾R2 ¤ + ¾R2 ¡ 2½¾R ¾R¤ VW W W ¾R2 ¤ + ¾2R ¡ 2½¾R¾R¤ V Á [¾R ¡ ½¾R¤ ] VW´¤ Á ¤ [½¾R ¡ ¾R¤ ] ¡ W´ ¡ + bias, V WW W ¾2R¤ + ¾2R ¡ 2½¾R¾R¤ VWW W ¾R2 ¤ + ¾R2 ¡ 2½¾R¾R¤ where bias is the same formula given in the main text. Interpreting the formula above, the share of wealth invested in domestic assets is equal to the minimum-variance portfolio share (¯rst term), corrected to account for discrepancies in expected returns (second term), to hedge 3 against uncertainty in the expected returns themselves (third and fourth term), and to hedge against nontradables uncertainty (the bias term). Only the last term is associated with hedging against nontradables. The ¯rst four terms are present even in the absence of nontradables. The key point is that a higher expected return of one country's assets leads investors of all countries to shift their portfolio toward that country's assets, and therefore leads neither to a systematic di®erence in portfolio shares across investors in di®erent countries, nor to a systematic tendency to skew investors' portfolios toward the assets issued in their countries of residence. Such systematic tendency is still captured by the term bias, which measures the impact of country-speci¯c variables on wealth allocation, although theoretically the presence of nontradables may also have a small secondary impact on the composition of investors' portfolios through their e®ects on the preference terms VW´ =VWW W and V W´¤ =VWW W . Similar considerations apply in the case of stochastic volatility. Assuming for simplicity of exposition that only domestic asset returns are heteroskedastic, the processes for asset returns are now dR(t) = ´dt + ¾R (t) d!(t) dR¤(t) = ´dt + ¾R¤ d!¤(t) (A.11) (A.12) where the law of motion for ¾R (t) is given by: q d¾R (t) = ¡k [¾R (t) ¡ ¾¹R] dt + Á ¾R (t)dz(t); In other words, ¾R follows an autoregressive process similar to the one considered above for expected returns: the conditional volatility of domestic returns is subject to shocks dz and is time-varying around a steady-state average ¾¹R . Deviations from the steady-state average decay at the rate k. Assuming that at some initial time t = 0 it is ¾R(0) > 0, the square root term in the previous equation guarantees that ¾R is always positive at any time t. We denote the correlations involving ¾R as ½¾R ´ [E (d!dz)] =dt, ½ ¾R¤ ´ [E (d! ¤dz)] =dt and ½¾X ´ [E (dzd»)] =dt. The modi¯ed Bellman equation is now: ±V [W; X; ¾R ] = max U [C; X ] + VX X¹ + VW [W ´ ¡ C] C;n 1 2 ¡V¾R k (¾R ¡ ¾¹R) + VXX X 2¾X 2 4 h i 1 + VWW W 2 n2 ¾2R + (1 ¡ n)2 ¾2R¤ + 2n (1 ¡ n) ½¾R¾R¤ 2 1 + V¾R ¾R Á2¾R + V WX WX ¾X [n½RX ¾R + (1 ¡ n) ½R¤ X ¾R¤ ] 2 p +VW¾R W Á ¾R [n¾R½¾R + (1 ¡ n) ¾R¤ ½¾R¤ ] p +VX¾R X¾X ½¾X Á ¾R and taking the ¯rst-order condition, the portfolio share invested in domestic assets is equal to p ¾R2 ¤ ¡ ½¾R¾R¤ VW¾R Á ¾R [¾R½¾R ¡ ¾R¤ ½¾R¤ ] n= 2 ¡ + bias. ¾R¤ + ¾2R ¡ 2½¾R¾R¤ VWW W ¾R2 ¤ + ¾2R ¡ 2½¾R¾R¤ As in the case with time-varying asset returns, we now have an additional hedging component related to stochastic volatility. The ¯rst two terms are present even in the absence of nontradables. All investors, no matter where they are located, prefer to invest in assets whose return rises when volatility increases. The term bias, on the other hand, captures systematic discrepancies in national portfolios as the result of optimal hedging behavior. We do want to be somewhat cautionary though by again pointing out that nontradables may have a small secondary impact on portfolios through their e®ect on the preference term V W¾R =VWW W . 2 The sign of ¿ 0 without balanced growth In the context of a deterministic framework we want to show that the sign of ¿ 0 is opposite to that of the growth rate of the fraction spent on nontradables. Without uncertainty, the di®erential equation for ¿, described in Appendix A, becomes: (1 ¡ ¿ 0z 1+m )(¿ ¡ ´ + ¹) = ²(± + °¹ ¡ ´) ¿ 1 + °²m (B.1) It follows that dX dC d¿ dW ¿ 0z ¡ = ¹¡ ¡ =¹¡ (¹ ¡ ´ + ¿) ¡ ´ + ¿ = Xdt Cdt ¿ dt W dt ¿ ¿ 0z 1+m = (1 ¡ )(¹ ¡ ´ + ¿) = ²(± + °¹ ¡ ´) (B.2) ¿ 1 + °²m 5 Therefore, dC=C > dX=X if and only if ´ > ± + °¹. Assume that the latter condition holds. Since m = (1 ¡ ®) ®¡1(C=X)1¡1=² = C=pX, it