Why Can Financial Firms Charge for Diversifiable Risk? Ian Moran, Andrew Smith, David Walczak 10 April 2003 Presentation Overview • • Determinants of Insurance Premiums • in 5 logical steps Pricing and accounting • why recognition criteria are different • • profit and loss on inception Conclusions © Deloitte & Touche. Premium Factors 110 premium 105 Impairment Profit Margin Tax + Agency Systematic Risk Free 100 95 90 10% diversifiable 10% systematic 20% diversifiable © Deloitte & Touche. liability risk 20% systematic Step 1: Pure Modigliani and Miller • Fair premium = PV of liabilities • discount rate reflects liability risk • • systematic (non-diversifiable) risk only The following are irrelevant: • expected return on investments • insurer cost of equity or debt • capital allocated © Deloitte & Touche. Step 2: Myers – Cohn and Extensions • Additional frictional costs • cost of investing • tax on profits • • agency costs Capital allocation now matters • premium include loading for cost of allocated capital © Deloitte & Touche. Step 3: Franchise Allocation Franchise value 200 100 110 market capitalisation market capitalisation target total return 12% 20 dividend 206 target franchise growth 3% equity implied 30% target ROE This year actual © Deloitte & Touche. Next year target franchise value at risk shareholder value Step 4: Cost of Impairment statutory net assets at year end default option © Deloitte & Touche. Step 5: Capital Optimisation based on Hancock, Huber & Koch, 2001 20 default option franchise 18 capital costs too high 16 optimal capitalisation 14 franchise value at risk 12 10 0 © Deloitte & Touche. 10 20 30 equity 40 50 Premium Factors: Reminder 110 premium 105 Impairment Profit Margin Tax + Agency Systematic Risk Free 100 95 90 10% diversifiable 10% systematic 20% diversifiable © Deloitte & Touche. liability risk 20% systematic Conclusions • • • • • Frictional costs drive a wedge between the prices we see in capital markets and prices of insurance cover. Therefore, any search for a universal pricing framework that replicates both markets is a fruitless endeavour Accounting practice necessarily decomposes the value of a firm into equity, e, recognised by accounting standards, and an additional franchise value f representing intangible elements outside the scope of accounting standards. It is common pricing practice to add a “margin for profit”. We rationalise this as the shareholders’ required return on the franchise value f. Rational product pricing takes account of the impact of a new contract both on the equity and the franchise value of a business. Accounting, by definition, reflects only the change in equity. © Deloitte & Touche. Conclusions (ctd) • • • • Any part of the premium corresponding to the change in franchise value will emerge as a profit or loss on inception. In the past, various devices were used to smooth out the profit on inception. These included the invention of fictional assets (deferred acquisition costs) and fictional liabilities (market value margins). These devices corrupt the accounting definitions of assets and liabilities, and therefore represent a cure (inconsistent recognition) that is worse than the disease (income volatility). This is not to deny the importance of risk loadings in setting premiums, which should allow for effects both on accounting equity and nonaccounting effects on franchise value. © Deloitte & Touche. Why Can Financial Firms Charge for Diversifiable Risk? Ian Moran, Andrew Smith, David Walczak 10 April 2003