Fisher’s Theory of Debt Deflation Irving Fisher, Multi-millionaire “ Stock prices have reached what looks like a permanently high plateau. I do not feel that there will soon, if ever, be a fifty or sixty point break below present levels, such as Mr. Babson has predicted. I expect to see the stock market a good deal higher than it is today within a few months.” (Irving Fisher, New York Times, October 15 1929) Fisher’s pre-Great Depression Model Fisher’s pre‐Great Depression model treated finance as just like any other market, with supply and demand setting an equilibrium price. However, in building his models, he made two assumptions to handle the fact that, unlike the market for say, apples, transactions in finance markets involved receiving something now (a loan) in return for payments made in the future. Fisher’s pre-Great Depression Model Fisher assumed: “ (A) The market must be cleared—and cleared with respect to every interval of time.” (B) “The debts must be paid.” (Fisher 1930, The Theory of Interest, p. 495) Irving Fisher, pauper We may tentatively assume that, ordinarily and within wide limits, all, or almost all, economic variables tend, in a general way, toward a stable equilibrium... But the exact equilibrium thus sought is seldom reached and never long maintained. New disturbances are, humanly speaking, sure to occur, so that, in actual fact, any variable is almost always above or below the ideal equilibrium... Irving Fisher, pauper It is as absurd to assume that, for any long period of time, the variables in the economic organization, or any part of them, will "stay put," in perfect equilibrium, as to assume that the Atlantic Ocean can ever be without a wave. (Fisher 1933, p. 339) A Disequilibrium Model A disequilibrium‐based analysis was therefore needed, and that is what Fisher provided. He had to identify the key variables whose disequilibrium levels led to a Depression, and here he argued that the two key factors were "over‐indebtedness to start with and deflation following soon after". A Disequilibrium Model • He ruled out other factors—such as mere overconfidence—in a very poignant passage, given what ultimately happened to his own highly leveraged personal financial position: I fancy that over‐confidence seldom does any great harm except when, as, and if, it beguiles its victims into debt. (p. 341) Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory Fisher then argued that a starting position of over‐indebtedness and low inflation in the 1920s led to a chain reaction that caused the Great Depression: "(1) Debt liquidation leads to distress selling and to… Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (2) Contraction of deposit currency, as bank loans are paid off, and to a slowing down of velocity of circulation. This contraction of deposits and of their velocity, precipitated by distress selling, causes… Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (3) A fall in the level of prices, in other words, a swelling of the dollar. Assuming, as above stated, that this fall of prices is not interfered with by reflation or otherwise, there must be… Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (4) A still greater fall in the net worths of business, precipitating bankruptcies and … Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (5) A like fall in profits, which in a "capitalistic," that is, a private‐profit society, leads the concerns which are running at a loss to make … Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (6) A reduction in output, in trade and in employment of labor. These losses, bankruptcies, and unemployment, lead to … Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (7) Pessimism and loss of confidence, which in turn lead to … Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (8) Hoarding and slowing down still more the velocity of circulation. The above eight changes cause … Fisher’s Debt Deflation Theory (9) Complicated disturbances in the rates of interest, in particular, a fall in the nominal, or money, rates and a rise in the real, or commodity, rates of interest." (p. 342) Bernanke’s View Fisher’ s idea was less influential in academic circles, though, because of the counterargument that debt‐deflation represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors). Absent implausibly large differences in marginal spending propensities among the groups, it was suggested, pure redistributions should have no significant macroeconomic effects. ” (Bernanke 2000, Essays on the Great Depression, p. 24) Bernanke Was Wrong If the world were in equilibrium, with debtors carrying the equilibrium level of debt, all markets clearing, and all debts being repaid, this neoclassical conclusion would be true. But in the real world, when debtors have taken on excessive debt, where the market doesn't clear as it falls, and where numerous debtors default, a debt‐deflation isn't merely "a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors)", but a huge shock to aggregate demand. Bernanke Was Wrong Crucially, even though Bernanke notes at the beginning of his book that "the premise of this essay is that declines in aggregate demand were the dominant factor in the onset of the Depression" (p. ix), his equilibrium perspective made it impossible for him to see the obvious cause of the decline: the change from rising debt boosting aggregate demand to falling debt reducing it. Bernanke Was Wrong In equilibrium, aggregate demand equals aggregate supply (GDP), and deflation simply transfers some demand from debtors to creditors (since the real rate of interest is higher when prices are falling). But in disequilibrium, aggregate demand is the sum of GDP plus the change in debt. Rising debt thus augments demand during a boom; but falling debt subtracts from it during a slump. Bernanke Was Wrong In the 1920s, private debt reached unprecedented levels, and this rising debt was a large part of the apparent prosperity of the Roaring Twenties: debt was the fuel that made the Stock Market soar. But when the Stock Market Crash hit, debt reduction took the place of debt expansion, and reduction in debt was the source of the fall in aggregate demand that caused the Great Depression.