follows that the fraction spent on nontradables 1= (1 + m) rises (falls) over time if ² < 1 (² > 1). Moreover, since dC 1+m = ¹¡ ²(± + °¹ ¡ ´); Cdt 1 + °²m (B.3) it follows that @ (dC=Cdt) =@m > 0 when the two consumption goods are complementary in preferences (²° < 1). Therefore, @ (dC=C dt) @ (dC=Cdt) @m = = @ (C=X) @m @ (C=X) µ 1¡® =¡ ® ¶ µ (1 ¡ °²) (± + °¹ ¡ ´) (² ¡ 1) C X (1 + °²m)2 ¶ ¡ 1² (B.4) is negative (positive) when ² < 1 (² > 1). It is now easy to check that the sign of ¿ 0 is the opposite of that of the growth rate of the fraction spent on nontradables. We show this for ² < 1; so that the growth rate of tradables consumption is a negative function of the ratio C=X. Consider the impact of an unanticipated permanent increase in X occurring at time 0. Conjecture ¯rst that ¿ 0 = 0. In this case, tradables consumption at time 0 does not react to the change in X. However, the fall in the C=X ratio instantaneously translates into a higher growth rate of tradables consumption. Although the growth rate of tradables consumption decelerates in the future, the level of tradables consumption is always higher than before the shock to X: In fact, suppose that at some future time ~t the after-shock path of C crosses the before-shock path. Necessarily, at this future date C=X is lower than it would have been before the shock. But this implies that at ~t the growth rate of tradables consumption must be higher than the growth rate before the shock, so that the two consumption paths can never intersect. As a result, tradables consumption is always higher after the shock to X: Since ¯nancial wealth is not a®ected by the shock, the budget constraint is violated. Suppose now that ¿ 0 > 0: At time 0, tradables consumption jumps upward in response to the rise in X: The logic is the same as above: if there 6 existed a time t~ at which the old and new path of C met, at that time the consumption ratio C=X would be lower than before the shock, and dC=C would be paradoxically higher. As C is permanently above the old path, once again the budget constraint is violated. Only the case ¿ 0 < 0 does not entail logical inconsistencies or violations of the transversality condition. One can use similar arguments for ² > 1 and for ´ < ± + °¹, to show that the sign of ¿ 0 is always the opposite of that of the growth rate of the fraction spent on nontradables. 3 Small levels of risk We want to show that under balanced growth, a marginal increase in the standard deviation of X from zero has a negligible e®ect on ¿ and ¿ 0 as they depend on the variance of X rather than the standard deviation. Proposition. Let ¹ = ° ¡1(´¡±) and ±¡(1¡°)¹ > 0. Holding ½, ½RX, ½R¤ X , ¾X =¾R, and ¾X =¾R¤ constant, @¿ =@¾2X and @¿ 0 =@¾2X, both evaluated at 2 ¾X = 0, are ¯nite functions of X and W . ^ ´ §=¾x2, Proof. Recalling the de¯nition of § and ¾ in Appendix A, de¯ne § ^ and ^ ¾^ ´ ¾=¾2x; and hold § ¾ constant with respect to changes in ¾X . After substitution of n from equation (A.8) back into the Bellman equation, the latter becomes: 2 ±V = U(C; X ) + VW W ´ ¡ VW C + VX X¹ + A(W; X; ¾X )¾2X where ^ ¡1i 1 1 VWW W 2 V WX WX ^ ¾0 § + + VXX X 2 0 ^ ¡1 0 ^ ¡1 2 i§ i 2 i§ i ³ ´2 0 ¡1 ^ i ¾^ § 1 V 2 X 2 0 ^ ¡1 ¡ WX [^ ¾§ ^ ¾ ¡ 0 ¡1 ]: ^ i 2 VW W i§ A(W; X; ¾2X ) ´ Now take the right hand side di®erential of the Bellman equation with 2 2 respect to ¾X ; evaluated at ¾X = 0. Using (i) the envelope condition UC = VW , (ii) the homogeneous function property VW W + VXX = 7 (1 ¡ °)V , (iii) the balanced growth condition ¹ = 1° (´ ¡ ±); and (iv) the fact that without uncertainty ¿ = 1° ± + (1 ¡ 1° )´ = ´ ¡ ¹ , we get: V¾X2 = a 0A(W; X) where a0 = (± ¡ (1 ¡ °)¹)¡1 and A(W; X) is shorthand for A(W; X; 0). Di®erentiating the equation above with respect to W, and using the envelope condition VW = UC , we get: aAW = VW¾X2 = UCC which implies @¿ W @¾2X @¿ aAW : 2 = @ ¾X UCC W Similarly, di®erentiating with respect to both X and W yields aAWX = VWX¾2X = @ @UC = 2 @X @¾X @ @¿ 0 @¿ 0 (U ¿ + U ) = U CC CX CC 2 2 + U CCX W 2 @¾X @¾X @ ¾X which implies @¿ 0 aAWX aAW UCCX = ¡ 2 2 @¾X UCC UCC 2 This proves that both @¿ =@¾X and @¿ 0 =@¾2X; evaluated at ¾2X = 0; are ¯nite functions of X and W . 8